Sie sind auf Seite 1von 359

The Effectiveness of Foreign Aid: A Case Study of Nepal

Ph.D Thesis
By
Badri Prasad Bhattarai

Thesis Submitted to UWS in Fulfilment of the


Requirement for the Degree of Doctor of Philosophy

School of Economics and Finance


University of Western Sydney
Sydney, Australia

University of Western Sydney


August 2005
Statement of authentication

The work presented in this thesis is, to the best of my knowledge and belief, original
except as acknowledged in the text. I hereby declare that I have not submitted this
material either in whole or in part, for a degree at this or any other institutions.

………………………………………

Badri Prasad Bhattarai


University of Western Sydney
10 August 2005
Contents

Statement of authentication………………………………………………………. iii


Acknowledgement……………………………………………………………….. iv
List of Tables…………………………………………………………………….. ix
List of Figures……………………………………………………………………. xiii
Abbreviations…………………………………………………………………….. xv
Abstract…………………………………………………………………………... xvii

Chapter 1: Introduction………………………………………………………… 1
1.1 Background…………………………………………………………………… 1
1.2 Statement of the problem……………………………………………………... 8
1.3 The scope of the present research…………………………………………….. 12
1.4 Definition of foreign aid……………………………………………………… 14
1.5 Organisation of the study…………………………………………………….. 15
Appendix 1.1

Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal…… 18


2.1 Introduction…………………………………………………………………… 18
2.2 Political history……………………………………………………………….. 23
2.3 History of economic policy reforms………………………………………….. 26
2.4 Growth and structural change………………………………………………… 29
2.5 Poverty………...……………………………………………………………… 33
2.6 Income distribution…………………………………………………………… 41
2.7 Employment/unemployment………………………………………………….. 42
2.8 Nepal’s poverty reduction strategy…………………………………………… 44
2.9 Policy reforms………………………………………………………………… 47
2.9.1 Foreign trade and liberalisation…………………………………………… 47
2.9.2 Financial sector development and deregulation…………………………... 52
2.9.3 Macroeconomic stability.………………………………………………….. 55
2.10 Corruption and governance reform………………………………………….. 57
2.10.1 Anti-corruption measures in Nepal……………………………………. 59
2.11 Concluding remarks………………………………………………………….. 62
vi

Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective…………………. 65


3.1 Introduction……………………………………………………………………. 65
3.2 Significance of aid…………………………………………………………….. 67
3.3 Sources of aid…………………………………………………………………. 70
3.3.1 Japan’s aid……………………………….………………………………... 74
3.3.2 India’s aid…………………………………………………………………. 75
3.3.3 China’s aid………………………………………………………………… 77
3.3.4 The World Bank, the IMF and the ADB in Nepal………………………… 79
3.4 Sectoral distributional of aid………………………………………………….. 85
3.5 Types of aid…………………………………………………………………… 88
3.5.1 Project and program aid………………………………………………….. 88
3.5.2 Technical cooperation/assistance………………………………………… 88
3.5.3 Humanitarian and emergency aid………………………………………... 90
3.5.4 Food aid………………………………………………………………….. 91
3.6 Rationale and use of aid………………………………………………………. 91
3.6.1 Savings-investment gap…………………………………………………… 92
3.6.2 Foreign exchange gap…………………………………………………….. 93
3.6.3 Government budget deficit……………………………………………….. 94
3.7 Micro issues of foreign aid…………………………………………………… 96
3.7.1 Aid conditionality and country ownership……………………………….. 96
3.7.2 Fungibility of aid…………………………………………………………. 98
3.7.3 Coordination between donors and recipients…………………………….. 99
3.7.4 Tied aid…………………………………………………………………… 100
3.7.5 Absorptive capacity………………………………………………………. 100
3.7.6 Foreign aid policy………………………………………………………… 101
3.8 Foreign debt burden………………………………………………………….. 103
3.9 Concluding remarks………………………………………………………….. 104
Appendix 3.1

Chapter 4: Review of the Literature…………………………………………... 107


4.1 Introduction…………………………………………………………………... 107
4.2 Aid, economic growth, savings and investment……………………………… 109
4.2.1 Summary………………………………………………………………….. 150
4.3 Aid and fiscal behaviour……………………………………………………… 161
vii

4.3.1 Heller type studies of fiscal response…………………………………….. 161


4.3.2 McGuire type studies of aid fungibility…………………………………... 168
4.3.3 Other major studies of fiscal behaviour…………………………………… 174
4.3.4 Summary………………………………………………………………….. 177
4.4 Concluding remarks…………………………………………………………… 182

Chapter 5: Methodology and Data……………………………………………… 184


5.1 Introduction…………………………………………………………………… 184
5.2 Unit root tests…………………………………………………………………. 186
5.3 Test for cointegration…………………………………………………………. 188
5.3.1 The Engle-Granger (1987) approach……………………………………… 189
5.3.2 Johansen’s approach………………………………………………………. 189
5.3.3 Error correction mechanism (ECM)………………………………………. 192
5.4 Granger causality test…………………………………………………………. 193
5.5 Impulse response function…………………………………………………….. 194
5.6 Data sources and their description…………………………………………….. 197
5.6.1 Statistical summary of data and data limitations………………………….. 199
5.7 Computer programs and software…………………………………………….. 203

Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal………………………………… 204


6.1 Introduction…………………………………………………………………… 204
6.2 Model and data……………………………………………………………….. 207
6.2.1 Model specification (aid and growth)……………………………………. 207
6.2.2 Model specification (aid and policy)…………………………………….. 211
6.2.3 Data………………………………………………………………………. 214
6.3 The empirical results and their interpretations………………………………. 216
6.3.1 Unit root tests……………………………………………………………. 216
6.3.2 Cointegration and error correction mechanism………………………….. 220
6.3.3 Effectiveness of different components of aid……………………………. 231
6.4 Aid policies and per capita real GDP………………………………………... 238
6.5 Summary and conclusion……………………………………………………. 248
Appendix 6.1
viii

Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment…………………………….. 252


7.1 Introduction…………………………………………………………………… 252
7.2 Foreign aid and savings-investment-a brief review of the debate……………. 256
7.3 Theoretical considerations and empirical models…………………………….. 258
7.3.1 Empirical model…………………………………………………………... 260
7.3.2 Data and methodology…………………………………………………….. 262
7.4 Unit root tests…………………………………………………………………. 265
7.5 Empirical results and interpretations…………………………………………. 267
7.5.1 Granger causality test results……………………………………………... 271
7.5.2 Generalised impulse response analysis…………………………………… 273
7.6 Summary and conclusion…………………………………………………….. 278

Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour………………… 280


8.1 Introduction…………………………………………………………………… 280
8.2 Fiscal response models……………………………………………………….. 282
8.3 Data and summary statistics of the variables…………………………………. 285
8.4 Unit root test………………………………………………………………….. 286
8.5 Cointegration test results……………………………………………………… 289
8.6 Impulse response function……………………………………………………. 293
8.7 Summary and conclusion…………………………………………………….. 298

Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations…………… 299


9.1 Summary of findings…………………………………………………………. 300
9.1.1 Aid and per capita GDP…………………………………………………... 301
9.1.2 Aid and the savings-investment gap……………………………………… 302
9.1.3 Aid and the fiscal behaviour……………………………………………… 303
9.2 Concluding remarks…………………………………………………………... 304
9.2.1 Nepal with foreign aid……………………………………………………. 305
9.2.2 Foreign aid could be more effective……………………………………… 306
9.3 Policy recommendations……………………………………………………... 310

References
Appendix 6.2
Appendix 6.3
ix

List of Tables

Table 1.1: Average net official development assistance (ODA), 1960-2002…. 4


Table 2.1: GDP growth rates for South Asian countries, 1970-2003………… 19
Table 2.2: Per capita aid and debt services for South Asian countries,
1970-2002 ……………………………………………………………………….. 21
Table 2.3: Structure of selected South Asian economies-sectoral shares in
GDP, 1983-2002………………………………………………………………… 30
Table 2.4: Selected economic indicators of the Nepalese economy, 1966-
2003………………………………………………………………………………. 31
Table 2.5: Structure of Nepalese economy-sectoral shares in GDP, 1975-
2003………………………………………………………………………………. 32
Table 2.6: Trends in the incidence of poverty (head-count ratio), 1977-1996. 35
Table 2.7: Incidence of poverty under different poverty lines
(head-count ratio), estimated in 1989…………………………………………… 36
Table 2.8: Poverty incidence by region, 1996………………………………….. 36
Table 2.9: Poverty among caste/ethnic groups, 1995/96………………………. 37
Table 2.10: Trends of social indicators of Nepal, 1970-2002………………….. 38
Table 2.11: Social indicators for South Asian countries, 1970-2002…………. 39
Table 2.12: Trends of income distribution, 1977-1996………………………… 41
Table 2.13: Level and sources of household income, 1996……………………. 42
Table 2.14: Unemployment rates, 1999………………………………………… 44
Table 2.15: Export, import and total trade as percentage of GDP, 1970-2002. 50
Table 2.16: Average growth rates of fiscal sector indicators, 1966-2002…….. 56
Table 2.17: Control of corruption index for South Asian countries, 1996-2002 58
Table 3.1: Average total aid, bilateral and grants aid, 1960-2002……………. 66
Table 3.1A: Average aid/GDP ratios in South Asian countries, 1970-2002…. 67
Table 3.2: Average bilateral and multilateral aid, 1960-2002………………… 73
Table 3.3: Japan’s share of total bilateral aid, 1960-2002…………………….. 74
Table 3.4: India’s share of total bilateral aid, 1960-1990……………………… 75
Table 3.5: India’s aid for road projects, 1953-1985……………………………. 76
Table 3.6: China’s share of total bilateral aid, 1960-1990……………………... 77
Table 3.7: China’s aid for road projects, 1963-1990…………………………… 78
x

Table 3.8: Active projects financed by the World Bank, 1999-2004………….. 80


Table 3.9: Road and suspension bridges financed by the World Bank, 1970-
2003……..………………………………………………………………………… 80
Table 3.10: Some educational projects financed by the World Bank and
others, 1970-2003………………………………………………………………… 81
Table 3.11: IMF financial arrangements for Nepal, 1985-2003……………….. 84
Table 3.12: ADB sectoral distribution of cumulative lending as at 31 Dec
2003……………………………………………………………………………….. 85
Table 4.1: Summary of aid-growth and aid-savings empirical analyses…….. 151
Table 4.2: Summary of empirical analyses of aid and fiscal behaviour……… 178
Table 5.1 Sources of data……………………………………………………….. 198
Table 5.2: Statistical summary of data, 1970-2002……………………………. 200
Table 5.2A: Statistical summary of data, 1983-2002………………………….. 203
Table 6.1: Average growth rates of real GDP and policy variables for
South Asian countries, 1980-1990, 1991-2002 and 1970-2002……………….. 205
Table 6.2: Correlation coefficients, 1983-2002………………………………… 215
Table 6.3A: ADF test (Lag = 2) with constant and time trend, 1983-2002…... 217
Table 6.3B: ADF test (Lag = 2) with constant only, 1983-2002……………….. 218
Table 6.4A: PP test (Lag = 2) with constant and time trend, 1983-2002…….. 219
Table 6.4B: PP test (Lag = 2) with constant only, 1983-2002…………………. 220
Table 6.5: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (variables
lnRGDPP and lnAR), 1983-2002………………………………………………. 221
Table 6.6: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (variables
lnRGDPP, lnAR and lnKP), 1983-2002………………………………………… 223
Table 6.7A: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.4),
1983-2002………………………………………………………………………… 226
Table 6.7B: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.4
with dummy), 1983-2002……………………………………………………….. 228
Table 6.8A: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (taking bilateral
aid only), 1983-2002……………………………………………………………. 232
Table 6.8B: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (taking
multilateral aid only), 1983-2002………………………………………………. 233
xi

Table 6.9A: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (taking grants


aid only), 1983-2002…………………………………………………………… 236
Table 6.9B: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (taking loan
aid only), 1983-2002…………………………………………………………… 237
Table 6.10A: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.7a),
1983-2002………………………………………………………………………. 239
Table 6.10B: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.7b),
1983-2002………………………………………………………………………. 240
Table 6.10C: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.7c),
1983-2002………………………………………………………………………. 241
Table 6.11A: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.7d),
1983-2002………………………………………………………………………. 243
Table 6.11B: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.7e,
1983-2002………………………………………………………………………. 244
Table 6.12A: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.7d
with dummy), 1983-2002……………………………………………………… 246
Table 6.12B: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 6.7e
with dummy), 1983-2002……………………………………………………… 247
Table 7.1: SR, IR, AR and GAP for South Asian countries, 1970- 2002…… 255
Table 7.2: Correlation matrix in growth, 1970-2002………………………… 263
Table 7.3: ADF test (Lag = 2), 1970-2002…………………………………….. 265
Table 7.4: PP test (Lag = 2), 1970-2002………………………………………. 266
Table 7.5 ADF test for residuals for testing cointegration, 1970-2002……... 267
Table 7.6: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 7.6),
1970-2002………………………………………………………………………. 268
Table 7.7: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 7.8),
1970-2002……………………………………………………………………… 269
Table 7.8: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 7.7),
1970-2002……………………………………………………………………… 270
Table 7.9: Estimate of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio Test (equation 7.4),
1970-2002……………………………………………………………………… 270
Table 7.10: Bivariate Granger causality test results, 1970-2002…………… 272
xii

Table 8.1: Government revenue and expenditure for South Asian


countries, as a percentage of GDP, 1975-2001………………………………... 281
Table 8.2: Correlation matrix of model variables, 1975-2002………………. 286
Table 8.2A: Correlation matrix of variables, 1975-2002……………………. 286
Table 8.3: ADF test with constant only (Lag = 2), 1975-2002……………….. 287
Table 8.3A: ADF test with constant and time trend (Lag = 2), 1975-2002…. 287
Table 8.4: PP test with constant only (Lag = 2), 1975-2002………………….. 288
Table 8.4A: PP test with constant and time trend (Lag = 2), 1975-2002……. 289
Table 8.5: Cointegrating test results (equation 8.1), 1975-2002……………... 290
Table 8.6: Cointegrating test results (equation 8.2), 1975-2002……………... 291
Table 8.7: Cointegrating test results (equation 8.3), 1975-2002……………… 292
xiii

List of Figures

Figure 3.1: Foreign aid to Nepal as percentage of GDP, 1960-2002…………... 68


Figure 3.2: Per capita aid (US$ at current prices), 1960-2002………………… 68
Figure 3.3: Foreign aid as percentage of domestic revenue, 1960-2002………. 69
Figure 3.4: Foreign aid as percentage of government expenditure, 1960-2002. 69
Figure 3.5: Sectoral distribution of aid as percentage of total aid, 1974-83….. 86
Figure 3.5A: Sectoral distribution of aid as percentage of total aid, 1984-00… 87
Figure 3.6: Technical cooperation as percentage of total aid, 1966-2002…….. 89
Figure 3.7: Emergency aid as percentage of total aid, 1995-2002…………….. 90
Figure 3.8: Food aid as percentage of total aid, 1975-2001……………………. 91
Figure 3.9: Aid and savings-investment gap as percentage of GDP, 1970-2002 92
Figure 3.10: Aid and trade balance as percentage of GDP, 1970-2002……….. 93
Figure 3.11: Budget deficit and aid as percentage of GDP, 1960-2002……….. 94
Figure 3.12: Foreign debt as percentage of GDP, 1970-2001………………….. 103
Figure 4.1: A graphical presentation of McGuire model……………………… 169
Figure 5.1: Growth rates of real GDP and foreign aid/GDP ratio, 1970-2002. 202
Figure 7.1: Trends of investment rate (IR) and saving rate (SR), 1970-2002.. 264
Figure 7.2: Trends of aid/GDP ratio (AR) and GAP (=SR-IR), 1970-2002….. 264
Figure 7.3: Generalised impulse response of DlnSR to one S.E. shock in
DlnIR……………………………………………………………………………… 274
Figure 7.4: Generalised impulse response of DlnIR to one S.E. shock in
DlnSR…………………………………………………………………………….. 275
Figure 7.5: Generalised impulse response of DlnAR to one S.E. shock in
DlnIR…………………………………………………………………………….. 275
Figure 7.6: Generalised impulse response of DlnIR to one S.E. shock in
DlnAR……………………………………………………………………………. 276
Figure 7.7: Generalised impulse response of DlnAR to one S.E. shock in
DlnSR……………………………………………………………………………. 276
Figure 7.8: Generalised impulse response of DlnSR to one S.E. shock in
DlnAR……………………………………………………………………………. 277
Figure 7.9: Generalised impulse response of DlnSR and DlnAR to one
S.E. shock in DlnIR……………………………………………………………… 277
xiv

Figure 7.10: Generalised impulse response of DlnSR and DlnIR to one


S.E. shock in DlnAR……………………………………………………………. 278
Figure 8.1A: Generalised impulse response to one S.E. shock in DlnGd……. 294
Figure 8.1B: Generalised impulse response to one S.E. shock in DlnAID…… 295
Figure 8.2A: Generalised impulse response to one S.E. shock in DlnGnd…... 295
Figure 8.3A: Generalised impulse response to one S.E. shock in DlnREV…... 297
Figure 8.3B: Generalised impulse response to one S.E. shock in DlnAID…… 297
Acknowledgements

I would like to express my sincere gratitude to all those who supported me in this
work. First of all, with a deep sense of gratitude, I wish to express my sincere thanks
to both my supervisors, Professor Anis Chowdhury and Dr. Girija Mallik, for their
immense help in planning and executing the work in time.

The confidence and dynamism with which Professor Anis Chowdhury and Dr. Girija
Mallik guided the work should be no surprise to those who know them. Their
company, motivation and assurances during periods of frustration will be remembered
for life. Their profound knowledge of the research topic and methodology and their
timely feedback and constructive guidance made it possible for me to complete this
thesis on time.

The cooperation I received from the administrative staff of the School of Economics
& Finance is gratefully acknowledged. I would also like to thank research chairs
Professor Raja Junankar and Dr. Kevin Daly for their constant encouragement and for
providing me with excellent research support.

I am also grateful to the School of Economics & Finance for giving me the
opportunity to work as a casual tutor. This not only helped me financially, but also
gave me an opportunity to sharpen my knowledge of basic economic theories and
their application.

The Ph.D. Completion Award from the UWS Research Office has been enormously
helpful in my final year of study. This helped me to work full-time on my research
and allowed me to complete the thesis on time.

I would like to share this moment of happiness with my parents, brothers and other
family members. My parents endured tremendous hardship to support me financially.
I remain ever indebted to their kindness.

I express gratitude from deep in my heart to my wife Anu (Janu) for the inspiration
and moral support she provided throughout my Ph.D. Her loving support and
understanding were critical in moments of doubt and frustration.

I would also like to thank all my friends and colleagues who supported me directly
and indirectly. They were very patient in listening to my various arguments, and
provided valuable suggestions.

My final word of thanks goes to Ms. Angela Damis for her excellent copy-editing.

Badri Prasad Bhattarai University of Western Sydney


The Effectiveness of Foreign Aid: A Case Study of Nepal

Abstract

This thesis examines the effectiveness of foreign aid in Nepal, and adds to the
growing literature on the issue of aid effectiveness. Until the mid 1960s, almost all
development projects in Nepal were financed by foreign aid. Since 1970, the average
aid/GDP ratio remains at over 6 per cent, and in 2002 foreign aid financed over 50 per
cent of Nepal’s development expenditure.

Despite the constant flow of foreign aid and decades of aid-financed development
efforts in Nepal, it remains one of the poorest countries in the world, with per capita
income of about US$ 243 and almost 40 per cent of the total population living in
absolute poverty. A casual observer of these facts could easily conclude that foreign
aid to Nepal has not been effective, though they would not be able to say what would
have happened in the absence of aid.

This thesis is the first rigorous study of aid effectiveness in Nepal. It examines the
issue from three complementary perspectives. First, it looks at aid’s contribution to
per capita GDP within the framework of the neoclassical production function. Aid is
assumed to contribute to technological progress via technical assistance and
importation of capital goods. Second, it examines aid’s contribution to Nepal’s gross
domestic investment within a framework of the two-gap model. Since aid is
channelled through the government, the thesis lastly examines the impact of foreign
aid on government expenditure and revenue efforts.

Our study uses time-series data for the period 1970-2002, and employs cointegration
and the error correction mechanism as the estimation procedure. The results show that
aid has a positive and significant relationship between per capita real GDP, savings
and investment in the long-run. Fiscal response analysis indicates that more aid is
spent on non-development expenditure than development expenditure and that aid
does not impact negatively on revenue raising efforts. In addition, we find that aid
effectiveness improves in a good policy environment, that is, one characterised by a
stable macroeconomy, openness to trade and a liberalised financial sector.

The study also finds that bilateral and multilateral aid are equally effective in the
long-run. However, grants aid has a stronger positive association with per capita real
GDP in the long-run than loans aid. Finally, the relationship between aid and per
capita real GDP in the short-run is found to be negative in both aggregate and
disaggregated forms. This implies that Nepal, as in the case of most other developing
countries, suffers from lack of absorptive capacity and high aid volatility.
Abbreviations

ADB/AsDF Asian Development Bank/Asian Development Fund


CBS Central Bureau of Statistics
CIAA Commission for the Investigation of Abuse of Authority
CPI Consumer Price Index
DAC Development Assistance Committee
EC European Council
FDI Foreign Direct Investment
FNCCI Federation of Nepalese Chamber of Commerce and Industry
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GLS Generalised Least Squares
GNP Gross National Product
HMGN His Majesty’s Government of Nepal
IBRD International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (of the
World Bank)
IDA International Development Agency (of the World Bank)
IDS International Development Statistics, (of the OECD)
IFS International Financial Statistics, (of the IMF)
IFAD International Finance for Agricultural Development
IMF International Monetary Fund
INGO International Non-governmental Organisation
MTEF Medium Term Expenditure Framework
NBL Nepal Bank Limited
NIDC Nepal Industrial Development Corporation
NPC Nepal Planning Commission
NRB Nepal Rastra Bank
ODA Official Development Assistance
OECD Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development
OLS Ordinary Least Squares
PRGF Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility
PRSP Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper
PRSC Poverty Reduction Support Credit
RBB Rastriya Banijya Bank
xvi

SAP Structural Adjustment Program


TPC Trade Promotion Centre
2SLS Two Stage Least Squares
3SLS Three Stage Least Squares
UK United Kingdom
UN United Nations
UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
UNDP United Nations Development Program
UNHCR United Nations High Commissioner for Refugee
UNICEF United Nations Children’s Fund
UNFPA United Nations Population Fund
UNTA United Nations Technical Assistance
USA United States of America
USAID United States Agency for International Development
USSR Union of Soviet Socialist Republics
VAT Value Added Tax
VDC Village Development Committee
WFP World Food Program
Chapter 1

Introduction

“…the general aim of aid (loans, grants and technical assistance) is to provide in each
underdeveloped country a positive incentive for maximum national effort to increase its rate of
growth. The increase in income, savings and investment which aid indirectly and directly makes
possible will shorten the time it takes to achieve self-sustaining growth” (Rosenstein-Rodan,
1961: 107).

“Aid is but one resource of many, and its effectiveness depends on many factors, not all of them
economic or aid-related” (Cassen and Associates, 1986: 31).

“…the final answer to the [critical question of aid effectiveness depends on further research on]
pressing macroeconomic and microeconomic questions surrounding foreign aid, such as whether
aid can foment reforms in policies and institutions that in turn foster economic growth, whether
some foreign aid delivery mechanisms work better than others, and what is the political economy
of aid in both the donor and the recipient” (Easterly et al., 2003: 6).

1.1 Background

Foreign aid to developing countries has been an important source of development finance

for more than half a century. 1 However, development practitioners both in donor and

recipient countries remain sceptical about the effectiveness of aid. Between 1960 and

2002, over US$ 1100 billion worth of total foreign aid flowed to the developing

countries. However, only a few countries (mainly in East and South East Asia) could

1
Foreign aid includes grants, concessional loans (with long repayment periods at very low interest rates)
for development projects, and assistance for meeting humanitarian needs and emergencies. The first major,
official foreign economic assistance was the Marshall Plan, designed by the United States to help war-
devastated European countries during the late 1940s. Beginning in 1948 for a four-year period, the United
States provided a total of over US$ 12 billion. Of the total amount more than 90 per cent was in grant form.
Because of this huge amount of aid, per capita aid increased substantially during the period of aid
disbursement in Western Europe. The Marshall Plan significantly contributed to the economic
reconstruction of these countries. By 1950, the level of industrial production was found 25 per cent higher
than in 1938 (Browne, 1990). The World Bank (the International Bank for Reconstruction and
Development) was created to raise and channel long-term development funds, and it became a major source
of foreign aid for most developing countries. Conceived during World War II at Bretton Woods, New
Hampshire, the World Bank initially helped rebuild Europe after the war. Its first loan of US$ 250 million
was to France in 1947 for post-war reconstruction. Reconstruction has remained an important focus of the
World Bank’s work, given the natural disasters, humanitarian emergencies, and post conflict rehabilitation
needs that affect developing and transition economies. However, it has sharpened its focus on poverty
reduction as the overarching goal of all its work.
Chapter 1: Introduction 2

improve their conditions significantly. The weighted average annual GNP per capita

growth rate of low-income countries (excluding India and China) during 1965-89 was

only 1.4 per cent, and that of lower middle income was 2 per cent. The performance of

these countries worsened during the next ten years, despite an increase in aid flows. The

weighted aid/GNP ratio to low income countries (excluding India and China) increased

from 4.1 per cent in 1980 to 12.6 per cent in 1994. Yet the weighted average annual GNP

per capita growth rate in low-income countries (excluding India and China) during 1985-

95 was -1.4 per cent and that of lower middle-income countries was -1.3 per cent. 2

Consequently, poverty in many of these low and lower middle-income countries

increased over the past decades as noted by the former President of the World Bank,

James Wolfensohn, “…if we take a closer look, we see something else –something

alarming. In developing countries, excluding China, at least 100 million more people are

living in poverty today than a decade ago. And the gap between rich and poor yawns

wider”. 3

Numerous studies of aid effectiveness have failed to arrive at a consensus, and the above

quotations show the changing perspectives on aid and its effectiveness. 4 After a brief

period of disillusionment in the late 1960s and the early 1970s about the effectiveness of

aid, there was a renewed hope that countries could be moved out of poverty through the

allocation of aid. This saw a rise in net aid flows to developing countries in real terms

until the early 1990s (White, 2004). However, disillusionment about aid effectiveness

2
Figures quoted here are from World Development Report, 1987 and 1997.
3
Foreword to Thomas et al. (2000), The quality of Growth, OUP for the World Bank.
4
The World Bank has summarised the mood in the following terms:
“The complexity of social and economic change means that the impact of aid cannot be separated easily
from other factors. Developing countries themselves bear most of the burdens of development, and rightly
claim credit when development succeeds … Levels of development assistance are small relative to … the
scale of the challenge at hand. Development aid totalled about $54 billion in 2000; this was … only a small
fraction of total investment (nearly $1.5 trillion)” (World Bank, 2002a, pp. ix, xv).
Chapter 1: Introduction 3

again set-in, in the mid 1990s, with few signs of world poverty disappearing (Hudson,

2004). This has led to a decline in net aid flows both in real terms and as a percentage of

donor countries’ GNP. In nominal terms, aid flows to developing countries peaked at

US$ 62.7 billion in 1992, but fell by US$ 15 billion in the following four years to reach

US$ 47.9 billion in 1997 (White, 2004). Since then it has recovered slightly, especially

following the Asian financial crisis, but the recovery has been erratic. Aid remains a tiny

share of donor GNP, which fell from 0.35 per cent in the 1960s and 1970s to 0.2 per cent

in the 1990s, in contrast to the United Nation’s (UN) target of at least 0.7 per cent (White

and Woestman, 1994). Table 1.1 presents decade averages of aid from main donors since

1960.

Table1.1: Average net official development assistance (ODA), 1960-2002

Average net ODA at


current prices
(US$ million) 1960-69 1970-79 1980-89 1990-00 1960-02
DAC countries 6,088 13,760 34,860 55,137 28,681
Non-DAC bilateral donors - 3,870 4,400 1,481 2,915
Multilateral donors 450 3,721 9,251 15,896 8,155
All donors 5,722 17,038 37,945 56,039 31,122

Notes: (a) DAC = Development Assistance Committee of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation
and Development (OECD).
(b) Multilateral donors = World Bank, Asian Development Bank and other regional development
banks.
Source: OECD, 2004

The economic rationale of foreign aid has evolved in parallel with the evolution of

development theories. During the 1950s, economic growth was regarded as the main

policy objective in developing countries. It was believed that through economic growth,

poverty and social inequalities could be eliminated. 5 Foreign aid was considered a

5
GNP growth as both the objective and yardstick of development was central in the work of early
development economists such as Rosenstein-Rodan’s (1943) “big push” theory, and Rostow’s (1956)
“take-off into sustained growth”.
Chapter 1: Introduction 4

necessary capital resource transfer mechanism that would result in high savings rates and

consequently self-sustained growth for developing countries. In other words, in the

1950s, aid was seen principally as a source of capital that would push economic growth

through higher investment.

During the 1960s, the concept of economic development was still dominated by GNP

growth as the main objective. Insufficient savings at an early stage and foreign exchange

(required to import capital goods) at a later stage of economic development were

identified as the key constraints on economic growth by the two-gap models developed

by Hollis Chenery and his associates. Within the framework of the two-gap models, the

role of foreign aid is supposed to boost investment by reducing the savings gap and/or the

foreign exchange gap. During the 1960s, as sectoral development processes began to be

better understood, the focus was extended to the importance of investment on human

capital and technical assistance (Thorbecke, 2000).

By the 1970s, development economists and practitioners began to realise the

shortcomings of GNP-oriented development strategies. These included concerns about

rising unemployment and inequality and a lack of progress in social developments despite

economic growth in developing countries. Thus, the primary objective of aid shifted

towards raising the standard of living of poor people through increased employment

opportunities. Changing their foreign aid strategy, the World Bank, United States Agency

for International Development (USAID) and other donors focused on anti-poverty

programs. Many investment projects were diverted from traditional sectors such as

power, transportation and telecommunication to projects in agricultural and rural

development and social services, education and health (Brown, 1990). They also placed a
Chapter 1: Introduction 5

greater emphasis on technical assistance. Particularly, in the rural areas, foreign aid was

combined into a package of capital and technical assistance projects constituting

integrated rural development programs.

The foreign debt crisis severely hit the world during the 1980s. The Mexican financial

crisis of 1982 spread to other developing countries; the magnitude of the debt crisis was

huge. These developments changed the strategy of foreign aid. Donors began to

emphasise external (balance of payments) and internal (budget) balance; these became

important objectives and necessary conditions to the restoration of economic growth and

poverty alleviation. More importantly, the World Bank and the IMF used a common

strategy, the Structural Adjustment Program, to tackle the debt crisis.

The new approach shifted aid away from a strategy of aid-financed investment towards a

strategy of aid-induced economic reforms. In other words, access to aid was made

contingent upon the adoption of an appropriate policy framework, through the imposition

of policy conditionality. Thus during the 1980s and 1990s, Stabilisation and Adjustment

Programs became the dominant objectives of aid (Browne, 1990; UNCTAD, 2000).

Under these programs, donors pushed recipient countries for the implementation of

appropriate adjustment policies through conditionality attached to program lending. The

effectiveness of conditional aid became a debatable issue in the 1990s. 6

Although donors have been making great efforts to parallel aid strategies with

development doctrines since the 1950s, the effectiveness of aid is still debatable. A large

number of econometric and descriptive analyses have been conducted to measure the

6
See, for example, Oxfam (1995), Killick (1997), Kanbur (1999), and Mussa and Savastano (1999).
Chapter 1: Introduction 6

effectiveness of aid, mainly based on cross-country time-series and panel data. One of the

most influential recent studies is that of Burnside and Dollar (1997, 2000). They find that

aid can work only in a good policy environment, defined as low inflation and low or zero

budget deficits, and a liberalised economy.

The World Bank’s (1998) Assessing Aid is along the same lines as Burnside and Dollar,

and conveys three principal messages. First, aid works in a good policy environment.

Second, aid cannot buy good policy. 7 Third, aid allocation does not appear to be based on

the policy environments of recipient countries. The focus therefore has been on the role

of a country’s good policy environment for making aid more effective. The cited studies

have influenced many donors to shift the focus of their aid strategies towards the good

policy environment of recipients (see Easterly, 2003). The studies have, however, been a

source of controversy among policy makers and academic researchers.

For example, using the same data set used by Burnside and Dollar (BD), Dalgaard and

Hansen (2001) show that aid spurs growth regardless of the state of a country’s policy

environment. Hansen and Tarp (2000, 2001) also find that aid increases the growth rate

but is not conditional on policy environment. While the formation of a policy index and

its interaction with aid is the main basis of the BD findings, Guillaumont and Chauvet

(2001) reveal that the interaction between aid and the policy index is found to be

insignificant. More recently, Easterly et al. (2003), employing the same methodology as

BD but with an extended data set, find that the link between aid and economic growth

does not necessarily depend on a good policy environment. Further, Easterly (2003) and

many others criticise the BD findings on a number of methodological grounds.

7
The World Bank states “in the past donor agencies have tried to ‘buy reforms’ by offering assistance to
governments that were not otherwise inclined to reform. This approach failed”.
Chapter 1: Introduction 7

While these recent empirical works analyse the effectiveness of aid on growth conditional

on policy variables, they fail to explicitly recognise that aid is given primarily to the

government of a country. Any impact of aid on the economy is mediated by government

behaviour. The issue has been addressed by using fiscal response models. These models

begin with the proposition that the governments have a utility function and their basic

task is to allocate revenue among various expenditure categories, subject to a budget

constraint. 8 In a developing country foreign aid is treated as another form of revenue.

There are two broad approaches to modelling fiscal responses to aid. One follows the

seminal work of Heller (1975) and the other follows McGuire (1978).

In the Heller type models, if the available revenue (aid plus domestic revenue) fails to

meet the target expenditure, then utility is not maximised. These models thus determine

the optimal level of foreign aid for a target level of expenditure given the available

domestic resources. It is assumed that a utility-maximising government tries to minimise

the loss arising out of the non-availability of necessary aid by adjusting domestic

resources or expenditure. On the other hand, if aid flows are guaranteed, the government

may either reduce its revenue (tax and domestic borrowings) efforts or increase its

expenditure targets. Studies such as Heller (1975) and others (for example, Khan and

Hoshino, 1992; Franco-Rodriguez et al., 1998; Franco-Rodriguez, 2000) find that aid

reduces government revenue efforts. By contrast, researchers such as McGillivray (2000)

find that aid has no significant impact on revenue efforts. Likewise, the findings on the

impact of aid on government expenditure are mixed.

8
The utility function of policy makers can vary. It can coincide either with economic growth, and the
overall welfare of society, or with self-enrichment and power. The former regards the government or the
state as benevolent. The latter is found in the work of neoclassical political economists who regard the state
as a Leviathan.
Chapter 1: Introduction 8

The McGuire type models assume that governments want to maximise utility in terms of

the provision of public goods, subject to a budget constraint (aid plus domestic revenue).

The government determines the allocation of aid plus revenue among various categories

of public expenditure, which may or may not be optimal given the conditions with regard

to the use of aid. Thus, these models examine the extent of deviation of aid use from its

intended uses as stipulated in an aid document. That is, these models investigate the issue

of aid fungibility. 9 They also analyse the impact of aid on government revenue. As in the

case of the Heller type models, one cannot derive any conclusive judgement about aid

fungibility and aid’s impact on revenue from the McGuire type studies. For example,

Pack and Pack, (1990 and 1993) find opposing results in the case of Indonesia and

Dominican Republic.

1.2 Statement of the problem

As indicated, aid effectiveness has been a major issue among policy makers and

researchers. After the success of the Marshall Plan, more attention was paid to the

development of developing countries. While a number of developing countries became

independent within a decade from aid dependency, others’ economic condition remained

almost the same, with slow economic growth, and in some cases, the situation turned bad

to worse. For example, in 1966 Ethiopia, India and Thailand were all considered poor

countries. By 2000, India’s per capita real income more than doubled, from US$ 187 in

1966 to US$ 462 in 2000, and its poverty rate fell from 64 per cent in 1977 to 34 per cent

in 2000 (based on income of less than US$ 1 per day). During the same period,

Thailand’s per capita income increased from US$ 609 to US$ 2720, and poverty fell from

9
Aid is said to be fungible if the recipient uses aid for purposes other than those intended by the donors.
Chapter 1: Introduction 9

over 25 per cent to 2 per cent of the population. However, in Ethiopia there was almost

no growth in per capita GDP – it hovered around US$ 115-US$ 120. 10 Another two

contrasting cases are Republic of Korea (South) and Pakistan. Both had similar economic

conditions in the late 1950s and received aid amounting to about US$ 7-9 per capita

during the early 1960s. Today South Korea is a member of the OECD and Pakistan’s real

per capita GDP stands at only US$ 546 (in 2003) as opposed to Korea’s real per capita

GDP of US$ 12,332. (See appendix 1.1 for socio-economic indicators and aid flows in

selected aid-dependent countries).

In the case of Nepal, despite the constant flow of foreign aid, and decades of aid-financed

development efforts, it remains one of the poorest countries in the world and the poorest

in the South Asia, with per capita income of about US$ 243. Until the mid 1960s, almost

all development projects in Nepal were financed by foreign aid. Aid as a percentage of

GDP is still over 6 per cent, and aid still finances over 50 per cent of Nepal’s

development expenditure. Yet slow economic growth persists and almost 40 per cent of

the population lives in absolute poverty. Serious doubts about the effectiveness of aid in

Nepal have therefore arisen. A casual observer of these facts could easily draw the

conclusion that aid to Nepal has not been effective; however, they would not be able to

say what would have happened in the absence of aid. Furthermore, aid is only one factor;

there are many other factors that contribute to economic growth.

Only few attempts have been made to date to address the issue of aid effectiveness in

Nepal. For example, Mihaly (1965) and Stiller and Yadav (1979) were early studies that

10
WB/WDI online database. Data are based on constant 2000 prices. See also World Bank (1998). Note the
comparison does not identify the exact factor (whether it was aid or something else such as trade) that may
have contributed to higher per capita income growth and the reduction of poverty in India and Thailand. In
India and Thailand aid/GNP ratios were minimal during the period (on average less than one per cent).
Chapter 1: Introduction 10

addressed the issue of foreign aid in Nepal. Based on descriptive analyses, the authors

argued that policy makers had a poor understanding of the role of aid in the Nepalese

economy. They identified lack of absorptive capacity as a main problem for the effective

utilisation of aid. However, in a regression analysis using data from 1964/65 to 1981/82,

Poudyal (1988) found positive effects of aid on the level of GDP. After almost four

decades later, Mihaly (2002) maintains that aid has not been effective in Nepal due

mainly to the lack of administrative capacity and strong political will. 11

Dhakal et al. (1996) performed bivariate Granger causality tests using eight sample

countries – four each from Asia (India, Nepal Pakistan and Thailand) and Africa

(Botswana, Kenya, Malawi and Tanzania). For Nepal they used data from 1960 to 1990.

They did not find any causal relationship between foreign aid and economic growth in

Nepal. However, this study suffers from two problems. First, the authors have taken

grants only as foreign aid data and excluded concessional loans. Second, they did not

elaborate the causes of aid ineffectiveness. Instead as in other developing countries, they

simply believed that political corruption and aid diversion to importing consumption

rather than capital goods attributed to aid’s failure to impact economic growth.

In line with the earlier studies, Singh (1996) in a descriptive analysis found that foreign

aid failed to boost economic growth in Nepal. Singh pointed out that poor people did not

benefit from aid; instead the main beneficiaries of aid were high-ranking officials, ruling

politicians, contractors, and consultants. Thus, aid mainly benefited the rich, which

created inequality across the country.

11
This is the second edition of his 1965 work, Foreign Aid and Politics in Nepal.
Chapter 1: Introduction 11

Khadka (1996) examined the relationships between aid and some key macroeconomic

variables, such as savings, investment and economic growth in Nepal, for the period

1960-90. He found a positive correlation between GDP and per capita aid, which he

believed counter-intuitive given the current state of the economy. Thus, Khadka, based

on his descriptive analysis, concluded that foreign aid failed to improve levels of income,

savings and investment. However, in another study, using a simple regression analysis for

the period 1960-90, Khadka (1997) found that aid had a positive impact on the growth of

GDP. In this study, he used only bilateral disbursements for aid data and excluded

multilateral disbursements. Furthermore, he did not include any policy variables in the

model except exports and imports. Thus, the study does not provide a clear picture of aid

effectiveness in Nepal.

It is apparent that, although these studies have made some efforts in examining the issue

of aid effectiveness in Nepal, they have failed to reach a general consensus. More

importantly, they have not employed time-series econometric techniques that have been

developed recently to enhance the robustness of findings by excluding the possibility of a

spurious relationship. These studies also could not consider the long- run and short-run

dynamics of aid–growth relationship. Furthermore, they have failed to recognise

explicitly that the aid effectiveness issue should also be examined from the perspective of

fiscal behaviour as aid is ultimately channelled through the government.


Chapter 1: Introduction 12

1.3 The scope of the present research

This research is the first-known attempt to empirically investigate the issue of aid

effectiveness in Nepal by using the latest time-series econometric techniques, such as

cointegration and the error correction mechanism. The issue will be examined both at the

aggregate and disaggregated levels of aid for their impact on economic growth. In order

to enhance the understanding of the processes through which aid affects growth, the

research will also investigate the relationships between (a) aid and savings; (b) aid and

investment; and (c) aid and fiscal behaviour. It will also investigate the role of policies.

Hypotheses to be tested

Against the background of the literature survey, the following hypotheses will be tested:

(a) Aid affects growth positively through technical progress.

(b) Aid effectiveness is enhanced in a good policy environment.

(c) Aid has a positive relationship with investment.

(d) Aid leads to an increase in government domestic revenue and both development

and non-development expenditure.

There are a number of factors which can influence the relationship between aid and

economic growth. These factors include: (a) political motives of donors (see Mosley et al.,

1991 for general issues and case studies; Mihaly, 2002 and Khadka, 1997 for Nepal), (b)

corruption (see Knack, 2001 for general issues and Panday, 2001 for Nepal), (c)

misallocation of aid due to domestic politics (see Boone, 1996 and Collier and Anke, 2004

for general issues and Dhakal et al., 1996 for Nepal), (d) lack of coordination and absorptive

capacity (see Killick, 1991 for general issues and Stiller and Yadav, 1979 for Nepal), (e)

weak institutions etc (see Cassen and Associates, 1986 and 1994 for general issues and
Chapter 1: Introduction 13

Panday, 2001 for Nepal). This thesis does not intend to examine these factors that may

affect aid effectiveness. In line with many other studies, it examines aid effectiveness by

looking at aid’s impact on the most important macroeconomic variable, GDP per capita

growth. If the result is positive overall then one can assume that the micro factors were by

and large favourable. Given the data limitations, this is the best one can do econometrically.

However, we have examined three important macroeconomic factors, which may have

implications for the aid-growth relationship. They are policy environment (hypothesis (b)

above), aid’s effect on investment (hypothesis (c) above), and fiscal behaviour (hypothesis

(d) above).

Models, methodology and data

Models

The study uses a modified neoclassical production function for the analysis of the aid–

growth relationship. It is assumed that aid contributes to growth through technological

progress via technical assistance and capital imports. The analysis is augmented by

incorporating policy variables.

In the spirit of the two-gap model, the effectiveness of aid is investigated by examining the

relationships between aid and investment, and between aid and savings. We assume that

investment is influenced by both domestic savings and foreign aid.

Finally, following Heller (1975) and McGuire (1978), fiscal response models are used to

examine fiscal behaviour of governments. In particular, we investigate how aid affects

development and non-development expenditure and domestic revenue raising efforts.


Chapter 1: Introduction 14

Methodology

Since the effect of aid on economic growth and other variables in any one-year depends on

the past years aid (lagged values), it is crucial that we examine the long-run relationships

between aid and other variables of interest. Therefore, this study will use cointegration

technique, which allows us to test for the presence of a non-spurious long-run equilibrium

relationship between the variables under study. The cointegration test also involves error

correction mechanism (ECM). The ECM is considered a dynamic process in that it involves

lags of the dependent and independent variables. While it captures short-run adjustments to

changes, the long-run relationship is established in the level form. Prior to conducting the

cointegration test, we perform two unit root tests (the Augmented Dickey–Fuller and the

Phillips–Perron tests) to ensure that all variables under consideration are of the same order

of integration, in particular I(1). In addition, Granger causality test (in the case of

relationships not cointegrated) is performed.

Data

We use annual time-series data for the period 1970-2002. Data have been obtained from the

IMF, International Financial Statistics (IMF/IFS) and the OECD, International

Development Statistics (OECD/IDS) online databases. For the fiscal response models, data

have been obtained from the Statistical Year Book of Nepal (1983, 1991, 1995 and 2003).

1.4 Definition of foreign aid

According to the OECD (2004), foreign aid is defined as an official development

assistance (ODA) given to the developing countries for the promotion of economic

development and welfare including humanitarian and emergencies aid. There are two

components of foreign aid: grants and loans. Grants component of aid are free resources
Chapter 1: Introduction 15

for which no repayment is required. A loan with at least 25 per cent of grant component

is considered as foreign aid. Grants components are measured in terms of interest rate,

maturity and grace period (interval to first repayment of capital) of a loan. It measures the

concessionality of a loan in the form of the present value of an interest rate below the

market rate over the life of a loan. Conventionally, market rate is taken as 10 per cent as

DAC (Development Assistance Committee) statistics. In other words, a loan carrying an

interest rate of 10 per cent has zero grant component. Thus, if the face value of a loan is

multiplied by its grant component, the amount is considered as grant equivalent of that

loan. However, grants and loans given for military purpose are excluded from aid. This

study is also based on these definitions of aid.

1.5 Organisation of the study

This thesis is composed of nine chapters. The present chapter contains the background of

the study, statement of the problem and objectives of the study. Chapter 2 provides a

comprehensive account of Nepal’s socio-economic development. Chapter 3 discusses the

trends in and patterns of foreign aid to Nepal. Chapter 4 presents the literature review.

Chapter 5 discusses data, models and methodology in detail. The main empirical findings

are analysed in chapters 6, 7 and 8: chapter 6 contains the analysis of aid–growth

relationship within a neoclassical production framework; chapter 7 analyses the

relationship between aid and investment; and chapter 8 examines fiscal response to aid.

The study’s summary of findings, conclusions and policy recommendations are presented

in chapter 9.
Chapter 1: Introduction 16

Appendix 1.1: Socio-economic indicators for selected aid-dependent countries,


(1970-2003)
Country/Years 1970s 1980s 1990s 2003
Guinea-Bissau (Per capita GDP US$ 135)
Aid/GNI (%) 18.65 50.24 52.07 63.65
Per capita aid (current US$) 29.3 85.74 102.94 97.50
GDP growth 3.2 2.91 1.98 0.60
Per capita GDP growth 0.1 0.23 -0.87 -2.26
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 37 - 44 45
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - - - -
Rwanda (Per capita GDP US$ 259)
Aid/GNI (%) 13.16 10.88 28.82 19.95
Per capita aid (current US$) 16.79 32.25 63.63 39.95
GDP growth 5.60 2.71 2.43 3.19
Per capita GDP growth 2.22 -0.31 -0.32 0.33
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 46 (1982) 40 (1990) 39 (2000) -
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - 36 (1984) 52 (2000) -
Nicaragua (Per capita GDP US$ 766)
Aid/GNI (%) 3.83 10.79 29.45 20.06
Per capita aid (current US$) 21.46 51.34 135.46 152.04
GDP growth 1.01 -0.71 3.11 2.31
Per capita GDP growth -2.16 -3.40 0.29 -0.27
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 57(1977) - 64 (1990) 68
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - 47 (1993) 44 (1998) -
Zambia (Per capita GDP US$ 354)
Aid/GNI (%) 3.94 13.99 26.46 13.37
Per capita aid (current US$) 20.63 51.62 93.35 53.84
GDP growth 1.75 1.26 0.66 5.10
Per capita GDP growth -1.36 -1.80 -1.77 3.45
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 49 (1978) - 49 (1990) -
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - - 65 (1991) 64 (1998)
Uganda (Per capita GDP US$ 276)
Aid/GNI (%) 2.38 7.45 15.79 15.56
Per capita aid (current US$) 3.39 16.86 35.15 37.95
GDP growth - 3.44 6.73 4.72
Per capita GDP growth - 0.18 3.55 1.90
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 48 (1973) - 46 (1990) 43
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - 88 (1989) 85 (1999) -
Chad (Per capita GDP US$ 218)
Aid/GNI (%) 7.87 12.77 15.20 10.57
Per capita aid (current US$) 15.52 27.42 36.19 28.77
GDP growth -1.03 5.38 1.96 11.30
Per capita GDP growth -2.98 2.66 -1.00 8.17
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 40 - 48 48
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - - - -
Ethiopia (Per capita GDP US$ 102)
Aid/GNI (%) - 8.27 12.90 22.80
Per capita aid (current US$) - 12.15 15.74 21.92
GDP growth - 2.37 3.19 -3.69
Per capita GDP growth - -0.73 0.82 -5.64
Chapter 1: Introduction 17

Life expectancy at birth (total years) - 45 (1990) - 42


Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - 45.5 (1996) 44 (1998) -
Senegal (Per capita GDP US$ 485)
Aid/GNI (%) 7.57 14.00 12.38 7.00
Per capita aid (current US$) 27.61 73.51 71.00 43.00
GDP growth 2.44 2.62 3.45 6.45
Per capita GDP growth -0.44 -0.20 0.75 4.03
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 44(1977) - 49 (1990) 52
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - - 45 (1991) -
Madagascar (Per capita GDP US$ 233)
Aid/GNI (%) 3.55 8.86 13.21 10.11
Per capita aid (current US$) 8.95 24.91 31.81 31.93
GDP growth 1.5 0.36 1.61 9.79
Per capita GDP growth -1.04 -2.29 -1.24 6.82
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 46 - 53 56
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) 49 (1980) 46 (1993) 61 (2001) -
Lesotho (Per capita GDP US$ 530)
Aid/GNI (%) 11.87 14.31 8.51 5.72
Per capita aid (current US$) 29.57 74.41 61.68 44.00
GDP growth 9.70 4.77 3.74 3.28
Per capita GDP growth 7.37 2.60 2.63 2.35
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 51 (1978) - 57 (1990) 37
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - 30 (1986) 36 (1995) -
Bolivia (Per capita GDP US$ 1,017)
Aid/GNI (%) 3.64 7.48 10.03 12.29
Per capita aid (current US$) 15.02 42.84 85.19 105.48
GDP growth 4.03 -0.44 3.99 2.45
Per capita GDP growth 1.55 -2.60 1.69 0.49
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 50 - 62 64
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - 20 (1986) 20 (1997) -
Kenya (Per capita GDP US$ 341)
Aid/GNI (%) 4.29 7.85 9.43 3.39
Per capita aid (current US$) 10.27 27.44 27.72 15.15
GDP growth 7.15 4.22 2.14 1.80
Per capita GDP growth 3.36 0.63 -0.50 -0.02
Life expectancy at birth (total years) 53 - 47 45
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - 34 (1992) 23 (1997) -
Ghana (Per capita GDP US$ 275)
Aid/GNI (%) 2.93 6.65 10.12 12.15
Per capita aid (current US$) 9.05 23.86 36.46 43.86
GDP growth 1.35 2.11 4.21 5.20
Per capita GDP growth -1.10 -1.09 1.67 3.31
Life expectancy at birth (total years) - 55 (1987) 60 (1997) -
Poverty headcount ratio, US$ 1 per day (PPP) (%) - 46 (1987) 44(1998) -

Notes: (a) All data are calculated at 10 years average except for 2003
(b) Data for life expectancy and poverty are based on a particular year such as 1977, 1979, 1986,
1988 and 1997 for each decade, if not indicated.
(c) Poverty head count ratio at national poverty line is much higher in some countries.
(d) Per capita GDP is reported for 2003 at constant prices 2000 for all countries.
Source: WB/WDI online database
Chapter 2

An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal

“Nepal remains one of the poorest countries in the world - per capita income is about $250,
around half the children under five are malnourished and progress towards Millennium
Development Goal targets remains slow. Growth in the 1990s has been respectable, averaging
5 per cent but its impact on poverty has been dampened by high population growth, by being
concentrated in the Kathmandu valley and the escalation of the conflict [with the Maoist
insurgents] over the past two years” (World Bank, 2003b: 3).

2.1 Introduction

Nepal’s per capita income of US$ 243 makes it the 12th poorest country in the world

and the poorest in South Asia. In purchasing power parity terms Nepal is the 30th

poorest country in the world. 1 According to the Census of 2001, Nepal’s total

population has reached 23.4 million, and the annual population growth rate is 2.4 per

cent. Agriculture is the main source of income: it provides a livelihood for over 80 per

cent of the population and accounts for 40 per cent of GDP (World Bank, 2003a).

Nepal is a landlocked South Asian country, lying between the two giants – India and

China. To the south, west and east is India; the north borders with China. The port

nearest to Kathmandu, the capital city of Nepal, is Calcutta (600 miles) in India.

Almost two-thirds of the total area of Nepal (147,181 square kilometres) is hills and

mountains. The highest peak in the world, Mount Everest, and other world-famous

peaks are situated in the Himalayan range on Nepal’s northern border.

Administratively, Nepal is divided into 5 Development Regions, 14 Zones, 75

Districts, 3,995 Village Development Committees (VDCs) and 36 Municipalities.

1
See further World Bank’s “Economic Update 2002”.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 19

Table 2.1: GDP growth rates for South Asian countries, 1970-2003

Year/Average growth rates 1970-75 1975-80 1980-85 1985-90 1990-95 1995-00 2003
Nepal
GDP growth rate 1.96 2.22 3.77 4.79 5.13 4.57 2.98
Per capita GDP growth rate -0.05 0.14 1.57 2.45 2.66 2.09 0.74
Per capita GDP* 144 150 157 177 202 228 243
Bangladesh
GDP growth rate 0.46 3.33 3.34 3.65 4.65 5.16 5.32
Per capita GDP growth rate -2.08 0.82 0.75 1.07 2.71 3.34 3.5
Per capita GDP* 236 239 254 269 295 342 410
India
GDP growth rate 3.3 4.21 5.58 6.14 5.32 6.09 8.00
Per capita GDP growth rate 0.97 1.87 3.33 3.95 3.36 4.27 6.43
Per capita GDP* 210 224 247 292 343 423 525
Pakistan
GDP growth rate 4.57 5.88 7.35 6.09 4.61 3.54 5.81
Per capita GDP growth rate 1.33 2.68 4.43 3.35 2.02 1.07 3.29
Per capita GDP* 271 292 353 419 476 506 537
Sri Lanka
GDP growth rate 3.62 5.41 5.09 3.7 5.56 5.11 5.49
Per capita GDP growth rate 1.67 3.75 3.84 2.68 4.33 3.77 4.26
Per capita GDP* 357 412 499 576 680 824 937

Note: * US$ at 1995 prices


Source: WB/WDI online database

Nepal’s per capita GDP growth has never been very encouraging. It increased

slightly, to over two per cent, in the 1980s and 1990s, perhaps due to economic and

trade liberalisation taking place in the late 1980s. Nepal’s average per capita GDP

growth rate in the last 30 years (1970-2000) has remained at around two per cent, and

thus its per capita GDP of US$ 243 is the lowest among the South Asian countries

(see Table 2.1). Despite a civil war of about 20 years’ duration, Sri Lanka has the

highest per capita income in South Asia with relatively consistent GDP growth rates,

followed by India.

Nepal is an aid-dependent country. Aid is used to finance over 50 per cent of

government development expenditures, and the aid/GDP ratio is currently about six
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 20

per cent. Among its bilateral donors, Japan has been providing the highest amount of

aid, followed by Germany, United Kingdom, Denmark and United States (particularly

since the 1980s). A substantial amount of aid is also given by India and China.

Multilateral institutions such as the Asian Development Bank (ADB), International

Development Agency (IDA), United Nations Development Program (UNDP), World

Food Program (WFP), United Nations Children Fund (UNICEF), United Nations

Technical Assistance (UNTA), United Nations High Commission for Refugees

(UNHCR) and other UN agencies are involved in promoting various sectors of the

economy.

Table 2.2 presents a comparative picture of aid dependence of Nepal and four South

Asian countries. Nepal’s dependency on foreign aid increased substantially until the

mid 1990s. Aid contributed to almost 70 per cent of its total government expenditure

(development and non-development) in the mid 1990s, compared to 34 per cent in the

mid 1970s. During the same period, per capita aid also increased from US$ 2.5 to

US$ 22. The total debt service as a percentage of Gross National Income (GNI)

increased from 0.08 per cent in the mid 1970s to almost 2 per cent in the 1990s.

Although Nepal’s external debt service is relatively low compared to other South

Asian countries, aid to Nepal as a percentage of total government expenditure is still

the highest in South Asia.


Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 21

Table 2.2: Per capita aid and debt services for South Asian countries, 1970-2002

Year/Country 1970-75 1975-80 1980-85 1985-90 1990-95 1995-00 2002


Nepal
Aid % of total govt. expenditure 33.81 43.51 50.81 67.83 69.34 50.46 37.59
Per capita aid (current US$) 2.52 6.55 12.72 21.46 22.15 18.23 15.14
Total debt service % of GNI 0.08 0.35 0.67 1.38 1.9 1.9 1.78
Bangladesh
Aid % of total govt. expenditure - 98.63 77.9 69.47 - - -
Per capita aid (current US$) - 11.87 13.01 15.79 14.87 9.41 6.72
Total debt service % of GNI 0.29 1.18 1.27 1.98 1.87 1.62 1.45
India
Aid % of total govt. expenditure - 9.56 6.76 3.87 4.18 2.62 2.05
Per capita aid (current US$) 1.72 2.21 2.51 2.15 2.26 1.69 1.39
Total debt service % of GNI 0.93 0.96 1.15 2.15 3.2 2.94 2.59
Pakistan
Aid % of total govt. expenditure 29.8 28.43 17.06 13.44 10.55 5.98 15.18
Per capita aid (current US$) 6.39 10.37 9.76 10.52 10.09 6.15 14.79
Total debt service % of GNI 2.63 3.13 3.89 5.00 5.07 5.08 4.75
Sri Lanka
Aid % of total govt. expenditure 10.24 21.94 25.98 27.15 24.59 10.00 7.59
Per capita aid (current US$) 5.80 17.98 28.5 36.45 40.71 21.96 18.01
Total debt service % of GNI 3.14 4.60 4.94 6.19 4.24 4.01 4.38

Source: WB/WDI online database

Nepal pursued an import substitution policy for a long time, through the active

participation of the public sector. Since the early 1960s, emphasis was placed on

protecting the economy from external competition. Under this policy, Nepal

established many public enterprises and protected domestic industries by imposing

high tariffs and quotas for imported goods. As in other developing countries, these

policies were a source of huge inefficiency and corruption. The public enterprises

failed to deliver efficient services and were running with huge losses, causing a

financial burden for the economy. Consequently, these policies led to lower economic

growth and macroeconomic instability.

Historically, India’s economic policies have significantly influenced the Nepalese

economy, mainly because of the free and open border between the two countries.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 22

Even until the 1960s, 90 per cent of Nepal’s trade was limited to India, a result also of

its lack of physical infrastructure and its landlocked position. India’s economic and

trade liberalisation in the early 1990s has directly influenced Nepal to pursue almost

identical policies.

With the advent of democracy in 1991, Nepal’s government has initiated economic

reform programs to promote a modern market-oriented economy. These reforms have

included a program of privatising public enterprises and the elimination of public

monopolies in domestic air transport and hydro-power generation. Nepal has also

eliminated price controls for most products, reduced consumer subsidies and

established a convertible currency for all current account transactions. Value-added

tax has been introduced to replace the existing sales tax, for the purposes of

broadening the tax base and making the taxation system more realistic and

transparent.

Despite these reform efforts, Nepal’s underdeveloped infrastructure, unskilled human

resources, physical constraints and poor institutional capacity have all served to limit

the country’s growth. Nepal’s problems have been compounded by continued political

instability, with more than nine governments in power in the last 13 years (since

1991), and the Maoist insurgency escalating violence across the nation.

This chapter will provide a comprehensive account of socio-economic development in

Nepal. It will begin with a brief discussion of Nepal’s political history, followed by a

brief historical account of its policy regimes, as both political developments and

policy regimes have possible direct implications for economic and social
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 23

development. Detailed discussion of recent policy reforms that may have had an

impact on aid effectiveness will be provided later in the chapter.

