Sie sind auf Seite 1von 6

f Slrarit~g power to build states

l
I

television organizations. Each group also had its own political parties, labor unions, and schools.
' Such a fragmented society would appear to foster antagonism and extremism. Surprisingly,
Lijphart found that the group leaders solved the conflicts peacefully and thereby promoted a
stable democracy for a divided society. This challenged the conventional wisdom at the time, as
20 ethnic division was not seen as compatible with stable democracy (Lijphart, 1968b). In his later
research, Lijphan found that several other countries also had the experience of consociationalism:
Austria 1945-1966, Belgium since 1970, Canada 1840-67, Colombia 1958-74, Cyprus 1960-63,
SHARING POWER TO Czechoslovakia 1989-93, India, Israel, and Lebanon 1943-1975 and since 1989, Malaysia on
and off since 1955, South Africa 1994--1999, and Suriname and Switzerland since 1943 (Lijphart,
BUILD STATES 1977; 1985: 89-90; 1996: 259; 1998: 101-102). In this way, Lijphart dcmomtratcd that consoci-
ationalism was not unique to the Netherlands, but a more cmrunonly existing practice of
democratic governance in divided societies.
Anna K. Jarstad Lijphart describes consociational democracy as 'govenunent by elite cartel designed to turn
a democracy with a fragmented political culture into a stable democracy' (Lijphart, 1969: 216).
Here the moderate attitudes of the leaders and their cooperative behavior is key. In the
Netherlands a consensus on who should belong to the state already existed before con-
sociationalisrn was introduced. Lijphart further defines consociation:tlism by four institutions
designed to accommodate confucts in deeply divided societies: grand coalition, proportionality,
Sharing power between warring parries has become a standard arrangement to end civil wars autonomy, and veto. All important rival groups should be included in a gr•nd coalition, according
during the post-Cold War era . One reason is that peace agreements have become significantly to strict proportionality or by deliberate over-representation of minorities. Such allocation should
more conunon. After 19R9, peace agreements have been signed in close to half of all civil wars. also apply to the bureaucracy and the di<tribution of economic revenues. Autonomy for each
Before 1989, peace agreements were quite rare, and many con.A.icts ended in the victory of one group should be provided for by decentralization of all matters not of common concern. Mutual
parry. After a victory, the life and liberty of defeated groups were often endangered. Peace veto rights in central government are central to block regulations and refonns that could alter
agreements seek to prevent such oppression. The vast majority of peace agreements include fundamental conditions of physical and cultural survival of the group (Lijphart, 1993: 188-189) .
provisions for the sharing of power to balance the influence of actors in the country. During the Lijphart suggests that these institutions can develop out of a consensual culrure, but the institutions
period 1989 to 2004, 70 out of all83 agreements signed provided for power-sharing (Jarstad and as such can also contribute to such a culture (