2.2 Political history

Until 1951, Nepal had been ruled by an oligarchy known as the “Rana Regime” 2 for

more than a century, leaving the country in a primitive economic condition and

isolated from rest of the world. While Nepal had never in its history been a British

colony, it was completely ruined by the Rana family. When India became independent

from colonial British rule in 1947, Nepal was greatly influenced by the achievement

of the independence movement. The Rana Regime was overthrown in 1951, and

Nepal opened the door to the rest of the world.

Since that time, Nepal made efforts to establish a multi-party political system.

Unfortunately in 1961, the 15-month old elected government was overthrown, and all

political parties were banned by the monarch of the time, King Mahendra. A party-

less political system known as the “Panchayat System” was considered more suitable

in the national interest, and was accordingly adopted.

The Panchayat system continued until the restoration of a multi-party political system

under a constitutional monarchy in 1990. The late King Birendra promulgated a new

constitution that established the multi-party system in November 1990. In the first

multi-party parliamentary election, the Nepali Congress secured the majority of seats

2
The Ranas headed the government (holding the prime ministerial position) and exercised more power
than the King. In other words, the King was a lame head of state; political and administrative control
remained in the hands of the Ranas.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 24

and formed the government. With the fall of the Nepali Congress majority

government in 1994, pulled down by a faction of its own party in parliament, a period

of intense fractious politics began.

In the latest election, held in May 1999, the Nepali Congress Party won an absolute

majority in parliament and the Communist Party of Nepal–United Marxist Leninist

(CPN–UML) emerged as the main opposition party. The Nepali Congress Party

formed a majority government and K.P Bhattarai became the Prime Minister. Once

again, due to a power struggle within the Nepali Congress, K.P. Bhattarai was

replaced by G.P. Koirala in March 2000. This government lasted for just over a year;

Sher Bahadur Deuba became the next Prime Minister.

The political turmoil continued, and the royal massacre on 1 June 2001 marked a

black day in the history of Nepal. Crown Prince Dipendra shot dead 10 members of

the royal family including his parents, King Birendra and Queen Aishwarya, and his

siblings, Prince Nirajan and Princess Shruti, before killing himself. The present King

Gyanendra, the younger brother of the late King Birendra, is the head of state and

Supreme Commander of the armed forces.

Nepali politics suddenly took a new turn in May 2002 when Prime Minister Deuba

recommended to the King the dissolution of the House of Representatives, to be

followed by a fresh election on 13 November 2002. As per the Prime Minister’s

recommendation, the King dissolved the parliament. On the eve of the election, Prime

Minister Deuba suggested to the King that the election be postponed for 14 months,

on security grounds. However, this time King Gyanendra sacked Deuba on the
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 25

grounds of incompetence in holding the parliamentary elections, and temporarily took

over all executive powers. At the same time, King Gyanendra made it clear that the

government should be headed by and composed of individuals of “clean image” (that

is, not involved in corruption charges), and who would not run for the office in the

forthcoming election.

Since then, the King’s appointed Prime Minister and his cabinet have governed the

country. The first appointed Prime Minister was Lokendra Bahadur Chand. He

resigned after being in office for less than a year, and the King appointed Surya

Bahadur Thapa as the new Prime Minister. However, Surya Bahadur Thapa also

resigned after heavy pressure from his own as well as the opposition parties; he was

blamed for having failed to maintain law and order in the country. The King surprised

political observers by asking the previously sacked Prime Minster Sher Bahadur

Deuba to form a coalition government. However, on 1 February 2005 the King sacked

the coalition government for the second time, and declared a state of emergency. He

blamed again the Deuba Government’s failure to tackle the Maoist insurgency. The

King assumed power and formed a new 10-member cabinet under his direct

leadership. This has plunged the country into political turmoil.

The Maoists have been escalating violence across the country since 1996 in an

insurgency that has claimed more than 8,000 lives. 3 Considerable damage has been

done to Nepal’s infrastructure. Over one-third of the country’s 3,900 Village

Development Committee buildings have been damaged or destroyed; 13 of 75

districts are without telephones; 5 hydroelectric plants are non-operational; 250 post

3
This is an estimate by the World Bank. Some other sources have put forward much higher figures.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 26

offices have been destroyed, and 6 airports have been closed. Due to the security

situation, local and national elections have been postponed, which has in turn created

more political uncertainty (World Bank, 2003b).

When a state emergency was imposed in November 2001, it lasted nine months but

failed to stop the violence of the insurgency – the killing of innocent people and the

destruction of infrastructure. A ceasefire was announced in January 2003, offering an

opportunity for dialogue between the government and rebels. It failed, however, to

produce any conclusive solutions. In February 2005, the newly formed government

under the King’s leadership proposed unconditional dialogue with the Maoists. The

rebels rejected the proposal and so far there are no signs of any progress. 4

2.3 History of economic policy reforms

During the oligarchic regime of the Ranas the country remained closed and isolated

from the rest of the world. The first opening of the economy happened with the treaty

of 1923 with the then British India, which made Nepal pursue a free-trade policy.

Some believe that imported goods from British India had a severe negative impact on

Nepal’s cottage industries (Dahal, 1987). Only limited policies aimed at economic

development were pursued. These included the establishment of the Nepal Industrial

Board, the introduction of the Nepal Company Act and the establishment of a few

match factories, cotton mills, jute mills and rice mills.

4
Nepal’s political landscape remains very uncertain. The regime has come under heavy international
pressure to honour human rights and to democratise.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 27

Nepal initiated planned economic development with the launching of the first

Development Plan in 1956. The plan mainly focused on the establishment of basic

industries, with the aim of creating employment opportunities. In line with the

dominant development philosophy of the time, in 1961 significant steps were taken

towards adopting import substitution policies. For example, legislation was

introduced to protect domestic infant industries from external competition. By the late

1960s, trade barriers and licensing systems had been adopted to protect the domestic

market (Sharma, 1999).

Until the late 1980s, Nepal continued to pursue a closed economy “dirigistic” policy

that involved the creation of public enterprises. Still, new policies were gradually

introduced. In 1982 a new industrial policy designed to increase the share of private

sector in the development of the industrial sector was introduced. At the same time,

the government adopted a policy of privatisation of public enterprises, but it was not

fully implemented.

Similarly, in 1982 the Foreign Investment and Technology Act was enacted. The

Commercial Bank Act was amended in 1984 in order to remove entry and exit

barriers. Under the financial sector reforms, the banking sector was opened to foreign

investors. As a result, in 1984 the Nepal Arab Bank Limited was established as the

first joint venture commercial bank. The commercial banks also began to accept

current and fixed deposits on foreign currencies (US dollar and Pound Sterling). In

1986, the deregulation of interest rates was initiated; this allowed commercial banks

to fix both deposit and lending rates at any level above the Central Bank’s minimum
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 28

prescribed level (Shrestha, 2004). In 1985, the Nepalese Rupee was devalued against

all foreign currencies.

Although the creation of public enterprises had almost ceased by the early 1980s, due

to widespread losses and poor performance they had already become a financial

burden to the government. The government’s involvement in public enterprises over

three decades and the over-expansion of development budgets with low revenue

mobilisation together led to budget deficits, which in turn resulted in high inflation

and unsustainable balance of payments deficits (Khatiwada et al., 2002).

Consequently, the economy faced macroeconomic instability. Thus arose the need for

restoring macroeconomic stability, structural adjustments and economic liberalisation.

An economic stabilisation program designed by the IMF was first pursued in 1985,

with subsequent graduation to a Structural Adjustment Program (SAP) in 1987.

Following the restoration of multi-party democracy in the early 1990s, a far-reaching

program of economic reforms and liberalisation has been adopted. More importantly,

these reforms measures have involved almost all sectors of the economy including

fiscal and monetary policy, trade policy, and financial policy reform.

Since the introduction of the 1987 SAP, Nepal’s macroeconomic and adjustment

policies in the 1990s were strongly influenced by the policy of conditionality applied

by aid donors. The fundamental objectives of conditionality were to reduce fiscal

deficits and to lower domestic deficit financing to less than one per cent of GDP.

These objectives were achieved through raising taxes, reducing subsidies and
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 29

transfers, minimising budgetary support to state-owned public enterprises, and

enhancing the aid absorptive capacity of the economy (see Sonali, 2003).

These programs also intended to restructure government expenditure so as to increase

the share of social sector spending in total expenditure. The full convertibility of the

Nepalese Rupee was implemented with an aim to have market driven exchange rates.

The government also initiated trade policy reforms through the elimination of import

quotas, and the restructure and reduction of tariff bands and average tariff rates.

Initiatives were also made to reform the agricultural sector.

2.4 Growth and structural change

Nepal’s economic growth has never been very encouraging as it has been severely

constrained by slow growth in the agricultural sector. Agriculture dominates the

Nepalese economy; in fact, it remains the main source of income and employment.

Although agriculture’s share in GDP is declining, it still accounts for about 40 per

cent of GDP. Low economic growth and widespread poverty have formed the general

outlook of the country, mainly due to the low productivity of the agricultural sector.

In addition, Nepal’s industrial base is very fragile. The country seriously lacks basic

infrastructure and its domestic market is limited. Its public service is inefficient and

plagued with weak institutions. In short, Nepal is plagued with growth-inhibiting

factors.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 30

Table 2.3: Structure of selected South Asian economies – sectoral shares in GDP,
(%) 1983-2002
Country 1983 1993 2002
Nepal
Agriculture 60.3 42.2 40.7
Industry 12.8 20.7 21.7
Manufacturing 4.6 8.8 8.3
Service 26.9 37.1 37.5
Bangladesh
Agriculture 30.7 26.3 22.7
Industry 21.9 23.8 26.4
Manufacturing 14.7 14.9 15.9
Service 47.4 49.9 50.9
India
Agriculture 36.6 31.0 22.7
Industry 25.8 26.3 26.6
Manufacturing 16.3 16.1 15.6
Service 37.6 42.8 50.7
Pakistan
Agriculture 30.3 25.0 23.2
Industry 22.1 24.7 23.3
Manufacturing 15.3 16.7 16.1
Service 47.7 50.3 53.5
Sri Lanka
Agriculture 28.3 24.6 20.5
Industry 26.3 25.6 26.3
Manufacturing 14.0 15.2 15.8
Service 45.4 49.7 53.2

Note: manufacturing is a part of industry


Source: WB/WDI online database

Table 2.3 shows the structure of selected South Asian economies from 1983 to 2002.

It shows that that even until 1983, the agricultural sector contributed over 60 per cent

to GDP in Nepal, thereby providing a major source of income. The sector’s share in

GDP decreased to 40.7 per cent in 2002, which is still the highest among the South

Asian countries. Trade and economic liberalisation significantly contributed to the

growth of non-agriculture sector, particularly in the mid 1980s. The share of the

manufacturing sector almost doubled from 4.6 per cent in 1983 to 8.8 per cent in

1993.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 31

Until the late 1960s, Nepal’s statistical system did not have good national account

records. By the early 1970s, only some limited data were available. Thus, an objective

assessment of Nepal’s early growth rate is not possible. As can be seen from Table

2.4, the Nepalese economy grew by around 4 per cent per annum since the mid 1960s.

The growth rate was ordinary (around 2.5 per cent) until 1980, and then picked up

following the introduction of various reform programs in the 1980s. Throughout the

1990s, the average growth rate was maintained at 5 per cent. With the recent political

uncertainty and violence, economic growth has lately begun to falter.

Table 2.4: Selected economic indicators of the Nepalese economy, 1966-2003

Average 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1999 1966 2000
growth rate -70 -75 -80 -85 -90 -95 -00 -00 -03
Real GDP 2.7 1.8 2.4 4.9 4.8 5.1 5.0 5.0 2.7
Agriculture 2.9 1.7 -1.0 5.1 4.1 1.5 3.4 3.4 2.3
Non- 2.6 2.2 9.0 4.7 5.5 8.1 6.0 6.0 0.4
agriculture
Inflation 5.1 10.5 5.2 9.7 11.6 11.3 7.9 7.9 3.3
Food 4.8 11.3 4.8 9.4 12.5 11.5 8.3 8.3 -
Non-food 2.6 8.7 6.7 10.4 10.0 10.9 7.3 7.3 -

Source: Economic Survey (various issues), Ministry of Finance

An important aspect of Nepal’s growth is that the share of non-agricultural sectors in

GDP has been substantially increasing in the last twenty years. The GDP shares of the

manufacturing and industry, construction, trade, restaurant and hotels, finance and

real state sectors have all increased rapidly since the 1980s (Table 2.5).
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 32

Table 2.5: Structure of Nepalese economy, sectoral shares in GDP (%), 1975-03

Sector/Fiscal Year 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2003


1. Agriculture, fisheries and 71.6 61.8 51.2 50.6 40.8 39.5 39.3
forestry
2. Non-agriculture 28.4 38.2 48.8 49.4 59.2 60.5 60.7
Mining and quarrying 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
Manufacturing and industry 4.2 4.3 5.7 6.0 9.3 9.2 8.1
Electricity, gas and water 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 1.4 1.6 1.8
Construction 3.7 7.2 8.5 9.0 11.0 10.2 10.4
Trade, restaurant and hotel 3.4 4.1 10.3 10.5 11.6 11.7 10.0
Transport, communications 4.3 7.0 6.0 5.7 6.7 8.0 8.6
and storage
Finance and real estate 6.9 8.4 9.0 9.3 9.8 10.1 10.8
Community and social services 5.7 6.8 8.6 7.9 9.0 9.2 10.1
Total (1 + 2) 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Note: There are minor differences in the figures in Tables 2.3 and 2.5 as for comparative purposes
they are taken from different sources.
Source: Economic Survey (various issues), Ministry of Finance

Historically, Nepal had a moderate level of inflation, with an average rate of inflation

of about 8 per cent during 1966-2000 (see Table 2.4). The inflation rate remained low

at 5 per cent in the 1960s, but increased to over 10 per cent in the 1970s mainly due to

the international oil crisis of the period. However, while the inflation rate came down

to about 5 per cent by the early 1980s, it rose over 10 per cent in the late 1980s until

the mid 1990s, largely due to the devaluation of the Nepalese currency. As mentioned

earlier, the rise in government budget deficit also contributed to the rise in inflation

during this period. Budget deficit as a percentage of GDP increased from less than 2

per cent in the 1970s to almost 6 per cent in the 1980s (including grants). By 2001-02

the inflation rate had fallen to around 3 per cent as budget deficit declined to below 4

per cent of GDP (including grants).

In sum, although substantial progress was made in the 1990s, Nepal still remains one

of the poorest countries in the world. Economic liberalisation in the early 1990s

apparently spurred notable growth, averaging five per cent per annum in the decade.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 33

However, growth in the past three years has been disappointing, due largely to the

Maoist insurgency and the effects of the global economic slowdown. Still widespread

poverty has persisted as the impact of growth has been dampened by high population

growth.

2.5 Poverty

Poverty is deep-rooted and widespread in Nepal. The Hindu caste system, which

categorises people primarily as either touchable or untouchable, still prevails,

determining the division of labour and work. To a large extent, the untouchable

groups of society are found to be poor, and have been exploited by touchable groups.

Despite the introduction of a number of measures against the caste system, it remains

alive in rural areas because of lack of education, the strong belief in fate held by

untouchables, and strong resistance to change from the upper castes. Poverty is, in

fact, strongly associated with castes and ethnicity.

The World Bank reported (2003a) that almost 42 per cent of the population lives in

absolute poverty and that 70 per cent have incomes of less than US$ 1.5 per day. The

most striking aspect is that there is a high regional variation in the incidence of

poverty in Nepal. Poverty is more acute and pervasive in rural areas, particularly in

the mountain regions.

No proper assessment of the poverty situation in Nepal was done until the late 1970s.

The National Planning Commission (NPC) conducted the first survey of poverty in

1977. The NPC report used a nutritional poverty line based on the income needed to

supply a minimum calorie requirement of 2,256 kilojoules per person per day. Daily

consumption of 605 grams of cereals (rice, maize, millet or wheat) and 60 grams of
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 34

pulses (lentil, black gram etc) was taken to meet this requirement. The expenditure

required to obtain that minimum level of consumption was estimated to be two

Rupees (Rs.) per person per day. The proportion of households and population living

below the poverty line was found to be higher in the far-west Development Region.

Moreover, while 17 per cent of people were found to be living below the poverty line

in urban areas, the poverty rate was more than double, 37.2 per cent, in rural areas.

The survey found that the national poverty rate was about 36 per cent.

Two more surveys were later conducted, by the Nepal Rastra Bank (NRB). These

included the 1984-85 Multi-Purpose Household Budget Survey (MPHBS), and the

1991-92 Nepal Rural Credit Survey. The MPHBS provided for different minimum per

capita daily calorie requirements to examine the incidence of poverty in the mountain

and Tarai (Plain) regions. It was fixed at 2,340 kilojoules for the hills and mountain

regions, and 2,140 kilojoules for the Tarai. The minimum per capita daily calorie

requirement was fixed at 2,250 kilojoules for the national average.

The World Bank (WB) in collaboration with the United Nations Development

Program (UNDP) carried out a survey of poverty in Nepal in 1989. This survey used a

poverty line based on the 1988-89 prices. That is, income was fixed at Rs. 210 per

person per month in the hills and Rs. 197 in the Tarai (Plain). In addition, in 1995-96,

the Nepal Living Standards Survey (NLSS) was conducted by the Central Bureau of

Statistics (CBS). This survey defined the poverty line based on a daily per capita

calorie requirement of 2,124 kilojoules. Expenditure was estimated to be Rs. 2,637

per annum; adding non-food requirements, the total minimum requirement was

estimated to be Rs. 4,404 per annum (CBS, 1996 and 1997; see also NPC, 1998). A

summary of the findings of these surveys is provided in Table 2.6.


Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 35

Table 2.6: Trends in the incidence of poverty (head-count ratio), 1977-1996

Source Year Population below poverty line (%)


Urban Rural Nepal
NPC (2256 kj) 1977 17.0 37.2 36.2
MPHBS/ NRB (2250 kj) 1985 19.2 43.1 42.5
WB/UNDP (Income) 1989 15.0 42.0 40.0
NLSS/CBS (2124 kj) 1996 18.0 47.0 42.0

Source: NESAC, 1998

As can be seen from Table 2.6, all the surveys reveal that the poverty rate in rural

areas has been more than double the rate in urban areas. Most disturbingly, the

poverty rate in Nepal increased from 36 per cent to 42 per cent in the space of two

decades, even when a lower poverty line was used in the NLSS/CBS. This is despite

the fact that the economy grew at an average rate of 5 per cent per annum in the

1990s. This indicates that most of the increase in income has accrued to the richer or

upper castes of the society, and hence income distribution has worsened (see Table

2.12) – an issue to be discussed later.

The poverty situation in Nepal appears alarming when poverty is defined using other

measures. For example, Lipton (1983) defines poor as those who spend 70 per cent or

more on food. The World Bank used US$ 150 per capita per annum to define absolute

poor (see World Bank, 1991). In 1989, the World Bank estimated the poverty rate in

Nepal using three different poverty lines: 2,256 kilojoules (based on NPC poverty

line), US$ 150 (World Bank) and Lipton’s. The estimates of poverty according to

these measures are given in Table 2.7. As can be seen, both the Lipton and World

Bank measures give a much higher poverty rate for Nepal.


Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 36

Table 2.7: Incidence of poverty under different poverty lines (head-count ratio),
estimated in 1989
Poverty Region (% in population)
Hills Tarai (Plains) Nepal
line Rural Urban Total Rural Urban Total Rural Urban Total
2,256 55 13 52 29 17 28 42 15 40
kilojoules
US$150 78 32 75 69 51 68 74 42 71
Lipton 65 52 64 70 50 68 68 51 66

Source: World Bank, 1991

Table 2.8 shows the incidence of poverty by region based on the Nepal Living

Standards Survey (NLSS) of 1995-96. The report reveals that the mountain regions

have the highest poverty rate (56 per cent). It also shows that the rural poverty rate is

about double the rate in urban areas. As mentioned earlier, the NLSS of 1995-96

defined the poverty line as based on a daily per capita calorie requirement of 2,124

kilojoules. Adding some essential non-food items, the incidence of poverty was

estimated at 42 per cent. A more recent estimate puts it at 38 per cent (NPC, 2001). 5

Table 2.8: Poverty incidence by region, 1996

Region Population below poverty line (%)


Poor Ultra-poor Total
Mountain 29.3 26.7 56.0
Hills 21.3 19.7 41.0
Tarai (Plains) 28.7 13.3 42.0
Nepal 24.9 17.1 42.0
Urban 13.2 9.8 23.0
Rural 26.4 17.6 44.0

Source: NPC, 1998

According to the 1995-96 NLSS, poverty in Nepal varies according to the various

caste/ethnic groups (see Table 2.9). The incidence of poverty is much higher among

the lower caste groups, particularly the Dalits who are untouchables (Damai, Kami

5
The NPC conducted this survey for the mid-term evaluation of the Ninth Plan (1997-2002).
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 37

and Sarki). While among the Dalits 65-68 per cent live below the poverty line, the

poverty rates among the Brahmins and Newars (two upper castes) are only 34 and 25

per cent respectively. Likewise, the poverty rate varies among the minority ethnic

groups. For example, the poverty rate is 38 per cent for the Muslims compared to 71

per cent for the Limbus and 45 per cent for the Gurungs.

Table 2.9: Poverty among caste/ethnic groups, 1995-96

Caste/Ethnicity Poverty (%) Caste/Ethnicity Poverty (%)


Newar 25 Magar 58
Brahmin 34 Tamang 59
Muslim 38 Sarki 65
Gurung 45 Damai 67
Tharu 48 Kami 68
Chhetri 50 Limbu 71
Rai 56 Others 40

Source: CBS, 1997

Income poverty is not the only kind of poverty, as increase in income alone does not

necessarily represent an improvement in human development. The UNDP’s Human

Poverty Index (HPI) seeks to measure the degree of deprivation using various social

indicators such as illiteracy, malnutrition among children, life expectancy at birth,

poor health care and poor access to safe water. According to the UNDP’s Human

Development Report 2004, Nepal’s HPI value is 41.2, which ranks Nepal at 69. There

is a wide regional disparity in HPI. For example, the HPI value in rural areas is 42.0

as opposed to 25.2 in urban areas. The corresponding measure of achievements in

human capabilities, the Human Development Index (HDI) in Nepal is 0.504, which is

lower than that of India (0.595), Bhutan (0.536) and Bangladesh (0.509). Nepal’s HDI

rank is 140. Achievements in human development in Nepal also vary significantly

across regions. The HDI in the mountain regions is the lowest (0.386) followed by the
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 38

Tarai (0.478) and the hills (0.512). The central, eastern and western regions of the

country have higher HDI (0.490, 0.493 and 0.491, respectively) than the far and mid-

western regions (0.404 and 0.402, respectively).

Table 2.10: Trends of social indicators of Nepal, 1970-2002

Indicators 1970-75 1980-85 1993-98 2000 2002


Average annual population 2.4 2.6 2.2 2.3 2.3
growth rate
Life expectancy (years) 43 49 58 58.9 59.9

Infant mortality rate (per 160 125 77 72 62


1,000 live births)
Under 5 mortality rate (per 234 180 107 95 83
1,000 children)
Adult literacy rate 16 22 33 41.8 44
Net primary school - 60 78 - -
enrolment rate
Access to safe water (per 8 24 59 - 84
cent of population)

Note: – indicates unavailability of data


Source: World Bank, 2003

Table 2.10 shows the trends of social indicators of Nepal. For example, life

expectancy increased from 43 years in the early 1970s to 59.9 years in 2002, the adult

literacy rate increased nearly threefold during the same period and the infant mortality

rate decreased, from 160 in 1970 to 62 in 2002 (see also Table 2.11). There was also a

notable increase in the access to safe water, from 8 per cent in 1970s to 84 per cent in

2002. The only discouraging figure is found for annual population growth rate, which

remained almost the same throughout the three decades.


Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 39

Table 2.11: Social indicators for South Asian countries, 1970-2002

Less than US $1 Less than US $2


Life Adult per day, per day, Under five
Year expectancy literacy % of total people % of total people mortality rate
Country at birth rate (PPP) (PPP) (per 1000)
Nepal
1970 42.36 16.36 - - 234
1980 47.95 22.4 - - 183
1990 53.57 30.44 41.81 87.47 143
2002* 59.85 44.01 39.13 80.94 83
Bangladesh
1970 44 24.5 - - -
1980 48.5 28.9 26.16 84.02 239
1990 54.7 34.2 35.8 86.4 205
2002* 62.1 41.01 36.03 82.82 73
India
1970 49.37 33.09 - - 202
1980 54.17 41.03 60.24 93.39 173
1990 59.12 49.33 48.14 91.17 123
2002* 63.38 61.3 34.7 79.9 90
Pakistan
1970 49.43 20.9 - - 177
1980 55.11 27.81 - - 156
1990 59.09 35.37 33.9 80.56 138
2002 63.81 41.45 13.36 65.56 101
Sri Lanka
1970 64.64 80.45 - - 100
1980 67.63 83.01 - - 46
1990 70.23 87.09 3.82 40.56 26
2002 73.79 92.08 - - 19

Notes: (a) * indicates that poverty data are for 2000, and some data may be one or two years back or
forward for a comparison purpose. (b) – indicates unavailability of data
Source: WB/WDI online database

Although Nepal’s social indicators have showed marked progress since 1970, it still

lags far behind than other South Asian countries. For example, while the adult literacy

rate increased substantially from 16 per cent in 1970 to almost 44 per cent in 2002,

during the same period Sri Lanka’s adult literacy rate increased to over 90 per cent

(from 64 per cent in 1970) followed by India 61 per cent (from 33 per cent in 1970).
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 40

Similarly, Nepal’s life expectancy increased to almost 60 years in 2002 from 42 years

in 1970; but it is still the lowest in South Asia.

Why is Nepal behind other South Asian countries in social development despite the

fact that it received the highest aid flows in relation to its GDP? 6 One may find the

answer in the political economy of aid allocation. As argued by Svensson (2000) and

Murshed and Sen (1995) recipient governments represent a variety of stake holders,

including wealthy individuals who might influence aid allocation. Boone (1996)

claimed that recipient governments divert aid to benefit the wealthy elite. These

arguments are relevant for Nepal, which has an entrenched class structure along ethnic

lines and caste system. As illustrated previously, poverty rate is the highest among the

low caste and certain ethnic groups who live mostly in the rural and mountain areas

(see Tables 2.8 and 2.9). It seems that aid did not favour the disadvantaged people in

the society.

The upper cast groups always take advantage of the poor governance and use their

local political power to capture aid financed projects. This generated more inequality

along ethnic and caste lines, and Nepal has the highest inequality in South Asia. Its

Gini-coefficient is found to be 0.57 (Table 2.12) compared to around 0.33 in

Bangladesh and Pakistan. Poverty among the low caste people and disadvantaged

rural areas has been fuelling ethnic conflicts in the country led by the Maoist

insurgents (see Murshed and Gates, 2005).

6
Aid/GDP ratio in Nepal during 1970-2002 was over 8 per cent (see Table 3.1A and Table 7.1 for
detail)
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 41

2.6 Income distribution

Income distribution in Nepal is largely influenced by land ownership patterns.

Agriculture is the main source of income and the majority of people live in the rural

areas where land is the key asset. Ineffective governance has failed to eliminate the

feudal system, which has a substantial role in creating income inequality in rural areas.

The Agriculture Census of 1981 revealed that 50 per cent of households, each having

less than 0.5 hectares, owned only 7 per cent of land. On the other hand, the top 10

per cent of households, with 3 hectares and above, owned nearly 48 per cent of the

total cultivated land. Similarly, the Agriculture Census of 1991 showed that around 43

per cent of households having less than 0.5 hectares owned only 11 per cent of

cultivated land, whereas the top 10 per cent of households having 3 hectares and more

owned around 42 per cent of the total cultivated land (Sharma, 2003).

Table 2.12: Trends of income distribution (1977, 1985 and 1996)

Household income share of Gini coefficient


Year First 40% Next 50% Top 10% Rural Urban Nepal
1977 12.6 28.2 59.2 0.60 0.50 -
1985 23.0 54.0 23.0 0.55 0.85 0.57
1996 11.0 37.1 52.0 0.51 0.55 0.57

Source: CBS, 1996

Table 2.12 shows trends of income distribution in Nepal. In 1977, around 90 per cent

of households shared less than 41 per cent of income while the top 10 per cent shared

almost 59 per cent of household income. The share of the top 10 per cent declined
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 42

slightly to 52 per cent in 1996. However, the Gini coefficient of 0.57 indicates that

nationally, income distribution is highly skewed in favour of the rich part of society. 7

There are also widespread regional disparities; the average income varies with

geography as well as location in rural or urban areas (Table 2.13). In the mountains,

the average household income is the lowest. The average household income in urban

areas is more than double the average household income in rural areas.

Table 2.13: Level and sources of household income, 1996

Income per Income by sources (%)


Region annum Farm Non-farm Others
(000 Rs.)
Mountains 32.3 62.0 18.0 20.0
Hills 45.0 58.0 24.0 18.0
Tarai (Plains) 44.5 64.0 22.0 14.0
Nepal 43.7 61.0 22.0 16.0
Rural 40.4 65.0 20.0 15.0
Urban 86.8 16.0 54.0 31.0

Source: CBS, 1997

2.7 Employment/unemployment

Employment opportunity is very limited in Nepal. Underemployment and disguised

unemployment are high and have been major problems. 8 In 1977, a study conducted

by the Nepal Planning Commission indicates that the unemployment rate was 5.6 per

cent in rural and almost 6 per cent in urban areas. Underemployment was estimated to

be about 63 per cent in rural and about 45 per cent in urban areas.

7
The UNDP (2004) and the World Development Report (2000/2001) used consumption based data and
reported a Gini coefficient of 0.37 in 1995-96.
8
Underemployment is generally defined as those who work less then 40 hours a week.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 43

Similarly, in 1981 a study conducted by the Asian Regional Team for Employment

Production revealed that unemployment and underemployment rates ranged from 21

to 28 per cent in the Tarai (Plains) and from 37 to 47 per cent in the hills respectively.

Underemployment in the country was reported to range from 25 to 40 per cent in

1987, while the unemployment rate stood at 5 per cent (Library of Congress, 1991).

According to the Census of 1991, the economically active population was found to be

56.6 per cent. Of the 10-14 and 15-59 year age groups, 22.9 and 67.9 per cent

respectively were found to be economically active (CBS, 1991).

The Central Bureau of Statistics (CBS) carried out the Nepal Labour Force Survey in

1998-99. According to this survey, the economically active population in the age

group 15 and above was 85.8 per cent. The survey further showed that out of a labour

force of 11.2 million (aged 15 years and above), 9.6 million people were found to be

active in the labour market. Since 178,000 were found to be unemployed, the total

number of employed workers was estimated at 9.46 million. The survey also reported

that out of 4.9 million children (in the age group of 5-14 years), 2.6 million were

involved in the labour market (CBS, 1999) showing a very high incidence of child

labour.

Out of 9.46 million in employment, 7.2 million were engaged in agricultural

employment, which shows the dominance of agriculture. Until 2001, 66 per cent of

the economically active population was involved in agriculture (CBS, 2001). The

second category of employment is elementary occupation, which includes

manufacturing, construction, transport, porters, domestic workers and street vendors,

along with firewood collection and water fetching. The CBS survey (1999) reported
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 44

that 1.5 million were paid employees in various sectors, and 4.1 million were unpaid

family workers, while 3.8 million were self-employed.

Table 2.14: Unemployment rates in’000 and %, 1999

Areas Urban Rural Nepal


Total 77 (7.9%) 101 (1.2%) 178 (1.8%)
Male 35 (5.9%) 63 (1.5%) 98 (2%)
Female 42 (9.4%) 37 (0.9%) 80 (1.7%)

Source: CBS, 1999

One of the evident weaknesses of these survey reports is that there is no consistent

definition of work (that is, employment), and hence the actual picture of

unemployment and employment could be misleading. For example, some activities

such as fetching water and collecting firewood (for cooking) are counted as an

economically productive activity. In Nepal these kinds of activities are not related to

employment; instead they reflect the minimum survival conditions of people. Thus,

the figures in Table 2.14 are to some extent misleading and do not provide the real

picture of the unemployment situation of the country.

2.8 Nepal’s poverty reduction strategy

As noted earlier, despite remarkable economic growth in the 1990s and significant

progress in social indicators such as infant and child mortality, literacy, and life

expectancy, Nepal remains one of the poorest countries in the world. Widespread

poverty persists and large inequalities prevail across ethnic groups. To cope with the

problem, the Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP) was prepared as part of the
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 45

Tenth Plan (2002-03 to 2006-07). 9 Nepal identified four key pillars for the PRSP in

the Tenth Plan: (1) generating economic growth; (2) improving service delivery; (3)

promoting social inclusion; (4) improving governance (NPC, 2003). At the same time,

the Medium Term Expenditure Framework (MTEF) was prepared to help implement

the Tenth Plan effectively, by prioritising expenditure and managing public resources

more efficiently. 10

The preparation of the MTEF was an important effort by the government to reorganise

the public expenditure program in order to achieve poverty reduction as targeted in

the Tenth Plan, within a realistic medium-term budget structure. Thus, the MTEF

indicates a strong country ownership with the formulation of its own strategy and

national priorities. 11 In other words, it was a national response to those donors

concerned about Nepal’s lack of appropriate policies for the management of

development priorities and aid resources.

Donor responses to the PRSP were positive, particularly those of the World Bank and

other multilateral donors. In October 2003, to support the implementation of the

PRSP, the World Bank (via IDA) provided US$ 70 million credit to Nepal, to be

followed by further instalments. The IMF also expressed appreciation for Nepal’s

9
The PRSP must be approved by the joint board of the World Bank and the IMF for a country to be
eligible for soft loans from these institutions.
10
The PRSP/Tenth Plan was prepared in mid 2001 (NPC, 2003). The Tenth Plan itself was considered
as a comprehensive Poverty Reduction Strategy, while the MTEF, established in November 2001, was
intended as a “complementary” tool in the implementation of the Tenth Plan. The Tenth Plan was a
departure from previous development plans, which had little involvement of stakeholders other than the
government. This led the NPC to note: “A major deficiency of Nepal’s planning and budgeting process
has been the over-optimism of five-year plans and annual budgets in relation to both resource
availability and implementation capacity…Lack of effective prioritisation of programs and
expenditures related to planned goals and objectives have also led to wide gaps in plans and actual
achievements. The MTEF aims at correcting these persisting problems…” (NPC, 2003: 2).
11
See NPC (2003, 2004) for a review and detailed discussion of the first, second and third MTEFs.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 46

formulation of the PRSP and recognised the government’s intention to strengthen the

participatory approach for the implementation and monitoring stages of the PRSP. It

agreed to help Nepal achieve the goals of the PRSP under the Poverty Reduction and

Growth Facility Program, approving US$ 72 million in November 2003.

However, these key donors stressed the need for further reforms to reduce the

pervasive poverty in Nepal. The World Bank’s first Poverty Reduction Strategy

Credit was based on a number of conditions, such as dropping 160 projects to

reduce/and prioritise development budgets, increasing the price of petroleum product

to cover losses, and prosecuting high-profile corruption cases (World Bank, 2003b).

Further, the IMF placed conditions on the use of its fund. For example, the

government was to meet revenue targets and resist spending pressures. It had to apply

tough measures such as cuts in exemptions, improvements in tax and custom

administration, and an increase in the value-added tax rate. The IMF noted that much

still remains to be done in the financial sector, and in the area of privatisation and

restructuring of public enterprises (IMF, 2003a).

Although it is too early to evaluate the effectiveness of the PRSP, the review of the

first and second MTEFs shows encouraging results in terms of restructuring and

managing the government budget. The government, for instance, claims that the

macroeconomic objectives of the Tenth Plan have been more realistic than previous

plans. The Tenth Plan/PRSP represents a broad strategy for poverty reduction with

many aspects, focusing, as it does, on areas such as growth (particularly in rural

areas), social inclusion, improved governance, and better delivery of social and

economic services.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 47

2.9 Policy reforms

This section provides a detailed discussion of policy reform measures in Nepal. In

particular, it looks at reforms in three areas: trade, the financial sector and

macroeconomic stability. Policies operating in these areas are claimed to have direct

impacts on aid effectiveness.

2.9.1 Foreign trade and liberalisation

In the past Nepal’s trade base was very narrow and limited to trade with India and

Tibet. Nepal pursued a restrictive trade policy until the mid 1980s, for the purposes of

promoting import substitution industrialisation and the growth of infant industries.

While restrictive trade policies failed to promote industrialisation in the country, the

international trading system began to move towards more liberalised trade regimes.

Thus, Nepal began trade liberalisation as part of the Structural Adjustment Program in

1987 with the financial support of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the

World Bank.

Nepal’s trade policy has always been influenced by two important factors. First,

Nepal is a landlocked country, located 600 miles away from the nearest port (Calcutta

in India). Second, Nepal is surrounded by India on three sides of its border, which is

largely open or unguarded. The high cost of transit to ports for access to the rest of the

world, and India’s control over the terms of transit as well as the open border, place

Nepal in a situation of de facto free trade with India. Therefore, any attempt to

establish trading relationships with the rest of the world through standard trade policy
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 48

instruments are likely to be constrained by the unofficial movements of goods and

services across the open border with India (Karmacharya, 2000).

Since the early 1990s, with the advent of democracy, the trade regime has been

opened and it is being liberalised in the context of multilateral trading system. More

importantly, India has initiated reforms to liberalise its trade and economic policies

during the same period. Thus, it has been more convenient for Nepal to follow almost

identical trade and economic policies as India. Furthermore, with the review of

various treaties, trade with India has become more transparent. India has allowed

transit facilities to ports in Bangladesh so that Nepal does not have to depend on the

Calcutta port alone. 12

Many measures have been adopted for the promotion of trade and its further

liberalisation. For example, the role of the public sector in trade has been gradually

reduced, with more emphasis placed on the private sector. More attention has been

paid to promote and diversify trade both in the range of commodities and in market

directions. Import licensing was eliminated. The tariff rates and slabs have been

gradually reduced. The highest tariff rate was reduced from more than 400 per cent in

1980s to 40 per cent in 1990s.The number of tariff slabs has also been reduced from

12
The trade policy, introduced in 1992 and amended in the late 1990s, helped liberalise trade by
reducing tariff rates and slabs, and abolishing licensing of imports. Nepal and India signed a trade
treaty in December 1996, which facilitated Nepal’s preferential market access to India. Nepal can
export to India, free of custom duty and quantitative restrictions, all manufactured products, except
three (cigarettes/tobacco, perfumes/cosmetics with foreign brand names, and alcoholic
liquor/beverages). Since 1997, Nepal has benefited from the opening of the Phulbari–Banglabandh road
transit access. The latest agreement, the Treaty of Transit of 1999, has also been an important milestone
for Nepal. Many efforts have been made to identify potential markets for Nepal’s goods and services.
Existing treaties agreements with various countries have been effectively reviewed implemented and
reviewed. See Trade Promotion Centre (1999) for details of Nepal’s trade and transit agreements with
India.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 49

more than 100 to 5. The prevailing basic tariff rates are 5, 10, 15, 25 and 40 per cent

(IMF, 2001).

Following India, Nepal introduced partial current account convertibility of its

currency in 1992 and full current account convertibility in 1993. The exchange rate

against convertible currencies was unified with the abolition of a dual exchange rate

system and it became market determined. Subsequently, the market exchange rate

became the basis for all current transactions. On the other hand, the exchange rate of

the Nepalese Rupee against Indian currency still continues to be officially determined.

This exchange rate regime has led to a real depreciation of the Nepalese Rupee

against the US$ and a real appreciation against Indian Rupee (Deraniyagala, 2003).

For export promotion, a number of export strategies were introduced in the 1990s.

Exporters were allowed to retain up to 100 per cent of their export earnings as their

convertible currency accounts in the domestic banks. Export duty drawback schemes

aimed to provide a refund paid on taxes of imported goods were introduced, as was

the bonded warehouse system, which facilitated tax refunds on imported raw

materials for specific exports such as garments. Export licences were abolished

(Deraniyagala, 2003).

A bilateral trade treaty was signed with India in 1996. The treaty eliminated most non-

tariff barriers to trade with India, including the value-added tax requirements, which

required at least 50 per cent content in Nepalese or Indian raw materials for duty free

access to the Indian market. In other words, the treaty allowed Nepalese manufactured

goods to be exported to India free of any duty or quota. As a consequence, Nepal’s


Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 50

exports to India increased by an average rate of more than 41 per cent per annum

during 1996-99 (Kaphley, 2000).

During the mid 1990s, trade with the autonomous region of Tibet in China was

formalised through a bilateral agreement on trade procedure and the mode of

payments. More importantly, a bilateral settlement agreement was signed allowing

use of the Chinese currency by Chinese tourists in Nepal. The accumulated Chinese

currency can be used for the payment of imports from China.

Table 2.15: Export, import and total trade as percentage of GDP, 1970-2002

GDP (%) 1970-75 1975-80 1980-85 1985-90 1990-95 1995-00 2002


Export 6.15 10.89 11.40 11.33 17.41 23.62 15.82
Import 9.93 15.33 19.65 20.75 27.39 34.01 28.39
Total trade 16.09 26.23 31.06 32.08 44.8 57.64 44.21

Source: IMF/IFS online database

Table 2.15 shows that there has been a gradual increase in Nepal’s international trade.

The total trade/GDP ratio increased to over 57 per cent in the late 1990s from around

31 per cent in the 1980s. But it decreased to 44 per cent in 2002 due mainly to the

political instability. However, throughout the 1980s the export/GDP ratio remained

almost unchanged. It increased only after the trade liberalisation of the early 1990s.

Thus, the export/GDP ratio increased to over 17 per cent in the first half of the 1990s

and to over 23 per cent in the second half of the 1990s, from 11 per cent in the 1980s.

The growth of exports in the 1990s was mainly driven by the growth of manufactured

exports. Throughout the period, the import/GDP ratio also increased almost in a

similar manner.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 51

Nepal’s new policy allowed foreign investments in almost all sectors of the economy.

Important steps were taken to attract direct foreign investment. One hundred per cent

foreign ownership was permitted in most sectors, except those with strategic

importance. Full repatriation of the return on investment in convertible currencies was

also permitted. Furthermore, foreign investors were allowed to own up to 25 per cent

of listed companies.

Although many efforts have been made to expand and promote trade, some

weaknesses and obstacles still remain. Because of Nepal’s landlocked position, Nepal

has to bear extra transportation costs for consignments going to and from Calcutta

port in India. Trade is also hampered by the lack of sound management, inadequacy of

skilled manpower and technology. There is also a shortage of financial and material

resources and modern communication and technological facilities.

Since 2002, political instability and the Maoist violence and strikes across the country

have been hindering export promotion. In addition, Nepalese exports are characterised

by a very high level of market concentration. Over 85 per cent of total exports from

Nepal go to three countries: United States, Germany and India. This makes exports

subject to a high degree of volatility. For example, increased dependence on the

Indian market, particularly since 1996 following the new treaty, has elevated risks

arising from Indian policy shifts. Thus, the recent slowdown in exports is not only

caused by domestic instability, but also by excessive concentration in a few limited

markets (IMF, 2002).


Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 52

In sum, trade policies have significantly improved in Nepal. There has been a shift

from the earlier regime of trade restrictions towards a more open regime. Nepal has a

higher degree of openness than most other South Asian countries. Nepal achieves a

score of 2 on the IMF trade restrictiveness index that clearly indicates an open

regime. 13

2.9.2 Financial sector development and deregulation

The history of financial sector development of Nepal has been short. It started with

the opening of the first ever commercial bank in the country, the Nepal Bank Limited

(NBL), in 1937. The NBL was established as a joint venture between the government

(51 per cent share) and the private sector (49 per cent share). It was the only bank or

financial institution in the country until 1956. The Central Bank of the country, the

Nepal Rastra Bank (NRB), was established in 1956.

Before the establishment of the NRB, Nepalese foreign exchange reserves used to be

held in India. In exchange, Nepal used to receive Indian currency, which despite its

inconvertibility with other currencies, was fully acceptable in Nepal. Thus, until the

establishment of the NRB, Nepal had no monetary policy of its own and its currency

was not linked to any other currency except India’s. Therefore, 1956 marked the

beginning of the real history of financial development in Nepal.

13
This index gives countries a score between 1 and 10. Scores 1-4 indicates open regimes; scores 7-10
indicates restrictive regimes. See Deraniyagala (2003).
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 53

Within a decade, a number of institutions were established in the public sector. These

included the Nepal Industrial Development Corporation, the Agricultural

Development Bank, the Employees Provident Fund Corporation, the Nepal Insurance

Corporation and the Securities Marketing Centre. During 1970-89, the branches of

commercial banks expanded in many rural areas with partial subsidies from the NRB.

The vigorous drive for branch expansion significantly contributed to the institutional

development of the banking system. Commercial bank branches increased from 80 in

1970 to 439 in 1990. At the same time, the authorities gradually tightened their

control over the financial system by introducing interest rate controls, higher liquidity

requirements and directed credit programs (Acharya, 2003).

Nepal initiated financial reform measures in the mid 1980s. Following the financial

sector reforms, a number of new financial institutions were established. For the first

time, foreign banks were allowed to operate as joint ventures with Nepalese investors.

As a result, three joint venture banks – the Nepal Arab Bank Limited, the Nepal

Indosuez Bank Limited and the Nepal Grindlays Bank Limited – were established

between 1984 to1987.

For the first time, in 1985, commercial banks were allowed to accept current and fixed

deposits in foreign currencies (US dollar and Pound Sterling). Until 1986, the interest

rates of commercial banks were fully controlled by the NRB. The NRB deregulated

the interest rate regime in 1986 and authorised commercial banks to fix interest rates

at any level above its prescribed levels. The financial sector was further liberalised

under the Structural Adjustment Programs of the World Bank and the IMF. The
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 54

creation of the auction market for government securities also contributed to the

development of the financial sector (Shrestha, 2004).

As a result of financial sector deregulation the financial sector has grown rapidly.

Since the early 1990s there has been a dramatic increase in the number of banking and

non-banking financial institutions. By 2000, there were 1,060 commercial bank

branches. By July 2000, there were 11 private commercial banks, 2 development

banks, 5 regional rural development banks, 48 finance companies, 2 insurance

companies, 34 savings and credit cooperative societies, and some other financial and

quasi-financial institutions. Total financial assets as at mid July 2000 were estimated

at more than Rs. 277 billion. The total financial assets/GDP ratio increased from 29

per cent in 1985 to almost 76 per cent in 2000 (Acharya, 2003). The M2/GDP ratio

increased from 10.62 per cent in 1970 to 53.54 per cent in 2002. The commercial

bank deposit as a percentage of GDP increased from 10 per cent in 1980 to 42 per

cent in 2000. During the same period, credit as a percentage of GDP increased from

12 per cent to 32 per cent. Thus, all indicators show that the financial sector of Nepal

has deepened significantly.

However, some serious problems have remained for the two largest commercial

banks, the Nepal Bank Limited (NBL) and the Rastriya Banijya Bank (RBB). These

two banks have a high proportion of non-performing loans. As of mid 1998, they had

losses of around US$ 450 million, equivalent to around 46 percentage of their annual

budget, with the share of non-performing loans around 18 per cent of total loans in

2000. The share of these two banks in the assets and liabilities of the banking sector is
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 55

around 50 per cent (Shrestha, 2004). To ensure sound and effective management, the

government has contracted out their management to foreign private sector parties.

Additionally, the World Bank and the IMF have indicated that there are weaknesses in

the NRB’s regulatory and supervisory capacities, and have recommended further

measures to address these issues. The IMF (2003) revealed that the NBL and the RBB

suffer from weak management, poor accounting practices, considerable political

interference, and high numbers of non-performing loans. Still, the new management

teams are making progress in recovering non-performing loans and have produced

updated financial accounts. They are also improving human resource and treasury

management.

2.9.3 Macroeconomic stability

The fiscal situation in Nepal has been historically weak, with budget deficits being a

permanent feature of the budgetary system. During the 1960s, the nominal rate of

growth of government expenditure was around 15 per cent on average. This increased

to more than 17 per cent in the 1970s and further to more than 19 per cent in the

1980s (see Table 2.16). During the 1980s, the budgetary situation was marked by high

expenditure growth followed by high deficits. In the first half of the 1980s,

government expenditure increased by 19.7 per cent compared to the growth of

revenue at 16.1 per cent only. The mismatch between expenditure growth and revenue

growth widened the budget deficit; this period saw the fastest widening of the deficit

in three decades. This was financed mainly by borrowing from the NRB. Higher
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 56

monetary expansion pushed inflation to over 10 per cent, and Nepal faced a serious

balance of payments crisis in the first half of the 1980s.

Table 2.16: Average growth rates of fiscal sector indicators, 1966-2002

Average Government Regular Development Revenue Grants Deficit


growth expenditure
rates
1966-70 14.7 13.4 15.8 19.4 13.1 18.4
1971-75 17.4 20.6 16.3 17.4 5.1 -0.7
1976-80 18.2 16.5 19.2 13.4 23.6 33.0
1981-85 19.7 20.2 19.7 16.1 3.5 41.8
1986-90 18.7 18.1 19.2 19.1 19.3 22.0
1991-95 14.8 24.7 9.3 21.7 28.8 5.3
1996-00 11.2 12.4 10.2 11.8 8.6 12.0
1966-00 16.6 18.0 15.7 17.0 14.6 18.8
2001-02 11.8 14.4 3.2 8.6 23.6 16.4

Source: Economic Survey (various issues), Ministry of Finance

Restructuring of the fiscal sector in Nepal was initiated with the adoption of an

economic stabilisation program in 1985 and the subsequent graduation to the

Structural Adjustment Program in 1987. The primary objectives of the fiscal sector

restructuring were to improve the buoyancy and elasticity of the tax system, increase

budget allocations to social sectors, reduce the fiscal deficit, and contain net domestic

financing to less than one per cent of GDP.

The restructuring also aimed to minimise the budgetary drain to public enterprises,

and rationalise subsidies and transfers. From the early 1990s onwards, the

government’s role was to increase the participation of the private sector in industrial
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 57

and other enterprises. At the same time, to reduce the government’s role in industry

and public enterprises, three public enterprises were privatised. 14

Following the introduction of stabilisation and adjustment policies, the 1990s witnessed

an improvement in revenue collection. The revenue/GDP ratio was 9 per cent in the

1980s; it rose to 10.7 per cent on average during the 1990s. At the same time the

expenditure/GDP ratio declined to 17.5 per cent in 2000 compared with 19 per cent in

1990. As a result, a significant improvement can be seen in fiscal deficit, which declined

from 7.8 per cent of GDP in the 1985-90 to 5.5 per cent during 1996-2000.

However, there remain some concerns. The decline in expenditure exceeds the increase

in revenue. Thus, the burden of reducing government deficit has fallen disproportionately

on the expenditure side. Since reduction of current expenditure is politically difficult, the

objective of reducing the budget deficit has been achieved by cutting development

expenditure (Table 2.16). This is likely to have long-term implications for the economy.

Foreign economic assistance can play a crucial role in maintaining development and

social sector expenditure.

2.10 Corruption and governance reform

In developing countries like Nepal corruption is a major impediment to progress. While

it reduces public revenue, it increases public spending. Thus, it can contribute to larger

fiscal deficits. Corruption is likely to increase income inequality because it allows high-

14
These were Harisiddhi Brick and Tile Factory, Bansbari Leather and Shoe Industry, and Bhrikuti
Paper and Pulp Industry.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 58

ranking officials to take advantage of government activities at the cost of the entire

population (Gupta et al., 1998).

Mauro (1995) showed that corruption reduces investment and in turn the rate of growth. It

also distorts markets and the allocation of resources. Thus, it is likely to reduce economic

efficiency and growth. Mauro (1995) estimated that an increase in corruption of one

standard deviation decreases investment and growth by 5 and 0.5 per cent of GDP

respectively.

Table 2.17: Control of corruption index for South Asian countries, 1996-2002

Year/Country 1996 1998 2000 2002


Nepal -0.26 -0.59 -0.42 -0.30
Bangladesh -0.43 -0.40 -0.64 -1.12
India -0.29 -0.17 -0.21 -0.25
Pakistan -0.91 -0.75 -0.70 -0.73
Sri Lanka -0.21 -0.24 -0.05 -0.14

Note: The index ranges from -2.5 (most corrupt) to +2.5 (least corrupt).
Source: World Bank, 2002c 15

Nepal is considered among the most corrupt developing countries in the world.

Transparency International (2004) gives Nepal a corruption index of 2.8 out of 10. For

Bangladesh, India, Pakistan and Sri Lanka the indices were 1.5, 2.8, 2.1 and 3.5

respectively. 16 Although the extent and magnitude of corruption varies with the

definition and methodological procedures, observers believe that corruption in Nepal is

deep-rooted and widespread. As can be seen from Table 2.17, the governance indicator

(only control of corruption is presented) reveals that Nepal experiences a high level of

corruption. Among South Asian countries, only Sri Lanka is found less corrupt,

15
See World Bank (2002c) for details.
16
The index ranges from 0 (most corrupt) to 10 (most clean). See
http://www.transparency.org/cpi/2004.en.html.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 59

followed by India. 17 Thus, Nepal’s low rate of growth may be associated with high

levels of corruption.

The deep-rooted and widespread corruption has also fuelled the ongoing civil unrest in

Nepal. The poor governance and pervasive corruption have shattered people’s high

expectation that arose from the restoration of the democracy in 1991 (see Panday, 2001).

Poor and landless people, in particular low caste ethnic groups, did not find any change

in their life except new government of a bit different elite politicians. The persistent

social injustice among various low caste ethnic groups has not been addressed

adequately. On the other hand, local politicians, high level government officials and

Ministers are found directly involved in various corruption scandals (see the following

section). Thus, it is not only poverty, but also corrupt practices associated with aid

allocation, that is fuelling the Maoist uprising. This has almost ended the people’s faith

in democratically elected governments in various parts of remote areas. Consequently,

many poor, uneducated and low caste people are voluntarily joining the Maoist war (see

Murshed and Gates, 2005 for details).

2.10.1 Anti-corruption measures in Nepal

Corruption is not a new phenomenon in Nepal. King Prithivi Narayan Shah, who unified

Nepal as a sovereign nation in 1768, made it clear that both bribe takers and givers

commit the worst crimes against the country. During the autocratic Rana Regime of

17
Kaufmann et al. (2004) have defined corruption as the exercise of public power for private gain, and
have treated corruption as a governance indicator. The index ranges from -2.5 to 2.5 (higher is better).
See the World Bank’s Policy Research Working Paper 3106 for the data and methodology used to
construct the governance indicators.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 60

1846-1951, some efforts were made to control corrupt practices. However, until 1950,

due to the limited economic activity, there were few opportunities for corruption.

After the popular democratic movement in 1951, the then government introduced the

Anti-Corruption Act 1952 to tackle corruption. The Anti-Corruption Department was

established in 1960. At the same time, the Special Police Department was used to

control growing corruption practices. In 1977, the Commission on Controlling Abuse of

Authority was established. After the restoration of democracy in 1990, the Commission

for Investigation of Abuse of Authority (CIAA) was set up to combat corruption.

Some efforts have since been made to control widespread corruption. In 1999, the

government announced a plan to combat corruption through three proposed anti-

corruption measures: a prevention of corruption bill, an amendment to the Commission

for Investigation of Abuse of Authority Act, and the establishment of the Special Anti-

corruption Court. Ironically, parliament remained deadlocked in early 2001, with

opposition parties calling for Prime Minister Koirala’s resignation for his alleged

involvement in a controversial Boeing lease fraud. After months of investigation, the

CIAA filed corruption charges against officials accused in the case, including the civil

aviation minister at the time. 18

In March 2001, the CIAA sought the Prime Minister’s permission to proceed against

Govinda Raj Joshi, the Minister for Local Development, for his allegedly dubious

18
“Riddle in the Middle: Koirala and Current Crisis”, Kathmandu Post, 26 March 2001; “CIAA
Charges Ex-Minister of Corruption”, The Rising Nepal, 30 October 2002. For more information about
corruption charges and related issues see www.kantipuronline.com, www.nepalnews.com and the
CIAA website, www.akhtiyar.org.np/reports.htm. See also Nepal Times on 20-26 September 2002 and
Kathmandu Post on 18 August, 30 October, and 27 November in 2002.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 61

intentions in amending selection guidelines for teachers when he was Minister for

Education in 1997. Joshi filed a petition in the Supreme Court challenging the CIAA’s

action. The CIAA was fighting another battle in the Supreme Court against the Attorney

General, who filed a writ petition challenging the CIAA’s authority to question his

decision to drop proceedings in a currency smuggling case.

The government also proposed an array of anti-corruption legislation in 2002, including

the Corruption Control Bill, the CIAA Bill, the Special Court Bill, the

Impeachment/Regulation Working Procedure Bill and the Management of Political

Parties Bill. All these bills, intended to make the detection and prosecution of corruption

in state and non-state sectors more effective, were adopted by parliament in April 2002.

The Corruption Control Bill and the Special Court Bill received royal assent in June

2002. With the establishment of the Special Court and the empowerment of the CIAA,

action taken by the CIAA has been more effective.

The CIAA filed corruption cases against high-profile officials and ex-Ministers, and

rebuked the Prime Minister for approving the Lauda Air deal. It is too early to assess the

long-term impact of these developments on official corruption levels, but they clearly

represent a beginning. CIAA initiatives have demonstrated that autonomous, public anti-

corruption agencies backed by constitutional power can make a difference, and can avoid

falling under the sway of partisan objectives.

However, the actions of the CIAA have not escaped criticisms. For example, although

many cases of corruption were investigated by the CIAA on the basis of the findings of

the Judicial Commission for Property Investigation, the commission’s report has not been
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 62

published yet. General public perception is that corruption has grown in the last 12 years,

that is, during the multi-party democratic system. The belief is that corruption is

encouraged and promoted by the government, ministers, parliament and the (weak)

judicial system.

The prevailing climate of political competition mobilised around corruption issues

remains a threat to the fight against corruption in Nepal as elsewhere. A further problem

is the absence of a functioning judicial system. While there is a rigorous anti-corruption

law, conviction rates are low, and sentences rarely carried out. The judicial process is

open to manipulation and cases drag on for years (Transparency International, 2001). For

example, Panday (2001) noted, “the auditor general of the country regularly identifies

arrears amounting to billions of rupees in government financial transactions every year

and draws the attention of the authorities for necessary actions….but nothing happens in

terms of taking action or executing the needed reform. This is a tradition from the days

of the ancient regime faithfully continued into the present political order” (2001: 19-20).

2.11 Concluding remarks

Nepal’s economic performance improved during the 1990s due mainly to trade and

economic liberalisation, initiated in the early 1990s. Since then, Nepal has made

significant progress in liberalisation of the trade, financial, monetary and industrial

sectors, and has thereby created an environment more conducive for growth. Despite

notable progress in the 1990s, the pace of reform implementation has slowed and

economic growth has been persistently hindered by political instability and the Maoist

insurgency.
Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 63

Nepal also made considerable progress in social indicators such as life expectancy,

literacy and access to safe drinking water. However, even now almost half of its

population lives in absolute poverty. Thus, a comprehensive Poverty Reduction Strategy

Paper (PRPS) has been incorporated in the Tenth Plan. The strategy is based on

extensive consultation within the public sector and with civil society, and is approved by

main multilateral donors. It aims to reduce poverty from 38 per cent in 2001 to 30 per

cent by 2007. To meet this target, the PRSP’s public expenditure program is based on the

Medium Term Expenditure Framework (MTEF), which is designed to help prioritise

expenditures. Under the MTEF, development expenditures have been prioritised in three

different categories. In addition, a performance based fund-release mechanism has been

implemented for development projects.

The PRSP has been welcomed by many donors who have begun to provide support for

the program. However, the IMF Joint Staff Assessment of the Poverty Reduction

Strategy Paper (2003) pointed out some weaknesses in the strategy. It noted: “While the

PRSP discusses the nexus between patterns of growth and poverty, especially in rural

areas and the importance of agricultural growth, discussion is limited to causal links

between policies and changes in poverty levels. Similarly, there is no explicit link

between past policies or programs and implications for prioritisation” (IMF, 2003: 4).

The IMF stressed the need for reform to further improve public expenditure

management, and imposed various conditions on the use of funds.

Nepal implemented the conditions prior to the disbursement of credit. For example, to

fulfil the conditions of the first Poverty Reduction Strategy Credit of the World Bank, the

government dropped many projects, appointed new professional management teams at


Chapter 2: An Overview of Economic and Social Development in Nepal 64

the two main commercial banks (the NBL and RBB), and handed over 150 public

primary schools to local management and 400 sub-health posts to district level

management. More importantly, for the first time in Nepal’s history, corruption charges

have been laid to prosecute three former ministers and 22 tax officials. However, more

still needs to be done to strengthen key institutions charged with fighting corruption,

including the CIAA and the National Vigilance Center. Nepal also needs to continue its

reform of the financial and monetary sectors and the public sector.
Chapter 3

Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective

“…foreign aid has proved to be an effective instrument contributing to significant


improvements in the socio-economic development of the country; and much of the physical
infrastructure such as roads, irrigation facilities, hydropower as well as education and health
services, drinking water and sanitation facilities have been built with foreign assistance. It has
also contributed to the development of policy dialogue, catalysed economic reforms,
enhanced the capability of policy makers; and provided financial assistance for public
services…notwithstanding these achievements, foreign aid in Nepal has had its shortcomings
as well. Progress in economic growth and poverty reduction has not been commensurate with
the inflow of aid into the country” (HMG/N, Foreign Aid Policy, 2002: 3).

3.1 Introduction

Foreign aid has been an important instrument in the socio-economic development of

Nepal. Since the early 1950s, almost all physical infrastructures have been financed

by foreign aid. Nepal’s geographical location, topography (its mountainous terrain)

and widespread poverty combined with high rates of population growth have

persistently made the country aid-dependent for more than half a century. The average

aid to GDP ratio increased from about 2 per cent in the 1960s to almost 10 per cent in

the 1990s.

Until the mid 1960s, Nepal was almost fully dependent on foreign grants for all its

development projects. The first Five Year Plan (1956-60) was entirely financed by

foreign aid. Most of these grants were on a bilateral basis and concentrated on the

establishment of public enterprises and building physical infrastructures. For example,

grants from India helped to build the airport in Kathmandu, the Kosi dam and various

irrigation projects. The former Soviet Union provided assistance to build cigarette and
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 66

sugar factories, a hydroelectric plant, and part of the East–West highway. China

assisted to construct roads, a trolley bus line in Kathmandu, and leather and shoe, and

brick and tile factories. US grants supported village development, agriculture,

education and public health. The US also helped start the Nepal Industrial

Development Corporation, which granted loans to several industries. Although during

the 1950s and 1960s the top priority was given to the development of infrastructure,

later, in the 1970s, the agricultural sector received high priority for the allocation of

aid.

Table 3.1: Nepal’s average total aid, bilateral and grants aid, 1960-2002

Year Total aid Bilateral aid Grants aid


(% of GDP) (% of total aid) (% of total aid)
1960-69 1.95 96.83 99.79
1970-79 4.34 66.31 72.52
1980-89 10.39 54.22 64.17
1990-99 10.04 60.48 67.57
1960-02 6.62 69.99 76.85

Source: OECD/IDS online database

Over the years, Nepal’s aid dependency increased considerably. As can be seen from

Table 3.1, the average total aid increased from about 2 per cent of GDP in the 1960s

to 10 per cent in the 1980s and aid flows remained at around 10 per cent of GDP in

the 1990s. Although bilateral aid still dominates, its share has declined. For example,

the share of bilateral aid decreased from almost 97 per cent in the 1960s to around 60

per cent in the 1990s. With it, the share of grants in total aid also declined. In the

1960s, almost all aid was grants; it decreased to around 67 per cent in the 1990s.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 67

Although Nepal’s overall aid dependency has increased, one can argue that its

increased access to loans and decreasing dependency on grants is a sign of Nepal’s

improved status among the donors. It is hoped that Nepal can eventually graduate

from a receiver of concessional loans to commercial borrowings. This chapter will

provide a comprehensive picture of foreign aid to Nepal from an historical

perspective. It begins by discussing the significance of aid. It then examines the

sources (bilateral and multilateral), sectoral distribution and rationale (use) of foreign

aid. The chapter will also reflect on micro issues such as country ownership, aid

coordination and absorptive capacity.

3.2 Significance of aid

One can use a number of indicators to assess the importance of foreign aid. The most

common indicator is the ratio of foreign aid to GDP. This shows the overall

significance of foreign aid in the economy. Among the South Asian countries, Nepal

had the highest aid/GDP ratio (over 8 per cent) during 1970-2002 (see Table 3.1A).

Table 3.1A: Average aid/GDP ratios in South Asian Countries (%), 1970-2002

Year/Country Nepal Bangladesh India Pakistan Sri Lanka


1970-2002 8.29 6.84 1.14 3.92 6.12
Source: OECD/IDS online databases

As can be seen from Figure 3.1, aid to Nepal sharply rose until the late 1980s. It

increased from around 2 per cent of GDP in the 1960s to over 10 per cent in the late

1980s. Aid flows peaked at 15 per cent of GDP in 1990. Since then aid flows to Nepal

started declining, as elsewhere. The aid/GDP ratio stood at 6 per cent in 2002. This
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 68

decline in aid dependence coincided with Nepal’s policy reforms and improved

economic performance in the 1990s.

Figure 3.1: Foreign aid to Nepal as percentage of GDP, 1960-2002

20
15
10 AR (Total Aid % GDP)
5
0
1960
1963

1966
1969
1972

1975
1978

1981
1984
1987

1990
1993
1996

1999
2002
Source: OECD/IDS online database

Figure 3.2 presents per capita aid to Nepal, which shows almost a similar trend as the

aid to GDP ratio. Despite population growth, per capita aid rose steadily from less

than US$ 2 in the 1960s to over US$ 25 (at current prices) by 1990. However, since

1990, it started to decrease and stood at about US$ 15 in 2002.

Figure 3.2: Per capita aid (US$ at current prices), 1960-2002

30
25
20
Per capita aid ($US at
15
current prices)
10
5
0
1960
1963
1966

1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993

1996
1999
2002

Source: OECD/IDS and IMF/IFS online databases

The importance of foreign aid can also be assessed by examining the aid to revenue

ratio and aid to government expenditure ratio. For example, in Nepal, throughout the
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 69

1980s until the early 1990s, foreign aid as a percentage of domestic revenue was over

100 per cent. After steadily declining since 1965, from 71 per cent to nearly 26 per

cent in 1969, it increased to over 180 per cent in 1989. 1 While it remained at over 90

per cent in the early 1990s, it declined from the mid 1990s to about 62 per cent in

2001 (Figure 3.3).

Figure 3.3: Foreign aid as percentage of domestic revenue, 1960-2002

200
150
100 Total aid as % of revenue
50
0
81

84

87

90

93

96

99
60

63

66

69

72

75

78
19

19

19

19

19

19

19
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

Source: IMF/IFS and OECD/IDS online databases

Figure 3.4: Foreign aid as percentage of government expenditure, 1960-2002

90
80
70
60
50 Total aid % of govt.
40 expenditure
30
20
10
0
60

63

66

69

72

75

78

81

84

87

90

93

96

99
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

Source: IMF/IFS and OECD/IDS online databases

1
The sudden rise in the aid/revenue ratio was due to disbursement of aid following Nepal’s signing on
Structural Adjustment Program with the IMF and the World Bank. Nepal also was able to attract larger
aid flows from other donors following its dispute with India over the trade and transit treaty. When
India closed its all transit points to Nepal except two in 1989, the crisis hit the Nepalese economy
severely, and needed support from donors.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 70

The importance of aid is also evident from government expenditure financed by aid

(Figure 3.4). Between 1960 and 2002, aid’s share in total government expenditure

was over 40 per cent on average. Foreign aid financed nearly 20 per cent of total

expenditure in 1960, while it increased to about 48 per cent in 1964-65. Foreign aid

financing rose to over 80 per cent of total expenditure in 1992.

In sum, all indicators show that foreign aid has played a major role in Nepal, and it

remains a highly aid-dependent country. However, Nepal’s aid dependence has been

declining since the early 1990s.

3.3 Sources of aid

The United States was the first country from which Nepal received foreign aid. A sum

of US$ 2000 was provided by the United States to the Rana Regime in January 1951,

just a month before the regime collapsed. Soon after, foreign aid from diverse sources

came into the country. Since 1952, India, despite being a recipient country itself,

became involved in providing aid to Nepal. In 1956, China also began to help Nepal,

followed by the former Soviet Union. These two regional powers (India and China)

and two superpowers (the United States and the former USSR) had their own strategic

interests in competing for aid to Nepal (see Khadka, 1997).

Nepal has been successful in tapping aid from various sources. While its neighbouring

countries of India and China are two traditional sources, Nepal has expanded its

diplomatic relations with a large number of donors, resulting in increased aid flows to

the country. By the late 1980s over 35 countries provided aid to Nepal (Khadka,
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 71

1997). In addition, 11 UN agencies, 7 multilateral lending agencies such as the World

Bank, and 8 private agencies (for example, the Ford Foundation) were involved in aid

programs.

Under the auspices of the World Bank, the Nepal Aid Group was established in 1976.

By 1987 16 countries and six international agencies were involved in the group. 2

After 1976, a large part of foreign aid came from this group. The level of commitment

from the Nepal Aid Group increased from Rs. 1.5 billion in 1976-77 to Rs. 5.6 billion

in 1987-88. The aid commitment further increased from Rs. 16.5 billion in 1995-96 to

Rs. 18.8 billion in 2000-01(Library of Congress, 1991; Paudyal, 2003). The increased

commitment by the group might be attributed to the Structural Adjustment Program

that was initiated in the late 1980s.

In the 1980s, bilateral US economic assistance, provided through the Agency for

International Development (USAID), averaged US$ 15 million annually. The US also

contributed to various international institutions and private voluntary organisations

that serviced Nepal. Its total contribution to multilateral aid agencies working in

Nepal was in excess of US$ 250 million in the 1980s. The members of the

Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) provided US$ 30 million aid

from 1979 to 1989. Communist countries provided US$ 273 million in bilateral aid

from 1970 to 1988. From 1981 until 1988, Japan was the premier source of bilateral

official development assistance (ODA) for Nepal, accounting for more than one-third

of all funds. The second largest donor during that period was the former West

Germany.

2
The Aid Group is now known as Nepal Development Forum and 23 countries and many international
agencies represented Nepal Development Forum 2000 held in France. In recent years, it has been held
in Nepal also.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 72

As can be seen from Table 3.2, since the 1980s, among the bilateral donors, Japan has

been the largest donor, followed by Germany, United States and United Kingdom.

These four countries still account for over 60 per cent in the share of total bilateral

aid. Until the mid 1960s the United States was the largest donor. US aid increased

from US$ 11.42 million in the 1960s to over US$ 22 million in 2000-02. German aid

increased from US$ 0.61 million in the 1960s to over US$ 31 million in 2000-02; aid

from the United Kingdom rose to almost US$ 31 million in 2000-02 from less than a

million dollar in the 1960s. More significantly, Japan’s aid increased from US$ 0.07

million in the 1960s to over US$ 90 million in 2000-02. Denmark, Switzerland,

Norway and Netherlands have also become major bilateral donors to Nepal.

In the case of multilateral donors, the ADB, IDA, UNDP and UNICEF are the major

donors. Except for the UNDP, the contributions of these donors were not very

significant in the 1960s. Together they provided US$ 1.35 million, and the UNDP

alone contributed US$ 1.2 million. From the 1970s, however, multilateral aid

increased. On average the ADB increased its aid from US$ 4.25 million in the 1970s

to over US$ 66 million in the 1990s. IDA aid also increased from US$ 6.91 million in

the 1970s to over US$ 54 million in the 1990s. Throughout the 1990s, aid from

multilateral donors increased substantially and accounted for around 40 per cent of

total aid during 1990-2000.


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 73

Table 3.2: Nepal’s average bilateral and multilateral aid, 1960-2002


(US$ million)
Major donors 1960-69 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-02
1. Japan 0.07 6.17 49.07 94.90 90.92
2. German 0.61 6.96 23.71 26.56 31.41
3. United Kingdom 0.84 7.82 16.96 25.53 31.02
4. Denmark 0.00 0.51 3.79 18.73 25.45
5. United States 11.42 9.54 17.00 17.59 22.92
6. Switzerland 0.28 2.61 11.17 13.71 12.81
7. Norway 0.03 0.33 3.09 7.65 11.17
8. Canada 0.01 2.05 8.67 4.66 4.21
9. Australia 0.21 0.74 2.04 4.25 4.02
10. Finland 0.00 0.02 5.83 9.49 5.27
11. Netherlands 0.00 0.90 3.62 7.75 8.81
12. Sweden 0.03 0.07 0.15 1.09 6.15
13. France 0.00 0.00 6.61 8.60 0.18
14. Belgium 0.00 0.36 0.64 0.45 0.67
15. Austria 0.00 0.08 0.93 2.21 1.47
16. Italy 0.00 0.01 1.05 0.32 0.22
17. New Zealand 0.00 0.31 0.13 0.35 0.47
18. Arab countries 0.00 3.35 3.24 1.88 7.79
19. Korea 0.00 0.00 0.00 1.60 1.80
A. Total bilateral 13.11 38.89 156.02 246.93 270.31
(including others)
1. ADB 0.00 4.25 36.13 66.10 41.58
2. IDA 0.19 6.91 51.80 54.26 26.15
3. UNDP 1.22 4.65 13.67 10.24 7.71
4. WFP 0.17 2.96 7.28 7.31 6.99
5. UNICEF 0.34 1.29 5.16 6.77 4.32
6. UNTA 0.49 0.86 1.89 3.52 4.00
7. UNHCR 0.05 0.06 0.08 4.78 4.65
8. OTHER UN 0.11 1.15 3.01 2.44 3.39
9. UNFPA 0.00 1.72 1.99 3.50 3.55
10. Arab Agencies 0.00 4.15 1.35 1.76 1.91
11. IFAD 0.00 0.00 4.92 1.61 0.97
B. Total 0.89 24.51 131.66 161.44 112.71
multilateral
(including others)
Total A + B 14.00 63.40 287.68 408.37 383.02

Notes: (a) Since OECD did not include India and China, aid from them could not be reported here.
However, the significance of aid from India and China is discussed separately later in the
chapter.
(b) IMF assistance is not regarded as aid. It is primarily given for budget and balance of
payments support. Thus, assistance from the IMF is not included in the list. However, many
bilateral and multilateral aid agencies make their aid contingent upon fulfilment of IMF’s
conditionality.
Source: OECD/IDS online database
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 74

According to the OECD (2004), among the top 10 donors of gross ODA (Official

Development Assistance) to Nepal for 2002-03 were Japan (US$ 87 million), IDA

(World Bank) (US$ 68 million), Germany (US$ 49 million), United Kingdom (US$

45 million), US (US$ 35 million), Denmark (US$ 33 million), ADB (US$ 31 million),

Norway (US$ 17 million), European Commission (EC) (US$ 15 million) and

Switzerland (US$ 14 million).

3.3.1 Japan’s aid

When the Japanese embassy in Nepal was established in 1968, Japan started

providing loans and grants to Nepal. Average Japanese aid was less than 1 per cent of

total bilateral aid in the 1960s, and it increased to almost 35 per cent in the 1980s.

Since the early 1980s, it has become the largest bilateral donor to Nepal. Japanese aid

stood at about US$ 60 million in 2003. Of total Japanese aid to Nepal, grant

assistance represents 58 per cent, loans 24 per cent and technical cooperation 18 per

cent, as at 28 April 2003 (see Japanese embassy, 2003).

Table 3.3: Japan’s share of total bilateral aid, 1960-2002

Year 1960-69 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 1960-00 2002


Average share (%)
of total bilateral aid 0.62 14.97 34.99 38.04 22.84 26.66

Source: OECD/IDS online database

The sectoral distribution of total grants aid from Japan as at April 28, 2003 shows that

the agricultural sector received the highest amount, accounting for 23 per cent. The

second highest share of grants (19 per cent) went to the social sector, which includes
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 75

education (8 per cent), health (3 per cent), safe drinking water (7 per cent) and other

social services (1 per cent). The remaining grant aid went to the infrastructure sector

(16 per cent), debt relief (12 per cent), the energy sector (8 per cent), communication

(8 per cent), food aid (4 per cent), disaster mitigation (4 per cent), civil aviation (3 per

cent) and other non-project sectors (3 per cent) (see Japanese embassy, 2003).

Japanese loan aid was provided mainly for projects. The highest share of loan aid as at

April 28, 2003 went to the Udaipur Cement Plant Project, accounting for 29 per cent.

The second highest share was received by the Kaligandaki “A” Hydroelectricity

Project (26 per cent). Among other projects, the Kulekhani No. 2 Hydropower Station

Project received 19 per cent of Japanese loans, the Kulekhani Disaster Prevention

Project, 10 per cent and Kulekhani Hydroelectric Project 6 per cent. 3

3.3.2 India’s aid

India has been providing development assistance to Nepal for over 50 years. It was

the second largest donor after the United States until the 1965. India became the

largest donor in 1966 and remained so until 1980-81.

Table 3.4: India’s share of total bilateral aid, 1960-1990

Year 1960-64 1965-69 1970-74 1975-79 1980-84 1985-90


Average share (%)
of total bilateral aid 20.35 50.35 42.63 26.31 21.98 13.23

Source: Khadka (1997)

3
The percentages represent accumulated total loans as at 28 April 2003. See www.np.emb-japan.go.jp
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 76

Table 3.4 shows that India’s aid increased substantially during the late 1960s. It

increased from 20 per cent of total bilateral aid in the first half of the 1960s to over 50

per cent of total bilateral aid in the late 1960s. In particular, in 1968 and 1969 it

reached over 60 per cent of total bilateral aid. However, after the late 1970s, India’s

average share decreased and by the late 1980s, it stood at 13 per cent of total bilateral

aid.

In the early days, Indian assistance was given more for infrastructure projects, such as

roads, railways and airports. 4 India spent over 56 per cent of its total aid at this time

building roads and airports. Table 3.5 shows road projects that were built during

1953-85 with Indian aid.

Table 3.5: India’s aid for road projects, 1953-90

Name of the project Length (km) Year constructed


Tribhuvan Raj path 116 1953-59
Siddhartha Raj marg 200 1965-72
Dakshinkali Road 19 1969
Mahendra Raj marg (eastern section) 300 1969-75
Kathmandu–Godawari Road 16 1973-75
Kathmandu–Trisuli Road 69 1972-75
Hanumannagr–Fatehpur Road 28.2 1975-77
Hanumannagar–Rajbiraj Road 13.5 1983
Mahendra Raj marg (Butwal–Kohalpur) 310 1984-86
Kohalpur–Mahakali Road 200 1986-92

Source: Various issues of HMG/N

More recently, Indian assistance has been extended to other sectors such as education,

health, agriculture and power. Thus, the amount of aid has increased substantially

over the years. It increased from an average of Rs. 150 million in the mid 1980s to Rs.

4
Nepal’s only railway, the Janakpur–Jayanagar line, was built with Indian aid.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 77

750 million in 1999-00. However, these figures exclude the supply of subsidised

commodities such as rice, sugar, cement and fertiliser, and the refund of

petrochemical excise duty levied on items exported from India. 5

3.3.4 China’s aid

Nepal’s diplomatic relationship with the People’s Republic of China was established

in 1955, further strengthening the age-old bilateral relationship between the two

countries. The first and second agreements between China and Nepal on economic aid

were signed in 1956 and 1960 respectively. Since then China has been providing

grants of financial and technical assistance to Nepal.

Table 3.6: China’s share of total bilateral aid, 1960-90

Year 1960-64 1965-69 1970-74 1975-79 1980-84 1985-90


Average share (%)
of total bilateral aid 5.5 15.2 16.91 15.11 8.43 4.2

Source: Khadka (1997)

China’s first assistance was to support Nepal’s Five Year Plan (1956-60) with a sum

of US$ 12.6 million. China’s aid increased from just 5.5 per cent of total bilateral aid

in the first half of the 1960s to 15 per cent in the second half of 1960s. It further

increased to almost 17 per cent by the mid 1970s. However, China’s importance has

declined considerably and its share in total bilateral aid stood at about 4 per cent by

the late 1980s.

5
See http://www.south-asia.com/embassy-india/indnepal.htm.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 78

The Chinese aid-financed projects are mainly in transport and industry. However,

China also provides aid to other sectors such as hydropower and irrigation, public

facilities, health, education and sports. 6 Table 3.7 presents the list of Chinese aid

funded road projects.

Table 3.7: China’s aid for road projects, 1963-90

Name of the projects Length (km) Year constructed


Arniko Highway 104 1963-67
Arniko Highway maintenance 13 1968-70
Prithivi Highway (Kathmandu–Pokhara Road) 174 1965-67
Kathmandu–Bhaktapur Road 13 1969-71
Gorkha–Narayanghat Road 60 1976-82
Kathmandu Trolley Bus 14 1973-75
Kathmandu ring Road 27 1974-77
Pokhara–Mustang Road 73 1987-90

Source: Various issues of HMG/N

China has constructed many important highways, such as the Prithivi highway, which

links Kathmandu and Pokhara, Nepal’s only tourist centre, apart from Kathmandu. As

a result, this highway opened up significant economic opportunity for ordinary

people. In addition, China helped build the ring road around Kathmandu, the trolley

bus system, and the Kathmandu to Bhaktapur road.

China also provided financial assistance to establish a number of industries –

industries that had great significance during the period when Nepal pursued import

substitution policies. During 1965-86 Chinese aid helped to establish the Bansbari

Leather and Shoe Factory, the Harishiddi Brick and Tile Factory, the Hetauda Cotton

6
Embassy of China in Nepal, www.chinaembassey.org.np
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 79

Textile Mills, the Bhaktapur Brick and Tile Factory, the Bhrikuti Paper Mills, the

Lumbini Sugar Factory and the Leather Globes and the Apron Manufacturing Unit.

One important difference between India and China’s aid is that China provided

assistance not only for road projects, but also for the promotion of consumer goods in

Nepal. India, on the other hand, helped build infrastructure in areas where they had

more strategic interests. India’s aid never involved promoting trade in Nepal, as that

would affect Indian exports (Khadka, 1997).

3.3.4 The World Bank, the IMF and the Asian Development Bank in Nepal

The World Bank

Nepal became a member of the World Bank on 6 September 1961. While the Bank’s

office was opened in 1971 in Kathmandu, its operations began in 1969. Its first credit

was provided to a telecommunications project from the International Development

Association (IDA). Since then, the World Bank has approved 79 credits, amounting

total of around US$ 1.6 billion. Active credits totalled US$ 341 million as at April

2004. The World Bank has been providing funds for the development of

infrastructure, telecommunications, education, Structural Adjustment Programs, and

poverty reduction programs and projects. Recently approved active projects are listed

in Table 3.8. These projects have prioritised financial sector restructuring and power

development followed by the education and health sectors.


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 80

Table 3.8: Active projects financed by the World Bank (IBRD and IDA),
1999-2004
Credit (US$
Name of the projects million) Approved date
Nepal health sector program project 50 09/09/2004
Education for all project 50 08/07/2004
Poverty alleviation fund project 15 01/06/2004
Second rural water supply and sanitation project 25.3 01/06/2004
Financial sector restructuring project 75.5 09/03/2004
Community school support project 5 30/6/2003
Nepal power development project 75.6 22/05/2003
Financial sector technical assistance project 16 19/12/2002
Nepal telecommunications sector reform project 22.56 11/12/2001
Road maintenance and development 54.5 23/11/1999
Total credit (1999-2004) 389.46

Source: World Bank, 2004

In 1964, the World Bank financed a transport survey to help prepare for a five-year

transport sector investment plan. Since 1970, the bank has funded six road projects in

Nepal and the building of suspension bridges in various parts of the country (Table

3.9). These projects have generated economic opportunities in some of Nepal’s

poorest regions. They improved the quality of transportation between Kathmandu and

the rest of the country, as well as strengthening the maintenance capabilities of the

road department.

Table 3.9: Roads and suspension bridges financed by the World Bank,
(1970-2003)
Pedestrian suspension
Road bridges Length (m) bridges Length (m)
Dhobi Khola 45 Kabeli (Phidim) 70
Bishnumati (Balaju) 60 Tamor (Taplejung) 100
Amlekhgung No. 1 62 Kali Gandaki (Purtighat) 80
Amlekhgung No. 2 92 Kali Gandaki (Ranighat) 153
Parwanipur 36 Ulli Khola (Gulmi) 100

Source: NRB, 2003


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 81

The World Bank has been involved in the development of telecommunications in

Nepal since November 1969. A more modern and reliable long-distance network has

been established, helping to bring telecommunication services to rural areas. A

satellite earth station funded by the World Bank has significantly improved the quality

of international telephone services and enabled the introduction of modern services

such as facsimile and data transmissions.

The World Bank has also provided finance for education projects. These have

developed the educational sector in many respects, their major achievements being

institutional development, staff training, building construction, the introduction of

computers and equipments, curriculum and textbook development, and the

introduction of new education programs.

Table 3.10: Some educational projects financed by the World Bank and others,
(1977-2003)
Credit
(US$
Name of the projects Duration million) Co-financer
Institute of Engineering development
project 1977-85 4.7 UK
Western region campus project 1979-87 12 ILO
Primary education 1984-92 8.6
Agricultural manpower project 1985-94 10.9
Engineering education project 1989-99 10 Canada and Switzerland
Higher education project 1994-01 17
Earthquake rehabilitation project 1989-96 23
DANIDA, Norway, Finland
Basic and primary education project 1992-98 30.3 and European Commission
DANIDA, Norway, Finland
Basic and primary education project 1999-03 12.5 and European Commission
Total credit (1977-2003) 129

Source: NRB, 2003


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 82

In the 1980s, the World Bank supported the implementation of the Structural

Adjustment Program. Nepal’s weak institutional capacities, poor governance and

other various problems in the banking, trade and agricultural sectors were identified

as major impediments for economic development. The World Bank’s first SAP was

launched in 1986 with US$ 50 million of credit, for the purpose of implementing

policy reforms. The SAP gave emphasis to sound macroeconomic management,

effective management of public finances, support for the agricultural and light

manufacturing sectors, liberalisation of trade, and reform of public enterprises.

A second structural adjustment was disbursed in 1989 with US$ 60 million credit.

The main aim of this credit was to consolidate and reinforce the earlier one, and also

to revamp the tax system, rationalise the management of development spending,

restructure the two main state-owned commercial banks (Nepal Bank Limited and

Rastriya Banijya Bank) and open up the financial sector, improve the distribution of

fertiliser, and make irrigation more effective. Both the first and second SAPs

programs have had a remarkable impact on the liberalisation of the trade regime and

the financial sector (already discussed in chapter 2).

Recently, the World Bank has begun to focus more on supporting Nepal’s Poverty

Reduction Strategy Paper (PRSP). In November 2003, it approved the Poverty

Reduction Strategy Credit (PRSC) worth US$ 70 million. The credit is intended to

implement measures to revive growth, improve service delivery, improve governance

and promote social inclusion. It also contributes to maintaining a sound

macroeconomic framework and protecting high priority programs by filling part of

Nepal’s financing gap.


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 83

It is believed that Nepal’s PRSP will be more effective through sustainable economic

growth. To stimulate broad based economic growth, the World Bank’s assistance

focuses on removing bottlenecks to growth such as the excessive role of the state and

the lack of adequate infrastructure. According to a report of the World Bank (2003),

its recent assistance to Nepal has focused on strengthening the quality of public

expenditure, the soundness of the financial system, and the investment climate. Also,

the World Bank has been supporting infrastructure projects that help promote

demand-driven irrigation schemes managed by local water user groups, and water

supply schemes, which reduce the time women spend collecting water. (In some parts

of the Nepal, it still takes four to five hours to collect drinking water.)

The International Monetary Fund (IMF)

Nepal became a member of the IMF on 30 September 1961. Details of the latest

financial loans from the IMF are presented in Table 3.10. The Structural Adjustment

Facility (SAF) and Stand-By Arrangement (SBA) were implemented during the 1980s

in conjunction with the World Bank’s Structural Adjustment Programs. These

programs have made significant contributions to economic and trade liberalisation in

Nepal. Based on Nepal’s progress and the government’s commitment to further

reforms, in November 2003 the IMF approved approximately US$ 72 million over

three years to establish the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF).
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 84

Table 3.11: IMF financial arrangements for Nepal, 1985-2003

Program Approved date Expiration Amount approved Amount drawn


date (SDR million) (SDR million)
PRGF 19 Nov 2003 18 Nov 2006 49.91 7.13
PRGF 5 Oct 1992 4 Oct 1995 33.57 16.79
SAF 14 Oct 1987 13 Oct 1990 26.11 26.11
Stand-By 23 Dec 1985 22 Apr 1987 18.65 18.65

Source: IMF, 2003b

Asian Development Bank (ADB)

Nepal was one of the 31 founding members of the ADB, which was established in

1966. The ADB lends to Nepal on highly concessional terms of interest (1.5 per cent

per annum, with loan repayments typically due over 32 years with 8-year grace

periods), from its soft-lending window, the Asian Development Fund (ADF). The first

loan of US$ 6 million was for air transport development, in 1969. Since then, ADB

loans have been increasing to Nepal. They grew by an average of US$ 80 million in

the 1990s. Cumulative ADB lending to Nepal as at 31 December 2003 was about US$

2 billion. 7

7
See on www.adb.org/documents/fact_sheets/NEP.asp.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 85

Table 3.12: ADB sectoral distribution of cumulative lending as at 31 Dec 2003

Sector Loan (numbers) Amount (US$ millions) % of total loan


Agriculture and 52 808.5 38.4
Natural resources
Energy 14 432.4 20.5
Social 19 410.4 19.5
infrastructure
Transport and 13 270.7 12.9
communication
Industry and non- 5 75.1 3.6
fuel minerals
Others 5 100.6 4.8
Finance 1 7.3 0.3
Total 109 2,105.0 100.00
Source: ADB, 2004

Table 3.12 shows that the agricultural sector received a significant share of ADB

loans, accounting for almost 40 per cent of all ADB lending to the country. Over time,

the pattern of ADB lending has changed. While the primary focus was on agriculture

and physical infrastructure up until the 1980s, lending for social infrastructure has

increased considerably in recent years. In the social infrastructure sector, the ADB

financed projects in primary and secondary education, rural water supply and

sanitation, gender and development, and urban management.

3.4 Sectoral distribution of aid

Figure 3.5 shows the sectoral distribution of foreign aid between 1974-83. The

transport and communication including power received the largest share of aid (65 per

cent) in the fiscal year 1974-75, and on average these three sectors received over 50

per cent of total aid during 1974-83. The agriculture sector received the second

highest share of aid followed by the social sector (including rural development). Thus,

until the early 1980s, more amount of aid was used to finance infrastructure. Although
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 86

aid financing increased from around 20 per cent in 1979-80 to almost 29 per cent in

1982-83 in the agriculture sector, the transportation, communication and power

remained main target of aid financing throughout the period.

Figure 3.5: Sectoral distribution of aid as percentage of total aid, 1974-83

80
Agriculture
60
Industry and commerce
40
Trans, power &
20 communication
0 Social services
1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982

Note: social services (including rural development)


Source: Poudyal (1988)

The same trend continued in the 1980s. Among the four sectors, transport, power and

communication received the largest amount of aid, followed by the agriculture and

social sectors (Figure 3.5A). Industry and commerce received the least amount.

However, from 1998 to 2000, a relatively higher amount of aid was allocated to the

social services sector.


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 87

Figure 3.5A: Sectoral distribution of aid as percentage of total aid, 1984-1999

70
60 Agriculture
50
40 Industry and commerce
30
20 Trans, pow er &
communication
10
0 Social services
1984
1985
1986

1987
1988
1989

1990
1991
1992
1993

1994
1995
1996

1997
1998
1999
Note: due to two difference sources of data, we have presented this Figure separately.
Source: CBS, 1991 and 2001

The agricultural sector, providing livelihood to the majority of Nepalese, has been

receiving the second highest amount of aid after the transport, power and

communication sector. In fact, in 1993 it superseded the transport, power and

communication sector. However, its share declined steadily since then, and is now

less than that of the social sector. Thus, there is a clear shift away from agriculture to

the social sector in aid allocation; given the importance and also the backwardness of

agriculture, this may seem a tough choice. Still, the continued dominance of the

transportation, power and communication sector may be linked to the prevalence of

widespread corruption among government officials (see, for example, Knack, 2001;

Mauro, 1995; Tanzi, 1998).


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 88

3.5 Types of aid

3.5.1 Project and program aid

Throughout the 1970s, almost all aid activities in Nepal were linked to projects, such

as financing infrastructure developments in the communication, health, education,

agricultural and rural sectors. By the late 1970s and early 1980s, the modality of aid

disbursement, especially from the World Bank, moved more towards program aid

designed to support policy reforms. Among various reasons for this shift, it was

believed that program aid would be quicker to disburse. Furthermore, it was

recognised that, contrary to expectations, project aid could not prevent fungibility of

aid. The movement towards program aid brought the World Bank and the IMF much

closer operationally. As seen in the previous section, the World Bank provided two

Structural Adjustment Programs followed by the IMF’s SAF and SBA. Nonetheless,

project aid still dominates in Nepal.

3.5.2 Technical cooperation/assistance

Technical cooperation encompasses all kind of assistance to improve the level of

knowledge, skills and technical capabilities of the recipient country. Although the

World Bank uses the terms technical cooperation and technical assistance

interchangeably, the OECD uses separate and distinct definitions. Technical

cooperation (or freestanding technical cooperation) includes activities financed by

donor countries to augment the level of knowledge, skills and productive aptitudes of

the population of developing countries. Technical assistance (or investment-related


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 89

technical cooperation) includes financing the design and/or implementation of project

or programs aimed at increasing the physical capital stock of a recipient country.

Figure 3.6: Technical cooperation as percentage of total aid, 1966-2002

80

60
Technical
40 cooperation % of
total aid
20

0
1966
1969
1972
1975
1978
1981
1984
1987
1990
1993
1996
1999
2002
Source: OECD/IDS online database

As can be seen from Figure 3.6, of the total foreign aid received, technical

cooperation in Nepal accounts for about 35 per cent on average. It was about 70 per

cent in 1969 and now stands at around 30 per cent. Technical assistance can reduce

technological gaps in developing countries by supplying well-trained foreign

personnel who bring new skills, ideas and equipment. These foreign experts may

work together with local people or may provide training to them, transferring those

skills and areas of knowledge required for long-term development.

However, many researchers and agencies have expressed doubts about the

merits of technical cooperation (see, for example, Buyck, 1991; Berg, 1993).

Technical cooperation has been found to be supply driven, with insufficient emphasis

given to the training of local people. Foreign experts get higher salaries and better

facilities than local staff. Recipient countries are often required to hire experts from

donor countries even when local experts are easily available and at a relatively lower
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 90

pay. Furthermore, technical cooperation is provided through loans instead of grants,

and thus creates debt burdens for developing countries (HMG/N, 2002).

3.5.3 Humanitarian and emergency aid

Humanitarian or emergency aid is provided during unfavourable circumstances such

as natural or man-made disasters. The purpose of humanitarian aid is more to save

lives than to achieve economic growth. It can consist of donations of food and other

commodities and services intended solely to help save people in situations of high

risk.

Figure 3.7: Emergency aid as percentage of total aid, 1995-2002

4.5
4
3.5
3
2.5 Emergency aid % of total
2 aid
1.5
1
0.5
0
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002

Note: Earlier data for emergency aid are not available.


Source: OECD/IDS online database

Compared to some African countries, Nepal has received limited amounts of

humanitarian aid, although almost every year it faces natural disasters such as floods

and landslides. However, since 1999, the proportion of humanitarian aid has

increased. As can be seen from Figure 3.7, emergency aid rose to over 4 per cent of

total aid in 2002 from less than 1 per cent in the late 1990s. This is due mainly to
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 91

dislocations caused by increased Maoist violence, and natural disasters such as floods

and landslides.

3.5.4 Food aid

Figure 3.8: Food aid as percentage of total aid, 1975-2001

8
6
4 Food aid % of total aid
2
0
1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

Source: OECD/IDS online database

Food aid was less than 1 per cent of GDP in Nepal during the entire 1975-2001

period. The share of food aid in total aid increased from less than 2 per cent in the late

1970s to over 6 per cent in the early 1980s. It then decreased to less than 1 per cent in

the early 1990s and remained at below 2 per cent for the rest of the period (Figure

3.8).

3.6 Rationale and use of aid

The rationale for foreign aid is found primarily in the two-gap model (reviewed in the

next chapter). That is, aid finances savings–investment and export–import (foreign

exchange) gaps. Any financing gap can be financed by borrowing from domestic

and/or foreign sources. These sources could be non-official (commercial) and/or

official (foreign aid). Commercial sources involve short-term borrowings and foreign
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 92

direct investment. For most developing countries, including Nepal, commercial

sources do not play a major role. Hence, for them foreign aid remains the main source

of financing savings–investment and foreign exchange gaps.

3.6.1 Savings–investment gap

With an average savings/GDP ratio of less than 12 per cent during 1970-2002, it can

be said that Nepal is a low saving country. Its savings rate increased from 10 per cent

in the 1980s to 13 per cent in the 1990s. On the other hand, its average

investment/GDP ratio was 16.6 per cent during 1970-2002. This increased from 17.6

per cent during 1980-90 to 20.2 per cent during 1990-2002. Thus, there is a gap

between savings and investment.

Figure 3.9: Aid and savings–investment gap (GAP) as percentage of GDP,


1970-2002
16

12

4
GAP (SR-IR)
0 AR

-4

-8

-12
1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

Source: IMF/IFS and OECD/IDS online databases

The gap has been widening over the years. In the late 1970s the savings–investment

gap stood at less than 4 per cent of GDP. In the 1980s, it rose to more than 7 per cent

of GDP (see Figure 3.9). During the same period, aid as a percentage of GDP was
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 93

high enough to fill the gap. On average, aid as percentage of GDP was over 8 per cent

during 1970-2002. Hence, the savings–investment gap was almost fully financed by

foreign aid; there were very limited private capital inflows in any form. However, the

aid financing need has declined since the early 1990s with an increase in remittance

income from Nepalese working abroad (Khatiwada, 2003).

3.6.2 Foreign exchange gap

Similarly, we find a very close association between aid/GDP and trade account

deficit/GDP ratios (Figure 3.10). The trade account deficit as a percentage of GDP

increased from less than 4 per cent in the 1970s to over 10 per cent on average in the

late 1980s to 1990s. During the same time frame, aid also increased, from less than 4

per cent of GDP in the 1970s to over 10 per cent in the late 1980s. Since the late

1990s, as foreign aid has declined Nepal has maintained its current account balance

with the overseas workers’ remittances.

Figure 3.10: Aid and trade balance as percentage of GDP, 1970-2002

16

12

0 Aid as % of GDP
Trade balance as % of GDP
-4

-8

-12

-16
1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

Source: IMF/IFS and OECD/IDS online databases


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 94

3.6.3 Government budget deficit

It is generally believed that the savings–investment gap is a result of government

budget deficit. Aid is a major source of financing the budget deficit. Figure 3.11

shows aid and budget deficit trends as percentages of GDP. Until the early 1970s,

average budget deficit was about 1 per cent of GDP. As budget deficit continued to

increase to an average of 9 per cent of GDP in the mid 1980s to the early 1990s,

average aid as a percentage of GDP also increased in the same period to almost 10 per

cent (Figure 3.11). Since the late 1990s, the average budget deficit was maintained at

below 7 per cent of GDP; but the average aid flow was slightly over 7 per cent of

GDP. This difference could be due to statistical factors (they are taken from different

sources). There are other possible reasons too. For example, some aid (especially

emergency aid) may be distributed directly without being recorded in the annual

budget (that is, discretionary off-budget spending). This kind of spending also raises

the possibility of lack of accountability and misuse.

Figure 3.11: Aid and budget deficit as percentage of GDP, 1970-2002

20

15

10

5 Aid as % of GDP
Budget deficit as % of GDP
0

-5

-10
1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

Source: IMF/IFS and OECD/IDS online databases


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 95

In sum, all three indicators – savings–investment gap, foreign exchange gap and

government budget deficit – support the two-gap model. In other words, aid to Nepal

is needed mainly to finance the savings–investment and/or foreign exchange gaps.

Since government budget deficit is the main source of the gaps, there is a close

association between government budget deficit and aid inflows. Foreign aid has been

an important source of funds for government development expenditure. Aid

contributed 55.7 and 56.3 per cent of development expenditure under the Eighth Plan

(1992-93 to 1996-97) and Ninth Plan (1997-98 to 2001-02) respectively (see Paudyal,

2003). Thus, on average, over 50 per cent of development expenditure is financed

through foreign aid in Nepal.


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 96

3.7 Micro issues of foreign aid

3.7.1 Aid conditionality and country ownership

Conditionality plays an important role in aid effectiveness. During the 1980s and

1990s conditional lending and aid grants in exchange for policy reform and structural

adjustment significantly increased, due largely to the approach of the World Bank and

the IMF. While the approach changed the traditional aid-financed investment towards

a strategy of aid-induced economic reforms, it also ensured that aid inflows are used

for the intended purpose and hence for the benefit of recipient countries. Despite the

mixed results and many criticisms of aid conditionality, access to aid has been made

contingent upon the adoption of appropriate policy framework through the imposition

of conditionality. 8 Critics of conditionality based aid often point out that recipient

countries usually lack commitment to implement imposed policy reforms. They may

agree to reforms at the time of financial difficulties when they seek donor assistance;

but as soon as the situation improves with the disbursement of aid, many of the

reforms are either reversed or delayed (see, for example, Darzen, 2002 and Boughton,

2003). The Nepal Development Forum meeting held in Paris in April 2000 pointed

out the lack of country ownership as one of the main reasons for the slow

implementation of reforms (Foreign Aid Policy 2002).

In addition to the lack of country ownership, the number of reforms needed to fulfil

the conditionality within the set time frame is often found beyond a country’s

8
See Sachs (1997), Leandro et al. (1999), and Stiglitz (2002) for more discussion about the
effectiveness of the World Bank and the IMF programs. For the effectiveness of conditionality, Killick
(1997) noted, “ in the general case, conditionality is not an effective means of improving economic
policies in recipient countries” (1997: 493).
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 97

administrative and institutional capacity. For example, conditionality includes

macroeconomic reforms (e.g., reducing budget deficits, devaluation, reducing

domestic subsided credit expansion), and other structural conditions such as freeing

controlled prices, reducing trade barriers and privatisation of public enterprises. All

together there are 18 reforms to be implemented within 3 to 4 months (mid November

2004-mid January 2005). See appendix 3.1 for details.

More importantly, these conditions create a sequencing problem for the efficient

implementation. If appropriate sequencing is not considered, conditions may

contradict each other and the expected benefits from the reforms may not flow. For

example, the Asian financial crisis has revealed that regulatory mechanism should

have been strengthened before liberalising the financial sector. Thus, as argued by

Boughton (2003), well-sequenced fewer conditions are more likely to succeed in

achieving their objectives.

Although conditionality induced policy reforms may yield benefits in the long-run,

they often have short-term costs due to the problems mentioned above. For example,

in Nepal increasing the price of petroleum products, dropping subsidies in fertiliser,

privatising public enterprises and increasing VAT rates had adverse effects on

agriculture, employment and business confidence. As a result, conditionality induced

policy reforms faced political resistance, which added fuel to political instability, and

in turn economic instability. The government has been forced to slow down the pace

of privatisation due to political pressure as it caused widespread unemployment.


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 98

Nepal also had to deal with political unrest following the rise of prices of petroleum

products, increase in VAT rates and removal of subsidies. 9

One of the visible weaknesses of these Structural Adjustment Programs in Nepal is

that they failed to have a significant impact on poverty reduction. In other words,

policy reforms did not promote investment in the agriculture sector. Increased

agricultural investment is needed to improve agricultural growth and productivity,

which play a crucial role in poverty reduction.

3.7.2 Fungibility of aid

If donor and recipient policy preferences differ substantially, aid finance is more

likely to be converted to fungible resources (see the literature review in the next

chapter). When aid is fungible, it tends to increase government spending on projects

not intended by donors. As the World Bank noted, “If aid financing is fungible, the

benefits of an aid-financed project are only loosely connected with the actual benefits

of aid financing” (1998: 60). In the case of Nepal, the World Bank (2000) in its Public

Expenditure Review noted that Nepal’s development budget tends to be over-

programmed because foreign aid is easily available to finance over 50 per cent of

development expenditure. Due to political reasons, the government often approves

projects that are generally less important in terms of socio-economic return. In the

majority of cases as discussed in section 3.4, capital-intensive projects are financed by

foreign aid, which do not contribute significantly to employment generation and

9
See IMF (2003) for an assessment of the pace of reforms. IMF (2003) noted that the pace of reform
and implementation were slow because of Nepal’s political instability. The Nepal Development Forum
meeting held in Paris in April 2000 also pointed out the lack of country ownership.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 99

poverty reduction. On the other hand, capital-intensive projects are generally believed

to encourage corruption through tendering and procurement processes. Furthermore,

if a significant portion of aid goes to finance non-traded sector, then aid may retard

economic growth in recipient countries. Yano and Nugent (1999) found evidence of

this in Nepal.

3.7.3 Coordination between donors and recipients

Aid effectiveness also depends on cooperation and coordination among donors,

between donors and recipient government departments, and among government

departments. For example, Nepal receives aid from more than 20 bilateral and 11

multilateral donors (see Table 3.2). Each donor has its own strategy and priority for

the development of Nepal, which may contradict the stance of other donors. If there is

no mutual understanding between donors about the needs of Nepal, it may result in a

resource gap in some priority sectors. On the other hand, there could be a glut of aid

projects in some sectors.

Similarly, the lack of coordination among different government departments also

reduces the effectiveness of aid. Thus, aid resources can be wastefully used. Nepal’s

Foreign Aid Policy 2002 pointed out, “aid coordination has become a burdensome

and cumbersome task” (2002: 6). Time-consuming procedures involved in

channelling aid from one department to another may make some donors move their

aid package somewhere else, and it may also lead to delays in the disbursement of aid

in subsequent years.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 100

Donor competition in hiring staff from government departments for project

management also creates problems. As Knack has suggested, “Foreign aid can also

weaken the state bureaucracies of recipient governments. This can occur most directly

by siphoning away scarce talent from the civil service, as donor organisations often

hire away the most skilled public officials at salaries many times greater than those

offered by the recipient-nation government” (2001: 313).

3.7.4 Tied aid

Aid may be tied through use of formal and informal restrictions. If a donor’s motive is

to promote home exports, tying aid may distort the economy of the recipient country

(Hjertholm and White, 2000). Generally, under tied aid, more capital-intensive goods

and services and technically advanced products are imported, which may not be

appropriate for the recipient country. Under tied aid recipient countries cannot take

advantage of competition from international markets to obtain the most suitable

sources of supply. In some cases, overseas technicians or experts take back almost all

of the given aid money. Furthermore, aid financed projects employ foreign

technology without making use of local technical knowledge. Recipient countries

cannot afford to maintain such projects in the long-run; they thus become financial

burdens.

3.7.5 Absorptive capacity

Aid effectiveness also depends on the absorptive capacity of recipient countries.

Donors should have good information about whether a recipient country is able to use
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 101

aid to generate economic growth and in turn reduce poverty. Knack (2001) found that

a higher level of aid erodes the quality of governance, which is measured by indices

of bureaucratic quality, corruption and the rule of law. When foreign aid started

pouring into Nepal after 1951, its absorptive capacity was so poor that it was unable

to direct aid finances effectively. It was entirely dependent on donors’ perceptions and

thus it had almost no control over foreign aid (Stiller and Yadav, 1979). Since 1951,

Nepal improved its absorptive capacity but not as much as is necessary. It still lacks a

quality institutional framework and efficient service delivery. Its weak institutions and

inappropriate policies have been the main obstacles to its ability to absorb aid

effectively. As is the case in other developing countries, Nepal does not have an

appropriate and effective mechanism to evaluate foreign technology and so in some

projects it has had to depend entirely on foreign technology and experts.

3.7.6 Foreign aid policy

Due to a lack of coherent foreign aid policy, for over 50 years Nepal failed to address

the above microeconomic issues of aid effectiveness. Until very recently, Nepal did

not have a government department designated to undertake regular supervision,

coordination and evaluation of aid financed projects. The cost of incoherent policy

can be very high; Nepal has already paid this cost being an aid dependent country. Up

until recently, aid to Nepal was always donor driven; it was always based on donor

motives and perceptions. For the first time, Nepal is counteracting this tendency

through the new policy framework called Foreign Aid Policy 2002.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 102

The policy highlights the various aid issues facing Nepal. It discusses the significance,

problems and prospects of aid to Nepal. It reviews past performance and current

problems associated with the national and donor perspectives. It introduces new

guidelines, strategies and policies for better aid utilisation. It appeals to donors to

develop mutual understanding about aid effectiveness, to appreciate Nepal’s particular

constraints such as widespread poverty, high rate of population growth, and

geography (land locked, mountainous terrain).

Foreign Aid Policy 2002 recognises that Nepal has failed to maximise the benefits of

past foreign assistance. Despite an increasing level of aid, its overall economic

performance has not improved. The lack of institutional capacity, appropriate

planning and management, timely supervision and evaluation of projects and

programs impede its development efforts. More importantly, Nepal’s absorptive

capacity remains weak. Differences persist between national needs and donors’

priorities, and projects and programs are largely donor driven. The difficulties in

matching donors’ perceptions with Nepal’s particular needs has perhaps reduced the

effectiveness of aid. A further problem has been that many aid inflows have not been

recorded in the government budget. Foreign Aid Policy 2002 addresses this by

highlighting the importance of efficient and effective accountability in the use of

foreign resources.
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 103

3.8 Foreign debt burden

A substantial part of foreign aid goes to servicing foreign debt. As can be seen from

Figure 3.12, Nepal’s external debt burden has been increasing. Foreign debt rose from

about 2-3 per cent of GDP in the early 1970s to nearly 60 per cent of GDP in the late

1990s.

Figure 3.12: Foreign debt as percentage of GDP, 1970-2001

70
60
50
40 Foreign debt as percentage
30 of GDP
20
10
0
70

73

76

79

82

85

88

91

94

97

00
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

20

Source: IMF/IFS online database

To maintain debt servicing, a high growth rate of exports is essential for borrower

countries. If exports grow faster than debt, a borrowing country does not have to fully

depend on grant aid and further capital inflows to service its debts. In the case of

Nepal, due to the narrow base and direction of exports (items are limited to garments,

woollen carpets and the like, going to India, United States and Germany and a few

other countries), export earning capacity is very weak and low.

The actual burden of foreign debt can be seen by considering debt service payments

(loan repayments together with interest) as a ratio of total exports of goods and

services. While Nepal’s debt service payment, as a ratio of total export of goods and
Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 104

services, was less than 1 per cent until the late 1970s, it increased to 10 per cent in

1990, but declined to 6 per cent on average throughout the 1990s, remaining the same

in 2001. On the other hand, the total external debt/total export ratio rose from 63 per

cent in 1979-80 to 395 per cent in 1990-91, and stood at 207 per cent in 2001 (Bhatta,

2003).

The increasing burden of debt service has been hampering development efforts in

Nepal, mainly by curtailing investment in social services and infrastructure. Since the

mid 1990s, the annual average external debt service alone consumed nearly 13 per

cent of government revenue, which was almost more than 14 per cent of regular

expenditure, and about 8 per cent of the total government expenditure (Bhatta, 2003).

3.9 Concluding remarks

This chapter has provided a comprehensive overview of aid flows to Nepal. Nepal

receives aid from more than 20 bilateral and 11 multilateral donors. Among the

bilateral donors Japan has been the largest donor followed by Germany, United

Kingdom and USA. The ADB and IDA (World Bank) have been major multilateral

donors to Nepal. Foreign aid has played a significant role in meeting the savings-

investment gaps and financing the government’s development expenditure. Foreign

aid has also been crucial for alleviating Nepal’s foreign exchange constraint. Thus,

much of the achievements of Nepal during the last three decades in socio-economic

development can be attributed to donor assistance. Some of the salient features of

foreign aid to Nepal during 1960-2002 can be summarised as follows:


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 105

• Average aid/GDP ratio increased from almost 2 per cent in the 1960s to

around 10 per cent in the 1990s.

• Average share of bilateral aid in total aid decreased from almost 97 per cent in

the 1960s to 60 per cent in the 1990s.

• Average share of grants aid in total aid decreased from almost 100 per cent in

the 1960s to around 67 per cent in the 1990s.

• Average aid/government total expenditure ratio increased from around 30 per

cent in the 1960s to almost 80 per cent in the late 1980s and remained around

40 per cent in the 1990s.

• Average aid/revenue ratio increased from less then 80 per cent in the 1960s to

over 100 per cent throughout the 1980s and 1990s; but it decreased to around

62 per cent in 2001.

• A larger proportion of aid has been used to build infrastructure, which is

generally regarded as non-tradeable. However, infrastructure assists the

tradeable sector.

• Nepal’s savings-investment and foreign exchange gaps has been fully financed

by foreign aid

Having discussed the role of aid in Nepal, next we analyse econometrically the impact

of aid on the Nepalese economy in chapter 6, 7 and 8.


Chapter 3: Foreign Aid to Nepal: An Historical Perspective 106

Appendix 3.1: Reform conditions imposed by the IMF under the PRGF
arrangements

Prior action for first review


(1) Implements VRS (voluntary retirement scheme) at the Rastriya Banijya Bank
(RBB) (Phase II)

Structural performance criteria


(1) Implement time-bound action plan to improve custom administration (timing-
Nov. 15, 2004 and Jan. 15, 2005)
(2) Fully operationalise the large tax payer office in the Inland Revenue Department
(timing- Nov. 15, 2004 and Jan. 15, 2005)
(3) Implement new framework for monetary operations, including a liquidity
monitoring framework (timing-Nov. 15, 2004)

Financial sector reforms


(1) Finalise audit of Nepal Rastra Bank’s (NRB) 2003/04 accounts by an international
auditor (timing-Jan.15, 2005)
(2) Strengthen the NRB (provide for compulsory retirement scheme in NRB
employee rules and regulations) (timing-Nov.15, 2004)

Public sector reform


(1) Finalise audit of Nepal Oil Corporation (NOC) 2003/04 accounts by international
auditor (timing- Feb. 15, 2005)
(2) Implement automatic pricing mechanism for oil products (timing-Dec. 31, 2004)

Structural benchmarks
(1) Cabinet approval of Fiscal Transparency Ordinance (timing- Jan. 15, 2005)
(2) Amend BFI ordinance including for consistency with other legislation (timing-
Feb. 15, 2005)
(3) Cabinet approval of Asset Management Companies Ordinance (timing-Jan. 15,
2005)
(4) Strengthen the NRB (revise human resource policies) (timing-Nov. 15, 2004)
(5) Prepare a time bound action plan to strength Financial Management and Internal
Audit Department of NRB (timing-Nov. 15, 2004)
(6) Implement restructuring plans for Agricultural Development Bank (ADBN) and
Nepal Industrial Development Corporation (NIDC) (timing- Nov. 15, 2004 and Jan.
15, 2005)
(7) Adopt Petroleum Products Sale and Distribution Ordinance (timing-Feb. 15, 2005)
(8) Complete liquidation/privatisation of five SOEs (timing- Nov. 15, 2004 and Jan.
15, 2005)
(9) Cabinet approval of amended Civil Service Ordinance (timing-Nov. 15, 2004)
(10) NRB to reconcile accounting data with program monitoring data (Quarterly test
date)
Notes: (a) See further IMF (2004) for the Quantitative Performance Criteria and Indicative Targets
(b) The World Bank also imposes conditions separately under PRSP. See World Bank
(2003b)
Chapter 4

Review of the Literature

“In the broadest sense… most aid does indeed ‘work’. It succeeds in achieving its
developmental objectives… contributing positively to the recipient countries’ economic
performance, and not substituting for activities which would have occurred anyway. That is
not to say that aid works in every count. Its performance varies by country and by sector. On
the criterion of relieving poverty, even the aid which achieves its objectives cannot be
considered fully satisfactory… [T]he relief of poverty depends both on aid and on the policies
of the recipient countries – a collaboration in which aid is definitely the junior partner. And
there is a substantial fraction of aid which does not work… Further, bilateral donors often
have political and commercial motives for aid, which can interfere with developmental
objectives. When these motives predominate, the results can be harmful to growth and to the
poor”(Cassen and Associates, 1994: 7).

4.1 Introduction

From World War II to date, the main goal of most developing countries has been to

achieve rapid economic growth. Foreign aid has provided a major source of finance

for developing countries trying to achieve this goal. For example, in some countries

aid as a share of government revenue has been more than 50 per cent (Sevensson,

1997). However, many of them have failed to improve their condition. There have

been extensive studies of the impact of aid on economic growth, and the findings

remain mixed.

Many researchers have attributed the failure of aid financed development to the lack

of good policy environment and poor governance. This has led donors to devise

conditional lending, known as program aid. Program aid is given to support the

recipient government’s budget on the condition that the government carry out

“growth-promoting” policy reforms and improve governance.1 Aid is disbursed in

1
Growth promoting policies are generally regarded as market friendly and less state intervention.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 108

tranches upon “satisfactory” policy reforms. However, many other researchers believe

that the very conditionality is the cause of aid failure. They argue that reform agenda

lacks country ownership as they are imposed by the donors. As a result, they face

political resistance. Moreover, the sequence and pace of reforms may not suit a

particular country’s condition. Reviewing the merits of conditional lending, Easterly

(2003: 38) has expressed doubts about the effectiveness of selectivity in aid

allocation. He has characterised the imposition of conditions as “no more than a

wistful hope, rather than a policy with consequences” in circumstances where “a

nation will selectively receive aid if it is a ‘good performer’ – unless it is a bad

performer, in which case it will receive aid from the ‘bad performer’ fund.” Easterly

(2003) has also argued that donors are as much responsible for the past failure of aid

as recipients. According to him, donors are judged by the amount of money spent and

hence are driven by the desire to “move money”. 2 This creates potential moral hazard

and incentive problems for both donors and recipients. He has, therefore, emphasised

the need for independent evaluations of aid-funded projects as recommended by the

Meltzer Commission (2000).

However, in this survey, we cover two aspects of the literature. First, we review the

main body of literature concerning aid effectiveness in terms of economic growth, and

related to this, the impact of aid on savings and investment. Second, since aid is

channeled through the government and government’s fiscal position has implications

for domestic savings and investment, we survey the studies that have examined the

impact of aid on government revenue and expenditure.

2
According to Easterly, Judith Tendler observation as far back in 1975 that “A donor organisation’s
sense of mission … relates not necessarily to economic development but to the commitment of
resources, the moving of money…” remains valid even today.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 109

4.2 Aid, economic growth, savings and investment

The first formal argument in favour of foreign aid was given by Rosenstein-Rodan

(1961). He argued that aid was required to change countries from economic

stagnation to self-sustaining economic growth. He believed that each dollar of foreign

resources in the form of aid would result in an increase of one dollar in total savings

and hence investment. McKinnon (1964) calls this the “classical view”. 3 Rosenstein-

Rodan extensively investigated the use of capital inflow and its requirements in

underdeveloped countries. Aid should be continued, he believed, until

underdeveloped countries could mobilise a level of capital formation sufficient for

self-sustaining growth. However, he argued that foreign capital inflow should be

within the limit of absorptive capacity of the developing countries.

Chenery and his associates (Chenery and Bruno, 1962; Adelman and Chenery, 1966;

Chenery and Strout, 1966) stressed that many goods have strategic importance in

efficient industrial growth but cannot be produced domestically in the early stages of

development. According to them, foreign aid can have a large favourable impact on

growth rate when such bottleneck is binding. 4 McKinnon (1964) calls this the

“modern view”. 5

Chenery and his associates identified three phases of development, and, based on an

extended Harrod–Domar growth model, argued that the stage of growth determines

3
Johnson (1958) held a similar view that foreign investment directly adds to domestic savings and
hence lifts the investment rate.
4
A similar view was held by Manne (1963).
5
McKinnon (1964) constructed a growth model of the Harrod-Domar type to illustrate the ideas of
Chenery and his associates. In particular, a general framework is given for evaluating the “pay-off” in
terms of economic growth of foreign transfers under different values of savings and export parameters.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 110

the size of the existing savings–investment gap. During the first phase, due to the

shortage of financial resources, investment levels are below the rate required to

achieve targeted growth. Aid can be used to fill the gap between available savings and

investment required to meet the targeted growth.

During the second phase, a trade gap appears, as export earnings are insufficient to

finance required imports of capital equipment and raw materials. Hence, foreign aid is

needed to finance imports. During the third phase, although the savings–investment

gap would disappear, due to structural rigidities the foreign exchange gap would

continue requiring aid to finance imports. Because of aid’s role in filling the savings–

investment and exports–imports gaps, the model developed by Chenery and his

associates has come to be known as the two-gap model.6

The two-gap model has been tested by a number of economists and policy makers

because of its path-breaking nature. For example, Rahman (1968) used the same

cross-sectional data that Chenery and Strout used for 31 less developed countries in

1962, and then ran a least squares regression of the savings ratio on the ratio of capital

inflows to GNP. Rahman found support for Haavelmo’s (1963) hypothesis that in a

developing country domestic savings is not only a function of national income but is

6
The idea of the two-gap model was first developed by Chenery and Bruno (1962) in the context of
Israel. Adelman and Chenery (1966) applied the idea to Greece. Then Chenery and Strout (1966)
formally developed the two-gap model to link aid to economic growth at different stages of
development. They used data from 31 developing countries to identify their stages of development and
to determine their needs for foreign assistance. The model was illustrated by using the example of
Pakistan’s transition.
The two-gap model was criticised on the grounds that it ignores the substitution possibilities between
imports of consumption and investment goods, and between domestic savings and foreign exchange.
The critics argue that developing countries should be able to transform surplus domestic resources into
export production to earn foreign exchange. But as Thirlwall (1983: 295) has noted, “If it were that
easy, the question might well be posed, why do most developing countries suffer from chronic balance
of payments deficits over long periods despite vast reserves of unemployed resources?”
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 111

also related inversely to the inflow of foreign capital. Thus, domestic savings may fall

if capital inflow is very large. These results appeared to challenge the assumption of

the models of Chenery and his associates that foreign capital is used only for

augmenting investment and not as a substitute for domestic savings.

Griffin (1970) also found evidence that contradicted the two-gap model. He argued

that aid was a substitute for savings, and hence a large part of foreign capital was used

to increase consumption rather than investment. Griffin raised the issue of fungibility

of aid. He argued that the government might increase public consumption with

increased foreign capital inflows by changing the composition of its expenditure. At

the same time, the easy availability of foreign aid might discourage the government

from taking steps to mobilise domestic resources. He further claimed that foreign

capital inflows financed the capital-intensive projects. This increased the capital-

output ratio in the economy. Based on an ordinary least squares (OLS) regression

analysis of data from 32 underdeveloped countries for the period 1962-64, Griffin

concluded that aid did not contribute to economic growth; instead aid was associated

with a drop in savings.

As in the case of his first study, in a second study with Enos, Griffin found a

significant negative association between aid and growth. Griffin and Enos (1970)

argued that instead of contributing to growth, aid could lower growth because it was

substantially motivated by the politics of donors. Their regression analysis of data

from 15 African and Asian countries for the period 1962-64 showed that there was no

close association between the amount of aid received and the rate of growth of GNP.

In the same study Griffin and Enos even found that average economic growth was
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 112

inversely related to the ratio of foreign aid to GNP in 12 Latin American countries for

the period 1957-64. They further found that an extra dollar of aid was associated with

a rise in consumption of about 75 cents, and a rise in investment of only about 25

cents. They concluded that while aid could lower savings, it might also retard long-

run economic growth by distorting the composition of investment. 7 However, Griffin

and Enos were aware of the limitations of their studies due to methodological and data

problems, some of which were later highlighted by their critics. 8

Kennedy and Thirlwall (1971) rejected the claim made by Griffin (1970), and Griffin

and Enos (1970) that foreign aid reduces domestic savings, and increases

consumption rather than investment. Commenting on Griffin (1970), they noted, “…..

a reduction in domestic saving is not a necessary concomitant of increased capital

imports, and even if it was this would not be a sufficient condition for rejecting capital

imports if consumption is a desirable or productive activity” (1971: 137). The

government might divert foreign assistance to public consumption expenditure such

as on education and health, which may have high positive return. They argued that

over all capital-output ratio might fall even though some particular capital-intensive

projects were financed by foreign capital. According to them, the negative regression

7
Yano and Nugent (1999) found that aid financed over expansion of non-traded sector may cause
growth immiseration. This study will be reviewed later in this chapter.
8
Weisskopf (1972) examined the relationship between foreign capital inflows and domestic savings for
a sample of 44 underdeveloped countries, using time-series data for the post-war period (at least seven
years). Weisskopf hypothesised that the level of domestic savings would be behaviourally related to the
level of net foreign capital inflows. Weisskopf’s conclusion was consistent with those of Rahman
(1968) and Griffin and Enos (1970), which both found that the impact of foreign capital inflows on
domestic savings in underdeveloped countries was significantly negative. Voivodas (1973), in a
simplified version of the two-gap model, found no significant relationship between the inflows of
foreign capital and the rate of growth of GDP. Voivodas used pooled data for 22 developing countries.
Critiques attributed his result to two violations of the underlying assumption of the two-gap model. The
first was the spill-over effect of foreign capital inflows on domestic consumption, ignored by the two-
gap model. The second was the assumption of a fixed capital–output ratio.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 113

result between foreign capital and domestic savings implies that foreign assistance is

given on the basis of recipient’s low savings.

In line with Kennedy and Thirlwall (1971), Stewart (1971) also criticised Griffin’s

views of foreign aid and domestic savings. She argued that in developing countries

while some forms of consumption expenditure (e.g., on health and education) may

increase growth, some forms of investment expenditure (e.g., in luxury goods

industries) might have a little impact on development. Thus, for the negative

relationship between domestic savings and foreign capital inflows, she noted, “the

regressions Griffin quotes show the relationship between current account of the

balance of payments and domestic savings and cannot be interpreted as a guide to the

impact of long term capital on domestic savings”(1971: 141). She argued that Griffin

had wrongly hypothesised that current account deficit (matched by capital flows in the

form of aid) caused lower savings. Rather the correct causality should be from low

savings to higher current account deficits and hence higher aid.

Eshag (1971), too, pointed out some internal inconsistencies in Griffin’s model. For

example, according to Eshag, Griffin’s results are due to implicit assumption of full

employment of resources and their flexible uses. In this framework, savings is the

only constraint on investment. Eshag wondered how consumption could rise if aid did

not increase income or output. According to him, this could happen if aid was in the

form of consumption goods, distributed free of charge like “dole”.

Papanek (1972) criticised Griffin’s view that aid leads to increased consumption

instead of domestic savings. Papanek acknowledged that so-called “revisionist”


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 114

contributions were useful in challenging overly optimistic views of the positive

benefits of foreign capital inflows. He also pointed out that as long as the effect of an

additional unit of foreign resources on investment is less than one, its effect on

savings would appear to be negative.

Papanek further argued that the negative statistical relationship between savings and

foreign inflows could be partly attributed to an accounting convention and might not

be a behavioural relationship. For example, if food aid is distributed to the poor,

domestic savings and investment may not be affected by the given food aid. However,

the accounting system could show a decline in savings because poor people consumed

in excess of their income. Thus, Papanek argued that developing countries with lower

economic growth and mass poverty are likely to receive a higher proportion of aid

that might increase consumption rather than investment. In addition, he noted, “as

long as both savings and foreign inflows are substantially affected by third factors

[such as natural disaster], the negative correlation between the two found in many

studies sheds little or no light on their causal relationship”(1972: 950).

In many studies, researchers simply ignored the different components of foreign

resources and used aggregate amount to investigate the relationship between foreign

aid and domestic savings. This might be a source of misleading conclusions.

Therefore, Papanek (1973) disaggregated all capital inflows into three components:

foreign aid, foreign private investment and all other inflows, in his cross-country

regression analyses of 34 countries in the 1950s and 51 countries in the 1960s. He

found that all inflows had a statistically significant positive effect on growth, but more

importantly, aid affects growth significantly more than any other factors.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 115

Newlyn (1973) attempted to reconcile the findings of Papanek and those of Rahman

and Griffin and Enos. He argued that “only if consumption grants are inappropriately

treated as capital items will the confusion cited by Papanek arise”. He added: “[T]he

confusion would be due to inappropriate specification of capital inflows rather than to

any characteristics inherent in the accounting convention in relation to behaviour”

(1973: 867). Newlyn further demonstrated that while negative values between 0 and 1

of regression parameters would normally mean a reduction in the dependent variable,

in this case national resources used for investment to promote growth, no such

implication could be drawn in the aid–savings context. Only if the negative parameter

value exceeds unity can it be concluded that aid leads to an absolute reduction in the

total amount of resources being used for investment.

Stoneman (1975) was critical of studies by both the “revisionists” and their critiques

for failing to distinguish between two main effects of foreign transfers. They are (a)

the balance of payments effect, and (b) the structural change effect. The former refers

to higher investment and consumption made possible by higher imports with the help

of foreign inflows. The later refers to the influence of foreign inflows on exports,

capital-output ratio and income distribution. Stoneman used cross section data from

188 countries between the period 1955 and 1970 and applied OLS method to test his

model. He assumed that economic growth depended on gross domestic investment,

net inflow of direct investment, net inflow of foreign aid and other foreign long-term

flows, and the stock of foreign direct investment. Stoneman found support for the

positive relationship between foreign aid and economic growth. However, he was

aware of the possibility of a non-linear relationship between foreign transfers and

economic growth, and concluded that “… we can offer no opinion on the possibility
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 116

that there is an initially favorable impact of foreign investment on growth, say up to

twenty percent of GNP, after which further domination has a negative effect”

(Stoneman, 1975: 18). 9

Over Jr. (1975) was critical of Griffin and Enos’ use of OLS technique and believed

that their work suffered from serious simultaneity bias. Therefore, he replicated

Griffin and Enos’ study by using the same data set; but instead of OLS, Over Jr. used

2SLS. In the system of equations, aid was first taken as a function of investment

levels (or savings); then savings was taken as a function of the fitted aid values from

the first equation. Based on his findings, Over Jr. rejected the claims of Griffin and

Enos (as well as of Weisskopf) and concluded, “…aid complements growth – and

even elicits an additional matching increase in the domestic savings rate” (Over Jr.,

1975: 755).

Gupta (1975) in a cross-country analysis of 40 developing countries attempted to re-

examine the debate between the revisionist (mainly of Rahman, Griffin, Enos) and

orthodox (e.g., Papanek) views on the savings-aid and growth-aid relationships by

taking the direct and indirect effects of foreign aid. Following the critiques of the

revisionists, the savings rate was assumed to depend, among other variables, on per

capita GDP, growth and foreign capital inflows. The indirect effect of foreign inflows

on savings rate was modeled by assuming that foreign inflows affect growth

positively which, in turn, affects savings. He claimed that the sign of the total (direct

plus indirect) affect cannot be determined a priori.

9
Later studies, to be reviewed, explicitly modelled the possibility of a non-linear relation and estimated
the optimal aid-GNP ratio.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 117

Thus, Gupta (1975) is the first known study to model the simultaneity between

savings and growth where both are affected by foreign inflows. As Over Jr. (1975),

Gupta used 2SLS, and the estimates revealed that foreign inflows affect savings rate

negatively (the direct effect), but growth rate positively (the indirect effect). The total

effect of foreign capital on savings rate was found to be negative. This result may

appear puzzling: if foreign inflows affect savings (and hence investment rate)

negatively then growth should be affected negatively as well. However, Gupta’s

findings can be justified if foreign inflows do not completely crowd out (offset)

domestic savings, and hence there would still be a net increase in total investible

resources. This is exactly what Newlyn (1973) said when he was trying to reconcile

the two different views on foreign aid.

Following Papanek (1973), Gupta also disaggregated foreign inflows into three

different components: foreign aid, foreign private investment and other foreign

inflows (e.g., short-term borrowings). He found the same results as in the model with

aggregate foreign inflows. That is, all the disaggregated components affect savings

negatively, but growth positively. In contrast to Papanek’s findings, Gupta also found

that the effect of aid was the least among the three components.

Thus, it seems that the earlier studies (1960s and 1970s) do not show a consensus on

the positive effects of aid. Contrary to the optimistic view, a number of studies found

that aid and other inflows reduced domestic savings and helped increase consumption.

Others argue (e.g. Stewart, Thirlwall and Papanek) that it is possible for aid to

associate negatively with savings. This happens as aid is given on the basis of needs

determined by low per capita income and low savings. Additionally, food aid, which
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 118

is supposed to increase consumption, could be negatively related to savings. 10 So too

could emergency relief aid designed to help with shocks and disasters. These types of

aid are not intended to maximise growth. Hence, any careful study of aid

effectiveness should distinguish between different types of aid. Any aid-growth study

must also recognise that the impact of aid on growth may take a longer period to be

detected econometrically.

Mosley (1980) performed a two-stage least squares regression (2SLS) with a sample

of 83 less developed countries for the period 1969-77. The model and methodology of

this study is very similar to Gupta (1975). In the model, level of development was

assumed to depend on savings, aid and other foreign capital inflows. Aid, in turn, was

assumed to depend on level of development. Thus, he hypothesised that aid

influenced and was influenced by a country’s level of development. Mosley (1980) is

the first study to recognise that the impact of aid might take some time to be noticed,

and hence used lagged response of GNP to aid. Mosley found a significant negative

correlation between aid and GNP per capita. However, when he divided samples into

30 poorest countries and 53 middle-income countries, he found a different result. In

the poorest country group, Mosley found that aid was positively correlated to growth,

if aid was lagged five years; but in the case of middle-income countries, he found that

aid was negatively correlated to growth.

Gupta and Islam (1983) used a sample of 52 developing countries for the periods of

1950-60 and 1965-73. The sample countries were divided into three different income

10
Some argued that even food aid might disrupt domestic production and distribution, making a
country more dependent on aid than before (Linear, 1985).
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 119

groups (based on 1973 per capita income) and three geographic regions (Asia, Africa

and Latin America). As in Gupta (1975), Gupta and Islam analysed direct and indirect

impacts of foreign capital inflows with a wide variety of social and structural

variables. They specified and estimated a simultaneous equations model in which the

savings rate and the growth rate affect each other, and both are affected by foreign

inflows. They also decomposed the aggregate foreign capital into three components:

foreign aid, foreign private investment and other inflows. While they found a positive

relationship between foreign aid and economic growth, they concluded that domestic

savings played a more important role in augmenting growth.

Dowling and Hiemenz (1983) found a significant and positive relationship between

aid and economic growth. Their study was based on a sample of 52 developing

countries over the period 1968-79. They further divided the total sample into high-

growth (31) and low-growth countries (21). They used an extended version of the

model applied by Papanek (1973) and Mosley (1980). The differences were that they

added four policy variables designed to express different aspects of government

policy in each country. Thus, Dowling and Hiemenz pioneered the study that

examines the role of policy environment in aid effectiveness. 11

These policy variables were: (1) degree of openness of the economy (expressed by

exports plus imports, both net of oil as a proportion of GDP); (2) the role of

government in domestic resources mobilisation (measured by central government tax

revenue as percentage of GDP); (3) the share of public sector in economic activities

11
In later studies, Boone (1996) and Burnside and Dollar (1997) concluded that aid does not work in an
environment of “bad” policies. This has been used to justify aid disbursement based on policy reforms.
Boone and Burnside-Dollar studies will be reviewed later in the chapter.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 120

(measured by total government expenditure in GDP); and (4) a measure of financial

repression (M2/GDP). They found that, especially in the high-growth countries, some

of these policies have positively influenced the aid–growth relationship. In particular,

liberal trade and financial policies improved overall growth performance in the case

of high-growth countries. In the case of slow-growth countries, only liberal trade

policies played an important role in explaining income growth with improvements in

government tax revenue. The share of government expenditure in GDP was not found

to have a significant impact on growth in either group of countries.

The Intergovernmental Task Force commissioned a study by Cassen and Associates

(1986) to assess the impact of aid. 12 Cassen and Associates found that aid could work

positively in recipient countries. They qualified this by arguing that if appropriate aid

was provided in a satisfactory policy context and if all other components of growth

were in place, then the statistical relationship between aid and growth would be

positive. In other words, aid did not work in every country; rather its performance

varied by country and sector. They further argued that the effectiveness of aid

depended on different components and sources of aid. In particular, they found that

bilateral aid was more politically and commercially motivated than multilateral aid,

and hence could have some harmful effect on growth.

Cassen and Associates also mentioned the importance of coordination and

management. For example, misunderstanding can often exist between official

agencies and non-government organisations. As a result, their work does not

12
This task force was the initiative of the donor countries, and the World Bank acted as the secretariat.
Cassen and Associate updated their work in 1994, and their conclusions remain more or less the same
as their 1986 study.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 121

contribute to any coherent set of activities; nor do they coherently complement

development activities undertaken within the country. Cassen and Associates reported

a proliferation of aid-funded projects, initiated here and there in an almost haphazard

way.

This creates what they described as “aid-overload”, that is, aid flows beyond the

administrative and management capacity of the recipient. This strains the recipient

government’s ability to supply counterpart funding, leading to delays in the

disbursement of aid funds and implementation of projects. In other words, aid fails

when it is provided beyond the absorptive capacity – a point noted earlier by

Stoneman (1975). Studies, for example, by Hadjimichael et al. and Durbarry et al., to

be reviewed later, identified optimal aid to GDP ratio at which diminishing returns to

aid applied in the economy.

Mosley et al. (1987) conducted multiple linear regression analyses for three time-

periods between 1960 and 1980. The equation to be tested was derived by assuming a

welfare function of the government as in Heller (1975). 13 The equation suggests that

the effectiveness of aid is determined by three parameters of the government welfare

function. They are: (a) weight attached to deviation of government investment from

desired level, (b) weight attached to deviation of borrowing from desired level and (c)

the extent to which desired government investment expenditure rises as private

investment diminishes. The effectiveness of aid is also assumed to depend on (d) the

share of aid allocated to recurrent budget, (e) the extent of aid to which aid crowds out

13
The Heller type models will be reviewed later in this chapter.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 122

private sector investment, (f) ratio of changes in output to changes in private capital

stock and (g) ratio of changes in output to changes in government capital stock.

In the cross-country data in the 1970s, they found very little correlation between the

growth of GNP and aid-GNP ratio. They hypothesised that this could be due partly to

non-aid influences on growth and party to inter-country differences in the way aid

was used. Since their primary concern was the inter-country differences in aid use

and its effect on aid effectiveness, they have divided the sample into four categories:

(a) low aid-low growth, (b) high aid-low growth, (c) high aid-high growth and (d) low

aid-high growth. They used the cut off points of over 5 per cent aid/GNP ratio and

over 4 per cent GNP growth to define a high aid and high growth country. They found

that the only two variables that had significant impact on growth in the 1970s were

savings rate and export growth. When they controlled their sample for these two

variables, the general finding was that “the rate of return on capital is higher and the

share of aid inflows allocated to the development budget are, on average, higher in

‘high aid, high growth’ countries than in ‘high aid, low growth’ countries, whereas the

impact of aid inflows on private-sector capital investment is about the same in each

group”.

Mosley et al. then investigated aid effectiveness over time with a system of three

equations. In the first equation, growth was assumed to depend on aid, other financial

flows, savings, growth of literacy rate and export growth. In the second equation aid

was a function of initial per capita GNP, initial mortality rate, growth, OPEC and

Arab League dummies. The third equation assumed that mortality rate was a function

of aid, initial per capita GNP and growth. Thus, the model incorporated the ideas of
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 123

Papanek and Stewart that aid is given on the basis of needs, and the interdependence

of aid, savings, growth and level of development. The main conclusion of Mosley et

al. study is negative. That is, they did not find any significant correlation between aid

and growth. 14 Among the possible reasons for this negative findings they identified

two reasons – (a) aid diversion to non-productive uses and (b) negative price effects to

the private sector (aid crowding out).

In another study, Mosley (1987) employed OLS and 2SLS using data from 1960 to

1984 for 67 developing countries. He found that there appeared to be no statistically

significant correlation in any postwar period, either negative or positive, between

inflows of development aid and the growth rate of GNP in developing countries when

other causal influences on growth were taken into account. He referred to the

micro/macro paradox, whereby most of micro project studies on aid effectiveness

found positive results, whereas macro studies did not find any evidence of positive

effects of aid. Mosley noted three points in relation to the micro/macro paradox. First,

there were inaccurate measurements in both micro and macro studies. Second,

fungibility of aid within the public sector could reduce the effectiveness of aid. Third,

is the possibility of crowding out of the private sector by aid-financed activities, as

they compete for skilled manpower. According to him, all these factors need to be

taken into account when examining the issue of aid effectiveness.

Bowles (1987) is the first known study to econometrically examine the issue of

causality between aid and savings. He used time-series data for 20 less developing

14
In a similar subsequent study, Mosley et al. (1992) found that countries progressed in a counter-
clockwise manner from low aid-low growth to low aid-high growth phase.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 124

countries from 1960-81 and employed the Granger causality test to examine the

causal relationship between foreign aid and domestic savings. In half of the sample

countries, Bowles found no causal relationship between aid and savings, and in the

other half, the direction of causality was mixed. In three cases changes in savings

were shown to cause changes in aid, in five cases the converse, and for the remaining

two there was bi-directional causality.

Rana (1987) performed a study of 14 Asian countries using both time-series and

pooled cross-section data for the period 1965-82. Following Gupta (1975) and Gupta

and Islam (1983), Rana used simultaneous equations techniques. In his model, there

were two endogenous variables (growth rate of GDP and gross domestic saving as a

percentage of GDP) and five exogenous variables (foreign aid as a percentage of

GDP; foreign capital investment including long-term borrowing as a percentage of

GDP; change in exports as a percentage of GDP; change in labour force; per capita

GDP). In contrast to Gupta and Gupta-Islam, Rana found that foreign capital made a

positive contribution to the growth of these Asian countries, and in general higher aid

flows were associated with more productive investment. 15

Levy (1988) conducted a study of 22 sub-Saharan African countries whose population

was over one million. In a pooled cross-section of time-series data, the study covered

a period of 14 years from 1968 to 1982, with two sub-periods before and after 1973.

The post 1974 data represented a period when domestic investment exceeded

domestic savings by more than the amount in the previous period. That is, the

15
A later study by Rana with Dowling (Rana and Dowling, 1988), found similar results that foreign
capital flows made a positive contribution to the growth of Asian developing countries.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 125

savings-investment gap in the post 1974 period was higher than the pre 1974 period.

The results in both sub-periods (1968-73 and 1974-82) and for the 15 years (1968-82)

period as a whole showed that aid was positively and significantly correlated with

investment and economic growth. In the first sub-period, the estimates indicated that

an additional dollar of foreign aid raised domestic investment by 0.92 dollars with a

standard error of 0.278. In the later period, the response of investment to aid was at

least as high as in the initial period. For the entire period, an additional dollar of aid

was found to be associated with an increase in investment by 1.08 dollars with a

standard error of 0.244.

Levy also found statistically significant and positive relationship between aid and

economic growth (in both their level and changes). The results were not found to be

sensitive to stages of development proxied by per capita income, nor to simultaneous

estimation bias.

Snyder (1990) revisited the aid-savings debate sparked by Griffin and Enos in the

1970s. Following the comments on Griffin and Enos by Stewart, Thirlwall and others

that the negative aid-savings relationship could be due to some omitted variables,

Snyder included per capita income as an additional variable in his study of 50 low-and

middle-income countries. He found that although savings correlated negatively and

significantly with aid, the relationship lost significance when per capita income was

included in the OLS regression. He also found significant negative relationship

between aid and per capita income, implying that poorer a country, higher is the aid

flows. Thus, Snyder’s findings lend support to the traditional views as opposed to

pessimistic views of Griffin and Enos. However, he noted that the coefficient of aid in
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 126

the regression, although small and statistically not significant, was consistently found

to be negative. Thus, he concluded that there could be some moderate tendency

toward aid switching (to consumption or unproductive use), but not to the extent as

claimed by Griffin and Enos.

Snyder also replicated Gupta’s 1975 study by including per capita income in the

model for 28 countries, which were common in both studies, to account for the

difference in their results. The coefficient of aid was found to be significant and

negative as in Gupta’s original study even after including per capita income.

However, when an additional 22, mainly poor and low-income countries, which

received substantial aid were added to the sample, the estimated coefficient of aid

became small and non-significant in the presence of per capita income. Snyder

believed that Gupta’s findings of strong negative aid-savings relationship could be

due to sample composition, which included a very few low income countries or sub-

Saharan African countries, but contained several middle income European countries,

oil exporters and other nations that are not typically aid recipients.

Snyder’s findings are broadly consistent with those of Bowles (1987) who did not

find any causality (in Granger sense) in half of his sample of 20 countries. As

highlighted earlier, in remaining countries the causality was mixed.

Killick (1991) also analysed aid inflows to sub-Saharan Africa and found that aid had

been less effective in promoting economic development than it was in other regions.

For aid ineffectiveness, Killick emphasised these four factors: (1) the recipient

country’s policy environment; (2) its limited absorptive capacity, (3) an unfavorable
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 127

world economic environment, partly due to donor policies; (4) weaknesses in donor

agencies.

Killick argued that the policies of a recipient country had a decisive influence on the

effectiveness of program, sectoral and project aid. For example, policy mistakes

contributed to a decline in export market shares and in savings and investment. Aid

effectiveness also depends on a country’s absorptive capacity – that is, whether a

country is capable of utilising additional aid to productive use (this depends on

available domestic resources such as skilled manpower, quality of institutions and

recurrent costs of project. Furthermore, donors’ own policies (for example, promotion

of commercial objectives and foreign policy) may be an obstacle for the effectiveness

of aid. Thus, in many ways, Killick’s conclusions are similar to those of Cassen and

Associates (1986).

Islam (1992) estimated the foreign aid and economic growth relationship in

Bangladesh by using annual time-series data for the period 1972-88. Total aid was

decomposed into grants and loans as a proportion of GDP to estimate the effect of

each on growth rate. Again aid was disaggregated into three components: food aid,

commodity aid and project aid. Islam’s results indicated that foreign capital could

play a positive role in the process of economic development. However, not all

components of aid were equally important. Loans and food aid appeared to have a

stronger influence on economic growth than commodity and project aid. Islam also

found that domestic resources contributed more strongly to growth than aggregated

foreign resources.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 128

Brewster and Yeboah (1994) conducted a study of 14 highly aid-dependent countries

in which both aid growth and aid/GNP ratios were greater than 6.7 per cent. They

used data from 1969 to 1987 and applied simple descriptive statistical techniques. The

results for 9 out of 11 aid-favoured countries showed negative savings growth over a

period of nearly two decades. They concluded therefore that aid had not been

contributing to growth and savings in desirable directions in the countries under

study. They suggested that the ineffectiveness of aid could be due to adverse terms of

trade, poor returns on investment and low labour productivity. That is, the adverse

effects of these factors could outweigh any positive benefits of aid.

Hadjimichael et al. (1995) examined the impact of macroeconomic policies,

exogenous factors and structural reforms on growth, savings and investment in sub-

Saharan Africa. They used 31 countries from the region for the period 1987-92.

Specific policy variables such as government investment, the public budget deficit

and inflation were taken into the analysis. Although the concepts of ‘absorptive

capacity constraint’ and aid ‘overload’were recognised by early studies (e.g. Chenery

and his associates, and Cassen and Associates), which may cause the returns to aid to

decline after a certain point, Hadjimichael et al. is the first study to examine the

possibility of a non-linear aid–growth relationship. Thus, a squared aid term was

included in the regression to capture possible non-linear aid–growth relationship.

They found that aid was subject to diminishing returns due to recipient countries’

absorptive capacity. The contribution of aid to GDP growth declines if aid/GDP ratio

exceeds 25 per cent.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 129

Walle and Timothy (1996) investigated effectiveness of aid from seven donor

countries (United States, United Kingdom, Japan, Canada, Denmark and Sweden) to

seven African countries (Botswana, Burkina Faso, Ghana, Kenya, Senegal, Tanzania

and Zambia). Walle and Timothy argued that despite some progress in human welfare

indicators, in most African countries aid did not contribute to fostering economic

growth and poverty alleviation. Due to political instability and civil conflict, progress

has been reversed in some countries. From 1980 to 1993 the rate of economic growth

was found to be negative in these African countries. In addition, similar to Cassen and

Associates and Killick’s observations, Walle and Timothy found that the lack of a

government’s own management capabilities contributed to the poor performance of

aid. Other weaknesses were lack of country ownership, poor coordination with

donors, and inability to cover recurrent costs.

Boone (1996) used five-year and decade average data for 96 countries from the period

1971-90 to analyse the importance of political regimes to aid effectiveness. He found

that while aid increased consumption, higher consumption did not benefit the poor.

Boone also claimed that aid had an insignificant impact on improvements in basic

measures of human development such as infant mortality, primary schooling ratios

and life expectancy. Since there was no significant relationship between aid and these

measures, Boone argued that aid inflows primarily benefited a wealthy political elite.

He further claimed that aid increased the size of government but did not significantly

increase investment. Finally, Boone found that the impact of aid did not vary
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 130

according to whether recipient governments were liberal democratic or highly

repressive. 16

Bowen (1998) used a sample of 67 less developed countries for the period of 1970-88.

Models were specified to allow for direct and indirect effects of aid on growth. He

modeled the direct and indirect effects by following a methodology, known as

“Expansion Methodology” where a basic model linking aid to growth was extended

by taking into account of aid’s influence on the constant and coefficients of other

variables. Bowen found that aid was not significantly associated with economic

growth directly; instead aid was found to have substituted domestic savings.

Khan (1999) performed an aid/GDP Ganger causality test using data from Pakistan

and found a negative and significant association between aid and economic growth.

The study was based on data from 1972-93. Khan attributed the negative aid–growth

relationship to the lack of cooperation between donors and recipients.

In some studies, for example, Yano and Nugent (1999), the effectiveness of aid was

judged according to a country’s ability to promote tradable sector and its contribution

to the expansion of the export market. Yano and Nugent estimated a model of the

“transfer paradox” for a small open economy with non-traded goods. They considered

the welfare effect of development aid and demonstrated that a transfer paradox can

occur in a small country in the presence of non-traded goods. 17 They used time-series

16
Boone found the same in his earlier 1994 study, which attracted the attention of the influential The
Economist magazine. The findings were summarised by the Economist (Dec. 10, 1994) as aid is “down
the rat hole”.
17
Aid is a transfer from developed countries to developing countries in order to enhance the welfare of
the recipient. However, paradoxically, welfare can decline if aid is used for the non-traded sector.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 131

data for 44 aid dependent countries for the period 1970-90, and showed that if aid

went to finance the expansion of non-traded (and/or import-competing sectors), a

transfer paradox might arise and net welfare might decline.

Yano and Nugent concluded: “[T]he expansion of the non-traded goods sector can

change the domestic price of the non-traded good in such a way that the otherwise

beneficial effect of aid may be offset” (1999: 432). They argued that “under certain

conditions, the over-expansion can more than offset the beneficial effect thereby

giving rise to the transfer paradox even in a small country” (1999: 432). They found

evidence of the immiserisation effect of aid in Congo, Uganda, Bangladesh and

Nepal. That is, aid may lead to slower or negative economic growth depending on its

sectoral distribution. As reviewed earlier, Levy (1988) alluded to the importance of

aid to accelerate structural change and the growth of tradable sector.

However, after re-examination of the Yano-Nugent (1999) model, Choi (2004)

pointed out “the expansion of the non-traded goods sector is necessary and sufficient

proof that the capital transfer is welfare improving and no transfer paradox

occur”(2004: 250). He argued that during the Marshall Plan, a significant portion of

aid was also used to purchase medicine to combat tuberculosis, build railroads and

water system in French North Africa, and this could not be welfare reducing. Based

on the Marshall Plan examples, he further argued that the expansion of non-traded

sector (such as infrastructure) was essential for the eventual expansion of the tradable

sector.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 132

Corruption could be a major reason for the ineffectiveness of aid in many developing

countries. Many argue that aid can increase political instability; a corrupt and an

inefficient government may survive with the support of aid. For example, Rodrik

(1996) suggests that aid can help a bad government to survive. Knack (2000) points

out that higher aid levels erode the quality of governance in a number of ways. They

encourage rent seeking and other forms of corruption, they fuel conflict over control

of aid, and more importantly, they allow the hiring of the most skilled people in the

donor’s organisation at high rates, which disadvantages the local organisations and

government.

Following Boone (1996), some later studies attempted to examine the effect of

corruption by incorporating various indices of governance. One important study in

this area is Burnside and Dollar.

The Burnside and Dollar and related studies

The study by Burnside and Dollar (BD) (1997, 2000) became very influential for

donors across the world, particularly because of its introduction of economic policy

and governance variables in the aid–growth equation. In addition, BD included

several institutional and political variables such as assassinations, ethnic

fractionalisation and institutional quality. 18 In many ways, BD’s studies shared the

conclusions of Boone (1994, 1996) and created a pessimistic view about aid. 19 Hence

BD’s work resulted in a wave of aid effectiveness studies, considerably different from

18
Burnside and Dollar (2000) is almost identical to their 1997 study. The study was slightly modified
by breaking down the original sample into middle-and low-income countries. Their study created a
heated debate on the issue of aid effectiveness among both academics and policy makers.
19
As with the study by Boone, Burnside-Dollar study was reviewed in The Economist under the title,
“Making Aid Work” (The Economist, Nov. 14, 1998).
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 133

the traditional aid effectiveness studies. The BD study (along with that of Boone)

generated as much academic controversies in the late 1990s as the GE (Griffin and

Enos) study along with Weisskopf did in the 1970s.

BD’s study was based on a panel of 56 countries and six four-year time periods, from

1970-73 to 1990-93. They constructed a policy index variable from measures of

budget surplus, inflation and openness to interact with foreign aid. They also used a

measure of institutional quality to capture security of property rights and efficiency of

the government bureaucracy. They ran a number of regressions in which growth rates

in recipient countries depend on initial per capita national income, aid, and indices

representing policies and institutions.

BD argued that the growth process is directly dependent on the quality of economic

policy and institutions. They found that in a good policy environment foreign aid had

a positive effect on growth. They further found that bilateral aid was influenced by

donor interest variables and strongly positively correlated with government

consumption, while multilateral aid was largely a function of income level, population

and good policy.

The World Bank (1998) extended the BD study. It used a general equilibrium-growth

model to examine the endogeneity and non-linear effects of aid, and the impact of aid

on economic policies and institutional environments in recipient countries. The World

Bank also addressed the issue of aid fungibility. Its empirical analysis revealed that

aid helps stimulate economic growth and reduce poverty but only when strong

institutions and good economic management exist in recipient countries. In other


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 134

words, aid leads to faster economic growth, poverty reduction and achievements in

many social indicators in developing countries with sound economic management, but

is less effective where there are weak institutions and policies. The World Bank’s

studies generated further interest in aid-effectiveness, initially sparked by BD.

Durbarry et al. (1998) used both panel (four periods with six-year averages) and

cross-section data techniques for 58 developing countries for the period 1970-93 to

investigate the aid–growth relationship. They employed an augmented Fischer–

Easterly type growth model in which macroeconomic and policy variables are

allowed to affect long-run growth rates. For possible non-linearity in the aid–growth

relationship, they included a quadratic term of the aid/GDP ratio in the regression.

They argued that the possibility of non-linearity in the aid–growth relationship should

be recognised from the outset. Durbarry et al. concluded that foreign aid inflows had a

beneficial effect on developing countries with stable macroeconomic policy

environment. However, according to them, it does not imply that aid affects growth

negatively in the absence of good policy. They noted that the inclusion of policy

variables provides a more fully specified model, but aid–growth effects are not

dependent on it as claimed by BD. They further argued that while a low amount of aid

did not generate faster growth, very high aid/GDP ratios (over 40-45 per cent) were

also associated with slower growth. This gives an indication that the optimum

aid/GDP ratio is around 40-45 per cent.

Guillaumont and Chauvet (2001) examined the effect of aid using pooled data for two

12-year periods – 1970-81 and 1982-93 for 66 developing countries. They argued that

the macroeconomic effectiveness of aid crucially depended on external and climatic


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 135

factors rather than on the economic policy environment. They found that aid was

effective in that it accelerated growth in vulnerable countries. They therefore

concluded that the worse the environment, the greater the need for aid and the higher

its potential for productivity. Their model was estimated using the two-stage least

squares technique incorporating an aid to GDP ratio, an aid–policy interaction term

(similar to the one used by BD, 1997, 2000), and an interaction term between aid and

a composite external environment indicator. The results revealed that the variables

that combined aid with the policy environment indicator was not statistically

significant, while the variables that combined aid with the external environment

indicator had a statistically significant (and positive) impact on growth. The finding

does not, in other words, support BD’s claim that aid effectiveness depends on a good

policy environment.

Dalgaard and Hansen (2001) also empirically investigated the aid–growth results of

the BD model. They used the same data set used by BD to reassess aid effectiveness,

and found that the BD results were crucially data-dependent. When five observations

were excluded from the samples (Gambia, 1986-89, 1990-93; Guyana, 1990-93; and

Nicaragua, 1986-89, 1990-93), the results changed because these observations had a

very big influence on the coefficient to the aid–policy interaction term. They also

showed that by deleting other combinations of observation the opposite outcome

could be produced, that is, aid stimulated growth irrespective of the policy

environment. However, they found support for the BD hypothesis that the aid–growth

relationship is non-linear and there is diminishing returns to aid.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 136

Collier and Dehn (2001) included shocks in the aid–growth relationship to analyse aid

effectiveness, and the shocks were measured by an index of export prices. They used

the BD data set and found that “negative shocks have substantial adverse effects on

output, which even over a period of four years or less are around twice as large as the

direct loss of export income” (2001: 10). They further discovered that once these

shocks were included, the BD result became robust to choice of sample. Thus, with

the inclusion of shocks in the BD model, Collier and Dehn found that the shocks were

highly significant. On the other hand, they claimed that the adverse effects of negative

shocks on growth could be mitigated through offsetting increases in aid.

Collier and Dollar (2002) re-examined the core BD results with an extended data set

from 59 developing countries and took four-year averages for the period 1974-97.

They found support for BD that aid works in a good policy environment. They also

concurred with the findings of the World Bank’s Assessing Aid that donors were not

successful in inducing lasting reforms in recipient countries. Hence, Collier and

Dollar concluded that aid should be directed to countries, which already have good

policy environment and better governance. That is, aid should be selective.

In addition, Collier and Dollar estimated the allocation of aid that would maximise the

reduction of poverty. They argued that to maximise poverty reduction, aid should be

allocated to countries that have a high level of poverty combined with a good policy

environment. That is, donors can affect growth through their allocation of aid, and

growth in turn will lead to poverty reduction only where there is a good policy

environment. Collier and Dollar argued that the actual allocation of aid was different
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 137

than that of poverty-efficient allocation, and claimed that with a poverty-efficient

allocation, aid productivity would be almost double.

Dalgaard et al. (2002) addressed various issues of aid effectiveness. They examined

cross-country correlations between aid, savings and growth, and demonstrated why

plots of cross-country averages were distorted by identification problems and

heterogeneity biases. They stated that “once these problems are taken into account,

cross-plots of aid versus growth and savings support the panel data regression results

of a positive impact of aid on growth” (2002: 2). Dalgaard et al. also investigated the

impact of geographic circumstances on aid effectiveness. 20 They estimated the model

using data from 1974-77 to 1990-93 of a panel of 54 countries. They found that in the

BD type growth equation, aid was much more effective in countries outside of the

geographical tropics. When Dalgaard et al. investigated the results of the BD (1997)

model, they found that aid was effective even in bad policy environments but aid had

diminishing impact on growth. They argued that in the BD model, the interaction

between aid and policy was ambiguous. Their findings are consistent with the studies

by Dalgaard and Hansen (2001) and Guillaumont and Chauvet (2001) as they also

found the interaction between aid and policy index to be statistically insignificant.

Easterly et al. (2003) re-assessed the relationship between aid, policy and growth as

modeled by BD (2000), extending data from 1993 to 1997. They added extra

countries and observations to the BD data set, but used the same methodology to re-

examine aid effectiveness in the context of good policy. The aid–policy interaction

term was found not only insignificant but also appeared with different signs. Thus,

20
Bloom and Sachs (1998) found that growth rates across the countries are affected by their geography.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 138

according to them, aid effectiveness does not depend on policy environment as

claimed by BD.

In fact, there is no general agreement about the identification of exactly which

policies are crucial. If the three policies emphasised by the BD model were actually

robust determinants of the return on aid, this would be a major breakthrough. From

this perspective, the findings of the BD model do not stand up to scrutiny. Easterly

(2003) points out that without further testing and research for the validity of the

conclusion, the general findings have been passed on via the media, and then cited by

international agencies claiming that an increase in foreign aid is justified for those

countries having good policies and governance. 21 As Easterly states, “a regression

result was passed from one source to the next without questions about the robustness

or broader applicability of the result” (2003: 25). Thus, he cast doubts about the

wisdom behind the policy recommendations that aid should be allocated selectively to

those countries with good policy. 22

Hansen and Tarp (HT) Survey of aid effectiveness studies

Hansen and Tarp (2000) examined and summarised empirical cross-country studies of

aid effectiveness going back to the 1960s, and concluded that aid contributed

positively to economic performance. They surveyed 131 cross-country regressions

from 29 different studies, which they categorised into “three generations”. The first-

21
International aid agencies such as the British Department for International Development, the
Canadian International Development Agency and many others have been influenced by the BD
findings and conditioned aid on policy reforms.
22
Easterly (2003: 38) has characterised the imposition of conditions as “no more than a wistful hope,
rather than a policy with consequences” in circumstances where “a nation will selectively receive aid if
it is a ‘good performer’ – unless it is a bad performer, in which case it will receive aid from the ‘bad
performer’ fund.”
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 139

generation studies used the Harrod–Domar growth model and the two-gap model. In

39 first-generation regressions, aid was assumed to be an exogenous net increment to

the capital stock of the recipient country, and hence it was not treated as a component

of national income adding to both consumption and investment. From the first-

generation studies they found that aid led to an increase in total savings. Thus, given

the underlying Harrod–Domar model, the implication is that aid spurs growth.

In the second-generation empirical work, Hansen and Tarp focused on the relationship

between aid and growth via investment. Moreover, in these studies different financing

components of investment such as domestic savings, aid and other foreign capital

inflows were separated. In 18 cross-country studies, a positive relationship was found

between aid and investment, implying that aid made a positive contribution to growth.

They found in 17 studies that there was a significant positive impact of aid on

investment, while only one study showed an insignificant effect. A second strand of

the second-generation literature investigated the relationship between aid and growth

in reduced-form equations. In 72 regressions, 40 showed a positive impact of aid on

growth, 1 a negative impact and 31 an insignificant effect.

The third-generation studies were primarily focused on four more recent studies

(Hadjimichael et al., 1995; Durbarry et al., 1998; Hansen and Tarp, 1999; and BD,

1997). These studies used large number of sample countries with panel type data from

over a number of years. They also included measures of economic policy and the

institutional environment in reduced-form growth regressions, along with traditional

macroeconomic variables. Finally, they addressed the endogeneity of aid and

explicitly treated the aid–growth relationship as non-linear.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 140

These empirical works suggest that aid increases savings and investments and that

there is a positive relationship between aid and growth. Hansen and Tarp’s survey

reveals that in each generation of studies, those claiming a negative aid–growth or

negative aid–savings relationship are clearly in the minority. They conclude,

We find a consistent pattern of results. Aid increases aggregate savings; aid

increases investment; and there is a positive relationship between aid and

growth….The positive aid—growth link is a robust result from all three

generations of work. (Hansen and Tarp, 2000: 122).

Post HT Survey

The World Bank (2001) conducted a study of 10 African countries. The study

demonstrates the effects of a range of African policy experiences. Despite large

amounts of aid going to these countries, not all have been able to reap the benefits.

Among the 10 countries surveyed, Ghana and Uganda have been most successful in

achieving sustained good policy and economic outcomes. According to the study,

based on reforms undertaken in the 1980s and 1990s, Ethiopia, Mali and Tanzania

have been mixed reformers, and Congo and Nigeria non-reformers. The study further

shows that a large amount of aid with bad policy environment could further delay

reforms. The cases of Ghana and Uganda indicate that donors should concentrate on

technical assistance and other “soft support” and on policy dialogues in the pre-reform

period. Thus, this study reinforced the conclusion of BD and conditionality based

lending.

Gounder (2001) used time-series data for the period 1968-96 to estimate the aid–

growth relationship in Fiji. While the model was based on a neoclassical production
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 141

function, it was estimated using ARDL approach to cointegration. The aid data were

disaggregated into various forms such as bilateral, multilateral, technical cooperation,

grants and loans aid. The results showed that foreign aid contributed significantly to

Fiji’s economic growth. However, not all forms of aid had the same effects. Bilateral,

grants and technical cooperation grants contributed more significantly to growth than

any other forms of aid.

Using the same methodology and data from 1975 to 1997, Gounder (2003) found a

positive and significant relationship between aid and growth in Solomon Islands. She

also performed Granger causality tests, which showed bidirectional causality between

aid and economic growth in Solomon Islands.

Hansen and Tarp (2001) analysed the aid–growth relationship by comparing the latest

studies of cross-country aid–growth regressions where the relationship was modeled

as non-linear. They used two different data sets: from 1974 to 1993 for 56 countries,

and 1960 to 1987 for 45 countries. Hansen and Tarp took into account country-

specific effects and aid endogeneity. They justified the introduction of country-

specific effects in the regressions by arguing that diversity among developing

countries in terms of their natural endowments and cultural and socio-economic

characteristics should be a major concern in cross-country comparison of aid

effectiveness.

Hansen and Tarp argued that in the models estimated by Hadjimichael et al. (1995),

Durbarry et al. (1998) and Lensink and White (1999), the aid variables were included

as uncentred regressors. As a result, the estimated coefficient of the aid variable was a
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 142

measure of the partial effect of aid on growth evaluated at no (zero) aid. Thus, they

noted, “we have chosen to center the aid variable around the sample mean, so the

estimated aid coefficient is the marginal effect of aid on growth evaluated at the

mean, 0.061” (2001: 552). When endogeneity of aid and country-specific effects are

taken into account, the empirical findings show that aid increases the growth rate,

which is not conditional on the policy index as claimed by BD (1997, 2000).

However, Hansen and Tarp found that there were decreasing returns to aid. They did

not identify the optimal aid/GDP ratio beyond which the decreasing returns will set in.

A possible reason for the ineffectiveness of foreign aid could be the negative effect of

high aid inflows on the absorptive capacity of a recipient country. Lensink and White

(2001) empirically examined the Aid–Laffer curve with respect to growth to show

that high aid inflows have negative effects. In the regression analysis, pooled cross-

section time-series data were employed, taking period averages calculated from three

five-year periods (1975-79, 1980-84 and 1985-89) and one three-year period, in 111

countries. They found aid/GNP ratio of about 50 per cent as the turning point at which

aid starts to have a negative effect on growth. This is considerably higher than the

findings of Hadjimichael et al.(1995) and Durbarry et al. (1998).

Hasan (2002) examined the aid–savings relationship, using cointegration and Ganger

causality techniques. The study used a sample of 27 developing countries for the

period 1960-98. The causality results showed that causal direction and lag vary

markedly across countries. In more than half of the countries studied, Hasan found no

causal relationship between aid inflows and domestic savings. In the remaining
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 143

countries the direction and pattern of causality were mixed. Thus, Hasan’s findings

are similar to those of Bowles (1987), reviewed earlier.

Mavrotas (2002) used disaggregated aid data to examine aid effectiveness in India.

Aid was disaggregated into project, program and technical assistance for the period

1970-92, and the cointegration technique was applied for the estimation procedure.

The findings suggest that in the case of India, the composition of aid seems matter for

the effectiveness of aid, given their different impacts on the economy. Mavrotas

concluded that both program aid and project assistance had a negative influence on

growth in India. However, a study by Dawson and Tiffin (1999) found that aid neither

promoted nor adversely affected economic growth in India. Using annual data from

1961-92, Dawson and Tiffin found that ODA (Official Development Assistance) was

stationary while GDP had a unit root. Thus, in their interpretation the long-run

relationship between aid and growth could not exist.

Instead of estimating the impact of aggregate aid, White and Dijkstra (2003)

attempted to estimate the effectiveness of program aid, mostly from Sweden. They

also conducted eight country case studies (Bangladesh, Cape Verde, Mozambique,

Nicaragua, Tanzania, Uganda, Vietnam and Zambia). They examined the impact of

donor–recipient policy dialogue on the pace of reforms and the impact of program

funds on imports and balance of payments.

As an estimation method, they employed quantitative techniques (to assess fund

impacts) and a qualitative approach (to assess policy dialogue). They also performed a

counterfactual analysis of balance of payments, assuming that the exchange rate


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 144

would be depreciated to increase exports (for example, 15 per cent), there would have

been no increase in reserve, and a different scenario for debt service (debt service paid

actual, no or low percentage paid, and paid in-between) in the absence of aid. They

concluded that program aid had been useful to achieve macroeconomic stabilisation

through financing the budget deficit and supporting the exchange rate to avoid

devaluation.

Islam (2003) examined the relationship between foreign aid and economic growth

under different political regimes. The model was based on the neoclassical production

function, and aid was assumed to augment technological progress. Islam used the

generalised least squares (GLS) method for the estimation procedure. The data were

for a sample of 21 sub-Saharan and 11 Asian countries for the period 1968-92, and the

countries were separated into two types of authoritarian regimes, tinpot and

totalitarian. Tinpot regimes are defined as focusing on personal consumption and

avoiding unnecessary spending on repression; they are thus considered a weak form

of dictatorship. Totalitarian regimes are those that entertain maximum power and use

highly repressive measures to stay in power but at the same time make an effort to

promote economic growth.

When the model was tested on sub-samples of tinpot and totalitarian countries

separately, the results indicated that the effect varies substantially across regime

types. The coefficient of aid was found positively significant for totalitarian countries

but negative and statistically insignificant for tinpots. The results further showed that

tinpot regimes involved more corruption than totalitarian regimes. Further, weak

forms of dictatorship (that is, tinpots) did not implement policy reforms, possibly
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 145

because of the pressure of special interest groups, whereas strong dictatorships

implemented policy reforms relatively easily. Thus, aid was found to be effective in

stimulating growth in totalitarian countries but ineffective in tinpot countries.

Chatterjee and Turnovsky (2005) developed a theoretical model through which

foreign aid affects macroeconomic performance. They decomposed total aid into tied

and untied aid and found that the long-run impact of a tied aid program depends

crucially on the elasticity of substitution in production. Thus, they noted that tied aid

is more effective in economies with a low degree of substitution between factors of

production. They further stressed, “tied aid generates dynamic adjustments, as public

capital is accumulated in the recipient economy. Its effect on the long-run growth rate,

and the extent to which this is beneficial, depends on the elasticity of substitution in

production, as well as co-financing arrangements, if any, imposed on the recipient

economy, and how its government chooses to react to the additional flow of

resources”(2005: 39).

Aid and Poverty

In recent years, the basic objective of foreign aid has been replaced by the objective of

poverty reduction in recipient countries. In the past few decades a bulk of research has

shed new light on role and effectiveness of aid in reducing poverty in developing

countries. Most donors are therefore changing their focus to pro-poor based economic

growth with the aim of poverty reduction. In other words, the effectiveness of foreign

aid is being analysed from a different perspective, focusing on aid’s capacity to

reduce poverty that has been the principal target for aid donors as well as many

developing countries.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 146

Mosley et al. (2004) based on cross-country evidence found a significant relationship

between pro-poor public expenditure and poverty reduction. The GMM and 3SLS

techniques were applied to data from 34 countries for the period 1980-2000. They

used a pro-poor public expenditure index to investigate the effect of aid on poverty

rather than on economic growth. They developed a range of methodologies for

devising one overall measure of pro-poor public expenditure. They considered public

expenditure on the basics of health care, primary education, water and sanitation, rural

roads and agricultural extension service as pro-poor. In addition to pro-poor

expenditure, they also used measures of inequality and corruption, which also

influenced the poverty leverage of foreign aid. They found that aid that went to pro-

poor public expenditure had a longer lasting impact on poverty.

Their findings are consistent with those of Collier and Dollar (2001, 2002). Mosley et

al. concluded: “[W]e feel that inter-country reallocations of aid could increase such

poverty impact. Among the criteria that could form the basis for such reallocations,

we find corruption, inequality and the composition of public expenditure to be

particularly strongly associated with aid effectiveness” (2004: 235).

Gomanee et al. (2005) found that aid improves welfare indicators measured by infant

mortality and Human Development Index (HDI). According to them, aid might have

direct (by increasing incomes or access to social services) and indirect (through an

effect on growth) effects on welfare. They used a panel of four four-year and one five-

year period averages data from 1980 to 2000 for 104 countries. When they divided the

sample into low-income and middle-income countries, they found greater impact of

aid on improving welfare in low-income than middle-income countries. However, in


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 147

contrast to Mosley et al. (2004), they did not find any strong support that aid impacts

welfare through pro-public expenditure (PPE). 23 Thus, based on the results, they

concluded, “although aid increases PPE in low-income countries, the efficacy of PPE

in increasing welfare is quite low while significant amount of aid to social sectors are

independent of government spending” (2005: 364)

Studies of aid effectiveness in Nepal

Although Nepal is an aid-dependent country, only few attempts have been made so far

to address the issue of aid effectiveness in Nepal in empirical terms. Mihaly (1965)

and Stiller and Yadav (1979) were early studies that addressed the issue of foreign aid

in Nepal. They claimed that aid had not been used effectively due to the lack of

administrative capacity and political instability. During 1951-59, ten different

cabinets were formed because of weak leadership and lack of strong political will.

Based on descriptive analyses, these authors argued that policy makers had a poor

understanding of the role of aid in the Nepalese economy, and the country therefore

suffered from poor absorptive capacity. Almost four decades later, Mihaly (2002)

maintained that aid has not been effective in Nepal, due mainly to lack of

administrative capacity and political will. In addition, Mihaly (2002) argued that

Nepal’s aid was greatly influenced by the strategic interests of donors. Thus, Mihaly

noted: “[A]n offer of aid can appear to manifest the donor’s political support for the

recipient – as did the Chinese cash grant to Nepal in 1956. And a facility financed by

aid can be of strategic value to the donor – as are the Indian and Chinese-built roads

in Nepal” (2002: 218).

23
They constructed PPE index estimating government expenditure on education, health and sanitation.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 148

Poudyal (1988) using data from 1964 to 1982 performed regression analyses between

foreign aid and economic growth, and aid and domestic savings. He found that aid

had a significant positive effect on the level of GDP. He also estimated the model

using five years lag of aid. For the one and two years lag, the coefficients were found

smaller and negative. But for the four and five years lag, the coefficient were positive

and larger. Thus, he claimed that the long running aid funded projects did not

contribute to the economy in the short-run. The negative short-run relationship

between aid and growth was attributed to the use of domestic resources (as a part of

recipient contribution) to support these long running foreign financed projects.

However, he did not find statistically consistent results between aid and domestic

savings. Paudyal strongly believed that foreign aid contributed positively to the

development of Nepal. It was only possible through aid to build major projects and

physical infrastructure, which would not have been built due mainly to resources

constraints.

Dhakal et al. (1996) tested causality in the Granger sense between foreign aid and

economic growth in eight countries, including Nepal, for the period 1970-90. The

other countries in the sample were India, Pakistan, Thailand, Botswana, Kenya,

Malawi and Tanzania. The empirical results showed that foreign aid did not cause

economic growth in Nepal. Of the possible reasons, they identified political

corruption as causing a significant diversion of aid, from importing capital goods to

consumption goods. Singh (1996) also expressed almost similar views about the

effectiveness of aid in Nepal. He found that despite a significant amount of foreign

aid, Nepal did not achieve any impressive economic progress during the three decades

(1950-1980). Based on a descriptive analysis, Singh concluded that a small group of


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 149

people (e.g. top level bureaucrats, ruling politicians, real state owners, researcher,

contractors and designers) benefited from aid in Nepal.

Khadka (1996) conducted a descriptive analysis of the role of foreign aid in Nepal’s

economy during 1961-90 by examining some macroeconomic indicators. Khadka

concluded that despite Nepal’s heavy dependence on foreign aid, the role of aid in

improving the level of incomes, savings and investment had not been significant. He

further noted that while a huge amount of aid was invested in the agriculture sector,

Nepal went from being a net exporter to a net importer of food grains. Thus,

according to Khadka, political and institutional factors might be highly important for

aid effectiveness in Nepal. However, in another study, using a simple regression

analysis for the period 1960-90, Khadka (1997) found that aid had a positive impact

on the growth of GDP. In this study, he used only bilateral disbursements for aid data

and excluded multilateral disbursements, and hence one only gets a partial picture.

In line with Mihaly (1965, 2002), Stiller and Yadav (1979), Singh (1996) and Dhakal

et al. (1996), Panday (2001) noted that Nepal failed to use foreign aid effectively. As

a result, Nepal suffered from under development and inequalities. He argued that

policy makers are governed by the demands of the aid system without due attention to

country ownership. Although exogenous influences are unavoidable in policy-making

process, the influence of endogenous actors (politician) and process in policy-making

is very weak in Nepal. For example, he noted, “aid provides not just financial

wherewithal but political legitimacy for the government. Senior political leaders

lobby with the donors, not their government or political colleagues, for projects that

are of interest to them or their constituencies” (Pandey, 2001:180). Thus, he believed


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 150

that poor governance, and lack of strong political leadership without any vision

completely ruined the country.

4.2.1 Summary

Based on the above survey, we can summarise the following main points about aid-

savings-growth relationships:

• The findings are mixed: some found negative and others found positive

relationships between aid and savings, and aid and growth.

• Majority of studies are cross-country analyses.

• Among the single country analyses only a few used the cointegration

technique. Therefore,

o the possibility of spurious relationship is high in the earlier analyses;

o they were also unable to detect long-run relationship between aid and

savings and/or growth.

• More importantly, there are very few studies that involved Nepal. None of

these studies:

o applied cointegration technique;

o disaggregated aid by types and source;

o included policy variables.

A summary of past studies is presented in Table 4.1.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 151

Table 4.1: Summary of aid-growth and aid-savings empirical analyses

Study Sample Methodology Findings Comments


Rosenstein Almost all aid Descriptive Aid contributes to First formal
-Rodan recipient self-sustaining economic
(1961) countries economic growth argument for
aid
Chenery Israel (1950-59) Estimates Aid plays dual role Linked aid to
and Bruno based on to boost economic
(1962) input-output investment and growth within
model and foreign exchange an extended
different resources. Harrod-Domar
assumptions growth model
about various that
parameters. incorporates
savings and
foreign
exchange
constraints
Adelman Greece (1950- OLS, 2SLS, Foreign aid First
and 61) Limited contributed to econometric
Chenery Information GNP growth estimation of
(1966) an extended
Horrod-Domar
growth model
Chenery 31 OLS Positive This remains a
and Strout underdeveloped relationship major model
(1966) countries, between aid and but its
(1957-62) growth and assumptions of
justified aid for constant
two reasons: to fill capital output
the savings– ratio and non-
investment gap substitution
and the foreign between
exchange gap savings and
foreign
exchange have
been
questioned
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 152

Rahman The same data OLS Negative Has attracted


(1968) set used by relationship criticism on
Chenery and between aid the ground that
Strout and domestic there might be
savings other factors
for the
negative
relationship
Griffin and 15 African and OLS Negative This is an
Enos (1970) Asian countries relationship extension of
(1962-64) and between aid Rahman, and
12 Latin and savings; suffers from
American aid retards the same
countries long-run shortcomings
(1957-64) economic
growth
Weisskopf 44 OLS with Impact of The model
(1972) underdeveloped time-series foreign capital ignored
countries data for at least inflows on continued
seven years domestic effects of
post–World savings was factors left
War II periods found behind by the
significantly war.
negative
Voivodas 22 OLS with No significant Focused only
(1973) underdeveloped pooled data relationship on spill-over
countries, between effects on
1956-68) capital inflows consumption
and GDP of foreign aid
growth without
including
feedback
effects
Papanek 34 OLS Significant The findings
(1973) underdeveloped positive effect are still
countries in the of aid on relevant as the
1950s and 51 growth study separates
countries in the different
1960s components of
aid
Stoneman 188 developing OLS Found positive Aid effects
(1975) countries, five relationship negatively
years period between aid after certain
between 1955 and growth point (beyond
and 1970 20 per cent of
GNP)
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 153

Over (1975) Same data set 2SLS Aid First study to


used by Griffin contributed to analyse
and Enos growth simultaniety
(1970) between aid
and savings
Gupta (1975) 40 developing 2SLS Total effects of First study that
countries aid on savings incorporated
were found feedback
negative between
savings and
growth
Mosley (1980) 83 less 2SLS Negative First study to
developed correlation recognise lag
countries between aid response of
(1969-77) and GNP per GNP to aid
capita
Dowling and 52 developing OLS, added Significant and First study to
Hiemenz countries, four policy positive use policy
(1983) (1962-79) in variables in the relationship variables
three-year model between aid
periods and growth
Gupta and 52 developing 2SLS Foreign capital Examined aid
Islam (1983) countries made effectiveness in
(1950-60) and significant countries at
(1965-73) contribution to different
growth income levels
and in different
regions
Cassen and Extensive Discussion Aid Very useful and
Associates qualitative based on effectiveness important
(1986) evaluation of practical depends on assessment that
aid experiences various factors highlighted a
effectiveness number of
issues for aid
effectiveness
Mosley et al. 81 developing Fiscal Aid had no Added extra
(1987) countries response significant explanatory
(1960-80) model and relationship variables in the
extended with GNP Papanek model
model of growth
Griffin (1970)
and Papanek
(1973), OLS
and 3SLS
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 154

Mosley (1987) 67 developing OLS, 2SLS No significant Highlighted the


countries relationship micro/macro
(1960-84) (either positive paradox in aid-
or negative) effectiveness
between aid findings
and GNP
growth
Bowles (1987) 20 less Bivariate Found no First study to
developed Granger causal econometrically
countries causality test relationship test aid-savings
(1960-81) between aid causality
and savings in
10 of 20
surveyed
countries
Rana (1987) 14 Asian Both time- Positive Similar to
countries series and contribution of Gupta (1975),
(1962-82) cross-section aid to growth but different
data, OLS, ILS findings
Rana and 9 developing ILS Foreign aid Similar
Dowling Asian partially findings with
(1988) countries, contributed to that of Rana
1965-82 economic (1987)
growth
Levy (1988) Sub-Saharan Pooled cross- Aid was Divided sample
African section of positively in two sub-
countries time-series correlated with periods based
(1968-82) data, OLS investment and on saving-
economic investment gap
growth
Snyder 50 low- and Panel data set, Found positive Also
(1990) middle-income OLS relationship acknowledge
countries between aid that there could
(1960s, 1970s and savings be some aid
and 1980s) when per diversion to
capita income consumption,
is included in but not to the
the model. extent as
argued by
Griffin-Enos
Killick Sub-Saharan Comparative Aid Recognised
(1991) African analysis with effectiveness donors’ policy
countries other depended on weaknesses.
(1960s-87) developing absorptive Thus, similar
countries capacity and findings as
policy Cassen and
environment of Associates
recipient
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 155

Islam (1992) Bangladesh, OLS Loans and Disaggregated


(1972-88) food aid aid into food,
affected commodity
growth and project aid
positively as in Papanek
more than (1973)
other forms of
aid
Hadjimichael 31 sub-Saharan They included Aid had a Included
et al. (1995) African some policy positive impact policy
countries, variables in the on growth variables and
(1987-92) model with aid aid square term
square term first time to
represent non-
linear
relationship in
the model
Boone (1996) 96 countries Five-year and Found no This study
(1971-90) decade- significant attracted much
average data, relationship attention due to
OLS between aid, its pessimistic
growth and views of aid
investment
Bowen (1998) 67 less 2SLS Aid was not Investigated
developed associated direct and
countries directly with indirect effects
(1970-88) growth and it of aid using
had a negative expansion
effect on methodology
saving rate
Burnside and Panel of 56 OLS and 2SLS Aid had a Has attracted
Dollar (1997) countries with positive impact wide criticisms
six four-year on growth only on
time periods, in a good methodological
from 1970-73 policy and data
to 1990-93 environment ground. But
has become
influential
among donors
World Bank Extensive Based on a Aid Consistent
(1998 investigation number of effectiveness with BD,
into aid background depended on which focused
effectiveness other papers the recipient’s more on policy
in various economic environment
countries policy and for the
institutional effectiveness
environment of aid
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 156

Durbarry et 58 developing OLS and GLS Aid–growth A very high


al. (1998) countries effects were not aid/GDP
(1970-93) dependent on ratios (over
policy variables 40-45 per
cent) create
aid over-load
Khan (1999) Pakistan Bivariate Found a negative Political
(1972-93) Granger and significant instability
causality test association might be a
between aid and major reason
economic growth
Yano and 44 aid- A model of Aid could lower However,
Nugent dependent transfer paradox welfare if aid was critics
(1999) countries, used in non- pointed out
(1970-90) traded goods that non-
sector traded sector
such as
infrastructure
is crucial for
development
Hansen and 131 cross- A survey of Aid increased A
Tarp (2000) country three savings and comprehensiv
regressions generations of investment and e study that
from 29 studies and re- positively clarified the
different examination of affected growth aid–growth
studies aid-growth relationship
relationship
Gounder Fiji (1968-96) Aggregate and Aid contributed to Used
(2001) disaggregated growth cointegration
forms of aid, technique for
ARDL approach time-series
to cointegration data

Hansen and 56 developing OLS and GMM Aid stimulated Took into
Tarp (2001) countries, growth, which account
(1974-93) was not country-
conditional on specific
policy index effects; found
established by BD more
convincing
results
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 157

Guillamont 66 Two pooled 12- Aid was found to be The results


and developing year periods effective to were not
Chauvet countries (1970-81) and accelerate growth inconsistent
(2001) (1982-93), OLS more vulnerable with BD
and 2SLS countries. findings that
aid only
works in a
good policy
environment
Dalgaard The same Deleted some BD model was found Provided
and Hansen data set used observations to to be data-dependent, further
(2001) by BD get different and hence aid evidence that
outcomes of BD stimulated growth BD findings
model irrespective of the were
policy environment misleading
and data
dependent
Lensink 111 Pooled cross- After a certain level Findings
and White countries, section time- of aid inflows, aid stressed the
(2001) (1975-89) series data, started to have absorptive
average three negative effects capacity of
five-year recipient
periods and one countries
three-years
period, 2SLS
World 10 African Comparison of Some countries have Supports
Bank countries policy been successful in BD’s
(2001) (1980s and experiences reforming and emphasis on
1990s) between achieving economic conditionality
countries growth based lending

59 OLS, headcount With a poverty Policy


Collier and developing poverty-gap and efficient allocation implications
Dollar countries square poverty- the productivity of were
(2002 (1974-97) on gap aid would be double unrealistic
four-year because if aid
averages was allocated
according to
mass poverty,
all aid would
have gone to
India and
China
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 158

Hasan (2002) 27 developing Cointegration For more than The


countries, and Granger half of 27 cointegration
(1960-98) causality test countries, there test was valid
was no only for two
relationship countries
between aid
and domestic
savings
Dalgaard et al. 54 countries, Investigated Aid was found Used
(2002) from 1974-77 BD model in a to be effective geographical
to 1990-93) bad policy even in a bad variables in the
environment policy model
environment
Easterly et al. BD model, Same Aid did not Demonstrates
(2003) data extended methodology promote the danger of
from 1993 to used by BD growth in a findings from
1997 good policy simplistic
environment research that
can form the
basis of aid
policy of
donors
White and 8 developing Qualitative The program One can
Dijkstra country case (policy aid had been extend further
(2003) studies dialogue) and successful in research on aid
quantitative maintaining effectiveness
(counterfactual macroeconomic through
analysis) of stabilisation, counterfactual
Swedish financing the analysis
program aid budget deficit
and supporting
the exchange
rate
Islam (2003) 21 sub- GLS Aid had a Shows that aid
Saharan and negative and effectiveness
11 Asian significant depends on
countries, effect on types of
(1968-92) growth political
regime –
tinpots and
authoritarian
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 159

Gounder Solomon ARDL and Found a Aid and


(2003) Island (1975- Granger significant and growth
97) causality positive relationship
relationship further
between aid confirmed by
and growth. the
bidirectional
causality
between them
Mosley et al. Data set is a GMM, 3SLS Found a Highlighted
(2004) pooled sample significant the importance
of 34 countries relationship of aid
(1980-00) between allocation to
poverty pro-poor
reduction and sectors
pro-poor
public
expenditure
Gomanee et al. A panel of four OLS Aid Welfare
(2005) four-year and contributed to enhancing role
one five-year welfare of aid does not
period for104 directly and necessarily
countries indirectly depend on pro-
(1980-00) through growth poor public
expenditure as
claimed by
Mosley et al.
(2004)
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 160

Studies of aid effectiveness in Nepal

Stiller and Nepal (1951- Descriptive Aid did not Lack of


Yadav (1979) 76) analysis contribute to leadership
economic and poor
development administrative
quality were
responsible
for the
ineffectivenes
s of aid
Paudyal Nepal (1964- OLS Aid had a positive This is the
(1988) 82) and significant first known
relationship with econometric
economic growth study of aid-
growth
relationship in
Nepal
Singh (1996) Nepal (1950- Descriptive Small group of Hypothesis
80) analysis people benefited not tested
from aid and created econometrical
severe income ly
distribution problem
Dhakal et al. 8 countries Bivariate Except for two Negative
(1996) from Asia and Granger causality countries, foreign aid relationship
Africa (1970- test significantly caused between aid
90) economic growth and growth in
Nepal.
Khadka Nepal (1961- Descriptive Aid did not Aid might be
(1996) 90) analysis contribute to helping to
economic growth and improve
savings in Nepal social
indicators
Khadka Nepal (1960- OLS Aid had a positive No
(1997) 90) relationship with explanation
growth for why the
results are
different from
the previous
descriptive
analysis
Mihaly (1965, Nepal (1950- Descriptive Aid is not effective in Aid
2002) 00) analysis Nepal effectiveness
did not
improve in
three decades
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 161

4.3 Aid and fiscal behaviour

Many recent studies have analysed the public sector’s fiscal response to aid in

developing countries. This is an important development since most aid goes to the

public sector. Since public-sector budget deficit/surplus has direct implications for

total domestic savings and the current account position, understanding the public

sector’s response to aid is a pre-requisite to understanding macroeconomic impact of

aid. Fiscal response involves identifying how aid funds are allocated between various

expenditure categories and how this ultimately affects levels of public expenditure

and revenue. There are two broad approaches in the literature that address the fiscal

response to aid and aid fungibility. One approach follows the seminal work of Heller

(1975); the other follows the framework of McGuire (1978). The Heller type models

examine government expenditure and revenue behaviour. The McGuire type studies

focus mainly on the issue of fungibility, that is, the use of aid in sectors (or projects)

not in line with the donor’s intended purpose. They also examine aid’s impact on

revenue.

4.3.1 Heller type studies of fiscal response

Heller (1975) examined aid and fiscal behaviour through an econometric model of the

public sector. A cross-section time-series data set was used for 11 African countries

for the period 1960-70. The econometric model developed by Heller has since been

used and tested by a number of researchers in estimating fiscal behaviour of aid.

In the model, Heller postulated that policy makers’ utility depends on the attainment

of target expenditures. Policy makers attempt to minimise loss by minimising


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 162

deviations of actual expenditure from target levels subject to a budget constraint given

by domestic revenue and aid. In particular, policy makers consider the following

activities: (a) alternative uses of public resources, for example, expenditures for

economic growth, for provision of current social and economic services, and for the

maintenance of political order and stability; (b) the distribution of total output

between the private and public sectors; (c) alternative modes of domestic financing

such as borrowing and taxation; (d) alternative types of external assistance, that is,

grants and loans.

The utility function of policy makers can be expressed as

U = F [ I g , (Y − T ), Gc , G s , B; A1 , A2 ]......... .......... .......... .......... .......... .......... ..( 4.1)

where Ig = public investment expenditure for development purposes, Y-T =

disposable income in the private sector, Gc = civil consumption in the public sector,

Gs = socio-economic consumption in the public sector, B = flow of public borrowing

from domestic sources, A1 = total foreign grants to the public sector from all sources,

and A2 = total foreign loans to the public sector from all sources.

Heller further assumed that a welfare-maximising government attempts to minimise

the following quadratic loss function:

L = α 0 + α 1 ( I g − I g * ) − α 2 / 2( I g − I g * ) 2 − α 3 (T − T * ) − α 4 / 2(T − T * ) 2 + α 5 (Gc − Gc* ) −

α 6 / 2(Gc − Gc ) 2 + α 7 (G s − Gs ) − α 8 / 2(G s − Gs ) − α 9 ( B − B * ) − α 10 / 2( B − B * ) 2 ...........(4.2)


* * *

subject to a budget constraint:


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 163

I g = B + (1 − P1 )T + (1 − P2 ) A1 + (1 − P3 ) A2 ................................................( 4.3)

G s + Gc = P1T + P2 A1 + P3 A2 ......................................................................(4.4)

where a starred variable indicates a target level for each variable. 1-P1, 1-P2 and 1-P3

are the proportions of tax, foreign grants and loans respectively spent on public

investment for development purpose.

The target variables were derived through estimation. For the final estimation

procedure, generalised least square (GLS) and two-stage least squares (2SLS) were

used. The findings showed that aid increased public investment but reduced domestic

taxes and borrowing. Grants were found to be more pro-consumption biased whereas

loans were found to be pro-investment. Tax increases were used more for public

consumption than public investment.

Gang and Khan (1991) used the Heller model to examine the relationship between

foreign aid and the fiscal behaviour of the Indian government. They employed non-

linear three-stage least squares (3SLS) for the estimation procedure and used times-

series data from 1961 to 1984. Gang and Khan used time-series data for a single

country, and employed non-linear three-stage least squares for the whole system.

They claimed that their procedure of combining single equation and 2SLS estimation

was an improvement on the earlier study of Heller. The results showed that grants,

loans and multilateral aid had no significant effect on government consumption. More

importantly, bilateral aid induced the transfer of domestic public resources from non-

investment to investment for development purposes. They argued that this might

happen for two reasons. First, bilateral aid was closely monitored by donors. Second,
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 164

tied aid imposed conditions to add certain resources into the same project (That is,

they needed counter financing by recipients). On the other hand, domestic tax revenue

was used to finance both civil and socio-economic consumption. Furthermore, an

increase in government consumption would be financed through increased tax

revenue but not through foreign aid.

White (1994) criticised the Gang and Khan study on a number of theoretical and

methodological grounds. White expressed doubts about the estimated target variables,

as there was no guarantee that the resulting estimated targets would be consistent with

constrained equations. White pointed out “It therefore appears that Gang and Khan’s

results are derived from the way in which the target series are estimated: as such the

results can tell us nothing about the Indian government’s fiscal response to aid

inflows” (1994: 160). In addition, White argued that Gang and Khan focused more on

partial results, ignoring reduced-form equations and hence suppressing the model’s

implicit dynamic elements. According to White, Gang and Khan produced misleading

interpretations because of these two factors.

Khan and Hoshino (1992) extended the coverage of Gang and Khan to five South and

South East Asian countries (India, Pakistan, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka and Malaysia).

The time-series data were used for India from 1955 to 1976, Malaysia from 1968 to

1976, Pakistan from 1955 to 1970, Sri Lanka from 1955 to 1976 and Bangladesh from

1972 to 1976. Due to the insufficient time-series data, they regressed the model for

pooled time-series cross-section data. The results showed that aid had impacts on both

the expenditure and the revenue sides of the recipient government’s budget.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 165

On the consumption side, aid was seen as an increase in income, and due to the

positive income elasticity, public consumption also increased but the marginal

propensity to consume of foreign aid was less than one. Loans were found to be more

important than grants for public investment. On the other hand, grants reduced the tax

burden while loans increased it. However, McGillivray (1994) pointed out that the

study only showed partial effects and ignored feedback effects. That is, Khan and

Hoshino did not estimate the reduced-form equation to obtain total (direct and

indirect) effects and suffered from the same problem as Gang and Khan.

Ahmed (1996) analysed the impact of aid on the public sector in four developing

countries (India, Pakistan, Bangladesh and Philippines) from the 1960s to the early

1990s. He included in his model the expected income feedback effects into the target

equations. This made his empirical work different from the earlier work by Heller

(1975), Gang and Khan (1991) and Khan and Hoshino (1992). Unlike the earlier

studies, he assumed that borrowing was used to finance both current consumption and

investment. Aid was also assumed to be endogenous in the model. He found that the

overall impact of aid on public sector investment, consumption, domestic borrowing

and taxation varied between countries. Generally, while aid led to an increase in both

public investment and consumption expenditure, it reduced taxation and domestic

borrowing.

Franco-Rodriguez et al. (1998) examined the impact of aid on public sector fiscal

behaviour for Pakistan using data from the period 1956-95. They analysed how aid

revenue affected the government’s fiscal behaviour with respect to tax, borrowing and

expenditure decisions. In a Heller (1975) type model, they allowed domestic


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 166

borrowing in addition to aid and tax revenue, for the purposes of financing both

capital and recurrent expenditures, and aid was assumed to be endogenous. In

addition, they replaced constraints (equations 4.3 and 4.4 above) on public sector

fiscal behaviour in the Heller model with the following:

I g = (1 − P1 )T + (1 − P2 ) A + (1 − P3 ) B

Gd + Gnd ≤ P1T + P2 A + P3 B

where Gd and Gnd are development and non-development expenditure respectively.

The rationale for an inequality constraint is “that there are external constraints, which

limit the manner in which the public sector in developing countries allocates revenue”

(Franco-Rodriguez et al. 1998: 1244). The results of their study showed that only half

of aid went to government consumption, and aid had a slightly positive impact on

public investment and a negative impact on tax efforts.

McGillivray (2000) investigated public sector behaviour in Pakistan using 1956-95

time-series data. The study is similar to the fiscal response model devised by Franco-

Rodriguez et al. (1998). While McGillivray allowed domestic borrowing to finance

both recurrent and capital expenditure in the model, the constraint equation was not

replaced by inequality. McGillivray found that both public investment and

consumption expenditure were positively associated with aid, and aid (both grants aid

and loans aid) had no impact on taxation and non-tax revenue. Grants aid did not have

any impact on public consumption expenditure, but loans aid was positively related

with both socio-economic and civil consumption expenditure.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 167

Franco-Rodriguez (2000) analysed the impact of foreign assistance to Costa Rica

using the same framework of fiscal response models as in Franco-Rodriguez et al.

(1998). The data covered the period 1971-94. While aid was endogenised on the

assumption that recipient governments had some control over the amount of aid that

was actually disbursed, borrowing was allowed to finance both development and

recurrent expenditure. The use of inequality in the budget constraint established the

maximum percentage of each revenue category that could be directed to public

consumption. When the model was applied for Costa Rica, it showed a very small

impact of aid inflows on public sector fiscal behaviour.

McGillivray (2002) used the model of Franco-Rodriguez et al. (1998) and time-series

data from 1960 to 1997 to examine the interaction between aid, structural adjustment

and the public sector fiscal behaviour in the Philippines. This study is similar to the

earlier study of Pakistan, but aid was disaggregated into multilateral and bilateral aid.

The results showed that there was a degree of fiscal indiscipline with respect to the

allocation of borrowing and multilateral aid. McGillivray found that almost all

multilateral aid had been allocated to consumption expenditure, and hence, the

multilateral aid to the Philippines had been highly fungible. Similarly, the majority of

bilateral aid had been allocated to public consumption and almost 100 per cent of

borrowing had been allocated to the consumption budget in the Philippines.

McGillivray and Ouattara (2003) investigated the impact of foreign aid on public

sector fiscal behaviour using time-series data for the period 1975-99 for Cote d’Ivoire.

They used the same model developed by Franco-Rodriguez et al. (1998) but in

addition to grants aid and loans aid, foreign debt service was included in the model.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 168

Like most fiscal response studies, target variables were approximated, as data on these

variables could not be obtained directly. These targets were estimated as a long-run

relationship, if it was possible to find a cointegrating regression between the target

variables and some explanatory variables. On the other hand, when it was not possible

to establish such a cointegrating relationship, the targets were approximated using

autoregressive techniques. The structural equations were estimated using the non-

linear three-stage least squares technique. McGillivray and Ouattara found that a large

portion of aid to Cote d’Ivoire was used for debt servicing, and aid did not appear to

induce reduction in borrowings. Furthermore, most borrowings were used to finance

government expenditure on both investment and consumption.

4.3.2 McGuire type studies of aid fungibility

Aid is said to be fungible if a recipient country uses aid for its own purposes rather

than those intended by the donors. McGuire type studies investigate whether spending

on sectors to which aid is directed actually increases by the amount of the given aid.

A graphical analysis of the McGuire model is presented in Figure 4.1 for a better

understanding of the aid fungibility problem. McGuire (1978) studied the fiscal

effects of federal grants and subsidies to local governments in the US. 24 Usually such

grants or subsidies are given for nominated use by the receiving government. They

may also come with the condition of matching funds from the recipient. Therefore,

the budget constraint of the recipient changes depending on the nature of grants. If the

grant (=BB’) is given without any restrictions, the budget constraint of the recipient

24
As noted by McGuire, the model is applicable to numerous other domestic or foreign grant programs
(McGuire, 1978: 26).
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 169

will shift outward from BB to B’B’. If the grant is conditional on matching funds

(=B’B”) for use in a particular sector then the budget constraint will move from BB to

BB”. Finally, if the grant (=BB’=BB*) is conditional only on its use (but no matching

fund) then the budget constraint will shift outward from BB to BB*B’, allowing an

increase in expenditure only on nominated sector.

Figure 4.1: A graphical presentation of McGuire model

B’

B B*

B B’ B”

Subsidised goods
Source: McGuire, 1978

According to McGuire, the actual post-grant budget constraint may differ from the

above as determined by legal conditions of the grant document. This can happen when

the recipient government’s utility function differs from that of the donor government.

There are a variety of ways the recipient government can transform a conditional

grant into fungible resources. Thus, McGuire used an unknown portion, φ, of the

grants to estimate fungibility, and assumed that the grant recipient was always at an
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 170

optimal point without taking into account grant conditionality. Given the pre-grant

budget constraint, if the recipient can treat a portion (0 ≤ φ ≤ 1) of the conditional

grant as if it were a pure revenue supplement, then the grant is fungible. If φ = 1, and

the post-grant optimal choice is an interior solution, grant is fully fungible. When φ =

0, grant is not fungible.

One of the well-known studies of aid fungibility was conducted by Pack and Pack

(1990) for Indonesia. Although they did not explicitly recognise McGuire’s work,

their model is very similar to his framework. They assumed that government faces a

budget constraint and possesses community indifference curves depicting the choice

for different public goods to be provided to citizens. Foreign aid was treated as a

budgetary supplement. 25 That is, revenue plus aid must equal total development and

current expenditure. There was no provision for internal borrowing since the fiscal

policy showed roughly balanced budgets during the investigation period of two

decades.

From the constrained optimisation solution, Pack and Pack (1990) derived three

equations for estimation in order to explore fungibility of aid and the effects of aid on

revenue raising efforts. The first equation was for non-development current

expenditure,

CEt = f (GDPt , AIDt ).................................................................................(4.5)

25
This is in line with the way Indonesia used to treat foreign aid before the changes brought about by
the economic crisis of the late 1990s. Foreign aid was regarded as revenue in the government budget.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 171

where CEt = per capita non-development current expenditure in year t, GDPt = per

capita gross domestic product, and AIDt = all categorical per capita development aid.

The second equation was for development expenditure,

Di ,t = g (GDPt , AIDi ,t , OAID j ,t , TIME )...........................................................(4.6)

where Di,t = current expenditure per capita category i in year t, AIDi,t = foreign aid

per capita designated for expenditure category i, OAIDj,t = all other categorical aid to

sectors other than i (all categorical total aid minus designated aid), and TIME = year,

included to capture the possibility that development expenditure may benefit from

scale economies or learning by doing.

The third equation was for government revenue,

Rt = h(Oilt , Non − oilt , AIDt )...............................................................................(4.7)

where R is revenue (excluding foreign aid), which is a function of oil and non-oil

gross product and aid.

The equations were estimated using a Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR)

technique for the period 1966-86. The estimated results showed that foreign aid did

not displace development expenditure, instead it stimulated total public expenditure.

Pack and Pack (1990) further found that most categorical aid was spent on the

purposes intended by donors. More importantly, their findings revealed that aid did

not lead to a reduction in domestic revenue.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 172

Pack and Pack (1993) conducted a similar type of analysis for the Dominican

Republic for the period 1968-86. In the model, as noted earlier, they assumed that

government possessed a community indifference curve and was faced by a budget

line. They estimated their model simultaneously using the SUR approach. The

findings in the case of the Dominican Republic are different from those found in

Indonesia. Foreign aid in the Dominican Republic was found to be fungible and is

consistent with the negative perception of aid that aid use diverges from its intended

purpose.

Khilji and Zampelli (1991) applied the McGuire framework to study the fungibility of

US aid to Pakistan for the period 1960-86. They used the Full Information Maximum-

Likelihood estimation technique, and found that US assistance, whether military or

non-military, was fully transformed into fungible resources, with an impact on

spending less significant than expected. An additional dollar was treated the same in

the budget regardless of its source.

Feyzioglu et al. (1996) used annual data from 1971 to 1990 for 14 developing

countries. They examined the effects of foreign aid on aggregate as well as various

other components of public spending. They explicitly postulated a variant of the

McGuire (1978) model, but contrary to McGuire allowed the aid recipient to be at a

sub-optimal level. In the spirit of Pack and Pack (1990), the recipient government

buys S public goods, {g1, g2…. gs}, in the market to provide to its citizens. It pays for

these goods by the fungible portion of foreign assistance and all other resources, R

(domestic and foreign), that it has at its disposal. A portion of the earmarked aid is

fungible if it can be treated as a revenue supplement.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 173

Feyzioglu et al. found that “a dollar given in official development assistance to

developing countries does not lead to a tax relief effect, instead it causes government

spending to increase by a dollar. Of this increase in government spending, roughly

three-quarters is spent on current expenditure and the remaining quarter on capital

expenditure” (Feyzioglu et al. 1996: 27). Hence, they claimed that the results were not

consistent with the earlier findings that foreign aid was spent entirely on consumption

and not on investment.

Following the same approach, Feyzioglu et al. (1998) analysed the relationship

between foreign aid and public spending for two different samples, 14 and 38

developing countries. They used a panel data set with annual time-series observations

from 1971 to 1990. In the first sample of 14 developing countries, they found that aid

was not fungible at the aggregate level and there was no associated tax relief. 26

However, in the case of a larger sample of 38 countries they found that aid was

fungible and part of the funds were used for tax reduction. The results further

indicated that aid was fungible in three out of five sectors examined. Governments

that received earmarked concessionary loans for agriculture, education and energy

reduced their own resources going to these sectors and used them elsewhere.

Moreover, only loans to the transport and communication sectors were fully spent on

the purposes intended by donors.

26
In the sample of 14 developing countries, a new measure of public investment that incorporated
investment by all levels of government as well as public enterprises was used. For the second sample,
that of 38 countries, they selected a country that had at least 35 per cent of the annual observation for
each of the variables used in regression.
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 174

Swaroop et al. (2000) estimated the impact of foreign aid on the central government’s

development and non-development spending in India. They used annual time-series

data from 1970 to 1995. They also used a panel database over the period of 1980-

1992 for 16 major states in India to analyse the inter-governmental fiscal link. The

study was based on the same underlying theoretical model as Feyzioglu et al. (1998),

and they used ordinary least squares and two-stage least squares regression for the

estimation procedure. To analyse aid fungibility, they made an attempt to demonstrate

two aspects of aid fungibility, one at the federal level and the other at the inter-

governmental level. They showed that the central government converted most foreign

funds, including those earmarked for state governments, into fungible funds and spent

on those activities that would have been undertaken anyway. However, foreign aid did

not influence the internally determined pattern of resource allocation in India.

4.3.3 Other major studies of fiscal behaviour

Gupta et al. (2003) examined the revenue response to inflows of foreign aid in 107

countries during 1970-2000. In the model, they decomposed foreign aid into loans and

grants, and investigated whether the impact of aid on the revenue effort depended on

the composition of aid. They modelled cross-country variation in tax shares as a

function of grants and loans flows in percentage of GDP, controlling for the structure

of the economy (agriculture value-added and industry value-added in percentage of

GDP), openness (the sum of exports and imports in percentage of GDP), and the level

of economic development (real income per capita). The results indicated that

concessional loans were generally associated with higher domestic revenue

mobilisation, while grants had the opposite effect. They argued that the relationship
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 175

between loans and tax efforts could be influenced by the fact that loans had to be

repaid. Thus, it had a positive effect on the domestic revenue effort. The results also

indicated that foreign aid was non-linearly related to domestic revenue and its impact

was influenced by the level of corruption.

Bulir and Lane (2002) analysed the impact of aid volatility on fiscal behaviour. They

argued that the positive impact of aid was undermined in some cases by the volatility

and unpredictability of aid. Aid is significantly more volatile than domestic fiscal

revenue, and the volatility of aid grows with the degree of aid dependence (see also

Bulir and Hamann, 2001). There has been a perception that aid commitments are a

weak basis for spending plans, particularly when aid is a large component of the

budget. In this case, projected fiscal deficits including committed aid will tend to

overstate the strength of fiscal position. As a policy implication, Bulir and Lane

argued that if aid is volatile or unpredictable, recipient countries have to pursue a

flexible fiscal framework in which tax and spending plans can be adjusted in response

to aid receipts.

McGillivray and Morrissey (2001) critically evaluated the findings of the impact of

aid on public sector fiscal behaviour. In particular, they focused on two important

issues in the earlier findings. First, aid leads to an increase in the total expenditure of

the recipient country by more than the value of the aid inflows, and second, aid

reduces tax revenue. They argued that “ the unintended outcomes resulted from mis-

perceptions or illusions regarding either the real or nominal value of the aid inflows,

or the way in which the aid was to be used” (2001:132).


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 176

According to McGillivray and Morrissey, the problem of aid fungibility is misleading

since the relevant issue is how aid affects fiscal behaviour and how spending plans are

implemented. They further argued that even in the presence of conditions for

fungibility, spending on the items donors want to support would not necessarily

increase by less than the value of the aid. In an earlier study, McGillivray and

Morrissey (2000) examined the concept of fungibility. They held that if donors and

recipients simply have different preferences in terms of allocation of public

expenditure, fungibility emerges easily; likewise in a case where there may be no

intended fungibility yet spending on the items targeted by donor could decrease.

Nevertheless, their conclusions were consistent with findings that aid was associated

with reductions in tax and other recurrent revenue.

4.3.4 Summary

We have presented a review of studies that address the impact of aid on government

fiscal behaviour. The survey reveals that the aid impact on fiscal behaviour varies

across countries. In some, aid did not lead to a reduction in revenue raising efforts and

aid was not diverted to unproductive uses. However, studies also found that aid was

diverted away from its intended purpose. Some studies found that aid had a positive

impact on public investment but negative impact on tax efforts; others found very

small impacts of aid on public sector fiscal behaviour.

More importantly, none of these studies used cointegration, and analysed impulse

response function to examine the time profile and adjustment of aid, revenue and

expenditure when shock hit any of them.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 177

There has been no study of fiscal response to aid in Nepal. A summary of past studies

is presented in Table 4.2.


Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 178

Table 4.2: Summary of empirical studies of aid and fiscal behaviour

Study Sample Methodology Findings Comments


Heller 11 African Used cross- Aid increased Seminal work on
(1975) countries section time- investment but fiscal response
(1960-70) series data, and reduced taxes model and used
GLS and 2SLS and borrowings government’s
utility
maximisation
framework
Pack and Indonesia, Time-series data Aid did not Model derived
Pack (1970-90) and used SUR lead to a from “median
(1990) reduction in voter model”.
domestic Focused more on
revenue efforts, aid fungibility
but stimulated rather than fiscal
total public impact
expenditure
Khilji and Pakistan Time-series data Aid was found McGuire type
Zampelli (1960-86) and used FIML to be fully model. Examined
(1991) technique fungible only the US aid

Gang and India (1961- Used time-series Grants, loans Heller type
Khan 84) data and and model. Due to
(1991) estimated full multilateral aid misspecification
system of had no of model there
simultaneous significant exist problems in
equation with effect on the interpretation
3SLS procedure government of results
consumption
Khan and 5 South and Pooled time- Loans were Extension of
Hoshino South East series and cross- found more Heller model.
(1992) Asian section data, positive for Failed to show
countries non-linear 3SLS investment total effects
(1956-76) than grants, (direct and
and while indirect) and thus
grants reduced ignored feedback
tax burdens, effects
loans increased
it
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 179

Pack and Pack Dominican Time-series Found a Model derived


(1993) Republic data and used divergence of from “median
(1968-86) SUR aid away from voter model”.
its intended The results are
purpose different from
their findings
for Indonesia.
Thus,
fungibility
depends on
country specific
factors
Ahmed (1996) 4 South Asian Pooled time- While aid led Heller type
countries series and to increases of model. Used
(1960-90) cross- section both public feedback
data. 3SLS consumption effects in
and estimation of
investment, it target variables
reduced
taxation and
domestic
borrowing
Feyzioglu et 14 developing Panel data, a Foreign aid McGuire
al. (1996) countries model of aid was spent on (1978) type
(1971-90) fungibility, both model. Not
OLS, and government conclusive
GMM consumption about the
and investment effectiveness of
aid
Feyzioglu et 14 and 38 Panel data, Aid was not McGuire
al. (1998) developing OLS and GMM fungible at the (1978) type
countries aggregate level model. Aid was
(1971-90) in a sample of found to be
14 countries more fungible
but aid was in agriculture,
found to be education and
fungible in 38 energy sector
countries
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 180

Franco- Pakistan Time-series Slightly Extended the


Rodriguez et (1956-95) data, non-linear positive impact Heller model by
al. (1998) 3SLS on public allowing
investment and borrowing on
negative impact both capital and
on tax effort consumption
expenditure and
treating aid as
an endogenous
variable
Swaroop et India (1970- Time-series Foreign aid did McGuire (1978)
al. (2000) 95) data, and used not influence type model. Aid
OLS and 2SLS the internally fungibility
determined investigated in
pattern of both federal and
resource state levels
allocation
Franco- Costa Rica Time-series A very small Heller type
Rodriguez (1971-94) data, non-linear impact of aid model. Not
(2000) 3SLS inflows on conclusive
public sector result; it could
fiscal be due to
behaviour inappropriate
target variables
and country
specific factors
McGillivray Pakistan Time-series Aid associated Heller type
(2000) (1956-95) data, non-linear positively with model.
3SLS both public Disaggregated
investment and aid into grants
consumption and loan aid,
expenditure but aid was not
and aid had no endogenised in
impact on the model
taxation
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 181

McGillivray Philippines Time-series Almost all Heller type


(2002) (1960-97) data, non- multilateral aid model.
linear 3SLS has been Ambiguous
allocated to results as he
consumption found
expenditure multilateral aid
and almost 100 was also
per cent allocated to
domestic consumption
borrowing
allocated to the
consumption
budget
McGillivray Cote d’Ivoire Time-series Large portion Heller type
and Ouattara (1975-99) data and of aid is used model. The
(2003) applied fiscal for debt findings
response servicing and it suggest that
model as a does not borrowing
maximising induce a should be
utility reduction in allowed for
framework, borrowing; both capital
non-linear also borrowing and
3SLS is used for both consumption
investment and expenditure in
consumption the model
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 182

4.4 Concluding remarks

During the 1960s, a number of studies empirically analysed the effects of foreign aid

on savings, investment and growth. Early advocates of development aid argued that

an increase in aid was necessary to boost investment, which in turn would help

achieve high economic growth. They highlighted that the required increase of aid was

only temporary as after some point in time a process of self-sustaining growth would

begin. Thus, aid was needed to help speed up the transition process to a self-

sustaining growth. The theoretical framework adopted by early advocates of aid was

an extension of the Harrod-Domar growth model, which came to be known as “two-

gap” model.

In the 1970s, the two-gap model was criticised on a number of grounds such as its

assumption of constant capital-output ratio and non-substitutability between domestic

and foreign resources. Several empirical studies found that aid affected savings

negatively, which in turn retarded economic growth. These studies also revealed that

an increased flow of aid primarily led to an increase in consumption rather than

investment. However, these studies came under severe criticisms on both

methodological and data grounds. Subsequent studies, which took account of some of

these criticisms found mixed results with regard to aid-savings-growth relationships.

Studies in the 1980s examined the aid-savings-growth relationships using more

complex models. They analysed the impact of policy environment, the possibility of

aid over-load (or the impact of a lack of absorptive capacity). There emerged some

consensus that the impact of aid may decline after certain levels of aid and policy
Chapter 4: Review of the Literature 183

environment are likely to affect aid effectiveness. There was also recognition of

limited contribution of aid as economic development depends on host of other factors.

A new trend in aid effectiveness studies emerged since the early 1990s. These studies

examined the fiscal behaviour in the presence of aid. As in the case of aid-savings-

growth studies, no firm consensus on the impact of aid on government revenue and

expenditure (both level and structure) has been found.

Since the late 1990s, the aid effectiveness debate shifted its focus to the conditional

policy environment of aid recipient countries. However, many observers feel uneasy

about conditional lending and fear that it may lead to less aid to countries, which need

aid the most.


Chapter 5

Methodology and Data

“Until not so long ago econometricians analysed time-series data in a way that was quite
different from the methods employed by time-series analysts…Neither group paid much
attention to the other until the appearance of two types of disquieting … studies. The first set
of studies claimed that forecasts using the econometricians’ methodology were inferior to
those made using the time-series analysts’ approach; the second type claimed that economic
data in fact are not stationary, and this could lead to serious problems with traditional
statistics … These revelations caused econometricians to look very hard at what they were
doing, leading to extensive research activity … that has markedly changed and improved the
way in which econometricians analyse time-series data” (Kennedy, 1992: 247).

5.1 Introduction

Past studies of aid effectiveness were mostly based on cross-country data; only few

studies used time-series data from individual countries. It is generally believed that

single country times-series analysis is more useful, as it can capture country-specific

features that may not be found in a cross-country analysis. Note though that time-

series data may produce spurious relations if the variables under study are linked to

common factors. If the variables follow a time trend (that is, their means and

variances are not constant over time), they are said to be nonstationary. Two

nonstationary variables may be found related, while in fact they are not, simply

because of the common nature of their time trends. Thus, according to Engle and

Granger (1987), the direct application of ordinary least squares or generalised least

squares to nonstationary data produces regression results that are misspecified or

spurious in nature. These regressions tend to produce performance statistics that are

inflated, such as high R2, F and t-statistic, which often lead researchers to commit

Type I errors (Granger and Newbold, 1974). 1

1
Type I error means the null hypothesis is rejected when it should not have been.
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 185

It is therefore important to test the nature of the time-series data. Most

macroeconomic time-series data are found to be nonstationary or integrated of order

1, denoted by I(1). That is, they can be made stationary by differencing the series

once. 2 Earlier researchers who performed single-country analysis used first difference

of the time-series data to avoid spurious regression. However, this creates the problem

of losing long-run information on the variables.

To deal with this, researchers are increasingly using cointegration and the error

correction mechanism (ECM) to estimate time-series relationships. In general a linear

combination of I(1) series is integrated of order 1. However, there exists a special case

where the linear combination of I(1) can be I(0) or stationary. In that case, the series

are said to be cointegrated.

It must also be remembered that the effect of aid on economic growth in any one year

is likely to be lagged and longer term. So, it is important to search for long-run

relationships between aid and growth whatever the mechanism by which aid exerts its

influence on economic performance. Cointegration allows us to test for the presence

of a non-spurious long-run equilibrium relationship between the variables under study

in a multivariate setting with and without a time trend. Both cointegration and the

error correction mechanism investigate long-run linkages and short-run dynamics

among the variables.

2
If a time-series has to be differenced d times, it is integrated of order d or I(d). If d = 0, the resulting
I(0) process represents a stationary time-series.
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 186

Our empirical estimation is composed of three steps. As a prerequisite, we first test

the stationarity/nonstationarity of the time-series data, that is, we test for the presence

of a unit root or I(1) for each variable. Second, we test for the number of cointegrating

vectors in the model. Third, we estimate and test for the long-run dynamic

relationship using the vector error correction model (VECM). In addition, we also

perform bivariate and multivariate Granger causality tests, if the variables are not

cointegrated. Finally, we analyse the impulse response function to simulate the

response of relevant variable to changes in aid, and vice versa if necessary. In this

chapter, we explain each of these in greater detail.

5.2 Unit root tests

Before testing for cointegration, a unit root test is required to ensure that the variables

under study are nonstationary I(1). The cointegration test is only applicable if the

variables are of the same order I(1). Thus, we employ two types of unit root tests, the

Augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) (Dickey and Fuller, 1979, 1981) and the Phillips–

Perron (PP) tests (Phillips and Perron, 1988), with a constant as well as a

deterministic trend. Using a constant and a trend in unit root tests has been standard

process because of the nature of time-series data.

For the ADF test, we estimate the following equation (5.1),

ΔYt = β 1 + β 2 t + ∂ 1Yt −1 + ∑ α i ΔYt −i + ε 1t ................................................(5.1)


n

i =1
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 187

where Yt is the relevant time-series, t is the time or trend variable, Δ is a first-

difference operator, and ε1t is an error term. This equation can also be estimated

without including a time trend. However, the ADF test does not adequately

distinguish between nonstationary series and stationary series that have a high degree

of autoregression. In the case of a structural break in the series, the ADF test may also

incorrectly indicate that the series contains a unit root (Culver and Papell, 1997).

We therefore perform the PP test, which provides more robust estimates when the

series have serial correlation and time-dependent heteroscedsticity and there is a

structural break. For the PP test we estimate the following equation,

ΔYt = β 1 + β 2 (t − T / 2) + ∂ 2Yt −1 + ∑ α i ΔYt −i + ε 2t ................................................(5.2)


m

i =1

In both equations (5.1) and (5.2), Δ is the first-difference operator and ε1t and ε2t are

covariance stationary random error terms. T is the number of observations. The lag

length n in equation (5.1) is determined by the Akaike’s Information Criteria (Akaike,

1973) to ensure serially uncorrelated residuals, and the lag length m in equation (5.2)

is determined as per Newey-West’s (Newley and West, 1987) suggestions.

The null hypothesis of nonstationarity is tested using the t-statistic with critical values

calculated by MacKinnon (1991). We test the null hypothesis that ∂1 and ∂2 are zero

against the hypothesis that ∂1 and ∂2 are less than zero. The null hypothesis that the

variables are nonstationary time-series is rejected if ∂1 and ∂2 are less than zero and

statistically significant. These tests are carried out for all variables by replacing Yt’s
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 188

with the variables under study in both equations (5.1) (the ADF tests) and (5.2) (the

PP test).

5.3 Test for cointegration

To understand a cointegrating relationship between variables, let us consider two

time-series, Yt and Xt, which are both nonstationary or I(1). Let us suppose that Yt

and Xt share the same stochastic trend; thus they may be tied together in the long run.

If Yt and Xt are I(1), and if the associated error term (a particular linear combination

of the variables) follows I(0), then the variables are said to be cointegrated. In other

words, two variables will be cointegrated if they have a long-run or equilibrium

relationship between them. We discuss here two approaches to the cointegration test:

the Engle–Granger (1987) approach and Johansen’s Maximum Likelihood Test

approach (Johansen, 1988 and Johansen and Juselius, 1990).

5.3.1 The Engle–Granger (1987) approach

This approach is generally used in the bivariate situation. One can test for

cointegration among the variables using the ADF or PP unit root tests on the residuals

(εt) estimated from the cointegrating regression between Yt and Xt (equation 5.3). Let

us assume that we have the following equation:

Yt = ϕ1 + ϕ 2 X t + ε t ....................(5.3)
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 189

To examine whether εt is I(0) or I(1), we should obtain the values of the error term

from the OLS estimates of equation (5.3) and perform unit root tests using the ADF

and PP procedures by replacing Yt with εt in equations (5.1) and (5.2) as mentioned

earlier. According to the Engle and Granger approach, if the error term is a stationary

process or I(0), then cointegration exists. In other words, although individually two

variables are nonstationary, if residuals are found to be stationary the regression is a

cointegration regression. The approach is called static because it ignores any dynamic

adjustments that may be present in a complete model.

5.3.2 Johansen’s approach

The Engel and Granger two-step approach cannot identify the number of

cointegrating vectors. Also, if the number of variables is more than two, the Engel and

Granger approach cannot estimate the parameters efficiently. Therefore, we use

Johansen’s method, first proposed by Johansen (1988), and Johansen and Juselius

(1990). The Johansen approach is capable of determining the number of cointegrating

vectors for any given number of nonstationary series of the same order.

Before applying the Johansen’s approach, one should first determine the lag length or

order of the vector autoregression (VAR). It is a key element in the specification of

the VAR, which forms the basis of inference for the cointegrating rank. Generally, the

lag length is chosen on the basis that the equation should pass all the diagnostic tests.

The most commonly used criteria are the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and

Schwarz Bayesian Criterion (SBC). These are given as


Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 190

AIC = ln Ω( r , p ) + ( 2 / T ) m..................................................(5.4)
&

SBC = ln Ω(r , p ) + (ln T / T ) m..............................................(5.5)


&

where Ω(r , p) = ε t ε t / T , m is the number of freely estimated parameters in a VAR


& & &/

model of lag = p and cointegrating rank = r, and ε t is a residual vector in the


&

restricted rank VAR, ln is the natural log and T is the number of observations. When

using AIC or SBC based on the estimated standard errors in equation (5.4) or (5.5)

respectively, the model with the lowest value for the AIC or SBC is chosen (see

Pesaran and Pesaran, 2003). The dominant practice is to choose lag length (p) using

one and or both of the information criteria plus the requirements that there should be

no evidence of serial correlation. One then uses the Johansen procedure to determine

the cointegrating rank.

Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990) formulate the process for

determining the cointegrating rank as follows. Consider an unrestricted VAR model

up to k lags in which the process Xt for given values of X-k+1,……X0, can be defined

as

X t = α + Π 1 X t −1 + ........... + Π k X t − k + ε t , (t = 1,2....T )...................................(5.6)

where Xt is a vector of I(1) variable, α is a vector of constant, and εt is error term.


Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 191

Since Xt is I(1), the equation (5.6) can be expressed in first-differenced error

correction form as follows: 3

ΔX t = α + Γ1 ΔX t −1 + ........... + Γk −1 ΔX t − k +1 + ΠX t − k + ε t ...............................(5.7)

where Γi = -(I-Π-……..-Πi), i = 1,……..,k-1 and Π = -(I-Π1 -………..-Πk)

The coefficient matrix Π provides information about long-run relationships between

the variables in the data vector. There are three possible implications. If the rank of Π

= p, it implies that the matrix Π has full rank and the vector process Xt is stationary. If

the rank of Π = 0, the matrix Π is a null matrix and equation (5.7) would be a

traditional differenced vector time-series model. If 0< r < p, it indicates that there

exist r cointegrating vectors; in such a case Π = αβ′, where α and β are p × r matrices.

The cointegrating vectors β have the property that β′Xt is stationary even though Xt

itself is nonstationary.

The Johansen procedure gives two likelihood ratio tests for the number of

cointegrating vectors: (1) the “maximum eigenvalue test” (λmax), which tests the null

hypothesis that there are at least r cointergrating vectors, as against the alternative that

there are r+1; (2) the “trace-test” (λtrace), where the alternative hypothesis that the

number of cointegrating vectors is equal to or less than r+1. The likelihood ratio test

statistics are as follows:

3
Error correction mechanism will be discussed later.
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 192

λmax = −T ln(1 − λr +1 ).............................................................(5.8)


&

λtrace = −T ∑ ln(1 − λ )........................................................(5.9)


n &
i = r +1
i

where λˆr +1 ,....λˆn are n-r smallest estimated eigenvalues in equation (5.9), T is the

sample size, and λi are the ordered (estimated) eigenvalues λ1> λ2> ……>λn.
&

5.3.3 Error correction mechanism

If the series are found to be nonstationary I(1) and cointegrated, Engle and Granger

(1987) and Granger (1988) suggest including an equivalent error correction model

(ECM) to re-parameterise the model. The ECM combines both short-run properties of

economic relationships in first-difference form and long-run information provided by

the data in level form. Furthermore, the ECM is considered a dynamic process

because it involves lags of dependent and independent variables and it thus captures

short-run adjustments to changes, in particular adjustments to past disequilibrium and

contemporaneous changes in the explanatory variables. The ECM also enables

researchers to estimate the speed of adjustment back to the long-run condition among

the variables. In this regard, Engle and Granger (1987) warn that failure to include the

lagged residual of the cointegrating equation in a (short-run) model in difference form

results in a misspecified relationship because the long-run properties of the model are

ignored.
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 193

Thus it can be concluded that if variables are found to be cointegrated, there must

exist an associated error correction mechanism (ECM) (Engle and Granger, 1987).

This can be shown in the following form:

ΔYt = φ 20 + ∑ φ 21i ΔYt −1 + ∑ φ 22 j ΔX t − j + ∑ φ 23k ΔZ t − k + ρ1 μ ( t −1) + ε 3t .............(5.10)


p p p

i =1 j =1 k =1

where Yt, Xt and Zt are relevant time-series, Δ denotes the first-difference operator,

μ(t-1) is the error correction term (ECT), where μt = Yt − α 0 − α1 X t − α 2 Z t , p is the lag

length (determined by AIC) and ε3 t is the random disturbance term. Here i, j and k

begin at one in order for the series to be related within a structural ECM (Engle and

Yoo, 1987). The ECT, μ(t-1), is the residual series of the cointegrating vector. For the

series to converge to the long-run equilibrium relation, –1≤ρ1≤0 should hold.

However, cointegration implies that ρ1 should not be zero.

5.4 Granger causality test

If the series are found to be I(1), but not cointegrated, we perform the Granger

causality tests. 4 To test Granger causality, we estimate a pth order vector

autoregressive model (VAR (p)), and we specify the following bivariate model:

ΔYt = φ 0 + ∑ β i ΔYt −i + ∑ λ j Δ X t − j + ε 5 t .......... .......... .......... .......... ......( 5.11)


p p

i =1 j =1

4
Granger causality testing for equations (5.11) and (5.12) is only valid if X and Y are not cointegrated
(MacDonald and Kearney, 1987). However, as discussed earlier, if the series are cointegrated, a
different approach to the causality test should be used.
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 194

ΔX t = θ 0 + ∑ α i Δ X t −i + ∑ δ j ΔYt − j + ε 6t .....................................................(5.12)
p p

i =1 j =1

where it is assumed that the disturbances ε5t and ε6t are uncorrelated. Equation (5.11)

postulates that the current Y is related to past values of itself as well as that of X, and

equation (5.12) postulates a similar behaviour for X. Unidirectional causality from X

to Y (X⇒Y) is indicated if the estimated coefficients on the lagged X in equation

(5.11) are statistically different from zero as a group (∑ λi ≠ 0), and the set of

estimated coefficients on the lagged Y in equation (5.12) is not statistically different

from zero (∑ δj = 0). Conversely, unidirectional causality from Y to X (Y⇒X) exists

if the set of lagged X coefficients in equation (5.11) is not statistically different from

zero (∑λi = 0), and the set of the lagged Y coefficients in equation (5.12) is

statistically different from zero (∑δj ≠ 0).

Feedback (or bidirectional) causality) (X⇔Y) is indicated when the sets of X and Y

coefficients are different from zero and statistically significant in both equations

(regressions). Independence (X ⊥Y) is suggested when the sets of X and Y

coefficients are not statistically significant in both regressions (equations).

5.5 Impulse response function

The impulse response function shows the response of dependent variables in the VAR

system to shocks in the error terms. Shocks or changes will alter the dependent

variable in the current as well as future periods. Since the dependent variable appears

in the regression with independent variables, the changes in the error term will also
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 195

have an impact on independent variables. In other words, an impulse response

analysis demonstrates how long and to what extent variables react to unanticipated

changes among one of them. The transmission of shocks among the variables is

investigated using the generalised impulse response analysis developed by Koop et al.

(1996) and Pesaran and Shin (1996).

Although two approaches are used to investigate impulse responses, the generalised

impulse response function is considered more efficient than the orthogonalised

impulse response one (see further Pesaran and Shin, 1996). Generalised impulse

responses are invariant to the reordering of the variables in the VAR. They also fully

take account of the historical patterns of correlations observed among different

shocks. Thus here we use the generalised impulse response function.

Impulse responses differ with model types. In the case of nonlinear models, the

impulse response is different across regimes; and it depends on the size of the shock

and the time that it occurs. History and shock independence are lost in nonlinear

models; thus measuring the effect of a shock of a given size hitting at a given time

period using impulse response may be very misleading (Koop et al., 1996). However,

in the case of linear models, the impulse response does not depend on the size of the

shock or the time at which it takes place. In other words, the impulse response

functions for linear models are both shock and history independent.

Furthermore, the impulse response function in a linear model typically measures the

effect of a shock of size 1. Shocks of different sizes produce only a scale effect; for

example, a shock of size 2 would produce an impulse response twice that of size 1.
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 196

More importantly, the effect of the shock is also independent of the time that it occurs

because the impulse response would be the same regardless of whether the economy

was in expansion or contraction (Koop, 1996).

Koop et al. (1996) developed a generalised impulse response function that addresses

the problems of history and size of shock and is thus applicable to both linear and

non-linear models. The generalised impulse response function uses the expected

values of the series conditional on only the history and/or shock. In precise terms, the

response is a representation of the average of possible reactions with the given choice

of history and current shock.

Let us assume that yt in a simple AR (1) process:

y t = α 0 + α 1 y t −1 + ε t ......................................................(5.13)

where εt is a random shock and α0 and α1 are parameters.

A simple form of the generalised impulse response function can then be given as

GI = E[ y t + n / ε t = δ , ε t +1 = 0,............, ε t + n = 0, ω t −1 = ω t0−1 ,θ = θ 0 ]

− E[ y t + n / ε t = 0, ε t +1 = 0,..............., ε t + n = 0, ω t −1 = ω t0−1 ,θ = θ 0 ...................(5.14)

where GI stands for the generalised impulse response function, θ is the set of

parameters and εt ……. εt+n are shocks. Equation (5.14) measures the effect of a shock

of a given size (δ) hitting at a given time period (ω0t-1), given that no other shocks hit

the system. The first term in equation (5.14) provides the expected realisation given
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 197

the once-and-for-all shock, and the second term is the expected realisation without the

shock.

Therefore, the generalised impulse response function can be defined as the difference

between the expected yt+n after the shock and the expected yt+n assuming no shocks. In

other words, it compares the value of yt+n after the shock has occurred (first

realisation) with its benchmark value (second realisation) where the economy has not

been subject to any shocks.

5.6 Data sources and their description

Data provided by the national sources differ significantly from those found in

international sources such as the IMF and UNDP. 5 This is particularly problematic in

the case of aid data. It is generally believed that OECD aid data are more reliable as

these are collected directly from the donors who have better recording system than

Nepal. Similarly, IMF data on macroeconomic indicators and socio-economic data of

the World Bank are considered more reliable. Although these data are mostly

collected from national sources, the IMF and the World Bank do internal consistency

checks and supplement the data from the national sources with their occasional

sectoral surveys/studies.

The IMF (2004) also identified data problems in Nepal. They noted, “The statistics

are deficient due to lack of comprehensive and regular data sources. The limited

source data suffer from inconsistencies, lags in availability, and insufficient detail.

5
See Mihaly (2002)
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 198

There are shortcomings in record keeping by agencies and access to records is not

timely due to processing lags. Reflecting source data problems, compilation methods

rely heavily on fixed ratios derived from past year surveys or ad hoc assumptions”

(2004: 51).

Therefore, this research uses data mostly from the international sources whenever

they are available. Table 5.1 lists the sources of variables data used in this study.

Table 5.1: Sources of data

IMF OECD World Bank CBS


Nominal GDP Total foreign aid Adult literacy rate Development
expenditure
GDP deflator Bilateral aid Labour force
Non-development
Gross domestic savings Multilateral aid Total population (regular) expenditure

Gross fixed capital Grants aid Public investment


formation (investment)
Loans aid
Total revenue (tax and
non-tax revenue)

Budget deficit

Domestic borrowing

Notes: (a) IMF: International Financial Statistics (IFS) online database


(b) OECD: International Development Statistics (IDS) online database
(c) World Bank: World Development Indicators (WDI) online database
(d) CBS: Statistical Year Book of Nepal

Definitions of variables used in estimation

RGDP = real GDP (converted from nominal to real using GDP deflator, (1995 = 100))

RGDPP = per capita real GDP (=RGDP/total population)

AR = total foreign aid as a percentage of GDP (net official development assistance

excluding military aid)


Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 199

BAR = bilateral aid as a percentage of GDP

MAR = multilateral aid as a percentage of GDP

GR = grants aid as a percentage of GDP

LAR = loans aid as a percentage of GDP

SR = gross domestic savings as a percentage of GDP

IR = gross fixed capital formation as a percentage of GDP

KP = capital stock

TR = exports + imports as a percentage of GDP

INF = inflation percentage change in CPI

BORR = domestic borrowing as a percentage of GDP

BDR = budget deficit as a percentage of GDP

MONR = broad money (M2) as a percentage of GDP

ADLR = adult literacy rate

AID = per capita aid (= total aid/total population)

REV = per capita revenue (= total tax and non-tax revenue/total population)

Gd = per capita development expenditure (= development expend/total population)

Gnd = per capita non-development expenditure (= non-dev. expend./total population)

5.6.1 Statistical summary of data and data limitations

Table 5.2 shows descriptive statistics of variables. During 1970-2002, the mean

growth rate of real GDP was 4 per cent. During the same period, aid as a percentage

of GDP grew at an average rate of 4.9 per cent. This indicates the possibility of high

correlation between Nepal’s economic growth and aid flows.


Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 200

Table 5.2: Statistical summary of variables, 1970-2002

Variables Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Skewness Kurtosis Normality Probability
RGDP 161137.80 142366.00 306622.70 86236.67 66986.56 0.69 2.22 3.43 0.18
RGDP
growth 4.00 4.40 9.68 -2.97 2.97 -0.52 3.21 1.43 0.49
RGDPP 8856.36 8337.57 12459.78 6883.54 1733.39 0.63 2.04 3.45 0.18
RGDPP
growth 1.72 2.06 7.30 -5.05 2.86 -0.49 3.25 1.30 0.52

AR 8.06 8.31 15.27 2.66 3.48 0.02 2.22 0.84 0.66


AR
growth 4.91 4.21 60.51 -28.43 19.99 0.98 4.34 7.25 0.03
BAR 4.79 4.76 8.96 1.69 1.93 0.11 2.19 0.97 0.62
MAR 3.26 3.54 7.62 0.37 1.72 0.09 2.71 0.16 0.92
GR 5.40 5.63 8.29 1.89 2.07 -0.37 1.92 2.35 0.31
LAR 2.65 2.59 6.98 0.46 1.64 0.69 3.09 2.60 0.27
TR 35.50 31.80 64.04 13.21 14.62 0.36 2.10 1.85 0.40

IR 16.67 17.59 22.53 5.71 4.72 -0.99 3.05 3.28 0.17


SR 10.79 11.23 15.02 2.57 3.47 -0.88 2.89 4.15 0.13

LF 8.11 7.82 10.81 6.11 1.48 0.44 1.94 2.59 0.27


POP 17.49 16.97 24.61 12.11 3.79 0.31 1.88 2.25 0.32
ADLR 28.27 27.00 44.00 16.00 8.46 0.31 1.90 2.19 0.33

INF 8.84 8.35 19.81 2.00 4.72 0.56 2.82 1.74 0.42
MONR 29.61 28.42 53.54 10.62 12.19 0.34 2.31 1.31 0.52
BDR 4.36 3.89 8.98 0.27 2.35 0.27 2.24 1.21 0.55

Notes: (a) RGDP is in Rs. (million), RGDPP is in Rs. (thousand).


(b) LF (labour force) and POP (total population) are in millions.
(c) The last two columns give the Jarque–Bera normality test with its probability. The other
test statistics measure the difference of the skewness and kurtosis of the series with those from
the normal distribution. Skewness is a measure of asymmetry of the distribution of the series
around the mean. Kurtosis measures the peakedness or flatness of the distribution of the
series.

During the sample period Nepal’s real mean GDP was Rs. 161,137.80 million and real

GDP per capita was Rs. 8,856.36 thousand. The mean investment rate and the mean

saving ratio were 16.7 per cent and 10.7 per cent respectively, showing an average

savings–investment gap of 6 per cent of GDP. During the same period the mean aid

flows was 8.06 per cent of GDP. This shows the importance of aid in filling the savings–

investment gap. The mean aid/GDP ratio is more than the mean savings–investment gap
Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 201

(as a percentage of GDP). This is expected as Nepal receives a significant amount of

humanitarian aid.

The mean trade/GDP ratio (35.5), inflation rate (8.8), budget deficit/GDP (4.4) and

M2/GDP (29.6) indicate that Nepal’s economy was reasonably open and

macroeconomically stable, and its financial sector moderately developed. That is, Nepal

had a reasonably good policy environment during the period of study.

The Jarque–Bera test for normality shows that except for one variable (AR growth =

growth rate of aid/GDP ratio), all variables are normally distributed (Table 5.2). A very

high standard deviation also indicates that the growth rate of the aid/GDP ratio suffers

from wild fluctuations. This has been confirmed by Figure 5.1, which shows the growth

rates of real GDP and aid/GDP ratio. During 1970-81, growth rate of real GDP

fluctuated between negative and positive values. For example, the real GDP growth went

from -0.5 per cent in 1973 to over 6 per cent in 1974. Likewise it fluctuated from -2 in

1980 to over 8 per cent in 1981. The coefficient of variation (CV) during 1970-1982 is

higher than in the period 1983-2002.

Therefore, in chapter 6 where the relationship between GDP and aid is examined, we

shall be using data for the period 1983-2002. Incidentally, this is also the period when

Nepal initiated the Structural Adjustment Program under the guidance of the IMF and

the World Bank, which resulted in an improved macroeconomic environment.


Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 202

Figure 5.1: Growth rates of real GDP and foreign aid/GDP ratio, 1970-2002

CV = 1.37 (1970-1982) CV = 0.55 (1983-2002)

12
10
8
6
4 Real GDP growth
2
0
-2
1970

1972

1974
1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986
1988

1990

1992

1994

1996
1998

2000

2002
-4

CV = 1.85 (1970-1982) CV = 1.47 (1983-2002)

120
100
80
60
40 Aid/GDP growth
20
0
-20
1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986
1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002
-40

Note: CV (coefficient of variation) = standard deviation/mean


Source: IMF/IFS and OECD/IDS online databases

Since the early 1980s, Nepal has maintained relatively higher economic growth due

mainly to economic liberalisation. During 1983-2002, the mean growth rates of real GDP

and per capita real GDP were 4.81 and 2.43 per cent respectively. During the same

period, the mean ratios of aid/GDP, trade/GDP and M2/GDP were 10, 44 and 37 per cent

respectively (Table 5.2A). The statistical summary of data for the period of 1983-2002

show that GDP and aid growth data are less volatile in the 1980s than the whole sample

period mainly because of high volatility in the 1970s.


Chapter 5: Methodology and Data 203

Table 5.2A: Statistical summary of variables 1983-2002

Variables Mean Median Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Skewness Kurtosis Normality Probability
RGDP 200690.85 192119.83 306622.68 116949.97 57407.22 0.32 -1.05 1.49 0.48
RGDP
growth 4.81 4.69 9.68 -2.97 2.68 -1.01 3.44 0.39 0.82
RGDPP 9876.32 9727.68 8927.97 6883.54 1495.71 0.10 -1.10 1.99 0.37
RGDPP
growth 2.43 2.34 7.30 -5.05 2.56 -0.93 3.22 0.36 0.83

AR 10.07 9.70 15.27 6.65 2.44 0.45 -0.62 0.94 0.63


AR
growth -0.45 -0.31 23.76 -20.78 13.02 0.23 -0.60 1.78 0.41
BAR 5.95 5.87 8.96 4.07 1.36 0.45 -0.59 1.27 0.53
MAR 4.13 4.08 7.62 1.19 1.37 0.27 1.61 0.59 0.75
GR 6.65 6.71 8.29 4.71 1.17 -0.07 -1.44 1.49 0.47
LAR 3.42 3.17 6.98 0.53 1.56 0.52 0.30 2.15 0.34
TR 43.85 43.26 64.04 30.10 11.96 0.23 -1.70 2.87 0.24

IR 19.56 19.40 22.53 16.44 4.20 -0.85 -0.90 2.54 0.28


SR 12.23 13.30 15.02 7.87 3.04 -0.88 -1.12 2.58 0.27

LF 9.04 8.91 8.27 6.20 0.64 0.22 1.33 1.20 0.55


POP 19.93 19.75 18.19 12.35 1.82 0.17 1.18 1.18 0.56
ADLR 33.75 33.50 44.00 25.00 4.14 0.24 -1.23 1.29 0.52

INF 8.77 8.30 19.00 2.48 4.69 0.60 0.06 0.26 0.88
MONR 37.27 34.91 53.54 27.52 8.80 0.73 -0.81 1.62 0.45
BDR 5.72 5.80 8.98 3.28 1.83 0.34 -1.18 1.63 0.44

Note: See Table 5.2

The data series on savings and investment do not have the same problem as GDP data. Thus, in

chapter 7 we shall use the longer data series (1970-2002), where the relationship between aid and

savings/investment is examined. The fiscal data are available only from 1975. Therefore, for the

investigation of aid and fiscal behaviour (chapter 8), we shall use data from 1975.

5.7 Computer programs and software

We have used Microfit version 4.0 developed by Pesaran and Pesaran (2003) for cointegration and

the error correction mechanism. We have also used Eviews 4.1, developed by Quantitative Micro

Software (2000), for the unit root tests and summary statistical analyses.
Chapter 6

Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal

“… ‘foreign assistance’ has become virtually a separate factor of production whose


productivity and allocation provide one of the central problems for a modern theory of
development” (Chenery and Strout, 1966: 679).

6.1 Introduction

This chapter examines the relationship between foreign aid and per capita real GDP.

The theoretical foundation of our analysis is the neoclassical production function,

where foreign aid is assumed to influence technology and capital formation. Using

this neoclassical framework, an empirical model is developed specifying the

relationship between foreign aid and per capita real GDP. This chapter investigates

aid’s influence through technology, while following chapter analyses its influence

through capital formation.

We begin our estimation first with aggregate aid and then disaggregated forms of aid.

The effectiveness of foreign aid is believed to be greater when there is

macroeconomic stability and few distortions. It has been argued that distortionary

policies such as trade restrictions and financial repression reduce the efficiency of

investment. Thus, following recent studies (for example, Burnside and Dollar, 2000;

World Bank, 1998 and Hansen and Tarp, 2000), we incorporate policy variables in

our model to investigate whether policy variables impact on the effectiveness of

foreign aid.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 205

Table 6.1 provides a comparative perspective of Nepal in terms of its policy

environment. Among South Asian countries, Nepal experienced the second highest

average growth rate, about 5 per cent during 1990-2002. During the 1990s, there have

been significant improvements in openness, financial deepening and inflation. For

example, average trade/GDP increased from about 32 per cent in the 1980s to over 50

per cent in the 1990s, and during the same period average M2/GDP increased from

28.08 per cent to about 42 per cent.

Table 6.1: Average growth rates of real GDP and policy variables for South
Asian countries, 1980-90, 1991-2002 and 1970-2002
Average real Average Average Average Average budget
Country GDP growth trade/GDP (%) M2/GDP (%) inflation rate deficit/GDP (%)
Nepal
1980-1990 4.11 31.57 28.08 10.60 -8.86
1991-2002 5.01 50.34 41.70 8.02 -7.05
1970-2002 4.00 32.97 30.20 8.80 -6.67
Bangladesh*
1980-1990 3.57 20.95 26.03 7.36*** -
1991-2002 4.94 28.59 31.15 4.31 -
1974-2002 4.81 22.99 26.58 5.49** -
India
1980-1990 3.90 14.86 41.66 9.10 -7.34
1991-2002 5.40 22.85 50.50 7.95 -5.54
1970-2002 4.48 17.01 41.45 8.26 -5.60
Pakistan
1980-1990 6.41 33.79 41.27 7.42 -6.64
1991-2002 3.80 36.64 46.18 7.91 -6.91
1970-2002 4.84 32.69 43.55 8.96 -7.10
Sri Lanka
1980-1990 4.87 68.02 30.62 13.61 -10.88
1991-2002 4.74 77.84 35.76 10.62 -7.69
1970-2002 4.58 69.76 30.78 10.30 -8.71

Notes: (a) Nepal’s budget deficit including grants during the periods 1980-90, 1990-2002 and 1970-2002 were -
6.21, -4.97 and -4.36 respectively.
(b) *, ** and *** indicate data from 1974-2002, 1987-2002 and 1987-90 respectively, and budget deficit
data are not available for Bangladesh.
Source: IMF/IFS online database.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 206

In addition, average inflation and budget deficit/GDP decreased to 8 and 7 per cent

respectively in the 1990s. Thus, macroeconomic stability, opening up the economy

and financial deepening may have contributed positively to economic growth in

Nepal. One can therefore expect aid to be more effective during this period because of

a better policy environment.

We perform unit root tests and employ cointegration and the error correction

mechanism to estimate the aid–growth relationship in Nepal using data for the period

1970-2002. However, as explained in chapter 5, due to large fluctuations of GDP and

aid data in the 1970s, sometimes moving from a high positive to a high negative

figure, we have limited our final estimation to a 20-year period (1983-2002). This also

happened to be the period when Nepal initiated policy reforms under the Structural

Adjustment Programs of the IMF and the World Bank and attained macroeconomic

stability.

The organisation of this chapter is as follows. The next section discusses the model,

data and methodology. Section 6.3 describes the results of the unit root test, followed

by an analysis of the results of the cointegration and error correction models. Section

6.4 has concluding remarks.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 207

6.2 Model and data

6.2.1 Model specification (aid and growth)

Our estimation proceeds with the formulation of a neoclassical production function

type model, as follows:

Yt = At F ( K t 1 Lt 2 )............................................(6.1)
α β β

where Yt is real GDP, Kt is the stock of capital, Lt is the labour force, and At

represents the level of technology with which inputs are used in the production

process. The parameters α, β1 and β2 measure the elasticities of Yt with respect to At,

Kt and Lt respectively. Subscript “t” represents time.

Assuming that the production function displays a constant returns to scale (i.e. β1+ β2

= 1), we can express equation (6.1) in per capita form, and taking natural logarithm,

we derive the following equation:

ln RGDPPt = α ln At + β 1 ln KPt .........................................(6.2)

where RGDPPt = per capita real GDP, At = level of technology, and KPt= capital

(K/Population). 1 ln is the natural logarithm operator.

1
Strictly speaking, it should be total employment. But due to unavailability of data, we are using total
population. This should not affect the overall result where there is a strict positive relationship between
total employment and population.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 208

Thus, equation (6.2) shows that a country’s per capita real GDP depends on the ratio

of factor inputs and the level of technology.

The level of technology can be affected by foreign aid, because aid contributes to the

acquisition of technical knowledge in developing countries (see Islam, 2003 and

Marvotas, 2002). This happens through two channels: (1) importation of capital

equipment and (2) technical assistance. Aid finances capital imports such as

machinery and equipment from developed countries. The import of new equipment

not only introduces new technology but also upgrades local technological knowledge.

In the context of Nepal, in the mid 1990s over 40 per cent of total aid came in the

form of technical assistance (HMG/N, 2002). Thus, it is reasonable to assume that

foreign aid affects GDP growth through technological progress as technical assistance

contributes to improving institutions and policies.

Foreign aid effectiveness depends on the absorptive capacity of recipient countries,

for which human capital may be considered an important component (see Chauvet

and Guillaumont, 2003). In other words, how effectively imported technology is used

depends on the skill level of the labour force. Labour may be abundant in developing

countries but most people are unskilled. Moreover, theories of technological diffusion

stress the importance of the recipient country having a sufficiently high level of social

capability for successful implementation of technologies imported from more

advanced countries (see, for example, Abramovitz, 1986 and Howitt, 2000). To

capture this, we have included the adult literacy rate as an additional determinant of

technology. We can therefore express the level of technology as follows:


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 209

ln At = α 0 + α 1 ln ADLRt + α 2 ln ARt ...............................................(6.2a )

Strictly speaking the level of technology is determined also by accumulated past aid

flows. To some extent the effect of past aid flows is captured in our estimation when

we use VAR with lag values of variables. Substituting equation (6.2a) into equation

(6.2), we get

ln RGDPPt = αα 0 + αα 1 ln ADLRt + αα 2 ln ARt + β 1 ln KPt ............(6.3)

For the purpose of estimation, we rewrite equation (6.3) as

ln RGDPPt = θ 1 + θ 2 ln KPt + θ 3 ln ADLRt + θ 4 ln ARt + u1t ...............(6.4)

where αα0 = θ1, αα1 = θ3, αα2 = θ4, θ2 = β1, and u1t = error term.

Although aid affects GDP through the level of technology and capital formation, we

are only investigating the technology effect in this chapter. The following chapter will

examine the capital formation effect of aid.

Coefficients of ARt and ADLRt measure the effect of aid on real per capita GDP

through their effects on the level of technology; thus equation (6.4) is our main model.

Next we disaggregate total aid down into bilateral and multilateral aid. Bilateral and

multilateral aid may differ along many dimensions such as donors’ motives and aid
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 210

conditionality (Ram, 2003). 2 The contents of the aid package and the conditions

associated with aid seem quite different for both bilateral and multilateral aid.

Multilateral aid has for quite some time been disbursed on a conditional basis for

Structural Adjustment Programs and the fulfillment of certain requirements. On the

other hand, bilateral aid has distinctive features, and largely depends on donors’

strategic interests. Thus, these two types of aid may have different impacts on the

economy, which can be estimated by using the following equation:

ln RGDPPt = ∂ 0 + ∂ 1 ln KPt + ∂ 2 ln ADLRt + ∂ 3 ln BARt + ∂ 4 ln MARt + u 2t ..............(6.5)

where BARt = bilateral aid as percentage of GDP and MARt = multilateral aid as

percentage of GDP.

We also disaggregate total aid into grants and loans aid, assuming that both kinds of

aid may have different impacts on the economy (Gupta et al., 2003). It is generally

argued that grants are free resources, and thus are likely to be misused. On the other

hand, loans are considered to be more effective due to the future repayment

obligations (Islam, 1992). However, loans may have a negative impact on growth by

due to debt burden. We investigate these different impacts incorporating grants and

loans aid in the following equation:

ln RGDPPt = δ 1 + δ 2 ln KPt + δ 3 ln ADLRt + δ 4 ln GRt + δ 5 ln LARt + u 3t ..............(6.6)

2
See also earlier works such as Griffin and Enos (1970) discussing aid and political motives. Burnside
and Dollar (2000) also found that bilateral aid is influenced by donor interest, while multilateral aid is
given according to income level, population and policy.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 211

where GRt, and LARt are grants and loans aid as percentage of GDP respectively.

6.2.2 Model specification (aid and policy)

In the recent literature, macroeconomic stability and good policy environment are

regarded as a crucial condition for effective aid implementation and thus for rapid

economic growth. The World Bank, for example, has emphasised the need for a

supportive macroeconomic framework for successful structural adjustments.

According to the World Bank, this involves low and predictable inflation, appropriate

real interest rates, real exchange rates that are competitive and stable, sustainable

fiscal policy, and a viable balance of payments position (World Bank, 1990). The

effectiveness of capital flows will be greater when there is macroeconomic stability

and few distortions. Generally, it is argued that distortionary policies such as trade

restrictions and financial repression 3 reduce the efficiency of investment. The role

played by macroeconomic factors and distortionary policies has been emphasised by

Kormendi and Meguire, 1985; Fischer, 1991 and 1993 and Easterly, 1993.

The role of international trade is considered to be crucial for technological progress in

developing countries. In the long run, exports spur economic growth through

technological progress (Krueger, 1978). Sengupta and Espana (1994) argue that trade,

particularly exports, bring economy-wide structural changes in the form of technical

innovations and diffusion of skill-intensive externality of human capital, and thus

contribute to a higher level of aggregate productivity. Trade also promotes growth

through increased specialisation, efficient resource allocation, and diffusion of


3
Financial repression arises due to the policy of fixing interest rate ceiling at a level not consistent with
high inflation rates of a country. This results in a negative or very low real interest rate. The negative
real interest rate discourages savings, and hence is detrimental for the growth of the financial sector.
The negative real interest rate also encourages inefficiency in the use of loans, which in turn lowers the
returns to investment.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 212

international knowledge (Sachs and Warner, 1995). At the same time, it also improves

a country’s credit ratings by generating hard currencies, and thus makes it easier to

obtain foreign loans. However, if imports rise at a faster rate than exports, a country’s

growth may hit a balance of payments constraint (Thirlwall, 2003). According to the

two-gap model, aid can help in this situation.

Choice of policy indicators

Fischer (1993) suggests the inflation rate as the best single indicator of

macroeconomic policies, along with budget surplus/deficit as a second indicator. The

inflation rate indicates government’s overall ability to manage the economy. That is,

high inflation rates imply that the government has lost control of its budget. He also

suggests including budget deficit as an additional explanatory policy indicator.

According to the World Bank (1990), reductions in fiscal deficits have typically been

at the core of successful Stabilisation Programs and are prerequisites for successful

structural adjustment and improved efficiency of investment. Thus, the reduction of

fiscal deficit may contribute to better economic performance. Following Fischer

(1993), we are taking inflation and budget deficit as indicators of macroeconomic

policy in our analysis.

Financial repression is also considered to be detrimental to growth. Many developing

countries over-regulate their financial sector through controls on interest rates and

restrictions on credit to the private sector. This hampers financial intermediation and

financial deepening. Many researchers have used the M2/GDP as an indicator of

financial deepening. We therefore use M2/GDP as an indicator of financial deepening

in our model.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 213

Various measures of openness have been proposed and empirically tested. There is no

single best measure; it all depends on availability of data and the methodology to be

employed. 4 Therefore, to reflect the degree of openness, we incorporate trade (exports

plus imports as a percentage of GDP) in the model.

In sum, we have used consumer price index (CPI) and budget deficit/GDP as

measures of macroeconomic policy, trade/GDP as a measure of openness, and

M2/GDP as a financial sector policy in the model. 5 We begin by looking at the two-

variable relationships to get an idea of how policy variables affect growth. The

equations we estimate are as follows:

ln RGDPPt = δ 21 + δ 23 ln TRt + u 4t ..........................................................(6.7a )

ln RGDPPt = δ 31 + δ 32 ln CPI t + u 5t ........................................................(6.7b)

ln RGDPPt = δ 41 + δ 42 ln MONRt + u 6t ...................................................(6.7c)

where TR = total trade/GDP, CPI = consumer price index, and MONR = M2/GDP.

Next, we estimate the following equations adding two policy variables at a time to the

main model (equation 6.4):

4
Edwards (1998), for instance, used a series of openness indices for trade policy and to proxy trade
distortions. Sachs and Warner (1995) considered five conditions – non-tariff barriers, average tariff
rates, a black market exchange rate, a socialist economic system, and a state monopoly on major
exports – to judge whether a country has a closed economy. If a country has one of these
characteristics, then it has a closed economy. All these measures are found to be inadequate in some
aspects. (See Dowrick, and Golley, 2004.)
5
Budget deficit as a measure of macroeconomic stability correlated highly with inflation and did not
perform well. Therefore, we did not use this budget deficit in our subsequent analyses.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 214

ln RGDPPt = δ 51 + δ 52 ln AR t + δ 53 ln KPt + δ 54 ln ADLR t + δ 565 ln TR t + δ 56 ln CPI t + u 7 t .......... .......... (6.7 d )

ln RGDPPt = δ 61 + δ 62 ln AR t + δ 63 ln KPt + δ 64 ln ADLR t + δ 65 ln TR t + δ 66 ln MONR t + u 8t .......... .......( 6.7e)

ln RGDPPt = δ 71 + δ 72 ln AR t + δ 73 ln KPt + δ 74 ln ADLR t + δ 75 ln MONR t + δ 76 ln CPI t + u 9t .......... .....( 6.7 f )

6.2.3 Data

We use annual time-series data from 1970 to 2002 for Nepal. Data on GDP,

investment, trade, adult literacy, population and labour force are obtained from the

IMF, International Financial Statistics (online) and the World Bank, World

Development Indicators (online). Data on aid flows are obtained from the OECD,

International Development Statistics (online). GDP deflator (1995 = 100) is used to

convert nominal GDP into real terms. Aid data are converted into national currency

using the nominal exchange rate, as IFS data are in national currency terms.

As mentioned in chapter 5, we observe wild fluctuations in the growth rates of aid

flows and GDP during the 1970s. We tried to smooth out data by taking the moving

average but it did not produce better (sensible) results. Therefore, we have used data

from 1983 to 2002 in our final analyses in this chapter. 6

6
Although one should have at least 30 years of data for cointegration analysis, we had to limit our
analysis to a shorter data length. Studies such as Murthy et al. (1994), Giles (1994), Granger et al.
(2000), Ratanapakorn and Sharma (2002), and Sander and Kleimeir (2003) also used short data series.
The shorter data series may make the estimates less robust. However, in order to back up our
conclusions, we have examined aid effectiveness from alternative perspectives in the following two
chapters using longer data series.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 215

Estimation of capital stock data

Following Ramirez (2000), capital stock is estimated as follows:

K t = K t −1 + I t − δK t −1

where Kt-1 is the stock of capital at time t-1, It is the gross investment during time t

and δ is the rate at which the capital stock depreciated in period t-1. The initial stock

of capital is estimated by summing five years of gross investment (1965-69) assuming

a rate of depreciation of 10 per cent. To ensure the robustness of the econometric

results, two alternative rates of depreciation (5 per cent and 20 per cent) were also

used, but the results were not significant. 7 Furthermore, we divide estimated capital

stock by total population to convert the model into a per capita form.

Table 6.2 presents correlation coefficients between real GDP (both total and per

capita) and the variables used in the model. As can be seen, most variables correlate

well with both real GDP and per capital real GDP.

Table 6.2: Correlation coefficients of variables, 1983-2002

Variables Real GDP Per capita real GDP


KP 0.93 0.93
AR 0.38 0.38
BAR 0.48 0.49
MAR 0.22 0.22
GR 0.49 0.49
LAR 0.18 0.19
TR 0.90 0.90
LF 0.99 0.99
POP 0.99 0.98
INF -0.30 -0.30
MONR 0.97 0.96
BDR 0.25 0.23
ADLR 0.99 0.98

7
See appendix 6.2 at the end of the thesis (after references).
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 216

6.3 The empirical results and their interpretations

6.3.1 Unit root tests

Prior to testing for cointegration, we examine the stationarity of time-series variables.

Since the final estimation is based on data from 1983 to 2002, ADF tests are

performed for this sub-period. Results of both ADF and PP tests on the level and first

difference of the variables are presented in Tables 6.3 and 6.4 respectively. Since in

the majority of cases AIC selected the lag length of 2, we fixed the lag length of 2 for

both tests. Tables 6.3A and 6.4A show the results with a constant and a time trend,

while Tables 6.3B and 6.4B present the results with a constant only. The use of a

constant and a time trend is a standard practice because of the nature of time-series

data.

The results indicate that the null hypothesis of nonstationarity cannot be rejected for

any of the variables in their level form. When the ADF test is applied to these

variables in first difference under the assumption of a constant and a deterministic

time trend, all variables are found to have unit roots except for lnRGDPP, lnMAR,

lnBDR, lnCPI and lnMONR.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 217

Table 6.3A: ADF test (Lag = 2) with constant and time trend, 1983-2002

First 10% critical 5% critical 1% critical


Variables Levels difference value value value

lnRGDPP -0.79 -3.91** -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnKP -2.11 -2.88 -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnAR -1.41 -2.58 -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnTR -2.77 -2.74 -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnBAR -2.78 -2.72 -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnMAR -0.85 -4.41** -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnGR -2.32 -2.57 -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnLAR -1.78 -3.10 -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnADLR -2.14 -2.84 -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnMONR -1.06 -5.76* -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnCPI -0.94 -3.37*** -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

lnBDR -2.36 -4.61* -3.26 -3.65 -4.49

Note: *, ** and *** indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 218

Table 6.3B: ADF test (Lag = 2) with constant only, 1983-2002

First 10 % critical 5 % critical 1% critical


Variables Levels difference value value value

lnRGDPP 2.18 -2.46 -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnKP -1.74 -2.66*** -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnAR -1.26 -2.44 -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnTR -2.33 -2.69*** -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnBAR -0.44 -2.79*** -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnMAR -3.72** -1.45 -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnGR -0.98 -2.36 -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnLAR -1.71 -3.04** -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnADLR -1.30 -2.64 -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnMONR -2.53 -3.98* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnCPI 1.37 -2.97 -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnBDR -2.15 -4.36* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

Note: See Table 6.3A.

On the other hand, the test results under the assumption of a constant only show unit

roots in the level form for all variables except for lnMAR, while in its first difference

form only six variables, lnKP, lnBAR, lnTR, lnMONR, lnLAR and lnBDR, are found

to be stationary (Table 6.3B). Thus, the ADF test is found to be inconsistent even in

the first difference form when the 1983-2002 period is considered.

We therefore apply the PP test. As mentioned in the previous chapter on

methodology, the PP test is more appropriate than the ADF test because it considers
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 219

structural breaks. When the PP test is performed under the assumption of a constant

and a deterministic time trend, all the variables are found to be stationary at the one

per cent significant level in the first difference form only (Table 6.4A).

Table 6.4A: PP test (Lag = 2) with constant and time trend, 1983-2002

First 10 % critical 5 % critical 1% critical


Variables Levels difference value value value

lnRGDPP -3.01 -7.44* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnKP -3.41 -8.07* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnAR -2.30 -6.51* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnTR -2.95 -5.49* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnBAR -3.31 -5.94* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnMAR -2.05 -8.56* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnGR -2.29 -5.10* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnLAR -2.87 -8.26* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnADLR -3.39 -7.97* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnMONR -1.22 -4.38** -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnCPI -1.40 -3.79** -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

lnBDR -2.72 -4.87* -3.26 -3.67 -4.53

Note: See Table 6.3A.

Table 6.4B provides the results of a PP test for the variables in both level and

differenced forms under the assumption of a trend only. We find that all the variables

in their level form are non-stationary except for lnMAR and lnMONR. In the case of
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 220

first difference form, however, the null hypothesis of nonstationarity is rejected for all

variables. Hence, our investigation of stationarity is based on the PP test.

Table 6.4B: PP test (Lag = 2) with constant only, 1983-2002

First 10% critical 5% critical 1% critical


Variables Levels difference value value value

lnRGDPP -1.58 -7.60* -2.65 -3.02 -3.83

lnKP -2.16 -7.70* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnAR -1.40 -6.38* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnTR -2.86 -5.11* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnBAR -0.75 -6.12* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnMAR -3.78** -5.35* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnGR -1.08 -5.22* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnLAR -2.25 -7.47* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnADLR -1.45 -7.64* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnMONR -2.47 -3.73** -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnCPI 1.02 -3.70** -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

lnBDR -1.97 -4.94* -2.65 -3.02 -3.80

Note: See Table 6.3A.

6.3.2 Cointegration and error correction mechanism

We began our empirical investigation simply by taking two variables: per capita real

GDP and foreign aid. This provides us with a preliminary picture of how aid affects
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 221

per capita real GDP. Results of the Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test for cointegration

are presented in Table 6.5.

Table 6.5: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(variables lnRGDPP and lnAR)

λmax λtrace
VAR(3) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.80360 r=0 r=1 32.55** 43.31**
0.41610 r=2 10.76 10.76

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.005 -0.025
Chi Square [0.57] [21.64]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnRGDPPt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 14.94 0.368

ΔlnARt-1
(7.99)* (2.82)**
ECT -0.085 -0.027
(-7.98)* (-1.39)

Diagnostic tests
R-Square 0.84 FF 0.32

R-Bar-Square 0.81 NORM 0.61

DW 1.70 HET 0.37

SC 0.53

Notes: (a) *, ** and *** indicate significant at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.
(b) Figures within the 1st and 3rd brackets represent the t-statistic and Chi Square
respectively.
(c) DW = Durbin-Watson test (see Durbin and Watson, 1950 and 1951).
(d) SC = Serial Correlation (Lagrange multiplier test of residual serial correlation,: see
Godfrey, 1978a and 1978b).
(e) FF = Functional Form (Ramsey’s RESET test using the square of the fitted values:
Ramsey, 1969).
(f) NORM = Normality (based on a test of skewness and kurtosis of residuals: Bera and
Jarque, 1981).
(g) HET = Heteroscedasticity (based on the regression of squared residuals on squared fitted
values, Koenker, 1981).
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 222

Since SBC and AIC indicate two different optimal lag lengths (4 and 1), we have

chosen 3 as the order of the VAR. 8 The results of λmax and λtrace indicate the presence

of one significant cointegrating vector. Thus, it can be ascertained from the LR

statistics that in the presence of a deterministic trend, per capita real GDP and

aggregate aid are cointegrated. In other words, there exists a linear combination of the

I(1) variables that links them in a stable long-run relationship. The second half of

Table 6.5 presents the long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients. It shows that

aid has a positive but statistically insignificant relationship with per capita real GDP.

The error correction mechanism (ECM) results indicate that the error correction

coefficient, estimated at -0.085, is statistically significant at the 1 per cent level.

However, the short-run coefficient of aid is found to be negative and statistically

insignificant. Nonetheless, the diagnostic tests of serial correlation, functional form,

normality and heteroscedasticity confirm a good representation of variables in the model.

In our next step, we estimate the production function with foreign aid as an explanatory

variable in addition to capital stock. The results are presented in Table 6.6. The test

statistics support the hypothesis of one cointegrating vector. Thus, the results suggest

that in the presence of a deterministic trend, per capita real GDP and aid are cointegrated.

More importantly, the long-run normalised coefficients of aid and capital stock are found

to be positive and statistically significant at 5 and 1 per cent respectively. It implies that

with the inclusion of capital stock, aid coefficient is found to be not only significant and

positive, but also elasticity of per capita real GDP with respect to aid increases.

8
The optimal order of the lag length is determined by using the AIC and SBC for all equations
considered here. In the case of two different optimal lag lengths, we first chose 2 as the order of the
VAR due to the short data lengths, and then checked to see whether the chosen order of the VAR
showed significant results and passed the diagnostic tests.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 223

In addition, the value of adjusted R2 increased from 0.81 to 0.88. Thus, we can

reasonably conclude that aid contributes to per capita real GDP by enhancing the level of

technical knowledge. This can happen through the new knowledge embodied in imported

capital goods, made possible by aid. Technical assistance aid also contributes to

enhancing technical knowledge. 9

Table 6.6: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(variables lnRGDPP, lnAR and lnKP)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.91005 r=0 r=1 48.17** 68.67**

r <= 2
0.50469 r=2 14.05 20.50
0.27588 r=3 6.45 6.65

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt lnKPt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.009 -0.073 -0.024
Chi Square [4.32]** [7.01]* [33.96]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnKP t-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 15.010 0.019

ΔlnARt-1
(9.97)* (0.64)
ECT -0.084 -0.043
(-9.95)* (-2.66)**
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.425
(3.93)*

Diagnostic tests
R-Square 0.91 FF 0.55

R-Bar-Square 0.88 NORM 0.60

DW 1.78 HET 0.12

SC 0.58

Note: See Table 6.5.

9
Aid’s contribution to capital formation through importation of capital goods is examined fully in the
next chapter.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 224

The short-run coefficient of aid is found to be negative and statistically significant.

This indicates that in the short run the country may not be able to manage aid

efficiently because of lack of absorptive capacity (more on this later in the chapter).10

The short-run negative coefficient of aid may also be due to the fact that aid flows

increase initially in response to a fall in GDP as pointed out by Papanek (1972, 1973).

This also shows the importance of examining the long-run aid–growth relationship

along with the examination of short-run dynamics. As our results demonstrate, foreign

aid is positively associated with real GDP per capita in the long-run, although aid’s

contribution in the short-run may be doubtful. That is, there can be a short-run – long-

run paradox in aid effectiveness.

The ECM results further show that the ECT is negative and statistically significant

(0.084) at the 1 per cent level, implying that the aid–growth relationship is stable in

the long-run. The statistically significant error correction coefficient with an

appropriate sign represents the speed of adjustment back to the long-run relationship

among the variables. In precise terms, it implies that disequilibria of this period from

long-run per capita real GDP is adjusted by 8.4 per cent in the next period. While the

model diagnostic tests, that is, the tests of serial correlation, functional form,

normality and heteroscedasticity, confirm a good representation of variables in the

model.

Having examined the existence of a long-run cointegrating relationship between per

capita real GDP, aid and capital stock, we now proceed to estimate our main model,

10
The lack of absorptive capacity perhaps explains the findings of negative aid–growth relationship in
some earlier studies.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 225

given by equation (6.4). That is, we incorporate the adult literacy rate (ADLR) in

estimating the aid–GDP relationship in the production function. 11 The results are

presented in Table 6.7A. As can be seen, the coefficient of aid (AR) increases

(although marginally) with the inclusion of the adult literacy variable. This suggests

that aid effectiveness depends on Nepal’s social capability to use aid.

11
ADLR is taken as an I(0) variable in all equations. Pesaran and Pesaran, (2003) noted: “The
additional I(0) variables included in the VAR allows for the short run movements in the I(1) variables
which moves them away from their long run equilibrium” (2003: 322). More importantly, it also
appears to improve the fit of the regression.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 226

Table 6.7A: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(equation (6.4) lnRGDPP, lnAR, and lnKP (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.92797 r=0 r=1 52.61** 71.22**

r <= 2
0.52635 r=2 14.94 18.61
0.16763 r=3 3.66 3.66

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt lnKPt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.010 -0.075 -0.023
Chi Square [6.72]* [9.48]* [48.25]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnARt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 15.234 -0.043

ΔlnKPt-1
(10.66* (-2.53)**
ECT 0.085 0.035
(10.64)* (1.15)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.419 ΔlnADLR 0.004
(3.91)* (1.23)

Diagnostic tests
R-Square 0.92 FF 0.54

R-Bar-Square 0.89 NORM 0.97

DW 2.09 HET 0.21

SC 0.49

Note: See Table 6.5.

The Joahnsen’s Likelihood Ratio test results indicate the presence of one significant

cointegrating vector and confirm that the variables are cointegrated. In terms of the

long-run relationship, all the coefficients are found to be positive and statistically

significant. Thus, in the long run, aid has a positive relationship with per capita real

GDP. However, the ECM results show that the error correction coefficient, estimated

at 0.085, is positive and statistically significant at the one per cent level. The positive
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 227

error correction coefficient is not consistent with the theory and suggests that last

period’s disequilibrium is not corrected to converge towards equilibrium.

As the ECT is found to be positive, we re-estimated equation (6.4) by adding a

dummy variable to the model; the results are presented in Table 6.7B. We used a

dummy for political instability, taking the value of 0 for the period 1983-89 and 1 for

1990-2002. Generally, it is believed that political instability lowers the availability of

factors of production and thus impedes economic growth. 12 Nepal was relatively

politically stable from 1970 until the late 1980s. But, throughout the 1990s up to the

present, Nepal has been facing severe political instability. 13

12
See, for example, Alesina and Perotti (1994), and Edward and Tabellini (1991).
13
As discussed in chapter 3, more than eight governments were formed between 1990 and 2003 and
Maoist rebel violence has been escalated across the country, claiming a total of more than 8,000 lives.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 228

Table 6.7B: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(equation (6.4) lnRGDPP, lnAR, and lnKP (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable and
dummy)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.93627 r=0 r=1 55.06** 63.38**

r <= 2
0.31041 r=2 7.43 8.32
0.04340 r = 3 0.88 0.88

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt lnKPt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.019 -0.069 -0.024
Chi Square [6.79]* [9.20]* [54.02]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnARt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 15.514 -0.054

ΔlnKPt-1
(10.78)* (-2.98)**
ECT -0.085 0.043
(-10.76)* (1.45)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.427 ΔlnADLR 0.004
(3.93)* (1.16)
Dummy -0.011
(-2.49)**
Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.93 FF 0.43

R-Bar-Square 0.90 NORM 0.86

DW 2.24 HET 0.36

SC 0.26

Note: See Table 6.5.

The model diagnostic tests, presented at the bottom of Table 6.7B, do not exhibit any

statistical problems and thus confirm a good representation of variables in the model.

Adjusted R2 shows that the model explains over 90 per cent of variation in per capita

real GDP, and the DW statistics confirm that the error term is serially uncorrelated.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 229

The coefficient of the dummy is negative and statistically significant at the five per

cent level, implying that political instability has a direct, negative impact on the

growth rate of per capita real GDP. If we compare the results with the ones without

the dummy, we find that the coefficient of aid (AR) has increased and that of capital

stock (KP) has decreased. That is, political instability has reduced the elasticity of per

capita real GDP with respect to capital stock. This is an interesting finding. This

clearly shows the cost of political instability; political instability adversely affects the

productivity of capital. The increase in aid elasticity shows the importance of aid

flows during political instability. There could be many reasons why aid elasticity

increases in the presence of political instability. One reason could be that the

government spends more aid money on infrastructure to offset any decline in private

expenditure during the political turmoil. The government may also spend more on

social sector (e.g. education) to ease political tensions. Both infrastructure investment

and increased social expenditure positively affect growth.

With the inclusion of the political dummy the coefficient of the ECM becomes

negative and statistically significant. Among the short-run coefficients, while the

coefficient of per capita real GDP is found to be positive and significant at the 1 per

cent level, the coefficients of capital and adult literacy rate are found to be positive

but insignificant.

Once again, we find that the short-run coefficients of foreign aid are negative and

statistically significant in both cases (with and without a political dummy). Poudyal

(1988) also found a negative relationship between aid and growth in the short-run. It

has an important implication in terms of absorptive capacity, aid conditionality and


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 230

aid volatility. Nepal’s immediate capacity for the effective use of aid appears to be

weak, for various reasons. They include shortages of skill, institutional weaknesses,

budget constraints with regard to counter fund for aid-financed projects. In addition,

the government is sometimes unable to mobilise the volume of aid on time and fails to

persuade donors that remaining funds will be spent efficiently. Thus, disbursement of

aid may be further delayed, hampering the government’s spending ability. 14

The negative effect of aid in the short-run may also be due to aid conditionalities. The

government is required to cut expenditure and pursue reforms, such as privatisation.

These may have an adverse effect on economic growth in the short-run.

The volatility of aid flows could contribute to negative GDP growth because of

uncertainty. Some recent empirical studies have focused on the magnitude and

consequences of aid volatility. They find that foreign aid is more volatile than

government current revenue in almost all developing countries. 15 According to these

studies, aid effectiveness has been undermined by the (uncoordinated and diverse)

nature of the international aid delivery system. Aid disbursement could also be more

volatile as a result of changing economic and political conditions in the recipient as

well as donor country.

14
It has been argued that in a developing country, absorptive capacity plays a crucial role for the
effectiveness of foreign aid (see, Killick, 1991). Other recent studies such as Burnside and Dollar
(2000), Hansen and Tarp (2000), and Lensink and White (2001) have used aid square term in the model
to see whether returns to aid are diminishing due to absorptive capacity problems.
15
See, for example, Bulir and Hamann (2003), UNCTAD (2000), and Lensink and Morrissey (2000).
In one study of 48 developing countries, Gemmell and McGillivray (1998) found that shortfalls in aid
disbursement are followed most frequently by reductions in government spending, sometimes by
increases in taxes, and sometimes by both. More importantly, the aid recipient country is unable to
offset unexpected non-disbursement of aid by borrowing, and thus has to pay very high cost.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 231

Summary: The empirical results show that foreign aid has a positive and statistically

significant effect on per capita real GDP in the long-run. The elasticity of per capita

real GDP with respect to aid is about 0.02 per cent. It implies that a 1 per cent

increase in aid flows leads to an increase of 0.02 per cent on average in per capita real

GDP. However, in the case of short-run dynamics, the immediate impact of changes

of aid has a negative impact in the changes of per capita real GDP, possibly due to

lack of absorptive capacity and aid volatility. Thus, there seems to be a paradox

between short-run and long-run effects of aid. We also find that interestingly aid

elasticity of per capita real GDP rises in the presence of political instability.

6.3.3 Effectiveness of different components of aid

Bilateral and multilateral aid

In the next step, total aid is disaggregated into bilateral (BAR) and multilateral

(MAR) aid as a percentage of GDP. We estimate equation (6.5) using only bilateral

aid as an explanatory variable (including capital stock and adult literacy). 16 Table

6.8A presents the results, showing that λmax and λtrace are significant enough to

indicate the existence of one cointegrating vector. A long-run equilibrium relationship

therefore exists between variables in equation (6.5). The long-run cointegrating

normalised coefficients are found to be positive and statistically significant at the 1

per cent level. However, the short-run coefficient of growth of bilateral aid is negative

although statistically insignificant. The error correction coefficient, estimated at

0.084, is found to be negative and statistically significant at the 1 per cent level.

The model diagnostic tests do not show any statistical problems.

16
We estimated bilateral and multilateral aid separately to avoid the degrees of freedom problem as we
have only 20 observations. However, we have also tried with both variables in the same equation and
the results are presented in appendix 6.3 at the end of the thesis (after references).
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 232

Table 6.8A: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(bilateral aid only, lnRGDPP, lnBAR, and lnKP (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable and
dummy)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.92381 r=0 r=1 51.48** 62.33**

r <= 2
0.32654 r=2 7.90 10.84
0.13662 r = 3 2.93 2.93

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnBARt lnKPt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.014 -0.101 -0.023
Chi Square [10.09]* [39.32]* [43.89]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnBARt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 15.794 -0.012

ΔlnKPt-1
(8.93)* (-0.66)
ECT -0.084 -0.001
(-8.92)* (-0.05)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.438 ΔlnADLR 0.009
(3.27)* (2.18)**
Dummy -0.003
(-0.64)

Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.90 FF 0.54

R-Bar-Square 0.86 NORM 0.70

DW 2.31 HET 0.26

SC 0.24

Note: See Table 6.5.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 233

Table 6.8B: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(multilateral aid only, lnRGDPP, lnMAR, and lnKP (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable
and dummy)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.94053 r=0 r=1 56.44** 68.66**

r <= 2
0.43813 r=2 11.52 12.21
0.033679 r = 3 0.68 0.68

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnMARt lnKPt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.013 -0.090 -0.023
Chi Square [5.98]** [13.22]* [53.64]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnMARt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 15.448 -0.044

ΔlnKPt-1
(12.52)* (-3.92)*
ECT -0.091 0.040
(-12.50)* (1.49)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.448 ΔlnADLR 0.006
(4.37)* (1.79)***
Dummy -0.004
(-1.20)

Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.94 FF 0.90

R-Bar-Square 0.91 NORM 0.21

DW 2.05 HET 0.26

SC 0.77

Note: See Table 6.5.

To investigate the effect of multilateral aid, we again estimate equation (6.5)

considering multilateral aid only (Table 6.8B). We find that per capita real GDP and

multilateral aid are cointegrated. In terms of a long-run relationship, the coefficient of


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 234

multilateral aid is found to be positive and statistically significant at the 5 per cent

level. The long-run coefficient of multilateral aid is about the same as that of bilateral

aid (0.013 and 0.014, respectively). Thus, in the long-run, both bilateral and

multilateral aid play almost equal role in affecting per capita real GDP.

Interestingly, however, the long-run coefficient of total aid (0.019) is higher than the

long-run coefficients of bilateral and multilateral aid individually. This implies

complementarities between bilateral and multilateral aid. This perhaps explains why

the political dummy is not significant when aid is disaggregated.

When we consider the ECM results, multilateral aid is found to be negative and

statistically significant. The error correction coefficient, estimated at -0.091, is found

to be statistically significant at the 1 per cent level. Thus, the short-run coefficient of

multilateral aid shows that the immediate impact of changes in multilateral aid is

negatively related with the changes in per capita real GDP. There could be two

reasons for the short-run negative relationship. It can happen due to adverse short-run

effect of conditional disbursement. Because of conditionality, which is often imposed

by multilateral donor, government has to reduce expenditure that may affect growth in

the short-run. At the same time, as in aggregate aid, the short-run negative effect of

multilateral aid on per capita real GDP confirms that Nepal does have problems of

absorptive capacity, and the impact of aid volatility on the economy is large.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 235

Grants and loans aid

To measure the impact of grants and loans aid, we further disaggregate total aid into

grants (GR) and loans aid (LAR) (equation 6.6). As in the case of bilateral and

multilateral aid, we estimate grants aid and loans aid one at a time. Table 6.9A

presents the results for cointegration. These indicate that during the period under

study, a long-run equilibrium relationship exists between grants aid and per capita real

GDP.

Among the long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients, all coefficients are found

to be positive and statistically significant at the 1 per cent level. More importantly, the

elasticity of per capita real GDP with respect to grants is found to be higher (0.018)

than those of bilateral (0.014) and multilateral aid (0.013). However, the short-run

coefficient of grants is found to be negative although insignificant.

We also estimate equation (6) using loans aid only. Table 6.9B presents the

Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test results for cointegration. The results indicate that per

capita real GDP and loans aid are cointegrated. In terms of a long-run relationship,

although the coefficients of loans aid and capital stock are found to be positive and

statistically significant at the 1 and 5 per cent levels respectively, the elasticity of per

capita real GDP with respect to loans aid (0.006) is found to be much smaller than

grants aid (0.018). Thus, the results reveal that grants aid is more important to the

Nepalese economy than loans aid. Loans aid causes a debt burden because of future

repayments whereas grants aid is free resources. 17 On the other hand, as with

multilateral and aggregate aid, the short-run coefficient of loans aid is found to be

17
See chapter 3 on Nepal’s foreign debt burden. There is a vast literature on the debt crisis in
developing countries. See, for example, Sachs (1988).
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 236

negative and statistically significant, suggesting once again lack of absorptive

capacity and the presence of aid volatility.

Table 6.9A: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(grants aid only, lnRGDPP, lnGR, and lnKP (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable and
dummy)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.91342 r=0 r=1 48.93** 64.62**

r <= 2
0.48392 r=2 13.22 15.68
0.11573 r = 3 2.45 2.45

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnGRt lnKPt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.018 -0.086 -0.023
Chi Square [8.65]* [33.65]* [36.33]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnGRt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 15.534 -0.018

ΔlnKPt-1
(8.63)* (-0.79)
ECT -0.082 0.008
(-8.62)* (0.23)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.421 ΔlnADLR 0.007
(2.95)* (1.87)***
Dummy -0.001
(-0.37)
Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.90 FF 0.31

R-Bar-Square 0.85 NORM 0.67

DW 2.11 HET 0.22

SC 0.51

Note: See Table 6.5.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 237

Table 6.9B: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(loans aid only, lnRGDPP, lnLAR, and lnKP (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable and
dummy)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.92516 r=0 r=1 51.84** 66.99**

r <= 2
0.48963 r=2 13.45 15.14
0.081174 r = 3 1.69 1.69

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnLARt lnKPt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.006 -0.088 -0.023
Chi Square [3.22]** [9.26]* [36.74]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnLARt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 15.805 -0.019

ΔlnKPt-1
(11.18)* (-2.72)**
ECT -0.090 0.028
(-11.16)* (0.94)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.477 ΔlnADLR 0.007
(3.99)* (2.02)**
Dummy -0.002
(-0.64)
Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.92 FF 0.70

R-Bar-Square 0.89 NORM 0.97

DW 2.11 HET 0.24

SC 0.66

Note: See Table 6.5.

Summary: The relationships between disaggregated forms of aid (bilateral,

multilateral, and grants and loans aid) and per capita real GDP are found to be

positive and statistically significant in the long-run. These findings shed light on the

effectiveness of aid in Nepal. First, loans aid has been less effective in the Nepalese
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 238

economy in the long-run compared with grants aid. Second, in the short-run, aid is

found to affect economic growth negatively, which might be attributed to adverse

effects of conditional attachment of aid disbursement. This also indicates that Nepal

does not have an adequate absorptive capacity. This may also be due to uncertainly

associated with the high volatility of aid flows.

6.4 Aid, policies and per capita real GDP

This part of the chapter examines the role of policy environment in the effectiveness

of aid. In other words, we investigate whether the aid/GDP relationship is affected

when policy variables are considered. As indicators of policy, we include TR (trade as

percentage of GDP – a measure of trade policy) 18 , CPI (consumer price index – a

measure of macroeconomic policy) and MONR (M2 as percentage of GDP – a

measure of financial sector policy). 19

We begin with the investigation of the effect of policy variables on per capita real

GDP. The estimated results are reported in Tables 6.10A to 6.10C.

18
One can argue that tariff rates as a proxy for trade policy variable is more appropriate than trade
because aid dependent country like Nepal trade as percentage of GDP might be high, even if policy
regime is restrictive. However, tariff rates do not capture the impact of non-tariff barriers, which were
very high in Nepal until the mid 1980s and the time series data are not available for the estimates of
effective rate of protection. See also footnote of page 212 for more discussion and Sharma (1999) for
Nepal’s trade policy.
19
We also used BDR (budget deficit as percentage of GDP) as an alternative measure of
macroeconomic policy, but that did not improve the results significantly. As a matter of fact, inflation
correlates highly with budget deficit.
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 239

Table 6.10A: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(equation (6.7a), lnRGDPP and lnTR)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.85829 r=0 r =1 39.07** 41.53**
0.11557 r=2 2.45 2.45

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnTRt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.017 -0.024
Chi Square [2.86]*** [38.53]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnRGDPPt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 16.98 0.468

ΔlnTRt-1
(9.32)* (3.63)*
ECT -0.094 0.027
(-9.30)* (0.93)

Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.86 FF 0.36

R-Bar-Square 0.83 NORM 0.44

DW 2.19 HET 0.16

SC 0.48
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 240

Table 6.10B: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(equation (6.7b), lnRGDPP and lnCPI)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.86935 r=0 r =1 40.70** 44.37**
0.16763 r=2 3.66 3.66

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnCPIt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.051 -0.020
Chi Square [5.03]* [22.54]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnRGDPPt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 14.43 0.303

ΔlnCPIt-1
(8.41)* (2.24)**
ECT -0.084 -0.139
(-8.38)* (-2.27)**

Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.86 FF 0.39

R-Bar-Square 0.83 NORM 0.58

DW 1.64 HET 0.27

SC 0.37
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 241

Table 6.10C: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002


(equation (6.7c), lnRGDPP and lnMONR)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.85307 r=0 r=1 38.35** 43.61**
0.23118 r=2 5.25 5.25

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnMONRt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 0.066 -0.027
Chi Square [4.91]* [34.73]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

ΔlnRGDPPt-1
Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients
Intercept 16.86 0.408

ΔlnMONRt-1
(8.94)* (2.89)*
ECT -0.094 0.056
(-8.92)* (0.85)

Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.85 FF 0.96

R-Bar-Square 0.82 NORM 0.67

DW 1.66 HET 0.23

SC 0.38

Notes: (a) *, ** and *** indicate significant at 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively.
(b) Figures within the 1st and 3rd brackets represent the t-statistic and Chi Square
respectively.
(c) DW = Durbin–Watson test (see Durbin and Watson, 1950 and 1951)
(d) SC = Serial Correlation (Lagrange multiplier test of residual serial correlation: Godfrey,
1978a and 1978b).
(e) FF = Functional Form (Ramsey’s RESET test using the square of the fitted values:
Ramsey, 1969).
(f) NORM = Normality (based on a test of skewness and kurtosis of residuals: Bera and
Jarque, 1981).
(g) HET = Heteroscedasticity (based on the regression of squared residuals on squared fitted
values: Koenker, 1981).
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 242

The Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test results for cointegration show that all three

policy variables are cointegrated with per capita real GDP. Among the long-run

cointegrating normalised coefficients, the coefficients of TR and CPI are found to be

positive and statistically significant at the 10 and 1 per cent levels, respectively

(Tables 6.10A and 6.10B), and the coefficient of MONR is found to be negative and

statistically significant at the 1 per cent level (Table 6.10C). While the long-run

coefficient of trade variable (TR) has the expected sign, the long-run coefficients of

both CPI and financial reform variable (MONR) do not. We expect them to be

associated negatively and positively with real per capita GDP, respectively, in the

long-run.

Next we examine the impact of these policies together on aid effectiveness. However,

we take two policy variables at a time due to the degrees of freedom constraint. That

is, we estimate the model taking a permutation of two policy variables: (1) TR and

CPI; (2) TR and MONR, and (3) CPI and MONR. The combination of CPI and

MONR did not produce statistically significant results and hence are not reported here

(see appendix 6.1). This could be due to high correlation between CPI and MONR.

The estimation results for the other two sets are presented in Tables 6.11A (with TR

and CPI) and 6.11B (with TR and MONR).


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 243

Table 6.11A: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002(equation


(6.7d), lnRGDPP, lnAR, lnKP, lnTR, and lnCPI (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.97326 r=0 r=1 72.42** 141.12**

r <= 2
0.83660 r=2 36.23** 68.70**

r <= 3
0.58810 r=3 17.73 32.46

r <= 4
0.45965 r=4 12.31 14.72
0.11392 r=5 2.41 2.41

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt lnKPt lnTRt lnCPIt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.032 -0.039 -0.058 0.165 -0.037
Chi Square [4.07]* [0.76] [2.52] [3.94]** [13.66]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients


Intercept 18.099 ΔlnKPt-1 0.080
(7.82)* (1.76)***
ECT 0.079 ΔlnTRt-1 -0.012
(7.80)* (-0.35)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.543 ΔlnCPIt-1 0.267
(3.20)* (2.89)**
ΔlnARt-1 -0.089 ΔlnADLR 0.006
(-3.62)* (1.25)

Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.89 FF 0.84

R-Bar-Square 0.83 NORM 0.52

DW 2.26 HET 0.64

SC 0.18

Note: See Table 6.10C.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 244

Table 6.11B: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002 (equation


(6.7e) lnRGDPP, lnAR, lnKP, lnTR, and lnMONR (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.96679 r=0 r=1 68.09** 148.71**

r <= 2
0.90586 r=2 47.25** 80.61**

r <= 3
0.61400 r=3 19.03 33.35

r <= 4
0.44921 r=4 11.92 14.31
0.11241 r=5 2.38 2.38

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt lnKPt lnTRt lnMONRt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.059 -0.218 -0.019 -0.289 -0.011
Chi Square [4.60]* [10.55]* [1.05] [3.64]** [1.11]

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients


Intercept 7.481 ΔlnKPt-1 0.018
(5.05)* (0.28)
ECT 0.074 ΔlnTRt-1 0.002
(5.03)* (0.04)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.117 ΔlnMONRt-1 -0.188
(0.61) (-1.97)***
ΔlnARt-1 -0.063 ΔlnADLR 0.011
(-2.02)** (1.51)

Diagnostic tests

R-Square 0.78 FF 0.15

R-Bar-Square 0.66 NORM 0.55

DW 1.80 HET 0.64

SC 0.67

Note: See Table 6.10C.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 245

The Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test results show that the variables under study are

cointegrated in both cases (i.e, when TR and CPI and TR and MONR are included in

the model). The long-run cointegrating normalised coefficient of aid increased in both

cases compared to when no policy variable was included (Table 6.7B), indicating that

aid-effectiveness improved in the presence of good policy environment. However,

although all the policy variables have the expected signs, the trade policy variable

(TR) is not significant. In addition, the error correction coefficients in both cases are

found to be a positive. Therefore, we re-estimated the equations (6.7d and 6.7e)

adding a dummy variable (to capture the effect of political instability), and the results

are presented in Tables 6.12A and 6.12B.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 246

Table 6.12A: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002 (equation


(6.7d), lnRGDPP, lnAR, lnKP, lnTR, and lnCPI, (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable) and
dummy)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.97440 r=0 r=1 73.30** 134.34**

r <= 2
0.83619 r=2 36.18** 61.04***

r <= 3
0.57667 r = 3 17.19 24.86

r <= 4
0.21891 r=4 4.94 7.67
0.12756 r=5 2.72 2.72

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt lnKPt lnTRt lnCPIt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.036 -0.028 -0.063 0.170 -0.038
Chi Square [4.90]** [0.38] [2.96]*** [4.32]** [14.35]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients


Intercept 18.303 ΔlnKPt-1 0.088
(7.84)* (1.93)***
ECT -0.080 ΔlnTRt-1 -0.011
(7.82)* (-0.30)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.578 ΔlnCPIt-1 0.264
(3.25)* (2.87)**
ΔlnARt-1 -0.103 ΔlnADLR 0.004
(-3.66)* (0.82)
Dummy -0.017
(-1.81)***
Diagnostic tests
R-Square 0.90 FF 0.66

R-Bar-Square 0.83 NORM 0.46

DW 2.33 HET 0.64

SC 0.13

Note: See Table 6.10C.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 247

Table 6.12B: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002 (equation


(6.7e), lnRGDPP, lnAR, lnKP, lnTR, and lnMONR, (ΔlnADLR as an I(0) variable
and dummy)

λmax λtrace
VAR(2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.98864 r=0 r=1 89.55** 165.39**

r <= 2
0.91507 r=2 49.31** 75.83**

r <= 3
0.50351 r = 3 14.00 26.52

r <= 4
0.40931 r=4 10.52 12.51
0.09458 r=5 1.98 1.98

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt lnKPt lnTRt lnMONRt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.297 -0.509 -0.122 -1.317 -0.030
Chi Square [26.14]* [30.98]* [16.87]* [24.21]* [5.07]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients


Intercept -0.212 ΔlnKPt-1 0.023
(-2.87)** (0.26)
ECT -0.063 ΔlnTRt-1 0.010
(-3.32)* (0.16)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.076 ΔlnMONRt-1 -0.320
(0.28) (-2.20)**
ΔlnARt-1 -0.178 ΔlnADLR 0.004
(-3.15)* (0.44)
Dummy -0.032
(-2.09)**
Diagnostic tests
R-Square 0.66 FF 0.01

R-Bar-Square 0.42 NORM 0.76

DW 1.89 HET 0.68

SC 0.38

Note: See Table 6.10C.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 248

In both cases (when TR and CPI and TR and MONR are considered), the dummy is

found to be negative and statistically significant, meaning that political instability

affects the economy adversely, as the productivity of capital stock declines.

However, with the inclusion of a political instability dummy variable the long-run

coefficients of aid has increased from 0.032 to 0.036, in the presence of trade and

macro policy variables and from 0.059 to 0.3 in the case of trade and financial sector

policy variables. In addition, all the variables in the model have right signs.

The sign and the size of the ECM term are also as per our expectation (negative and

less than one). This indicates that the model with policy variables is stable in the long-

run. The short-run dynamics shows that even in the presence of good policy variables,

changes of aid is negatively associated with the changes of per capita real GDP. The

signs of short-run coefficients of policy variables are also found to be perverse,

implying that it takes time for the economy to adjust to policy changes.

6.5 Summary and conclusion

This chapter presents our main empirical analysis of the effectiveness of aid in Nepal.

We have empirically investigated the impact of aggregate and disaggregated forms of

aid on per capita real GDP. To address the current debate on whether aid works only

in a good policy environment, we have included policy variables for macroeconomic

stability, financial sector development and openness in an extended model.

We generally find that aid is positively related to per capita real GDP in the long-run.

The channel through which aid affects growth of GDP is technological progress. That
Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 249

is, aid helps upgrade technology by helping import capital goods. Aid in the form of

technical assistance also improves Nepal’s institutional capacity. Overall capacity to

reap the benefit of aid depends on Nepal’s social capability as captured by the adult

literacy rate. However, in the short-run the impact of aid is negative. This could be

due to problems associated with absorptive capacity, aid management, coordination

and allocation, and aid conditionalities. We also find that aid assumes additional

importance during times of political instability, when the productivity of capital

declines. Aid flows in that circumstance can maintain the economy.

Among the disaggregated forms of aid, bilateral and multilateral aid play about the

same role. However, bilateral and multilateral aid have strong complementarities.

Grants aid is found to have a stronger positive association with per capita real GDP

than loans aid. These findings have some important implications. First, loan aid

creates a debt burden because of future repayments. Currently, almost 13 per cent of

revenue is used for debt service, which is about 8 per cent of total government

expenditure in Nepal. Debt service payment as a ratio of total exports increased from

less than 1 per cent in the 1970s to over 6 per cent in 2001. This persistently hampers

government’s expenditure on infrastructure and social development.

The second implication is that disbursement of aid is generally conditional on

structural adjustment. Therefore, the direct effect of multilateral aid on GDP may not

be observable as it works through policy variables; but the economy might be affected

negatively in the short-run. As our results show, aid effectiveness improves in the

present of good policies in the long-run. Nepal’s policy environment improved


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 250

significantly since the mid 1980s when it implemented various Structural Adjustment

Programs.

In sum, aid has been effective in increasing and maintaining the economic growth in

Nepal. Its effectiveness has improved in the presence of a good policy environment.

However, as is well-known, growth does not necessarily trickle down and improve

socio-economic conditions. In fact, as discussed in chapter 2, inequality and poverty

in Nepal have increased over time. So, even though aid seems to have contributed to

economic growth, one can question the quality of growth.


Chapter 6: Foreign Aid and Growth in Nepal 251

(equation (6.7f) lnRGDPP, lnAR, lnKP, lnCPI, lnMONR and ΔlnADLR(as an (I(0)
Appendix 6.1: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1983-2002

variable)

λmax λtrace
VAR (2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative
0.96791 r=0 r=1 68.78** 139.85**
0.86069 r<=1 r=2 39.42** 71.07**
0.56238 r<=2 r = 3 16.52 31.65
0.44266 r<=3 r=4 11.69 15.12
0.15782 r<=4 r=5 3.43 3.43

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnRGDPPt lnARt lnKPt lnCPIt lnMONRt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 0.015 -0.028 -0.0003 -0.099 -0.028
Chi square [1.48] [0.68] [0.0003] [1.09] [8.51]*

Error correction model for lnRGDPP

Variables Coefficients Variables Coefficients


Intercept 17.76 ΔlnKPt-1 0.059
(8.83)* (1.76)
ECT -1.96 ΔlnCPIt-1 -0.040
(-8.80)* (-0.55)
ΔlnRGDPPt-1 0.363 ΔlnMONRt-1 0.048
(2.19)** (0.71)
ΔlnARt-1 0.011 ΔlnADLR 0.005
(0.51) (1.33)

Diagnostic tests
R-Square 0.92 FF 0.46

R-Bar-Square 0.87 NORM 0.66

DW 1.94 HET 0.23

SC 0.93

Notes: *, ** and *** indicate significant at 1%, 5% and 10% level respectively. Figures within the
small and square brackets represent the t-statistics and Chi square respectively.
Chapter 7

Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment

“As a policy problem, the balance of payments limitation is quite similar to the savings–
investment limitation… It is not clear a priori … which of these … is more likely to limit
growth … The parallelism between the two is completed by the fact that a foreign capital
inflow plays a dual role in adding to both investment and foreign exchange resources”
(Chenery and Bruno, 1962: 85).

7.1 Introduction

In the previous chapter, we assumed that aid contributes to economic growth via

technological progress. This chapter hypothesises that aid contributes to growth

through enhancing the investment rate. It is generally the case that savings rates in

poor countries like Nepal are very low. This limits investment and thus economic

growth. In other words, they are locked into a “vicious circle” of low income, low

savings, low investment and hence low income. 1 This creates a gap between available

savings and investment needed for rapid economic growth. In such circumstances, it

is assumed that foreign economic assistance can fill this gap and hence enhance

economic growth. In this chapter, we look at the impact of foreign aid on the gap

between domestic savings and investment. It is assumed that each dollar of foreign

resources in the form of aid would result in an increase of one dollar in total savings

and investment. This is the basis for the extension of the Harrod–Domar growth

model into the two-gap model by Chenery and his associates.

The national income accounting identity S = I shows that ex post saving and

investment are equal for a closed economy. That is, in a closed economy, investment

1
Chenery and Strout (1966) describe this situation as “investment-limited growth”.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 253

is bound to be solely financed by domestic savings. Hence, one will get a very high

(almost perfect) correlation between domestic savings and investment. The same is

likely to occur even in an open economy if they have a closed capital account, or as

Feldstein and Horioka (1980) have shown, if capital does not move between

countries.

Most developing countries do not receive substantial private capital flows. Their

savings–investment gap is mostly filled by foreign aid. Therefore, we can apply the

Feldstein and Horioka approach to test the effectiveness of foreign aid in developing

countries. In the context of a developing country, a low savings–investment

correlation would indicate that foreign aid contributes to investment and hence to

economic growth. On the other hand, a high savings–investment correlation would

imply either mis-utilisation or ineffectiveness of foreign aid. In other words, it may

indicate a negative relationship between aid and savings, as argued by Griffin and

Enos (1970), and recently by Boone (1996).

Nepal is a low-saving country with an average savings/GDP ratio of less than 12 per

cent during 1970-2002. The savings rate increased marginally to 13 per cent in the

1990s. This rate is far less than what is required for high enough economic growth to

have any effect on poverty reduction and self-sustaining development. This is a remit

of a low level of income, with almost 40 per cent of the population remaining below

the poverty line. Public sector saving is either negative or very low due to low

revenue mobilisation and high consumption of government. On the other hand, the

average investment/GDP ratio was 16.6 per cent during 1970-2002. It increased from

17.6 per cent during 1980-90 to 20.2 per cent during 1990-2002. Thus, one can see a
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 254

gap between savings and investment, which gap can be financed through foreign

savings.

Table 7.1 presents the situation in Nepal from a comparative perspective. Among the

South Asian counties, Nepal’s average saving rate (SR) is higher than that of

Bangladesh and it is almost equal to that of India during the period 1970-2002.

Nepal’s average investment rate (IR) is also higher than that of Bangladesh and

Pakistan. Among the South Asian countries, Nepal’s aid/GDP ratio has been the

highest. As opposed to other countries, especially India, aid more than fully financed

Nepal’s savings–investment gap. As a matter of fact, a substantial amount of aid goes

for diaster relief. Aid also goes to service the debt on account of past loans.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 255

Table 7.1: SR, IR, AR and GAP for South Asian countries, 1970-2002

SR IR GAP AR
Country (savings/GDP) (investment/GDP) (SR–IR) (aid/GDP) AR-GAP
Nepal
1970-1979 8.32 11.45 -3.13 4.37 1.24
1980-1989 10.44 17.64 -7.19 10.69 3.50
1990-2002 12.97 20.19 -7.22 9.86 2.64
1970-2002 10.79 16.67 -5.88 8.29 2.41
India
1970-1979 9.85 16.77 -6.92 1.22 -5.70
1980-1989 9.80 20.65 -10.85 1.31 -9.54
1990-2002 11.83 22.26 -10.43 0.94 -9.49
1970-2002 10.71 19.96 -9.25 1.14 -8.11
Bangladesh
1973-1979 4.16 8.77 -4.61 9.20 4.59
1980-1989 3.86 11.06 -7.20 9.21 2.01
1990-2002 15.37 20.04 -4.67 3.68 -0.99
1973-2002 8.67 14.19 -5.52 6.84 1.32
Pakistan
1970-1979 10.40 15.28 -4.89 4.97 0.08
1980-1989 9.88 17.02 -7.14 4.02 -3.12
1990-2002 15.11 16.28 -1.17 3.13 1.96
1970-2002 12.07 16.12 -4.06 3.92 -0.14
Sri Lanka
1970-1979 13.43 17.51 -4.08 5.01 0.93
1980-1989 13.07 25.50 -12.43 9.58 -2.85
1990-2002 15.97 24.42 -8.45 4.71 -3.74
1970-2002 14.35 22.34 -7.99 6.12 -1.87

Source: IMF/IFS and OECD/IDS online databases

In this chapter, we investigate the relationship between aid and savings-investment

gap in Nepal. We employ cointegration and the error correction mechanism.

Furthermore, if the series are found to be I(1) but not cointegrated, we perform the

bivariate Granger causality test. In addition, we analyse the impulse response function

to examine the dynamic stability of the relationships under investigation.

The structure of the chapter is as follows. The next section contains a brief over-view

of the literature on aid and the savings–investment debate. Section 7.3 develops the
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 256

empirical model based on national income identities. Section 7.4 presents the data,

model and methodology. Section 7.5 discusses the empirical results. The final section

provides a summary and conclusion.

7.2 Foreign aid and savings–investment – a brief review of the debate

Many early studies have focused their investigation of the effects of foreign aid on

savings. Hansen and Tarp (2000) refer to them as “second-generation” studies. 2

However, aid’s role in filling the savings–investment gap remains a controversial

issue. During the mid 1960s, the discussion was dominated by the cogent two-gap

model, which advocated that foreign aid plays an important role in the development of

poor countries. In the second phase of discussion, the debate turned to the possibility

of an inverse relationship between foreign capital inflows and domestic savings.

About the time Chenery and his associates were developing the two-gap model, which

assumes a positive link between foreign aid and domestic savings-investment gap,

Haavelmo (1963) hypothesised that if capital inflows were very high, domestic

savings could be negative. Following a slightly modified Haavelmo model, Rahman

(1968) ran a regression of savings ratio on the ratio of capital inflows to GNP. 3 He

used cross sectional data for 31 developing countries for the year 1962, and found

evidence to support the Haavelmo hypothesis. Griffin and Enos (1970) and Weisskopf

(1972), in cross-country empirical analyses, also found an inverse relationship

2
Aid–growth production function type studies such as the one considered in the previous chapter are
referred to as “first-generation” studies.
3
Rahman (1968) suggested the following equation, s (t) = aY(t) + b1 H (t), where s is domestic savings,
Y is GNP, and H is capital inflows. He specified the model using savings ratio and foreign capital ratio
to GNP.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 257

between foreign inflows and domestic savings. They argued that instead of

accelerating development, foreign capital inflows retarded it and made developing

countries more dependent on such inflows. In particular, Griffin and Enos (1970)

generated controversy as they claimed that aid was provided not on the basis of

economic needs but in accordance with political expediency. 4 They also stressed the

fungibility nature of aid by arguing that as a result of donors’ biased strategies, at least

some portion of aid was spent on consumption rather than investment. Recently,

consistent with these early studies, Boone (1996) found no significant relationship

between foreign aid, growth and domestic saving. He found that most aid was spent

on consumption.

Griffin and Enos’ conclusions generated a series of responses. For example, Papanek

(1972, 1973), and Kennedy and Thirlwall (1971) argued that a country receives aid

because of its low savings rate, and more importantly, when savings are low, more aid

is given to meet shortfalls in domestic savings. Thus, one can find a negative

correlation between aid and domestic savings. In three generations of empirical work,

Hansen and Tarp (2000) found a strong and positive relationship between aid, savings

and growth (see further chapter 4). Their sample of 41 aid–savings regressions

revealed that foreign aid led to an increase in total savings.

Thus, the empirical estimates of the effects on savings of foreign aid vary with the

sample selection and model specification. More importantly, the lack of any

agreement as to the relationship between domestic savings and foreign aid may be due

4
More precisely, Griffin and Enos argued: “How much a country lends to another country will not be
determined by its need, or its potential, or its past economic performance, good or bad, or its virtue, but
by the benefit it yields in terms of political support” (1970: 315).
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 258

to the estimation problems associated with early studies. The early studies were based

on static cross-country analysis with inappropriate assumptions such as countries are

homogenous with respect to size, factor endowment, openness, economic structure

and institutional quality. Thus, one should address the issue of the impact of foreign

aid on domestic savings and the savings–investment gap in a dynamic framework

using time-series data from individual countries with systematic statistical tests for

nonstationarity and cointegration.

7.3 Theoretical considerations and empirical models

The theoretical rationale for the relationship between aid and the savings–investment

gap lies in the national income identities, where GDP (Y) is divided into four

components of expenditure: consumption (C), investment (I), government purchases

(G) and net exports (NX). Therefore, for an open economy, we have

Y = C + I + G + X − M .......... .......... .......... .......... .......... ...( 7.1)

where X – M = net exports (NX)

GDP can also be decomposed as

Y = C + S + T .......... .......... .......... .......... .......... .......... .........( 7.2)

where GDP (Y) equals the sum of consumption (C), saving (S) and taxes (T).

From (7.1) and (7.2) we get

C + I + G + X − M = C + S +T,

or X − M = S − I +T −G

or X − M = (S + T − G) − I
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 259

where S and (T – G) = private and government savings respectively and I =

investment, X = exports, M = imports. Thus, ex-post, the gap between aggregate

domestic saving (private and public) and domestic investment is equal to the gap

between exports and imports.

However, ex-ante, these two gaps may not be equal. Growth potential depends on

whichever gap is the largest. According to the two-gap model, if the foreign exchange

gap (X – M) required to achieve a target rate of growth is greater than the domestic

savings–investment gap, foreign aid is needed to fill the foreign exchange gap.

Similarly, foreign aid is needed to fill the savings–investment gap if it is the larger of

the two gaps. 5 In other words, foreign aid is needed to relax the limits to growth. In

the context of Nepal, we are assuming that growth is investment limiting, and that

foreign capital inflows can relax this by supplementing domestic savings. This is in

line with the historical sequence of experience originally suggested by Chenery and

his associates, that is, in the pre-take-off stage a developing country would have a

dominant savings–investment gap, followed by a dominant foreign exchange gap

(Thirlwall, 1999: 368). Foreign capital flows can be foreign direct investment, short-

term portfolio investment and foreign aid. However, in the case of Nepal, foreign

direct and portfolio investments are negligible. Thus, foreign aid (FA) is the only

option for foreign capital inflows (FS). Thus:

I = FA + DS + e.......... .......... .......... .......... .......... (7.3)

5
Here we are referring to gaps produced by the savings or exports required for the planned investment
or importation of capital goods to achieve a target growth rate. In this case, the gaps are
(a) savings–investment gap = s*Y – sY, where s* is the target savings rate and s is the actual savings
rate;
(b) foreign exchange gap = m*Y – mY, where m* is the target import rate and m is the actual import
rate, permitted by export earnings.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 260

where FA is foreign aid and DS is total domestic savings (private + public) and the

term (e) captures the impact of any other financial flows on investment. It also

captures net income (primary and secondary) from abroad.

7.3.1 Empirical models

One can test the two-gap model or the effectiveness of aid in filling the gap by

directly estimating equation (7.3) if the term e is not observable. However, if e is not

negligible as in the case of Nepal, the direct estimation of equation (7.3) using current

period data will not produce any meaningful results. In Nepal, workers’ remittance

(included in e) is an important source of foreign exchange and is close to 2 per cent of

GDP. As a matter of fact, critics argue that findings of many earlier studies were

misleading as they were merely estimating an identity.

Therefore, we can postulate a behavioural relationship between IR, SR and AR. We

hypothesise that savings positively affects investment. This follows from the loanable

fund theory; that is higher the savings, lower is the cost of borrowings and hence

higher will be the rate of investment. 6 Aid can also positively affect the investment

rate due to complementarities between private investment and aid funded public

projects such infrastructure, education and health. Therefore, we use a Cobb-Douglas

type relationship as follows:

IRt = β ( SRt 2 ARt 3 ).........................................................................(7.4)


α α

6
However, if one uses an acceleration type model, then higher savings may reduce investment due to a
deficiency in aggregate demand.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 261

where β represents institutional and regulatory factors that affect IR, and α2 and α3

are elasticities of IR with respect to AR and SR, respectively.

Taking natural logarithms on both sides of equation (7.4), we obtain,

ln IRt = α 1 + α 2 ln SRt + α 3 ln ARt + u t1 ....................................(7.5)

where lnβ = α1 and IR, SR and AR are ratios to GDP respectively. A positive

coefficient of AR would indicate that aid relaxes the investment limit to growth.

We first begin our empirical work with the estimation of a simple investment-savings

relationship:

ln IRt = β 1 + β 2 ln SRt + u t 2 .......................................................(7.6)

where IR is the ratio of gross domestic investment to GDP and SR is the

corresponding ratio of gross domestic savings to GDP. If the value of β2 is close to 1,

it would indicate that the entire source of finance of domestic investment is domestic

savings. That is, FA = 0 in equation (7.3). This will support Feldstein-Horioka (1980)

hypothesis. On the other hand, a value of β2 equal to 0 would mean that capital is

perfectly mobile and foreign capital (which in this case is foreign aid) is a perfect

substitute for domestic savings. That is, DS = 0 in equation (7.3). This will support

the extreme case of Griffin-Enos hypothesis. A value of β2 between zero and 1 would

mean both foreign aid and domestic savings contribute to investment.


Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 262

Next we directly examine the relationship between domestic savings and foreign aid.

In particular, we want to see whether aid supplements or substitutes domestic savings.

For this we estimate the following equation:

ln SRt = β 11 + β 12 ln ARt + u t 3 .....................................................(7.7)

where β11 is the average saving rate, AR is a ratio of aid to GDP and β12 captures the

impact of aid on the saving rate. If β12 > 0, aid supplements domestic savings;

if β12 < 0, aid substitutes domestic savings.

We also estimate the relationship between aid and investment as

ln IRt = β 21 + β 22 ln ARt + u t 4 .....................................................(7.8)

Finally, we examine the role of aid in augmenting investment rate by estimating

equation (7.4).

7.3.2 Data and methodology

In this chapter, we use annual time-series data from 1970 to 2002 for Nepal. Data on

GDP, investment, and savings are obtained from the IMF, International Financial

Statistics (IFS) online database. Data on aid flows are obtained from the OECD,

International Development Statistics (IDS) online database.


Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 263

We use gross fixed capital formation as a measure of investment and gross domestic

savings as a measure of savings. We have converted aid data into national currency

using nominal exchange rate and transformed all variables into percentage of GDP.

Table 7.2: Correlation matrix in growth,


1970-2002
Variables ARgr SRgr IRgr
ARgr 1.00
SRgr 0.17 1.00
IRgr 0.13 0.84 1.00

Note: SR = savings/GDP, IR = investment/GDP,


AR = aid/GDP, “gr” stands for growth rate

The correlation matrix shows a very strong positive association between savings and

investment rates (Table 7.2). Growth of aid/GDP ratio has a positive relationship with

the growth of both saving and investment rates. This implies that aid is positively

contributing to both savings and investment rates. Interestingly, the sum of partial

correlation coefficients of investment growth with savings and aid growth is close to

one, confirming the nature of identity as in equation (7.3). However, the partial

correlation coefficient with savings growth is much higher than that with aid growth.

This implies that savings play a more important role than aid in augmenting

investment.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 264

Figure 7.1: Trends of investment rate (IR) and saving rate (SR), 1970-2002

25

20

15
SR
10 IR

0
1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

Source: IMF/IFS online database

Figure 7.2: Trends of aid/GDP ratio (AR) and GAP (= SR–IR), 1970-2002

16

12

4
GAP (SR-IR)
0 AR

-4

-8

-12
1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002

Source: IMF/IFS and OECD/IDS online databases

Figures 7.1 and 7.2 present trends of variables under study. It shows that throughout

the 1970s, the GAP (=SR–IR) remained relatively small; on average it was less than 4

per cent of GDP. However, from the early 1980s to the late 1990s, the GAP on

average increased to over 7 per cent of GDP, and slightly decreased in 2000. When

we compare the trends in the aid/GDP ratio and GAP, Figure 7.2 indicates that on

average the aid/GDP ratio is larger than the GAP. This suggests that aid was either

misused or used for purposes other than investment, such as diaster relief and debt

repayments.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 265

7.4 Unit root tests

Since we are employing the cointegration test as our estimation procedure, we

perform first unit root tests to ensure that all variables are I(1). As in the previous

chapter, in order to test for the stationarity, both the ADF and PP tests are used. The

results of both tests on the levels and first difference of the variables are presented in

Tables 7.3 and 7.4. We have fixed the lag length of 2 based on AIC. The top section

of each Table shows the results with a constant only, while the bottom section shows

the results with a constant and a time trend.

Table 7.3: ADF test (Lag = 2), 1970-2002

ADF test With constant only


Variables Levels First difference 10% critical value 5% critical value 1% critical value

lnAR -2.07 -2.23 -2.63 -2.96 -3.67

lnSR -2.63 -3.75* -2.63 -2.96 -3.67

lnIR -3.59** -2.27 -2.63 -2.96 -3.67

With constant and time trend


Variables Levels First difference 10% critical value 5% critical value 1% critical value

lnAR -0.31 -2.97 -3.21 -3.56 -4.29

lnSR -2.64 -3.95** -3.21 -3.56 -4.29

lnIR -2.79 -2.79 -3.21 -3.56 -4.29

Note: *, ** and *** indicate significant at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.

The ADF results under the assumption of constant only indicate that lnSR is

nonstationary in its level form but stationary in its first difference form at the 1 per

cent significant level. Similarly, under the assumption of constant and time trend, the

results show that lnSR is nonstationary in its level form and stationary in the first
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 266

difference form at the 5 per cent significant level. On the other hand, the ADF test

results for lnIR under the assumption of constant only indicate that it is stationary in

its level form, while with a constant and a time trend the results show that InIR is

nonstationary in both level and first difference forms. lnAR is nonstationary in both

assumptions even in its first difference form.

When we performed the PP test, the results under the assumption of constant only

indicate that lnSR and lnIR are stationary in their level forms, while lnAR is

stationary in the first difference form at one per cent significant level. However, under

the assumption of a constant and a time trend, all variables are nonstationary in their

level forms and stationary in their first difference forms at the one per cent significant

level. Thus, these variables are fit for cointegration testing. That is, they are I(1)

variables as required by theory.

Table 7.4: PP test (Lag = 2), 1970-2002

PP test With constant only


Variables Levels First difference 10% critical value 5% critical value 1% critical value

lnAR -1.95 -6.57* -2.63 -2.96 -3.67

lnSR -3.73* -6.77* -2.63 -2.96 -3.67

lnIR -3.84* -7.61* -2.63 -2.96 -3.67

With constant and time trend


Variables Levels First difference 10% critical value 5% critical value 1% critical value

lnAR -0.52 -7.88* -3.21 -3.56 -4.29

lnSR -3.52 -6.96* -3.21 -3.56 -4.29

lnIR -2.54 -9.03* -3.21 -3.56 -4.29

Note: *, ** and *** indicate significant at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 267

7.5 Empirical results and their interpretations

For the two variable relationships, we first perform a residuals based approach to test

for cointegration, as proposed by Engle and Granger (1987). We have chosen 5 for the

maximum order of the ADF statistics. The results are presented in Table 7.5. Using

the ADF test, residuals from the regression between lnIR and lnSR are found to be

nonstationary even at the 10 per cent significant level (Part A of Table 7.5).

According to the theory, if the residual is I(1) the regression between lnIR and lnSR is

not a cointegrating regression. In other words, the relation between lnIR and lnSR

obtained from the OLS is spurious.

Table 7.5: ADF test for residuals for testing cointegration, 1970-2002

Part A: Residuals between lnIR and lnSR


Critical value Critical value
ADF (1) ADF (2) ADF (3) ADF (4) ADF (5) 5% 10%

Test statistics -2.48 -2.43 -1.96 -1.18 -1.94 -3.58 -3.22

Part B: Residuals between lnIR and lnAR


Critical value Critical value
ADF (1) ADF (2) ADF (3) ADF (4) ADF (5) 5% 10%

Test statistics -1.63 -1.59 -2.18 -1.43 -1.05 -3.58 -3.22

Part C: Residuals between lnSR and lnAR


Critical value Critical value
ADF (1) ADF (2) ADF (3) ADF (4) ADF (5) 5% 10%

Test statistics -1.89 -1.96 -2.25 -1.93 -1.4 -3.58 -3.22

Similarly, residuals from the regression equation between lnIR and lnAR are found to

be nonstationary; hence they are not cointegrated (Part B). We find the same results

for the residuals between lnSR and lnAR; that is, they are not cointegrated (Part C).
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 268

Since the residuals-based cointegration test is not found to be conclusive, we further

extend our test for cointegration using Johansen’s Maximum Likelihood test, which is

considered more efficient for the estimation. 7

We first focus our empirical investigation on the savings-investment relationship

(equation 7.6). As noted in chapter 5, we select the optimal lag length of 3, based on

the AIC and SBC. The results show that the variables are cointegrated (Table 7.6).

The long-run normalised coefficient of savings rate is found to be positive but

insignificant.

Table 7.6: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1970-2002


(equation (7.6), lnIR and lnSR)

λmax λtrace
VAR (3) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.45751 r=0 r=1 18.34*** 25.01***
0.19919 r=2 6.66 6.66

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnIRt lnSRt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.109 -0.006
Chi Square [0.08] [0.46]

Notes: (a) *** indicates significant at 10% level.


(b) Figures within the third brackets represent Chi Square.

According to the Feldstein and Horioka (1980) model, the low coefficient, estimated

at 0.10, is evidence in favor of international capital mobility (see also Leachman,

1991; Argimon and Roldan, 1994). In precise terms, in the case of Nepal, it implies

that most investment is financed by other sources such as foreign aid. In the first Five

7
See chapter 5 for detailed discussion of the cointegration test.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 269

Year Plan (1956-1960), foreign aid was used to finance almost 100 per cent of

development expenditure. In recent years, aid is still used to finance over 50 per cent

of development expenditure (see Paudyal, 2003).

Next, we look at the relationship between foreign aid and investment (equation 7.8).

The results indicate that the variables are cointegrated (Table 7.7). The long-run

coefficient of aid is found to be positive and statistically significant at the 1 per cent

level. Thus, foreign aid has been contributing to financing investment. Once again,

this result confirms the positive association between aid and investment, and our

result is consistent with the Feldstein and Horioka interpretation.

Table 7.7: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1970-2002


(equation (7.8), lnIR and lnAR)

λmax λtrace
VAR (4) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.48970 r=0 r=1 19.50** 28.49**
0.26650 r = 2 8.98 8.98

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnIRt lnARt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.284 -0.015
Chi Square [5.63]* [11.69]*

Notes: (a) * and ** indicate significant at 1% and 5% levels respectively.


(b) Figures within the 3rd brackets represent Chi Square

Next, we investigate the relationship between domestic savings and foreign aid,

equation (7.7). The test results show that only the trace test is significant at the 10 per

cent level. The results are presented in Table 7.8. The coefficient of aid is found to be

positive but it is statistically insignificant.


Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 270

Table 7.8: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1970-2002


(equation (7.7), lnSR and lnAR)

λmax λtrace
VAR (2) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.41811 r=0 r=1 15.80 25.29***
0.26560 r=2 9.49 9.49

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnSRt lnARt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.153 -0.050
Chi Square [0.50] [5.96]*

Notes: (a) * and *** indicate significant at 1% and 10% levels respectively.
(b) Figures within the 3rd brackets represent Chi Square

Finally, we investigate the influence of savings and aid on investment (equation 7.4).

The results show that the variables under study are cointegrated (Table 7.9).

Table 7.9: Estimates of Johansen’s Likelihood Ratio test, 1970-2002


(equation (7.4), lnIR, lnSR and lnAR)

λmax λtrace
VAR (3) Hypothesis LR test based on
Eigenvalues Null Alternative

r <= 1
0.65298 r=0 r=1 31.75** 56.23**

r <= 2
0.41119 r=2 15.88 24.48***
0.24918 r = 3 8.59 8.59

Long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients

Variables lnIRt lnSRt lnARt Trend


Coefficients 1.000 -0.711 -0.254 0.013
Chi Square [17.11]* [14.58]* [5.92]**

Notes: (a) *, ** and *** indicate significant at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.
(b) Figures within the 3rd brackets represent Chi Square

The long-run cointegrating normalised coefficients show that both savings and aid

have a positive and statistically significant (at 1 per cent) relationship with investment

in the long-run. The elasticity of investment with respect to savings, estimated at 0.71,
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 271

is quite high; it was found to be only 0.109 in the absence of aid (Table 7.6). Thus,

we can conclude that domestic savings play a more important role than foreign aid.

7.5.1 Granger causality test results

In the previous section, the residuals based tests showed that the variables under study

are not cointegrated. Furthermore, the Johansen tests revealed that they are

cointegrated mostly at only the 10 per cent level, which may be considered weak

evidence. Thus, we find it necessary to perform the bivariate Granger causality test

among the variables. It is worth mentioning that very few attempts have been made to

address the issue of a causal relationship between aid and savings (see Bowles, 1980

and Hasan, 2002). Thus, we examine the directions and patterns of the causal

relationships between aid, savings and investment by performing the bivariate

Granger causality test.

The empirical evidence of a negative aid–savings relationship suggests several

possible hypotheses. First, the “dependency hypothesis” posits that foreign aid causes

lower domestic savings (Griffin and Enos, 1970). Second, the reverse causality

hypothesis implies that countries with lower savings rates and unfavorable economic

conditions receive more foreign aid on the basis of their needs (Papanek, 1972, 1973).

Finally, the hypothesis of the feedback effect states that high inflows of aid cause low

domestic savings and low domestic savings attract high inflows of aid.

On the other hand, foreign aid and domestic saving may be independent of each other.

It is possible to argue that foreign aid depends on donors’ interests and exogenous
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 272

decisions, whereas domestic savings depends on income level along with other

domestic factors such as credit policy and financial deepening. Therefore, aid inflows

and domestic savings may not be correlated.

Since the causality test results are sensitive to the choice of the lag length, we have

used three different lag lengths, 2, 3 and 4, for all variables in each equation. The null

hypothesis in each case is that the variable under consideration does not “Granger

cause” the other variable. The causality test results are presented in Table 7.10.

Table 7.10: Bivariate Granger causality test results, 1970-2002

CHSQ, CHSQ, CHSQ,


Causality results Lag = 2 Lag = 3 Lag = 4

DlnIR ⇒ DlnSR 17.26* 16.24* 13.41*

DlnSR ⇒ DlnIR 4.89*** 8.08** 8.70**

DlnSR ⇒ DlnAR 7.07** 19.35* 25.47*

DlnAR ⇒ DlnSR 5.87** 6.17 4.97

Notes: (a) All variables are in natural logarithm 8 and Dln stands for change.
(b) CHSQ stands for Chi Square
(c) *, ** and *** indicate 1%, 5% and 10% significant levels respectively.

The results indicate that there exists bidirectional (feedback) causality between

changes in investment rate (IR) and savings rate (SR) in all three different lag lengths,

that is, IR ⇔ SR. Consistent with theory; savings cause an increase in investment,

which causes income to rise and hence savings. Investment also increases savings

directly, without an intervening increase in income. This happens through inflationary

financing and is known as forced savings (see Kalecki, 1976).

8
As we have transformed the variables in natural logarithm, we have used Chi Square instead of F-test,
which is considered more efficient.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 273

We also find unidirectional causality from savings rate (SR) to aid flows (AR),

consistent with some of the early studies. As mentioned earlier, Papanek (1972, 1973)

and Kennedy and Thirlwall (1971) argued that developing countries with a low

savings rate receive more aid on the basis of their needs. That is, countries with low

savings receive a higher amount of aid. It is also argued that aid is given in proportion

to the extent of poverty and other crises in the recipient country as measured by the

level and growth of income. On the other hand, the Chi Square statistics shows that

reverse causality from aid to savings does not exist when lag lengths 3 and 4 are

considered. This casts doubt on Griffin and Enos’ (1970) hypothesis that aid inflows

cause lower domestic savings.

7.5.2 Generalised impulse response analysis

Having examined the relationship between aid, savings and investment, we proceed to

examine certain dynamic properties by simulating the response of each variable to

exogenous shocks in other variables. That is, we analyse the time profile of the effect

of shocks at a given point in time from one variable to another. This is done by using

the generalised impulse response function (see further chapter 5). Specifically,

variables are given shocks of one standard error (SE) and the impulse response

functions are obtained from the cointegrating relations. Thus we analyse these

variables in the context of the VAR (3) model with the assumption of unrestricted

intercepts and restricted trend coefficients. As all variables are found to be I(1), we

have used their first difference forms (D stands for first difference) for the impulse

response analysis and all variables are in natural logarithm. The results are presented

in Figures 7.3 to7.10, for horizon of 14-year period.


Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 274

Figure 7.3: Generalised impulse response of DlnSR


to one S.E. shock in DlnIR

0.20
0.15
DlnIR
0.10
0.05
0.00
-0.05
DlnSR
-0.10
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Horizon

Figure 7.3 shows the impulse response of savings (DlnSR) to investment (DlnIR). At

the beginning, the shocks have larger effects, almost a 15 per cent rise in savings, but

it dies out quickly by about a four-year period. The feedback response of investment

(via the rise in savings) to the initial shock to investment itself is less than the

response of savings, implying that the system converges to equilibrium. Figure 7.4

shows the response of investment to one SE shock to savings. Investment increases

immediately by about 8 per cent, and the impact dies out by about the 7th year.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 275

Figure 7.4: Generalised impulse response of DlnIR


to one S.E. shock in DlnSR

0.25
0.20
DlnIR
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
DlnSR
-0.05
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Horizon

Figure 7.5: Generalised impulse response of DlnAR


to one S.E. shock in DlnIR

0.15
0.10 DlnIR
0.05
0.00
-0.05
DlnAR
-0.10
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Horizon

The impulse response of aid (DlnAR) to investment (DlnIR) is presented in Figure

7.5. Until about second year, there is a mismatch between the response of aid and that

of investment to the initial shock to investment. After that aid response follows the

pattern of investment response, but aid overshoots investment. The feedback

responses die out by about the sixth year. Figure 7.6 demonstrates that the initial

response of investment to shocks to aid flows is negative, and in the subsequent years

the response is not very pronounced. This may be due to Nepal’s weak absorptive

capacity.
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 276

Figure 7.6: Generalised impulse response of DlnIR


to one S.E. shock in DlnAR

0.20
0.15 DlnIR
0.10
0.05
0.00
DlnAR
-0.05
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Horizon

Figure 7.7: Generalised impulse response of DlnAR


to one S.E. shock in DlnSR

0.25
0.20
0.15 DlnSR
0.10
0.05
0.00
-0.05
-0.10
DlnAR
-0.15
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Horizon

Figure 7.7 shows the shocks response of aid to savings. The shock response of savings

and aid’s response are very similar to the response of investment to the initial shock to

aid flows. The impulse response of aid to savings (Figure 7.8) is also very similar to

aid’s response to investment shocks.


Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 277

Figure 7.8: Generalised impulse response of DlnSR


to one S.E. shock in DlnAR

0.15
0.10
DlnSR
0.05
0.00
-0.05
-0.10
DlnAR
-0.15
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Horizon

Figure 7.9 shows the responses of savings and aid to a one SE shock to investment.

The response to savings is larger than that of aid. This implies that although aid flows

respond to increased investment, domestic savings is the dominant source of

financing. Figure 7.10 shows the response of savings and investment to a one SE

shock to aid flows. We find that the initial impact is a drop in both savings and

investment, but after that both continue to rise and the impacts die out by the fourth

year.

Figure 7.9: Generalised impulse responses of DlnSR and DlnAR


to one S.E. shock in DlnIR

0.15
0.10 DlnIR
0.05
0.00 DlnSR
-0.05
-0.10 DlnAR
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Horizon
Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 278

Figure 7.10: Generalised impulse responses of DlnSR and DlnIR


to one S.E. shock in DlnAR

0.15
0.10 DlnIR
0.05
0.00
-0.05 DlnSR
-0.10
-0.15 DlnAR
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
Horizon

7.6 Summary and conclusion

In this chapter, we have made an attempt to shed light on the issue of aid and the

savings–investment gap in Nepal. The cointegration results indicate that there exists a

weak long-run relationship between domestic savings and investment. This implies

that foreign aid has been an additional source of financing investment. This result is

further confirmed by the positive association between aid and investment.

The bivariate Granger causality tests results show that there is bidirectional causality

between changes in domestic savings and investment. While there exists

unidirectional causality from changes in savings to changes in foreign aid, we do not

find support for the reverse causality from aid to savings. Hence, our results are

consistent with the hypothesis that aid is given based primarily on recipients’

investment needs, as reflected by their low savings rates.


Chapter 7: Foreign Aid, Savings and Investment 279

We have also analysed impulse response functions among variables. In most cases,

the responses die out by 6-7 years. We also find that the domestic savings response is

larger than the aid response to shocks in investment, showing the importance of

domestic financing of investment.


Chapter 8

Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour

“The magnitude of fungibility depends on a country’s budgetary structures, the degree to


which governments are able to manage their finances and the extent of donor
involvement…… What really matters in evaluating the effect of aid, however, is what the
government does with the resources it otherwise would have devoted to the project. It could
do the next best project not yet financed…or could choose to do a white elephant project with
political payoffs but with a return to the economy of zero” (World Bank, 1998: 70-73).

8.1 Introduction

In the previous two chapters we investigated aid–growth, aid–savings and aid–

investment relationships. In particular, we evaluated aid effectiveness in terms of its

association with per capita real GDP and the savings–investment gap. The aid–growth

relationship was first assumed to work through technological progress via aid’s

favourable effects on technical knowledge. Aid’s contribution to growth was then

analysed through its effect on capital accumulation, in particular, the savings–

investment gap.

One of the deficiencies of studies of aid–growth and/ or aid and savings–investment

gap relationships is that they fail to explicitly recognise that aid is given primarily to

the government. Thus any impact of aid on the economy will depend on government

behaviour. Furthermore, the government’s financial (budgetary) position is a major

determinant of domestic savings.

Table 8.1 presents a comparison between Nepal and three South Asian countries

(India, Pakistan and Sri Lanka) in terms of government revenue and expenditures and

aid. On an average Sri Lanka has the highest revenue/GDP and expenditure/GDP
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 281

ratios, followed by Pakistan, during the period 1975-01. Nepal’s revenue and

expenditure as percentages of GDP are the lowest among the South Asian countries. 1

However, Nepal received higher aid as a percentage of GDP compared to other South

Asian countries. The higher flows of aid perhaps contributed to lower public sector

borrowing in Nepal.

Table 8.1: Government revenue and expenditure for South Asian countries,
as percentage of GDP, 1975-2001
Country/Year Aid/GDP Revenue/GDP Borrowing/GDP Total expenditure/GDP
Nepal
1975-84 6.93 7.94 1.69 15.04
1985-94 12.25 9.19 1.89 18.28
1995-01 8.68 11.18 1.21 18.22
India
1975-84 1.19 12.37 5.07 13.47
1985-94 1.24 13.30 6.48 16.31
1995-01 0.75 12.49 4.98 15.6
Pakistan
1975-84 4.38 15.14 4.52 18.17
1985-94 4.27 17.65 5.71 23.17
1995-01 2.59 16.41 4.47 22.46
Sri Lanka
1975-84 8.36 19.96 6.29 31.84
1985-94 8.21 20.51 5.46 29.72
1995-01 3.05 18.01 6.70 26.22

Note: Bangladesh is not included due to non-availability of data.


Source: IMF/IFS online database and Statistical Year Book of Nepal, 1995 and 2003

This chapter examines the impact of aid on the fiscal (revenue and expenditure)

behaviour of the Nepalese government. Particularly, we look at the following

relationships: (a) aid and government’s development and non-development

expenditure; and (b) aid and revenue. The chapter is organised as follows. The next

section provides a graphical exposition of aid and fiscal behaviour. Section 8.3

presents the model, data and methodological procedures. The empirical results and

1
See chapter 2 on the trends in and patterns of revenue in Nepal. Pervasive corruption, a narrow tax
structure and inefficient tax administration have been major obstacles to revenue collection in Nepal.
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 282

analyses are reported in section 8.4. The final section provides summary and

conclusion.

8.2 Fiscal response models

The issue of fiscal response has been addressed in the literature through two different

approaches. The first approach follows the model developed by McGuire (1978), and

is concerned with the question of aid fungibility. Aid is said to be fungible if the

recipient uses aid for purposes other than those intended by the donors. The

assumption is that donors intend aid flows to finance specific activities; the question

is whether the flows are diverted to other purposes. In other words, if aid intended for

investment is actually diverted to government consumption spending, then the

potential growth impact of aid may be reduced. 2 Generally, government investment

spending is considered to make a greater contribution to growth than government

consumption spending. Thus, aid should not to be diverted to consumption spending.

Studies of this approach are Khilji and Zampelli (1991), Pack and Pack (1990, 1993),

Feyzioglu et al. (1998), and Swaroop et al. (2000).

The second type of model, based on the seminal work of Heller (1975), assumes

utility-maximising behaviour for the government, and examines the pattern of

different components of government expenditure when it is faced with a budget

constraint which is defined by revenue, borrowings and aid. To this end, governments

set targets for various expenditures and also set revenue targets for tax and borrowing.

2
Even if aid is used in the intended manner, it allows the government to increase its consumption
expenditure or fund other projects, which may not be so productive. In that case, too, aid effectiveness
will be low.
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 283

Then, they maximise their goal (economic growth or social welfare) by attaining these

revenue and expenditure targets. The assumption here is that the realisation of

revenue and expenditure targets maximises the goals. The flow of aid can change

either government’s expenditure targets or revenue/borrowing targets. Government

can also adjust its both expenditure and revenue/borrowing targets in response to aid.

In formulating our empirical model, we follow the work of Pack and Pack (1990,

1993) and Feyzioglu et al. (1998), which use a McGuire type theoretical framework.

The reason for using this type of specification is that it does not suffer from the

methodological problems of Heller type models. As White (1994) has pointed out, the

Heller type models suffer from important estimation problems. These arise from the

fact that the Heller type models use target variables in the utility function of the

government. If the available revenue (aid plus domestic revenue) fails to meet the

target expenditure, then utility is not maximised. However, target variables are not

observable and hence need to be estimated. The targets are taken to be the fitted

values from the regression equations linking target variables to their past values and

some plausible exogenous factors. White (1994) expressed doubts about whether

target values thus derived through estimation would necessarily be equal to the values

of target variables derived from the optimisation exercise. If the target value is very

close to the actual value then one would be regressing the variable on itself, producing

R2 which will be very close to 1. On the other hand, if the R2 is low, it would be very

difficult to see how the fitted values calculated using the estimated coefficients may

be meaningfully interpreted as the values of the targets. Thus, White (1994: 159)

notes: “the fit will be poor either because the wrong variables have been included in
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 284

the target equation, or because the outturn was far removed from the target. In the

later case, the coefficients will not be those used in the formation of targets”.

On the other hand, Pack and Pack (1990, 1993) and Feyzioglu et al. (1998) specify

various types of government expenditure and revenue as functions of GDP and some

plausible variables, all of which are observable. Hence these models do not need any

estimated variables such as targets as in the Heller type models. Pack and Pack and

Feyzioglu et al. used a standard utility function involving public goods to be

maximised subject to the government budget constraint.

Therefore, following Pack and Pack (1990, 1993) and Feyzioglu et al. (1998), we

examine the relationship between aid and three different categories of government

revenue and expenditures in Nepal as follows:

ln G d t = λ 20 + λ 21 ln GDPPt + λ 22 ln AIDt + D87 + u t 2 ..............................................(8.1)

ln G nd t = λ30 + λ31 ln GDPPt + λ32 ln AIDt + D87 + u t 3 .......... .......... .......... .......... .....(8.2)

ln REVt = λ 40 + λ 41 ln GDPPt + λ 42 ln AIDt + D87 + u t 4 ...........................................(8.3)

where Gd = per capita development expenditure, Gnd = per capita non-development

expenditure or current expenditure, Rev = per capita government revenue (tax plus

non-tax), AID = per capita aid and GDPP = per capita GDP. ln = natural logarithm.

All variables are expressed in current prices.


Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 285

D87 is a dummy variable (= 0 for 1975-86 and 1 for 1987-02). The dummy captures

the impact of Structural Adjustment Programs, which have important bearings on

government expenditure and revenue. In particular, the IMF-World Bank supported

Structural Adjustment Program (signed by Nepal in 1987) requires revenue effort to

increase and expenditure to be contained or cut in order to achieve a sustainable

budget outcome.

8.3.1 Data and summary statistics of the variables

We have used time-series data from 1975 to 2002; no reliable data prior to this period

are available. Government revenue and expenditure data are obtained from the Central

Bureau of Statistics (CBS) publication, Statistical Year Book of Nepal (1981, 1982,

1991, 1999, and 2003). Foreign aid data are obtained from the OECD publication,

IDS online database. For the model estimation, all variables are expressed as per

capita form at current prices and transformed into natural logarithm. 3 Table 8.2

presents the correlation among model variables. As can be seen, all variables are

highly correlated, indicating that our model relating them is highly plausible. We also

find that aid growth correlates highly with the growth of both development and non-

development expenditure as well as with the growth of revenue (Table 8.2A).

3
Since AID is in per capita form, the notation is different than previous chapters (AR).
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 286

Table 8.2: Correlation matrix of model variables, 1975-2002

Variables GDPP AID REV Gd Gnd


GDPP 1.00
AID 0.93 1.00
REV 0.98 0.90 1.00
Gd 0.97 0.98 0.95 1.00
Gnd 0.98 0.87 0.99 0.92 1.00

Table 8.2A: Correlation matrix of variables, 1975-2002

Variables AIDgr Gdgr Gndgr REVgr


AIDgr 1.00
Gdgr 0.37 1.00
Gndgr 0.28 0.06 1.00
REVgr 0.21 0.01 0.38 1.00

Notes: (a) All variables are expressed as a percentage of GDP.


(b) “gr” stands for growth.

8.4 Unit root tests

Since we are using cointegration tests to examine the relationship between aid and

various components of government revenue and expenditure, it is necessary to ensure

that all variables under study are of the same order. In other words, the standard

cointegration analysis requires the classification of the variables into I(1), that is, they

need to be nonstationary. In order to test for stationarity in the next step, therefore, we

perform ADF, and PP unit root tests.


Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 287

Table 8.3: ADF test with constant only (Lag = 2), 1975-2002
ADF test with constant only Critical values
Variables Levels First difference 10% 5% 1%

lnGDPP 1.94 -2.70*** -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

lnAID -2.69*** -1.05 -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

lnGd -2.60 -2.05 -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

lnGnd 0.03 -2.85*** -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

lnREV -0.81 -2.38 -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

Notes: (a) *** indicates significant at 10% level.


(b) All variables are expressed in natural logarithm form.

Table 8.3A: ADF test with constant and trend (Lag = 2), 1975-2002

ADF test with constant and trend Critical values


Variables Levels First difference 10% 5% 1%

lnGDPP -2.46 -3.52*** -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

lnAID -0.17 -2.30 -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

lnGd -0.24 -3.67** -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

lnGnd -2.41 -2.79 -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

lnREV -1.22 -2.36 -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

Note: ** and *** indicate significant at 5% and 10% levels respectively.

The ADF test results are presented in Tables 8.3 and 8.3A. The results show that only

two variables, lnGDPP and lnGnd, are found to be stationary at the 10 per cent

significant level in their first difference form with the assumption of a constant only.

On the other hand, only lnGDPP and lnGd are found to be stationary at the 10 and 5

per cent significant levels, respectively, with the assumption of a constant and trend.

Thus, a unit root problem exists even in their first difference form for lnAID, lnGnd
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 288

and lnREV with the assumption of a constant and a time trend; thus they are

nonstationary under the ADF test results.

Table 8.4: PP test with constant only (Lag = 2), 1975-2002

PP test with constant only Critical values


Variables Levels First difference 10% 5% 1%

lnGDPP 1.36 -7.41* -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

lnAID -3.89* -5.60* -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

lnGd -3.35** -3.95* -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

lnGnd -0.45 -7.17* -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

lnREV -0.74 -4.88* -2.62 -2.97 -3.69

Note: * and ** indicate significant at 1% and 5% levels respectively.

Since the ADF tests indicate inconclusive results, we perform the PP unit root test; the

results are presented in Tables 8.4 and 8.4A. As with the ADF test, we have fixed lag

lengths of 2 based on the AIC. Almost all variables have a unit root problem in their

level form both with a constant, and with a constant and a time trend assumptions.

However, they are found to be stationary in their first difference form at the one per

cent significant level. Thus, under both assumptions of a constant only and a constant

with a trend, the variables can be considered nonstationary in their level and

stationary in their first difference forms.


Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 289

Table 8.4A: PP test with constant and time trend (Lag = 2), 1975-2002
PP test with constant and time trend Critical values
Variables Levels First difference 10% 5% 1%

lnGDPP -2.41 -8.61* -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

lnAID -0.40 -8.35* -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

lnGd -0.05 -5.23* -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

lnGnd -3.09 -7.01* -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

lnREV -1.65 -4.86* -3.22 -3.58 -4.32

Note: * indicates significant at 1% level.

8.5 Cointegration test results

As the variables under study are found to be I(1), we proceed to perform cointegration

tests by applying Johansen’s Maximum Likelihood approach. We begin with equation

(8.1) relating development expenditure to aid and per capita GDP. As in the other

chapters, prior to testing for the cointegrating vectors, lag length of the vector

autoregressive system is determined by using the SBC and AIC. The λmax and λtrace

statistics are reported in Table 8.5 (Part A). The test results show that there is a

significant long-run relationship between aid and development expenditure.


Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 290

Table 8.5: Cointegrating test results, 1975-2002


(equation (8.1), lnGd, lnGDPP and lnAID), Part A

λmax λtrace
VAR (3) Hypothesis
Eigenvalues H0 H1

0.86332 r=0 r=1 49.75** 64.09**

0.55756 r <= 1 r=2 20.38** 34.35**

0.42787 r<= 2 r=3 13.95** 13.95**

Normalised cointegrating vectors (normalised on lnGd), Part B


lnGd lnGDPP lnAID Trend

1.000 -0.397 -0.111 -0.049

Chi Square [8.56]* [5.15]** [11.87]*

Note: * and ** indicate significant at 1% and 5% levels respectively.

The normalised cointegrating vectors are presented in Part B. The results show that

per capita development expenditure is positively associated with both per capita aid

and per capita GDP in the long-run. The long-run aid coefficient is significant at the 5

per cent level, but the elasticity of per capita development expenditure with respect to

per capita aid is quite low (0.11). The estimation of equation (8.1) with a dummy for

the Structural Adjustment Program did not change the result significantly, and the

dummy was not found to be significant. This implies that the Structural Adjustment

Program possibly did not affect development expenditure.

Next we estimate equation (8.2) relating per capita non-development expenditure to

per capita GDP (lnGDPP), per capita aid and a dummy (D87). The results (Part A of

Table 8.6) show that the variables under study are cointegrated at the 5 per cent
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 291

significant level. More importantly, there exists a long-run relationship between per

capita aid and per capita non-development expenditure. All the normalised

cointegrating vectors are found to be positive except for dummy (Part B). Because aid

is generally given for development purposes, the positive and significant association

between per capita aid and per capita non-development expenditure may be

considered a diversion of development aid to non-development expenditure. The

significant and negative coefficient for dummy implies that the Structural Adjustment

Program had negative impacts on non-development expenditure. That is, the

conditionality imposed by the World Bank and the IMF through the Structural

Adjustment Program seemed to have been effective in changing the government’s

spending patterns. 4

Table 8.6: Cointegrating test results, 1975-2002


(equation (8.2), lnGnd, lnGDPP, lnAID and Dummy (D87)), Part A

λmax λtrace
VAR (3) Hypothesis
Eigenvalues H0 H1
0.76756 r=0 r=1 36.47** 47.81**

0.33819 r< = 1 r=2 10.31 11.33

0.03971 r< = 2 r=3 1.01 1.01


Normalised cointegrating vectors (normalised on lnGnd), Part B
lnGnd lnGDPP lnAID D87 Trend

1.000 -0.221 -0.613 0.423 -0.074

Chi Square [0.56] [18.84]* [17.49]* [27.66]*

Notes: (a) * and ** indicate significant at 1% and 5% levels respectively.


(b) Since dummy is placed at Part B for a convenient purpose, the sign of the coefficient is
taken as positive in Table, which is actually negative.

4
The government reduced expenditure through the privatisation of public enterprises, which were
running with huge losses. The government had already cut subsidies to some enterprises, thus
maintaining a low budget deficit and domestic borrowing.
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 292

Interestingly, the elasticity of per capita non-development expenditure with respect to

per capita aid is found relatively larger (0.61) than that for development expenditure.

In other words, a 1 per cent increase in per capita aid leads to an approximately 0.6

per cent increase in the per capita non-development expenditure, whereas it leads to

only 0.11 per cent increase in per capita development expenditure (see Table 8.5).

Since aid is generally given for development expenditure, these results indicate the

possibility of diversion of aid to non-development expenditure. As is the case with

other developing countries, diversion of development aid is not a new phenomenon in

Nepal. In practice, due to political reasons, one can find many examples of diversion

of development aid to non-development expenditure.

Table 8.7: Cointegrating test results, 1975-2002


(equation (8.3), lnREV, lnGDPP and lnAID), Part A

λmax λtrace
VAR (3) Hypothesis
Eigenvalues H0 H1

0.65678 r=0 r=1 26.73** 51.35**

0.41795 r< = 1 r=2 13.52 24.61***

0.35827 r< = 2 r=3 11.08 11.08

Normalised cointegrating vectors (normalised on lnREV), Part B


lnREV lnGDPP lnAID Trend

1.000 -0.123 -0.482 -0.057

Chi Square [10.09]* [12.67]* [15.39]*

Note: *, ** and ** indicate significant at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.

Table 8.7 (Part A) presents the results of cointegration between per capita revenue,

per capita GDP and per capita aid. The results show that there is a long-run
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 293

relationship between all three variables. All the long-run normalised coefficients are

found to be positive (Part B). The long-run normalised coefficient of per capita aid is

found to be positive and significant at the one per cent level. A 1 per cent increase in

per capita aid contributes to almost 0.5 per cent increase in per capita revenue. Thus,

the results indicate that aid did not lead to a reduction in revenue raising efforts. This

may be due to the influence of aid (through technical assistance) on improving

administrative and institutional quality. 5 The finding of a positive influence of aid on

revenue is contrary to earlier studies such as Heller (1975), Franco-Rodriguez (2000)

and Pack and Pack (1993).

8.6 Impulse response function

To measures the time profile of the effect of shocks at a given point in time on the

expected future values of variables in a dynamic system, we have used the generalised

impulse response function. Here, we present the impulse response analysis of three

variables at a time. As noted earlier, all three variables are in natural logarithms,

measured on a per capita basis. Since all the variables under study are found to be

I(1), we proceed our analysis in the context of a cointegrated VAR(3) model with

unrestricted intercepts and restricted trend coefficients.

5
There has been considerable technical assistance for the preparation and the implementation of VAT,
as well as for broadening structural base of the Nepalese taxation system.
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 294

Aid and government expenditure

Figures 8.1 to 8.3 indicate the generalised impulse response over a 25-year period.

Figure 8.1A shows the response of per capita GDP (DlnGDPP) and per capita aid

(DlnAID) to once for all one standard error shock to per capita development

expenditure (DlnGd). We find that the shock has a larger and more persistent effect

on per capita development expenditure itself followed by per capita aid. This is quite

expected as development projects are of longer duration and once commenced cannot

be abandoned. The shock response of per capita aid to per capita development

expenditure shows a cyclical pattern over 16 years and then tends to die out.

Interestingly, the shock response of aid flows follows the response pattern of

development expenditure. It implies that the larger the development expenditure, the

larger will be the aid flow.

Figure 8.1A: Generalised impulse response(s) of DlnGDPP and


DlnAID to one S.E. shock in DlnGd

0.10
0.08 DlnGd
0.06
0.04
0.02 DlnGDPP
0.00
-0.02
-0.04 DlnAID
0 5 10 15 20 25
Horizon

Figure 8.1B shows the responses of per capita GDP and per capita development

expenditure to once for all one standard error shock to per capita aid. The effects of

shock to per capita aid decreased from a positive 13 per cent to an almost negative 4

per cent within a one-year period, and responses of aid to a shock to itself die out
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 295

quickly. This implies that changes in aid flows cannot be sustained for long. That is,

aid flows follow an average trend. Once again, we find that responses of development

expenditure to shocks in aid flows follow the same pattern as the responses of aid

itself. This implies a close connection between aid and development expenditure.

Figure 8.1B: Generalised impulse response(s) of DlnGd and


DlnGDPP to one S.E. shock in DlnAID

0.15
DlnGd
0.10

0.05
DlnGDPP
0.00

-0.05 DlnAID
0 5 10 15 20 25
Horizon

Figure 8.2A: Generalised impulse response(s) of DlnGDPP and


DlnAID to one S.E. shock in DlnGnd

0.06
0.05
0.04 DlnGnd
0.03
0.02
0.01 DlnGDPP
0.00
-0.01
-0.02
-0.03 DlnAID
0 5 10 15 20 25
Horizon

Responses of per capita GDP and per capita aid to once for all one standard error

shock to per capita non-development expenditure are presented in Figure 8.2A. It

shows that responses of non-development expenditure to a shock to itself die out


Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 296

relatively quickly than was the case for per capita development expenditure. Aid’s

response to a shock in non-development expenditure follows the responses of non-

development expenditure. We also find that responses of per capita non-development

expenditure to a one standard error shock to aid flows do not persist (Figure 8.2B), as

aid’s response to a shock to itself dies out quickly.

In sum, we find that in general aid responds to shocks to both development and non-

development expenditure. Additionally, shocks to aid flows cannot be sustained for

long.

Aid and government revenue


Figure 8.3A demonstrates the responses of per capita GDP and per capita aid to a one

standard error shock to per capita revenue. The response of revenue to shocks to itself

initially begins with a larger positive effect of over 8 per cent and then declines to

negative 6 per cent. It then converges quickly towards zero. Thus, it suggests that per

capita revenue does not have much cyclical effects of shocks. Interestingly, when

revenue response is negative in the early period, the aid response is found to be

positive. That is, aid is needed to fill the shortfall in revenue.

The responses of per capita GDP and per capita revenue to a one standard error shock

to per capita aid are displayed in Figure 8.3B. Generally, the responses of revenue to

the shock in aid flows follow the opposite pattern of responses of aid to the shock to

itself. This is largely in line with the pattern of responses of aid to a shock to revenue

(Figure 8.3A). That is, aid is needed to cover the short-fall in revenue.
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 297

Figure 8.3A: Generalised impulse response(s) of DlnGDPP and


DlnAID to one S.E. shock in DlnREV

A
0.10
0.08
0.06 DlnREV
0.04
0.02
0.00 DlnGDPP
-0.02
-0.04
-0.06
-0.08 DlnAID
0 5 10 15 20 25
Horizon

Figure 8.3B: Generalised impulse response(s) of DlnGDPP and


DlnREV to one S.E. shock in DlnAID

0.15
DlnREV
0.10

0.05
DlnGDPP
0.00

-0.05 DlnAID
0 5 10 15 20 25
Horizon
Chapter 8: Foreign Aid and Government’s Fiscal Behaviour 298

8.7 Summary and conclusion

We have investigated the revenue and expenditure behaviour of the Nepalese

government in the presence of aid flows. We have found that per capita aid, per capita

revenue and per capita development and non-development expenditure are all

cointegrated. The results also show that aid positively affects both development and

non-development expenditure in the long-run. However, since aid is mainly given for

development expenditure, the positive long-run relationship between aid and non-

development expenditure may indicate aid fungibility. This is in line with findings for

most developing countries.

However, contrary to most of the early studies, we have found that aid is positively

related to revenue in the long-run. Relevant to this may be aid in the form of technical

assistance to improve tax administration and the efficiency of the tax system.

The analysis of the impulse response function shows that aid responds positively to

shocks in both development and non-development expenditure as well as to shocks in

revenue. That is, government expenditure programs influence aid disbursement, and

aid is needed to cover the shortfall in revenue. This implies that aid is generally used

as revenue in the government budget. That is, aid flows can relax government budget

constraint, and there is no evidence that aid flows reduce revenue efforts.
Chapter 9

Summary, Conclusions and Policy Recommendations

“The central challenge for today’s conventional country-focused aid delivery system is
managing divergent views on strategies for development and poverty reduction, while
improving coordination, increasing ownership, and reducing aid dependence” (Kanbur and
Sadler, 1999: 4).

Foreign aid has been and remains an important source of financing the needs of

developing countries in their quest for economic progress. This is no different for

Nepal. About half of Nepal’s development expenditure remains financed by foreign

aid. Yet Nepal remains one of the poorest countries of the world with nearly 40 per

cent of its population living in absolute poverty. However, there has been no

comprehensive macroeconomic study of foreign aid effectiveness in Nepal. This

thesis aims to fill this gap.

The impact of foreign aid on economic growth remains a subject of considerable

debate. Its performance varies across countries due to geography, policy environments

and socio-economic conditions. A substantial portion of aid may be used to finance

projects with low rates of return, and in some cases, aid promotes consumption rather

than investment. In particular, aid can contribute to the increase in a government’s

recurrent expenditure and reduced revenue effort. In other words, aid can make a

government lazy. Critics have also pointed out that aid facilitates corruption.

Furthermore, while bilateral aid is mainly based on a donor’s political and

commercial motives, multilateral aid is often attached with conditions, which may not

necessarily coincide with the recipient’s own preferences or needs. More importantly,
Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 300

aid is only one factor contributing to economic growth; its effectiveness depends on

many other factors such as absorptive capacity, quality of institutions, resource

endowment and policy environment.

These diverse and complex issues have important implications for evaluating aid

effectiveness. Therefore, in this study of Nepal, we have examined the effectiveness

of aid in both aggregate and disaggregated forms (for example, loans versus grants),

as well as in terms of its sources, that is, bilateral and multilateral. We have

incorporated policy variables to investigate whether aid effectiveness improves in the

presence of a good policy environment. We have also examined the nature of

government expenditure and revenue efforts in the presence of foreign aid.

9.1 Summary of findings

The analysis employs time-series econometric techniques such as cointegration and

the error correction mechanism, using data for the period 1970-2002. The empirical

analysis is divided into three parts. In the first part, the relationship between aid and

per capita real GDP is examined within a framework of the neoclassical production

function. In the second part, the relationship between aid and investment is examined

within the framework of the two-gap model. In the third part, the relationship between

aid and government’s expenditure and revenue is investigated within the framework

of the fiscal response model. The results show that aid has a positive and significant

relationship with per capita real GDP, savings and investment. The fiscal response to

aid suggests that aid induces more non-development expenditure than development
Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 301

expenditure; however, aid does not have any negative impact on revenue raising

efforts.

9.1.1 Aid and per capita GDP

Within the framework of the neoclassical production function, aid is assumed to

augment technology through technical assistance and new knowledge embodied

imported capital goods. Thus, foreign aid becomes a variable in the production

function. In addition to examining the impact of total aid, we have disaggregated aid

by its forms (for example, loans and grants) and sources (for example, bilateral and

multilateral aid). The analysis has been extended to examine the influence of policy

environment on aid effectiveness.

Aid, whether in aggregate or in disaggregated form, is found to have a significant

positive relationship with per capita real GDP in the long-run. Grants aid have a

relatively stronger positive association with per capita real GDP than loans aid. This

finding has important implications. Loans aid adds to debt burden, and if government

revenue and export earnings do not rise fast enough, the debt burden may impede

economic growth.

Both bilateral and multilateral aid have been found to play an equally important role.

However, judging from their joint effect on per capita real GDP, it seems that there

are significant complementarities between bilateral and multilateral aid. This may be

due to the fact that bilateral donors are linking their support to the approval of the

multilateral donors since the introduction of Structural Adjustment Program.


Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 302

Our model has been extended by incorporating three policy variables with regard to

macroeconomic stability, openness and financial deepening. The indicators used for

this are inflation, total trade as a proportion of GDP and M2/GDP. The results suggest

that aid effectiveness improves in Nepal in the presence of a stable macroeconomy, a

liberalised trade regime and a liberalised financial sector. We also find that political

instability affects the economy adversely, as indicated by the significance of the

dummy variables used for political instability. In such situations, aid can keep the

economy going.

Finally we find that aid has a negative relationship with per capita real GDP in the

short-run. This indicates that Nepal suffers from excessive aid volatility and a lack of

absorptive capacity. This may also be due to aid conditionality. Reforms imposed by

conditionality may adversely affect the economy in the short-run. On the other hand,

the failure to implement conditionality by the deadline causes delay in aid

disbursement, which disrupts government expenditure plans.

9.1.2 Aid and the savings–investment gap

The purpose of investigating the relationship between aid and the savings–investment

gap is to evaluate aid’s contribution to economic growth via its contribution to capital

formation. The starting point of this investigation is the hypothesis that a low

correlation between domestic investment and domestic savings is an indication that

foreign financing is filling the savings–investment gap. The empirical results confirm

this hypothesis. The result is further confirmed by the findings of positive associations

between aid and investment.


Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 303

We also find unidirectional causality from changes in savings to changes in foreign

aid. However, we did not find reverse causality between them. This implies that aid

responds positively to savings shortfalls and, contrary to the views of some critics, aid

does not adversely affect domestic savings. We have also analysed the impulse

response functions among variables. Changes in all variables converge towards zero,

after a shock suggesting that they are in equilibrium relationships in the long-run. The

analysis further reveals that the investment response to shocks in domestic savings is

larger and takes longer to die out than the response to shocks in aid. This indicates

that domestic savings is a more dominant source of finance. This has also been

confirmed by the findings of bidirectional causality between savings and investment.

9.1.3 Aid and fiscal behaviour

Since government’s budgetary position is an important determinant of domestic

savings and the government plays an important role in a nation’s capital formation,

we investigate aid’s impact on government’s expenditure and revenue. The empirical

findings show a positive and significant relationship between per capita aid and per

capita non-development expenditure and a low elasticity of development expenditure

with respect to aid. This indicates perhaps the problem of aid fungibility as aid is

mainly given for development purposes. But this may also be due to the fact that

Nepal receives significant amounts of humanitarian aid.

The impulse response analysis shows that the shocks to aid have relatively less effects

on non-development expenditure compared to effects on development expenditure.


Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 304

This reflects the long-term nature of development expenditure, which cannot be

adjusted quickly to shortfalls in funding.

9.2 Concluding remarks

Based on our empirical findings we can conclude that the overall contribution of

foreign aid in Nepal has been positive. Foreign aid fully financed the development

expenditure of the First Five-Year Plan and still contributes over 50 per cent to the

development expenditure.

Before 1950 when the country was ruled by the Rana Regime, Nepal did not have any

link with the rest of the world except with the then British India and Tibet. The

movement of goods and people from one part of the country to another usually

required passage through India. Travel time to the capital Kathmandu from some parts

of the country could take a minimum of 15 to 30 days. 1 There were a few all-weather

roads in Kathmandu only – none in other parts of the country. This lack of

infrastructure made it almost impossible for Nepal to expand trade and economic

activity. There were no educational institutions in the country except for the Tri-

Chandra Campus and Darbar High School in Kathmandu and some Sanskrit Schools

(for the priests). Traditional (herbal and spiritual) medicine provided the only

available heath service for the majority of the population. Thus, life expectancy at

birth was too low, while child mortality rate was very high. The situation has

improved markedly since then.

1
For example, while the flying time between Bhojpur district and Kathmandu is about 45 minutes, the
land travel used to take almost one month in the 1960s.
Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 305

9.2.1 Nepal with foreign aid

Soon after the downfall of the Rana Regime in 1951, foreign assistance came into the

country mainly for the development of infrastructure. Since then Nepal has achieved

notable progress. For example, motorable roads increased from less than 280

kilometres in 1951 to over 15,000 kilometres in 2003. Likewise, irrigated land

increased from about 6,000 hectares in 1951 to over 716,000 hectares (excluding the

farmer-managed irrigation system) in 2003. During the same period, production of

electricity increased from less than 1.5 megawatts to over 370 megawatts (Mihaly,

2002). Moreover, one can now find many schools, universities and hospitals across

the country. Telephone lines, healthcare facilities and the availability of safe drinking

water also substantially increased. These have contributed to a remarkable progress in

Nepal’s social development. For example, the adult literacy rate increased from 16 per

cent in 1970 to 45 per cent in 2002; life expectancy at birth increased from 42 years in

1970 to 60 years in 2002, and the under-five mortality rate (per 1000 live births)

decreased from 234 in 1970 to 83 in 2002.

As noted by Poudyal (1988), these achievements have been possible through foreign

assistance; Nepal’s own revenue was too low to meet the development effort it

required. In other words, resource gaps (namely, the savings–investment and foreign

exchange gaps) were huge in Nepal. To enable the country to meet its development

objectives, these gaps have been financed by foreign aid.

Therefore, one can conclude that despite the low rate of economic growth, foreign aid

has been an important contributory factor in Nepal’s socio-economic development.


Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 306

Hence, our findings that aid contributes to economic growth are consistent with the

fact of Nepal’s socio-economic progress in the last 50 years. The findings of our study

are in line with those of such studies as Papanek (1972, 1973) and Hansen and Tarp

(2000). Our findings also show the importance of policy environment.

9.2.2 Foreign aid could be more effective

This thesis is concerned with macro issues of aid effectiveness; thus micro issues of

aid effectiveness are not discussed explicitly. However, from the results of our macro

analyses, we can infer some bearings of micro issues such as absorptive capacity, aid

management and coordination and the like on aid effectiveness. These issues are

identified below as possible contributory factors to the weakness in aid utilisation in

Nepal. These weaknesses appear to have caused a short-run – long-run paradox. That

is, while aid has positive impacts in the long-run, in the short-run aid has negative

impacts.

Lack of absorptive capacity and coordination

Nepal’s new era began with the political change that ended the Rana Regime in 1951.

Nepal made an attempt to modernise by introducing more liberal socio-economic

policies. However, it was not an easy task because the entire system (of family rule)

had to be replaced with democratic norms and values. Thus, when aid came into the

country, policy makers had little knowledge about how to use and channel aid

effectively. Still, because it had an underdeveloped economy and because of donors’

strategic interests, aid started pouring in. Nepal seriously needed guidelines for the

supervision and allocation of aid. In the absence of a proper system of assessment,


Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 307

one observes a persistent misuse of aid. The negative or low returns to aid caused by

the misselection of capital intensive projects were never examined. Furthermore,

Nepal’s technological and institutional capabilities were too weak to utilise aid

effectively. There was no skilled manpower, and there were always a shortage of

policy makers in the early days of the country’s development.

Some of these weaknesses still persist, causing a low absorptive capacity. The

problem is compounded by a lack of coordination among various government

departments. There is also no proper coordination among donors, leading to high aid

volatility, overlapping aid-funded projects and lopsided allocation of aid.

Donor driven aid

As noted above, Nepal was unprepared and almost unable to utilise aid funds when

aid started pouring in after 1951. Consequently, aid to Nepal was mainly based on

donors’ own perceptions and Nepal had little control over the use of aid. Many

projects and programs are still donor driven in Nepal. This has been acknowledged by

the government: “many projects and programs are still excessively driven by donor

demands. As a consequence, the effectiveness of foreign aid is reduced” (HMG/N,

Foreign Aid Policy, 2002: 5). In addition, bilateral aid, which is motivated by donors’

strategic interests, accounts for over 60 per cent. Nepal’s two traditional donors are

India and China. Their strategic interests were more dominant in the early 1950s until

the early 1980s, when they competed with each other to influence Nepal’s foreign and

economic policies. As Mihaly (2002) noted, India (as did the United States) always

tried to diminish Chinese influence in Nepal. Indian aid went to infrastructure that

held militarily rather than socio-economic importance. The competing strategic


Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 308

interests in Nepal at times created not only political tensions but also adversely

affected the economy. 2

Lack of country ownership

Critics have identified lack of country ownership as a major cause of aid

ineffectiveness through the failure to implement policy reforms. Although Nepal has

implemented policy reforms demanded by aid conditionality, it has often dragged its

feet as it has found some reforms, especially privatisation, too difficult to implement.

Political resistance to reforms is not uncommon when reforms are imposed rather than

designed through a democratic process. This is all more important for Nepal where

there is a strong left leaning political movement.

Aid allocation

Aid effectiveness depends on its allocation. Although tied project aid is not

necessarily beneficial for a country, aid effectiveness may decline if a significant

amount of aid goes to finance current government consumption or non-development

expenditure. In Nepal, there has been a high propensity to spend aid money for non-

development purposes and for the non-traded sector. On the other hand, when aid

money goes to development expenditure involving large capital-intensive

infrastructure projects, it may facilitate corruption, an issue discussed below.

Evidence from other studies shows that aid spent on pro-poor projects such as public

health and primary education and rural development is more effective.

2
During 1988, Nepal purchased 500 truckloads of arms as per Nepal’s arms deal with China. India
reacted strongly and that created political tension between Nepal and India. Consequently, the
relationships between the two countries were strained, particularly in 1989 when India closed 14 of 16
its transit points after the dispute. Nepal had to bear a heavy economic cost due to insufficient transit
points to trade not only with India but also the rest of the world.
Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 309

Current state of corruption

Until recently in Nepal’s history, there was never any investigation into the corruption

of high profile government officials or ministers, despite the fact that Nepal is one of

the corrupt nations in the world. Political observers believe that aid was directly used

to strengthen the corrupt regime in power during the party-less Panchayat system of

1961-90. Thus, the effectiveness of aid was obviously reduced. Only after the early

1990s has the problem of corruption been addressed more seriously, as part of

conditions imposed by international donors such as the World Bank and the IMF. Yet

all the evidence shows that corruption remains ripe in Nepal. When it comes to the

utilisation of foreign aid, the problem of corruption is compounded by the fact that

Nepal does not have a transparent and reliable recording system for all foreign aid

resources. If donors direct aid to project accounts without informing the relevant

government department, the aid cannot be included in the national budget. As a result,

a significant amount of such transactions can be misused. In other words, aid

effectiveness falters due to lack of accountability and a sound management system,

both of which encourage corruption.

In sum, Nepal suffered from the absence of a coherent foreign aid policy. Being an

aid-dependent country, Nepal should have prepared a comprehensive foreign aid

policy for the effective utilisation of aid years ago. Instead, Nepal has been utilising

foreign aid without any guidelines or system for assessing the impact of aid on the

economy for over a half century. While Nepal has become more aid-dependent, it has

failed to prioritise sectors that would have reaped the maximum benefit of aid inflows.

The lack of a comprehensive aid policy has been responsible for the uncoordinated
Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 310

inflow of foreign aid for donor domination and for the mismanagement of aid funds.

Only very recently Nepal has formulated a national foreign aid policy.

9.3 Policy recommendations

The rationale for foreign aid is that it assists a developing country to achieve rapid

economic growth and poverty reduction. In the case of Nepal, foreign aid can help

achieve targeted economic growth by improving aid effectiveness of aid through the

design and implementation of appropriate and consistent foreign aid policies

compatible with national interests. More precisely, aid should be channelled to those

areas/sectors where aid can have relatively high economic and social returns. For

example, more aid should be directed to pro-poor sectors such as agriculture, primary

health and education.

Nepal’s main source of income and employment is the agricultural sector. Yet most of

Nepal’s poor live in rural areas. Thus, in the context of Nepal, poverty reduction that

is enhanced by rapid economic growth can be achieved through productivity growth

in Nepal’s agricultural sector. Despite some efforts in the past, the agricultural sector

is still far behind in lifting the living standard of the majority of the Nepalese. As

NPC (2003) noted, with more than three-quarters of the total population still engaged

in agriculture, the sector needs to be given a high priority. By recognising past

mistakes through appropriate assessment, supervision and policy implementation,

Nepal can rectify persistent problems and maximise the benefits of aid in this sector.
Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 311

However, Nepal’s sectoral distribution of aid indicates that more amount of aid has

been directed to the building of capital infrastructure across the country rather than to

the development of the agricultural sector. Nepal therefore needs to channel more

foreign aid to the agricultural sector, and it needs to do so effectively. Aid has a direct

impact on the productivity growth of the agricultural sector. Aid brings new

technology, which plays a key role in modernising the sector. Aid can finance

improvements as well as the building of new irrigation facilities across the country.

More importantly, aid helps finance agriculture research that facilitates the use of land

in accordance with geographical conditions and farmers’ needs.

A larger proportion of aid should also go to the primary healthcare sector. Studies find

that the productivity of workers is directly related to the condition of their health (see

Dasgupta, 1993 and Sachs, 2001). Nepal’s poor suffer not only from malnutrition, but

also have very poor access to safe drinking water and basic healthcare facilities. The

Nepal Human Development Report has rightly advocated for larger public expenditure

in this sector.

Since Nepal has a shortage of skilled labour, increased emphasis also needs to be

given to the development of its human resources. Labour productivity can be

improved through appropriate education and training. Nepal’s adult literacy rate is

still below 50 per cent, and the female literacy rate is lower than the male rate. Since a

skilled labour force is directly linked to economic growth (being a factor of

production), providing education and training (specifically vocational) to illiterate

people is certain to improve living standards, by giving people an opportunity to earn


Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 312

higher income. Therefore, investment in primary education and vocational training

should be increased.

This will strengthen the aid absorptive capacity that is required for Nepal to achieve

rapid economic growth and poverty reduction. One can in fact justify a higher

allocation of aid and investment in education on other grounds. For example,

educating an illiterate person will indirectly help improve health and sanitation at the

personal and family levels. In other words, education has a positive multiplier effect

in changing a backward society into a more modern, (economically) productive

society.

Since aid effectiveness also depends on the extent of corruption in the recipient

country, Nepal should also combat corruption. An efficient foreign aid management

team (specific government department) with strong financial discipline is required to

maximise the benefits of aid. As donor agencies stress the importance of

decentralisation, strong corruption measures should be introduced at the local

government levels (such as district council and Village Development Committee). In

addition, regular evaluation of the effectiveness of projects and programs needs to be

conducted, to ensure that targeted socio-economic returns are being met. By carefully

scrutinising and supervising capital-intensive infrastructure projects, Nepal can

minimise corruption.

While conditionality in aid disbursement can influence aid allocation and utilisation,

the donors should take extreme care in designing conditionality. To begin with, the

pace and sequence of reforms should be within the country’s administrative and
Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 313

institutional capacity. Secondly, reforms should be politically accepted, and hence

should be agreed through the political process of dialogue, involving various stake-

holders.

Aid to Nepal comes not only from donor governments but from International Non-

governmental Organisations (INGOs) as well. Although a large number of INGOs are

working in Nepal, the government does not always have a direct link with them in

terms of their economic assistance. To maintain transparency and accountability,

regular supervision and effective reporting provisions (in the national budget) about

the operations and effectiveness of INGOs are required. It is also important to compile

data on INGOs aid for future research.

Finally, while foreign aid is an important source of revenue, Nepal should be able to

improve and broaden its domestic sources of revenue. Aid can help in many ways. For

example, technical assistance can help to improve and extend the tax base as well as

create a more efficient tax administration. Aid contributes to higher economic growth,

which eventually helps to expand domestic revenue. Most significantly, Nepal’s aid

dependency can be reduced through linking aid-financed projects to an improved

domestic revenue mobilisation capacity. To achieve all this, the question of reducing

Nepal’s aid dependency over a reasonable time frame needs to be addressed.

Scope for future research

In this thesis, we have empirically examined the aid and growth relationship and

found that aid has been generally effective in promoting economic growth. Yet

Nepal’s socio-economic conditions remain appalling. The poverty rates among the
Chapter 9: Summary, Conclusion and Policy Recommendations 314

socio-economically disadvantaged people and in rural and mountain areas are very

high. This has resulted in high inequality. Corruption is also rampant in the country.

All these conditions imply that the benefits of growth are not trickling down.

It is also generally believed that aid could have been more effective in the absence of

corruption and political interference in aid allocation. The literature indicates that

there could be a two-way relationship between aid and corruption, especially when

donors are motivated by their own political and strategic objectives. This is an

important aspect given Nepal’s strategic location between two rival Asian powers,

India and China.

We also find in the literature that aid allocation can lead to resentment, which in turn,

can become violent. This implies that aid can be used to dampen social violence and

to reconstruct the economy. This is a relevant issue for Nepal, as the country is beset

with Maoist insurgency fuelled by extreme poverty and inequality. Therefore, this

aid-growth research could be extended to examine the following issues:

(a) Aid’s impact on human development such as poverty, literacy rates, and infant

mortality rate along the lines suggested by Mosley et al. (2004) and Gomanee

et al. (2005);

(b) The link between aid and corruption along the lines suggested by Sevensson

(2000), Knack (2001) and Gupta et al. (1998);

(c) The role of donor motives in aid effectiveness as suggested by Khadka (1997)

and Mosley (1985);

(d) The link between aid and social conflict as suggested by Collier and Anke

(2004) and Gounder (2005).


References

Abramovitz, M. (1986), “Catching up, Foreign Ahead, and Falling Behind”, Journal
of Economic History, Vol. 46, pp. 385-406

Acharya, M. (2003), “Development of the Financial System and its Impact on Poverty
Alleviation in Nepal”, Nepal Rastra Bank Economic Review, Vol. 15, pp.1-33

ADB (2004), “The Sectoral Distribution of Cumulative Lending as of 31 December


2003” Asian Development Bank, www.adb.org/documents/fact_sheets/NEP.asp

Adelman, I. and Chenery, H.B. (1966), “Foreign Aid and Economic Development:
The Case of Greece”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 48, pp. 1-19

Ahmed, A. (1996), “Macroeconomic Impact of Foreign Aid on Less Developed


Countries: Some Empirical Evidence”, Working Paper Series 9602, Deakin
University Faculty of Management

Akaike, H. (1973), “Information Theory and Extension of the Maximum Likelihood


Principle” in Petrob, B.N. and Csaki, F. (eds) Second International Symposium on
Information Theory, Budapest, pp. 267-81

Alesina, A. and Perotti, R. (1994), “The Political Economic of Growth: A Critical


Survey of Recent Literature”, World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 8, pp. 352-71

Argimon, I. and Roldan, J. M. (1994), “Saving, Investment and International Capital


Mobility in EC Countries”, European Economic Review, Vol. 38, pp. 59-67

Bera, A.K. and Jarque, C.M. (1981), “An Efficient Large-Sample Test for Normality
of Observations and Regression Residuals”, Australian National University Working
Papers in Econometrics, Canberra

Berg, E.G. (1993), “Rethinking Technical Cooperation: Reforms for Capacity


Building in Africa”, United Nations Development Program, New York
316

Bhatta, G. (2003), “An Assessment of the Impact of External Debt on Economic


Growth of Nepal”, Nepal Rasta Bank–Economic Review Occasional Paper, Vol. 15,
pp. 243-63

Bloom, D. and Sachs, J.D. (1998), “Geography, Demography, and Economic Growth
in Africa”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 2, pp. 207-73

Bowen, J. L. (1998), Foreign Aid and Economic Growth: A Theoretical and


Empirical Investigation, Ashgate Publishing Ltd, England

Bowles, P. (1987), “Foreign Aid and Domestic Savings in Less Developed Countries:
Some Tests for Causality”, World Development, Vol. 15, pp. 789-96

Boone, P. (1996), “ Politics and the Effectiveness of Foreign Aid”, European


Economic Review, Vol. 40, pp. 289-329

Boughton, J. (2003), “Who’s in Charge? Ownership and Conditionality in IMF-


Supported Programs”, IMF Working Papers 191, International Monetary Fund,
Washington, D.C.

Brewster, H. and Yeboah, D. (1994), “Aid and the Growth of Income in Aid-
Favoured Developing Countries: Policy Issues”, Cambridge Journal of Economics,
Vol. 18, pp. 145-62

Browne, S. (1990), Foreign Aid in Practice, Printer Publishers Limited, London

Brown, S. (1990), Foreign Aid and Tractors, New York University Press, New York

Bulir, A. and Hamann, J. (2001), “How Volatile and Unpredictable are Aid Flows and
What are the Policy Implications?’’ IMF Working Paper 01/167, International
Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.
317

Bulir, A. and Hamann, J. (2003), “Aid Volatility: An Empirical Assessment”, IMF


Staff Papers 50, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Bulir, A. and Lane, T. (2002), “Aid and Fiscal Management”, IMF Working Paper
112, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Burnside, C. and Dollar, D. (1997), “Aid, Policies and Growth”, Policy Research
Working Paper 1777, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Burnside, C. and Dollar, D. (2000), “Aid, Policies and Growth”, American Economic
Review, Vol. 90, pp. 847-68

Buyck, B. (1991), “The Bank’s Use of Technical Assistance for Institutional


Development”, Policy Research and External Affairs Working Papers 578, World
Bank, Washington, D.C

Campbell, J. and Perron, P. (1991), Pitfalls and Opportunities: What


Macroeconomists Should Know about Unit Roots, MIT Press, Cambridge and London

Cassen, R. and Associates (1986), Does Aid Work?, Clarendon Press, Oxford

Cassen, R. and Associates (1994), Does Aid Work?, Clarendon Press, Second edition,

Oxford

CBS (various), Statistical Year Book of Nepal, Kathmandu, Nepal

CBS (1991), Population Census 1991, Central Bureau of Statistics, Kathmandu,


Nepal

CBS (2001), Population Census 2001, Central Bureau of Statistics, Kathmandu,


Nepal

CBS (1996), Nepal Living Standard Survey Report 1996, Central Bureau of
Statistics, Vol. 1, Kathmandu, Nepal
318

CBS (1997), Nepal Living Standard Survey Report 1996, Central Bureau of
Statistics, Vol. 2, Kathmandu, Nepal

CBS (1999), Nepal Labour Force Survey, Central Bureau of Statistics, Kathmandu,
Nepal

Chatterjee, S. and Turnovsky, S.J. (2005), “Financing Public Investment through


Foreign Aid: Consequences for Economic Growth and Welfare”, Review of
International Economics, Vol. 13, pp. 20-44

Chauvet, L. and Guillaumont, P. (2003), Aid and Growth Revisited: Policy Economic
Vulnerability and Political Instability, Annual World Bank Conference on
Development Economics, World Bank and Oxford University Press

Chenery, H.B. and Burno, M. (1962), “Development Alternatives in an Open


Economy: The Case of Israel”, Economic Journal, Vol. 72, pp. 79-103

Chenery, H.B. and Eckstein, P. (1970), “Development Alternatives for Latin


America”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78, pp. 966-1006

Chenery, H.B. and Strout, A.M. (1966), “Foreign Assistance and Economic
Development”, American Economic Review, Vol. 56, pp. 679-733

Choi, E.K. (2004), “Aid Allocation and the Transfer Paradox in Small Open
Economies”, International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol.13, pp. 245-51

Cohen, D. (1994), Foreign Finance and Economic Growth: An Empirical Analysis, in


Laiderman, L. and Razin, A. (eds), Capital Mobility: The Impact on Consumption,
Investment and Growth, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

Colding, B. and Andersen, P. (2000), “Food Aid as an Aid Instrument: Past, Present
and Future”, in Trap, F. (ed) Foreign Aid and Development: Lessons Learnt and
Directions for the Future, Routledge, London and New York
319

Collier, P. and Dehn, J. (2001), “Aid, Shocks and Growth”, Working Paper 2688,
World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Collier, P. and Dollar, D. (2001), “Can the World Cut Poverty in Half? How Policy
Reform and Effective Aid Can Meet International Development Goals”, World
Development, Vol. 29, pp. 1787-1802

Collier, P. and Dollar, D. (2002), “Aid Allocation and Poverty Reduction”, European
Economic Review, Vol. 46, pp. 1475-1500

Collier, P. and Anke, H. (2004), “Aid, Policy and Growth in Post-Conflict Societies”,
European Economic Review, Vol. 48, pp. 1125-45

Collins, S.M. and Won, A.P. (1989), “External Debt and Macro Performance in South
Korea”, in Sachs, J.D. (ed), Developing Country Debt and the World Economy,
University of Chicago Press, Chicago and London

Culver, S.E. and Papell, D.H. (1997), “Are There Unit Roots in the Inflation Rate?
Evidence from Sequential Break and Panel Data Models”, Journal of Applied
Econometrics, Vol. 12, pp. 435-44

Dahal, K. (1987), Indo-Nepal Trade: Problems and Prospects, Ratna Pustak Bhandar,
Kathmandu, Nepal

Dalgaard, C.J. and Hansen, H. (2001), “On Aid, Growth and Good Policies”, Journal
of Development Studies, Vol. 37, pp. 17-35

Dalgaard, C.J., Hansen, H. and Tarp, F. (2002), “On the Empirics of Foreign Aid and
Growth”, University of Nottingham, Credit Research Paper 02/08

Dar, A. and Amirkhalkhali, S. (2003), “On the Impact of Trade Openness on Growth:
Further Evidence from OECD Countries”, Applied Economics, Vol. 35, pp. 1761-66
320

Dasgupta, P. (1993), An Inquiry into the Well-being and Destitution, Clarendon Press,
Oxford

Dawson, P.J. and Tiffin, R. (1999), “Is There a Long Run Relationship Between ODA
and GDP? The Case of India”, Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 6, pp. 275-77

Deraniyagala, S. (2003), “The Macroeconomics of Poverty Reduction in Nepal – An


Overview”, UNDP Asia and the Pacific Regional Workshop on Macroeconomics of
Poverty Reduction, 4-6 January, Kathmandu, Nepal

Devarajan, S. and Swaroop, V. (1998), “The Implication of Foreign Aid Fungibility


for Development Assistance”, Policy Research Working Paper 2022, World Bank,
Washington, D.C.

Dhakal, D., Upadhyaya, K. and Upadhyaya, M. (1996), “Foreign Aid, Economic


Growth and Causality”, Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Economiche e Commerciali,
Vol. 43, pp. 597-606

Dickey, D.A. and Fuller, W.A. (1979), “Distributions of the Estimators for
Autoregressive Time-Series with a Unit Root”, Journal of the American Statistical
Association, Vol. 74, pp. 427-31

Dickey, D.A. and Fuller, W.A. (1981), “Likelihood Ratio Statistics for Autoregressive
Time-Series with a Unit Root”, Econometrica, Vol. 49, pp. 1057-72

Dowling, J. M. and Hiemenz, U. (1983), “Aid, Savings and Growth in the Asian
Region”, The Developing Economics, Vol. 21, pp. 3-13

Drazen, A. (2002), “Conditionality and Ownership in IMF Lending: A Political


Economy Approach”, IMF Staff Papers 49, International Monetary Fund,
Washington, D.C.
321

Dowrick, S. and Golley, J. (2004), “Trade Openness and Growth: Who Benefits?”,
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 20, pp. 38-56

Durbarry, R. (2004), “Foreign Aid: Is it All Consumed?”, Journal of International


Development, Vol. 16, pp. 189-99

Durbarry, R., Gemmell, N., and Greenaway, D. (1998), “New Evidence on the Impact
of Foreign Aid on Economic Growth”, Credit Research Paper 98/8, University of
Nottingham

Durbin, J. and Watson, G.S. (1950), “Testing for Serial Correlation in Least Squares
Regression I, Biometrica, Vol. 37, pp. 409-28

Durbin, J. and Watson, G.S. (1951), “Testing for Serial Correlation in Least Squares
Regression II, Biometrica, Vol. 38, pp. 159-78

Easterly, W. (1993), “How Much Do Distortions Affect Growth?”, Journal of


Monetary Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 187-212

Easterly, W. (2003), “Can Foreign Aid Buy Growth?”, Journal of Economic


Perspectives, Vol. 17, pp. 23-48

Easterly, W., Levine, R. and Roodman, D. (2003), “A Comment on Burnside and


Dollar’s Aid, Policies and Growth (2000)”, Working Paper 26, Centre For Global
Development

Edwards, S., and Tabellini, G. (1991), “Political Instability, Political Weakness, and
Inflation: An Empirical Analysis”, NBER Working Paper 3721, National Bureau for
Economic Research

Edwards, S. (1998), “Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really


Know?”, Economic Journal, Vol. 108, pp. 383-98
322

Embassy of China in Nepal (2003), “Sino-Nepal Development Cooperation”,


www.chinaembassy.org.np

Embassy of India in Nepal (2003), “Indian Development Assistance to Nepal”,


http://www.south-asia.com/embassy-india/indnepal.htm

Embassy of Japan in Nepal (2003), “General Introduction of Japan’s ODA to Nepal”,

www.np.emb-japan.go.jp/oda/general.html

Engle, R.F. and Granger, C.W. (1987), “Cointegration and Error Correction:
Representation, Estimation, and Testing”, Econometrica, Vol. 55, pp. 251-76

Engle, R.F. and Yoo, B.S. (1987), “Foresting and Testing in Cointegrated System”,
Econometrica, Vol. 35, pp. 143-59

Eshag, E. (1971), “Comment”, Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of


Economics and Statistics, Vol. 33, pp. 149-56

Eviews (2000), Eviews 4 User Guide, Quantitative Micro Software, USA

Feder, G. (1980), “Economic Growth, Foreign Loans and Debt Servicing Capacity of
Developing Countries”, The Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 16, pp. 352-68

Feldstein, M. and Horioka, C. (1980), “Domestic Savings and International Capital


Flows, Economic Journal, Vol. 90, pp. 314-29

Feyzioglu, T., Swaroop, V., and Zhu, M. (1996), “Foreign Aid’s Impact on Public
Spending”, Policy Research Working Paper 1610, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Feyzioglu, T., Swaroop, V. and Zhu, M. (1998), “A Panel Data Analysis of the
Fungibility of Foreign Aid”, The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 12, pp. 29-58

Fischer, S. (1991), “Macroeconomics, Development and Growth”, NBER


Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 32, pp. 329- 64
323

Fischer, S. (1993), “The Role of Macroeconomics Factors in Growth”, The Journal of


Monetary Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 485-512

Franco-Rodriguez, S., Morrissey, O. and McGillivray, M. (1998), “Aid and the Public
Sector in Pakistan: Evidence with Endogenous Aid”, World Development, Vol. 26,
pp. 1241-50

Franco-Rodriguez, S. (2000), “Recent Development in Fiscal Response with an


Application to Costa Rica”, Journal of International Development, Vol. 12, pp. 429-
41

Friedman, M. (1958), “Foreign Economic Aid: Means and Objectives”, Yale Review,
Vol. 47, pp. 24-38

Gang, I.N. and Khan, H.A. (1991), “Foreign Aid, Taxes and Public Investment”,
Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 34, pp. 355-69

Gemmell, N. and McGillivray, M. (1998), “Aid and Tax Instability and the
Government Budget Constraints in Developing Countries” Credit Working Paper
98/1, University of Nottingham

Giles, J.A. (1994), “Another Look at the Evidence on Foreign Aid Led Economic
Growth”, Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 1, pp. 194-99

Godfrey, L.G. (1978a), “Testing Against General Autoregressive and Moving


Average Error Models When the Regressors Include Lagged Dependent Variables”,
Econometrica, Vol. 46, pp.1293-1301

Godfrey, L.G. (1978b), “Testing for Higher Order Serial Correlation in Regression
Equations When the Regressors Include Lagged Dependent Variables”,
Econometrica, Vol. 46, pp.1303-10
324

Gomanee, K., Morrissey, O., Mosley, P. and Verschoor, A. (2005), “Aid, Government
Expenditure and Aggregate Welfare”, World Development, Vol. 33, pp. 355-70

Gounder, R. (2001), “Aid–Growth Nexus: Empirical Evidence from Fiji”, Applied


Economics, Vol. 33, pp. 1009-19

Gounder, R. (2003), “Causality Analysis of Development Assistance and Economic


Growth in Solomon Island”, Pacific Economic Bulletin, Vol. 18, pp. 31-40

Gounder, R. (2005), “Neglected Dimensions of Development: Inequality, Conflict


and Aid”, International Journal of Social Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 60-72

Granger, C.W. and Newbold, P. (1974), “Spurious Regression in Econometrics”,


Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 2, pp. 111-120

Granger, C.W. (1988), “Some Recent Development in the Concept of Causality”,


Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 39, pp. 199-211

Granger, C.W.J., Huang, W.N., Yang, C.W., (2000), “Bivariate Causality Between
Stock Prices and Exchange Rates: Evidence from the Recent Asian Flue”, The
Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 40, pp. 337-54

Griffin, K. (1970), Underdevelopment in Spanish America, George Allen and Unwin,


London

Griffin, K. (1970), “Foreign Capital, Domestic Savings and Economic Development”


Bulletin of Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 32, pp. 99-
112

Griffin, K. and Enos, J.L. (1970), “Foreign Assistance: Objectives and


Consequences”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 18, pp. 313-27
325

Guillaumont, P. and Chauvet, L. (2001), “Aid and Performance: A Reassessment”,


Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 37, pp. 66-93

Gupta, S., Clements, B., Pivovarsky, A., and Tiongson, E.R. (2003), “Foreign Aid and
Revenue Response: Does the Composition of Aid Matter?”, IMF Working Paper 176,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C

Gupta, S., Davoodi, H., Alonso-Terme, R. (1998), “Does Corruption Affect Income
Inequality and Poverty?”, IMF Working Paper 176, International Monetary Fund,
Washington, D.C.

Gupta, K.L. (1975), “Foreign Capital Inflows, Dependency Burden, and Saving Rates
in Developing Countries: A Simultaneous Equation Model”, KYKLOS, Vol. 28, pp.
358-74

Gupta, K.L. and Islam, M.A. (1983), Foreign Capital, Savings and Growth – An
International Cross-Section Study, Reidel Publishing Company, Dordrecht

Haavelmo, T. (1963), “Comment on Wassily Leontief: The Rate of Long-run Growth


and Capital Transfer from Developed to Underdeveloped Areas”, The Econometric
Approach to Development Planning, North-Holland, Amsterdam

Hadjimichael, M.T., Dhaneswar, G., Martin, M., Roger, N. and Ucer, M.E. (1995),
“Sub-Saharan Africa: Growth Savings and Investment, 1986-1993”, Occasional
Paper 118, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Hafer, R.W. and Sheehan, R.G. (1991), “Policy Inference Using VAR Models”,
Economic Inquiry, Vol. 39, pp. 44-52

Hansen, H. and Tarp, F. (1999), “The Effectiveness of Foreign Aid”, Development


Economics Research Group, University of Copenhagen
326

Hansen, H. and Tarp, F. (2000), “Aid Effectiveness Disputed”, In Tarp, F. (ed)


Foreign Aid and Development: Lessons Learnt and Directions for the Future,
Routledge, London and New York

Hansen, H. and Tarp, F. (2001), “Aid and Growth Regressions”, Journal of


Development Economics, Vol. 64, pp. 547-70

Harrison, A. (1996), “Openness and Growth: A Time-Series, Cross-Country Analysis


for Developing Countries”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 48, pp. 419-47

Hasan, M.S. (2002), “Concessional Foreign Capital Inflows and Domestic Savings
Across Countries: Dependency Hypothesis Re-Visited”, Journal of Economic Studies,
Vol. 29, pp. 388-422

Heller, P.S. (1975), “A Model of Public Fiscal Behaviour in Developing Countries:


Aid, Investment and Taxation” American Economic Review, Vol. 65, pp. 429-45

Hirschman, A.O. (1984), “A Disssenter’s Confession: The Strategy of Economic


Development Revisited”, in Meier, G. and Seers, D. (eds), Pioneers in Development,
Oxford University Press, Oxford

Hjertholm, P. and White, H. (2000), “Foreign Aid in Historical Perspective:


Background and Trends”, in Tarp, F. (ed), Foreign Aid and Development: Lessons
Learnt and Directions For the Future, Routledge, London

HMG/N, Economic Survey (various issues), His Majesty’s Government of Nepal,


Ministry of Finance, Kathmandu, Nepal

HMG/N (2002), Foreign Aid Policy, His Majesty’s Government of Nepal, Ministry of
Finance, Kathmandu

Howitt, P. (2000), “Endogenous Growth and Cross-Country Income Differences”,


American Economic Review, Vol. 90, pp. 111-30
327

Hudson, J. (2004), “Introduction: Aid and Development”, Economic Journal, Vol.


114, pp. 185-90

IMF, International Financial Statistics (various issues), Online Database,


www.imf.org or http://ifs.apdi.net/imf/ifsbrowser.aspx

IMF (2001), “Nepal: Recent Economic Developments”, IMF Country Report 173,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

IMF (2002), “Nepal: Recent Economic Developments”, IMF Country Report 143,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

IMF (2003), “Nepal: Joint Staff Assessment of the Poverty Reduction Strategy
Paper”, IMF Country Report 361, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

IMF (2003a), “Public Information Notice”, PIN No. 03/110, International Monetary
Fund, Washington, D.C.

IMF (2003b), “Latest IMF Financial Arrangement to Nepal”, International Monetary


Fund, www.imf.org/external/country/NPL/index.htm

IMF (2004), “Nepal: First Review of Three-Year Arrangement Under the PRGF and
Request for Waiver of Performance Criteria”, IMF Country Report 329, International
Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Islam, A. (1992), “Foreign Aid and Economic Growth: An Econometric Study of


Bangladesh”, Applied Economics, Vol. 24, pp. 541-44

Islam, M.N., (2003), “Political Regimes and the Effects of Foreign Aid on Economic
Growth”, The Journal of Development Areas, Vol. 37, pp. 35-53
328

Ivanova, A., Mayer, W., Mourmouras, A. and Anayiotos, G. (2003), “What


Determines the Implementation of IMF-Supported Programs?”, Working Paper 8,
International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Johansen, S. (1988), “Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors”, Journal of


Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 12, pp. 231-54

Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990), “Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference


on Cointegration with Application to the Demand for Money”, Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, Vol. 52, pp. 169-210.

Johnson, H.G. (1958), International Trade and Economic Growth, George Allen and
Unwin, London

Kalecki, M. (1976), Essay on Development Economics, Harvest, Brighten, Sussex

Kanbur, R. (1999), “Prospective and Retrospective Conditionality: Practicalities and


Fundamentals”, in Collier, P. and Pattillo, C. (eds), Investment and Risk in Africa,
Macmillan, Basingstoke

Kanbur, R. and Sadler, T. (1999), The Future of Development Assistance: Common


Pools and International Public Goods, Overseas Development Council, Washington,
D.C.

Kaphley, K.P. (2000), “Nepal’s Drive Towards Export Promotion and


Diversification”, in Ministry of Finance (ed), Perspective for Nepalese Economy,
Ministry of Finance, Kathmandu, Nepal

Karmacharya, B.K. (2000), “Nepal’s Integration with the Global Economy and its
Impact on Sustainable Human Development”, Background Paper for
UNCTAD/UNDP Global Program on Globalization, Liberalization and Sustainable
Human Development, New York
329

Kathmandu Post (various issues), www.kantipuronline.com

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Mastruzzi, M. (2004), “Governance Indicators for
1996-2002”, Policy Research Working Paper 3106, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Kennedy, P. (1992), A Guide to Econometrics, The MIT Press, Cambridge

Kennedy, C. and Thirlwall, A.P. (1971), “Comment”, Bulletin of the Oxford


University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 33, pp. 135-38

Khadka, N. (1996), “A Study of the Impact of Aid on Nepal’s Economy”, Economia


Internazionale, Vol. 49, pp. 585-609

Khadka, N. (1997), Foreign Aid and Foreign Policy: Major Powers and Nepal,
Vikash Publishing House, New Delhi

Khan, S.R. (1999), Do World Bank and IMF Policies Work?, Palgrave, New York.
Khan, H.A. and Hoshino, E. (1992), “Impact of Foreign Aid on the Fiscal Behaviour
of LDC Governments”, World Development, Vol. 20, pp. 1481-88

Khatiwada, Y.R. (2003), “Macroeconomic Policy and Poverty in Nepal: Key Issues”,
UNDP Asia and the Pacific Regional Workshop on Macroeconomics of Poverty
Reduction, 4-6 January 2003, Kathmandu, Nepal.

Khatiwada, Y.R., Sharma, S.K., and Kharel, R.S. (2002), “Nepal: Sources of
Economic Growth”, Institute for Integrated Development Studies, Kathmandu, Nepal

Khilji, N.M. and Zampelli, E.M. (1994), “The Fungibility of US Military and Non-
Military Assistance and the Impacts on Expenditures of Major Aid Recipients”,
Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 43, pp. 345-62

Killick, T. (1991), “The Developmental Effectiveness of Aid to Africa”, Working


Paper Series 646, World Bank, Washington, D.C.
330

Killick, T. (1997), “Principal Agents and the Failings of Conditionality”, Journal of


International Development”, Vol. 9, pp. 483-95

Knack, S. (2000), “Does Foreign Aid Promote Democracy”, Development Economics


Research Group, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Knack, S. (2001), “Aid Dependence and the Quality of Governance: Cross-Country


Empirical Tests”, Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 68, pp. 310-29

Koenker, R. (1981), “A Note on Studentizing a Test for Heteroskedasticity”, Journal


of Econometrics, Vol. 17, pp. 107-12

Koop, G. (1996), “Parameter Uncertainty and Impulse Response Analysis”, Journal


of Econometrics, Vol. 72, pp. 135-49

Koop, G., Pesaran, M.H., Potter, S.M. (1996), “Impulse Response Analysis in
Nonlinear Multivariate Models”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 74, pp. 119-47

Kormendi, R.C. and Meguire, P.G. (1985), “Macroeconomic Determinants of


Growth, Cross-Country Evidence”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 16, pp. 141-
63

Krueger, A.O. (1978), Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development:


Liberalisation Attempts and Consequences, Ballinger, Cambridge

Leachman, L.L. (1991), “Saving, Investment and Capital Mobility Among OECD
Countries”, Open Economics Review, Vol. 2, pp. 137-63

Leandro, J., Schafer, H., and Frontini, G. (1999), “Towards a More Effective
Conditionality: An Operational Framework”, World Development, Vol. 27, pp. 285-
99
331

Lensink, R. and Morrissey, O. (2000), “Aid Instability as a Measure of Uncertainty


and the Positive Impact of Aid on Growth”, Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 36,
pp. 31-49

Lensink, R. and White, H. (2001), “Are There Negative Returns to Aid?”, Journal of
Development Studies, Vol. 37, pp. 42-64

Levy, V. (1988), “Aid and Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa: The Recent Experience”,
European Economic Review, Vol. 32, pp. 1777-95

Library of Congress (1991), “Nepal – A Country Study”, Library of Congress


Country Study, www.info-nepal.com

Lin, S. and Sosin, K. (2001), “Foreign Debt and Economic Growth”, Economics of
Transition, Vol. 9, pp. 635-55.

Linear, M. (1985), Zapping the Third World: the Diaster of Development Aid, Pluto
Press, London

Lipton, M. (1983), “Poverty, Undernutrition and Hunger”, Staff Working Paper 597,
World Bank, Washington, D.C.

MacDonald, R., and Kearney, C. (1987), “On the Specification of the Granger
Causality Tests Using the Cointegration Methodology, Economics Letters, Vol. 25,
pp. 149-53

MacKinnon, J.M. (1991), “Critical Values for Cointegration Test”, in Engle, R.F. and
Granger, C.W.J. (eds), Long Run Economic Relationships: Readings in Cointegration,
Oxford University Press, Oxford

Manne, A. (1963), Key Sectors of the Mexican Economy, 1960-70, in Manne, A. and
Markowitz, H. (eds), Studies in Process Analysis, John Wiley & Sons, New York
332

Mauro, P. (1995) “Corruption and Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.


110, pp. 681-712

Mavrotas, G. (2002), “Aid and Growth in India: Some Evidence from Disaggregated
Aid Data”, South Asia Economic Journal, Vol. 3, pp. 19-49

McGillivray, M. (1994), “Impact of Foreign Aid on the Fiscal Behaviour of LDC


Governments: A Comment on Khan and Hoshino (1992)”, World Development, Vol.
22, pp. 2015-17

McGillivray, M. (2000), “Aid and Public Sector Behaviour in Developing Countries”,


Review of Development Economics, Vol. 4, pp. 156-63

McGillivray, M. (2002), “Aid, Economic Reform and the Public Sector Fiscal
Behaviour in Developing Countries”, Credit Research Paper 02/11, University of
Nottingham

McGillivray, M. and Morrissey, O. (2000), “Aid Fungibility in Assessing Aid: Red


Herring or True Concern?”, Journal of International Development, Vol. 12, pp. 413-
28

McGillivray, M. and Morrissey, O. (2001), “Aid Illusion and Public Sector Fiscal
Behaviour”, The Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 37, pp. 118-36

McGillivray, M. and Morrissey, O. (2001), “A Review of Evidence on the Fiscal


Effects of Aid”, Credit Research Paper 01/13, University of Nottingham

McGillivray, M. and Ouattara, B. (2003), “Aid, Debt Burden and Government Fiscal
Behaviour in Cote d’ Ivoire”, Credit Research Paper 03/05, University of Nottingham

McGuire, M.C. (1978), “A Method for Estimating the Effect of a Subsidy on the
Receiver’s Resource Constraint: With an Application to the US Local Governments
1964-1971,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 10, pp. 25-44
333

McKinnon, R.I. (1964), “Foreign Exchange Constraints in Economic Development


and Efficient Aid Allocation”, The Economic Journal, Vol. 74, pp. 388-409

Meltzer Commission (2000), Report, www.house.gov/jec/imf/meltzer.pdf

Mertz, R.A. and Mertz, P.M. (1983), Arab Aid to Sub-Saharan Africa, Westview,
Boulder, Co

Mihaly, E.B. (1965), Foreign Aid and Politics in Nepal: A Case Study, Oxford
University Press, London

Mihaly, E.B. (2002), Foreign Aid and Politics in Nepal: A Case Study, Himal Books,
Kathmandu, Nepal

Modeste, N.C. and Butts, H. (2003), “The Impact of Guyana’s Foreign Debt Burden
on Its Rate of Economic Growth”, International Review of Economics and Business,
Vol. 50, pp. 581-91

Mosley, P. (1980), “Aid, Savings and Growth Revisited”, Bulletin of the Oxford
University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 42, pp. 79-85

Mosley, P. (1985), “The Political Economy of Foreign Aid: A Model of the Market
for a Public Good”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 9, pp. 373-93

Mosley, P. (1987), Overseas Aid: Its Defence and Reform, Wheatsheaf Books LTD,
Brighton

Mosley, P., Hudson, J., and Horrell, S. (1987), “Aid, the Public Sector and the Market
in Less Developed Countries”, Economic Journal, Vol. 97, pp. 616-41

Mosley, P., Harrigan, J., and Toye, J. (eds) (1991), Aid and Power: The World Bank
and Policy Based Lending, London: Routledge
334

Mosley, P., Hudson, J., and Horrell, S. (1992), “Aid Effectiveness and Policy”, in
Bird, G. (ed), International Aspect of Economic Development, Surrey University
Press, Guildford

Mosley, P., Hudson, J., and Verschoor, A. (2004), “Aid, Poverty Reduction and the
New Conditionality”, Economic Journal, Vol. 114, pp. 217-43

Murshed, S.M. and Gates, S. (2005), “Spatial-Horizontal Inequality and the Maoist
Insurgency in Nepal”, Review of Development Economics, Vol. 9, pp. 121-34

Murshed, S.M. and Sen, S. (1995), “Aid Conditionality and Military Expenditure
Reduction in Developing Countries: Models of Asymmetric Information”, Economic
Journal, Vol. 105, pp. 498-509

Murthy, V.N.R., Ukpolo, V., and Mbaku, J.M. (1994), “Foreign Aid and Economic
Growth in Cameroon: Evidence from Cointegration Tests”, Applied Economics
Letters, Vol. 1, pp. 161-63

Mussa, M. and Savastano, M. (1999), “The IMF Approach to Economic


Stabilisation”, Working Paper 104, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

NESAC (1998), Nepal Human Development Report 1998, Nepal South Asia Centre,
Kathmandu, Nepal

Newey, W.K. and West, K.D. (1987), “A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite,


Heteroscedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix”,
Econometrica, Vol. 55, pp. 703-08

Newlyn, W.T. (1973), “The Effects of Aid and Other Resource Transfers on Savings
and Growth in Less Developed Countries: Comment”, Economic Journal, Vol. 83, pp.
867-69
335

NPC (1998), The Ninth Plan (1997-2002), Nepal Planning Commission, Kathmandu,
Nepal

NPC (2001), The Mid-term Evaluation of the Ninth Plan (1997-2002), Nepal Planning
Commission, Kathmandu, Nepal

NPC (2003), Medium Term Expenditure Framework: Fiscal Year 2002/03-2004/05,


Nepal Planning Commission, Kathmandu, Nepal

NPC (2004), Medium Term Expenditure Framework: Fiscal Year 2004/05-2006/07,


Nepal Planning Commission, Kathmandu, Nepal

NRB (2003), World Bank Group and Nepal, Research Department, Nepal Rastra
Bank, Kathmandu, Nepal

OECD, (various issues), International Development Statistics, online database,


www.oecd.org

OECD (2004), Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development,

http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/23/11/1882605.gif

Over Jr, A.M. (1975), “An Example of the Simultaneous Equations Problem: a Note
on Foreign Assistance: Objectives and Consequences”, Economic Development and
Cultural Change, Vol. 24, pp. 751-56

Oxfam (1995), The Oxfam Poverty Report, Oxfam, Oxford

Pack, H. and Pack, J.R. (1990), “Is Foreign Aid Fungible? The Case of Indonesia”,
Economic Journal, Vol. 100, pp. 188-94

Pack, H. and Pack, J.R. (1993), “Foreign Aid and the Question of Fungibility”,
Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 75, pp. 258-65
336

Panday, D.R. (2001), Corruption, Governance and International Cooperation: Essays


and Impression on Nepal and South Asia, Transparency International Nepal,
Kathmandu, Nepal.

Papanek, G.F. (1972), “The Effect of Aid and Other Resource Transfers on Savings
and Growth in Less Developed Countries”, Economic Journal, Vol. 82, pp. 934-50

Papanek, G.F. (1973), “Aid, Foreign Private Investment, Savings and Growth in Less
Developed Countries”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81, pp. 120-30

Paudyal, M.P. (2003), “Macroeconomic Implications of Foreign Aid in Nepal”, Nepal


Planning Commission – A Journal of Development, Vol. 23, pp. 20-41

Pelagidis, T. and Mastroyiannis, T., (2003), “The Saving–Investment Correlation in


Greece: Implication for Capital Mobility”, Journal of Policy Modelling, Vol. 25, pp.
609-16

Pesaran, M.H. and Pesaran, B. (2003), Working with Microfit 4.0: Interactive
Econometric Analysis, Oxford University Press, Oxford

Pesaran, M.H. and Shin, Y. (1996), “Cointegration and Speed of Convergence to


Equilibrium”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 71, pp. 117-43

Phillips, P.B. and Perron, P. (1988), “Time-Series Regression with a Unit Root”,
Biometrika, Vol. 75, pp. 335-46

Poudyal, S.R. (1988), Foreign Trade, Aid and Development in Nepal, Commonwealth
Publishers, New Delhi

Rahman, A. (1968), “Foreign Capital and Domestic Savings: A Test of Haavelmo’s


Hypothesis with Cross-Country Data”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 50,
pp. 137-38
337

Rajan, R.G. and Subramanian, A. (2005), “What Undermines Aid’s Impact on


Growth?” IMF Working Paper 126, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Ram, R. (2003), “Roles of Bilateral and Multilateral Aid in Economic Growth of


Developing Countries”, KYKLOS, Vol. 56, pp. 95-110

Ramirez, M. (2000), “Foreign Direct Investment in Mexico: A Cointegration


Analysis”, The Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 37, pp. 138-62

Ramsey, J.B. (1969), “Test for Specification Errors in Classical Linear Least Squares
Regression Analysis”, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B, pp. 350-71

Rana, P.B. (1987), “Foreign Capital, Exports, Savings and Growth in the Asian
Region”, Savings and Development, Vol. 1, pp. 5-26

Ratanapakorn, O. and Sharma, S.C. (2002), “Interrelationships Among Regional


Stock Indices”, Review of Financial Economics, Vol. 11, pp. 91-108

Rodrik, D. (1996), “Understanding Economic Policy Reform”, Journal of Economic


Literature, Vol. 34, pp. 9-41

Rosenstein-Rodan, P.N. (1943), “Problem of Industrialisation of Eastern and South


Eastern Europe”, Economic Journal, Vol. 53, pp. 202-11

Rosenstein-Rodan, P.N. (1961), “International Aid for Underdeveloped Countries”,


Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 43, pp. 107-38

Rostow, W.W. (1956), “The Take-off into Self-Sustained Growth”, Economic


Journal, Vol. 66, pp. 25-48

Sachs, J. D. (1997), “IMF is a Power Unto Itself”, www.stern.nyu.edu


338

Sachs, J.D. (2001), “Macroeconomics and Health: Investing in Health for Economic
Development”, Report of the Commission on Macroeconomics and Health, WHO

Sachs, J.D. (1988), “International Policy Coordination: The Case of the Developing
Country Debt Crisis”, in Feldstein, M. (ed), International Economic Cooperation,
University of Chicago Press, Chicago and London

Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A. (1995), “Economic Reform and the Process of Global
Integration”, Brooking Paper on Economic Activity, Vol. 1, pp. 1-118

Saini, K.G. (1982), “The Monetarist Explanation of Inflation: The Experience of Six
Asian Countries”, World Development, Vol. 10, pp. 871-84

Sander, H. and Kleimeier, S. (2003), “Contagion and Causality: An Empirical


Investigation of Four Asian Crisis Episodes”, Journal of International Financial
markets and Money, Vol. 13, pp. 171-86

Sevensson, J. (1997), “When Is Foreign Aid Policy Credible? Aid Dependence and
Conditionality”, Policy Research Working Paper Series 1740, World Bank,
Washington, D.C.

Sevensson, J. (2000), “Foreign Aid and Rent Seeking”, Journal of International


Economics, Vol. 51, pp. 437-61

Sharma, K. (1999), Trade Liberalisation and Manufacturing Performance in


Developing Countries: New Evidence from Nepal, Nova Science Publisher Inc., New
York

Sharma, P.S. (2000), Economic Liberalisation in Nepal, in Ministry of Commerce


(ed), Perspective for Nepalese Economy, Kathmandu, Nepal

Sharma, S. (2003), “Poverty in Nepal”, UNDP Asia and the Pacific Regional
Workshop on Macroeconomics of Poverty Reduction, 4-6 January, Kathmandu, Nepal
339

Shrestha, G.K. (2004), “Financial Sector Reforms in Nepal”, Nepal Rastra Bank-
Economic Review, No.16, pp. 75-90

Sengupta, J.K. and Espana, J.R. (1994), “Exports and Economic Growth in Asian
NICSs: An Econometric Analysis for Korea”, Applied Economics, Vol. 26, pp. 41-51

Singer, H.W. (1965), “External Aid: For Plans or Projects?”, Economic Journal, Vol.
75, pp. 539-45

Singh, N.K. (1996), Foreign Aid, Economic Growth and Politics in Nepal, Anmol
Publications, New Delhi

Snyder, D.W. (1990), “Foreign Aid and Domestic Savings: A Spurious Correlation?”,
Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 39, pp. 175-81

Sonali, D. (2003), “The Macroeconomics of Poverty Reduction in Nepal: An


Overview”, UNDP Asia and the Pacific Regional Workshop on Macroeconomics of
Poverty Reduction, 4-6 January, Kathmandu

Stewart, F. (1971), “Comment”, Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of


Economics and Statistics, Vol. 33, pp. 138-49

Stiglitz, J. (2002), Globalisation and Its Discontents, Penguin Group, Australia

Stiller, L.F. and Yadav, R.P. (1979), Planning for People, Human Resources
Development Research Centre, Kathmandu, Nepal

Stoneman, C. (1975), “Foreign Capital and Economic Growth”, World Development,


Vol. 3, pp. 11-26

Swaroop, V., Jha, S. and Rajkumar, A.S. (2000), “Fiscal Effects of Foreign Aid in A
Federal System of Governance: The Case of India”, Journal of Public Economics,
Vol. 77, pp. 307-30
340

Tanzi, V. (1998), “Corruption around the World: Causes, Consequences, Scope and
Cures, IMF Staff Paper, Vol. 45, pp. 559-94

Tavares, J. (2003), “Does Foreign Aid Corrupt?” Economics Letters, Vol. 79, pp. 99-
106

Tendler, J. (1975), Inside Foreign Aid, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore

Thirlwall, A.P. (1983), “Foreign Trade Elasticities in Centre-Periphery Models of


Growth and Development”, Banca Nazionale Del Lavoro, Quarterly Review,
September

Thirlwall, A.P. (1999), Growth and Development: With Special Reference to


Developing Countries, MacMillan Press Limited, London

Thirlwall, A.P. (2003), Trade, the Balance of Payments and Exchange Rate Policy in
Developing Countries, Edward Elgar, UK and USA

Thorbecke, E. (2000), “The Evolution of the Development Doctrine and the Role of
Foreign Aid, 1950-2000” in Tarp, F. (ed), Foreign Aid and Development; Lesson
Learnt and Directions for the Future, Routledge, London and New York

Trade Promotion Centre (1999), Nepal’s Trade and Transit Agreements, Trade
Promotion Centre, Kathmandu, Nepal

Transparency International (2001), “Global Corruption Report”, South Asia Regional


Report, www.transpareny.org

Transparency International (2004), “Transparency International Corruption


Perception Index 2004”, www.transpareny.org/cpi/2004/cpi2004.en.html

UNCTAD (2000), “The Least Developed Countries 2000 Report”, United Nations,
New York and Geneva
341

UNDP (2001), Nepal Human Development Report 2001, United Nations


Development Program, www.undp.org/statistics/data/cty/cty_f_NPL.html

UNDP (2004), Human Development Report 2004, United Nations Development


Program, www.undp.org.np/publications/hdr2004

Van den Boogaerde, P. (1991), “Financial Assistance from Arab Countries and Arab
Regional Institutions”, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Voivodas, C. S. (1973), “Exports, Foreign Capital Inflow and Economic Growth”,


Journal of International Economics, Vol. 3, pp. 337-49

Walle, N.V.D. and Timothy, A.J. (1996), Improving Aid to Africa Aid, Overseas
Development Council, Washington, D.C.

Weisskopf, T. E. (1972), “The Impact of Foreign Capital Inflow on Domestic Savings


In Underdeveloped Countries”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 2, pp. 25-38

White, H. (1992), “What Do We Know About Aid’s Macroeconomic Impact? An


Overview of the Aid Effectiveness Debate”, Journal of International Development,
Vol. 4, pp. 121-37

White, H. and Woestman, L. (1994), “Aid Quality: Measuring Trends in Donor


Performance”, Development and Change, Vol. 25, pp. 527-54

White, H. (1994), “Foreign Aid, Taxes and Public Investment: Further Comment”,
Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 45, pp. 155-63

White, H. (2004), “Trends in the Volume and Allocation of Official Flows from
Donor Countries”, International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 13, pp. 233-
44
342

White, H. and Dijkstra, G. (2003), Program Aid and Development: Beyond


Conditionality, Routledge, London and New York

Wolfensohn, J. (2000), “Foreword” to Thomas et al, The quality of growth, Oxford


University Press, New York

World Bank (1987), World Development Report 1987, Oxford University Press, New
York

World Bank (1997), World Development Report 1997, Oxford University Press, New
York

World Bank, World Development Indicators, (various issues), Online Database,


www.worldbank.org

World Bank (1990), “Adjustment Lending Policies for Sustainable Growth”, Policy
and Research Series 14, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

World Bank (1991), Nepal: Poverty and Income, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

World Bank (2000), Nepal Public Expenditure Review, World Bank, Washington,
D.C.

World Bank (2001), Aid and Reform in Africa: Lessons from Ten Case Studies, World
Bank, Washington, D.C.

World Bank (2002a), The Role and Effectiveness of Development Assistance: Lessons
from World Bank Experience, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

World Bank (2002b), “Nepal Development Forum Economic Update”, World Bank,
www.worldbank.org.np
343

World Bank (2002c), “Governance Indicators: 1996-2002”, World Bank,


http://www.worldbank.org/wbi/governance/govdata2002/index.html

World Bank (2003), “Nepal at a Glance”, www.worldbank.org.np

World Bank (2003a), “Nepal Economic Update”, World Bank,


www.worldbank.org.np

World Bank (2003b), International Development Association Program Document,


Report No. 26556-NEP, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

World Bank (2004), “Latest Active Projects in Nepal”, World Bank,


www.worldbank.org.np

World Bank Report (1998), Assessing Aid: What Works, What Doesn’t and Why,
Oxford University Press, New York

Yano, M. and Nugent J.B. (1999), “Aid, Non-traded Goods, and the Transfer Paradox
in Small Countries”, The American Economic Review, Vol. 89, pp. 431-49

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen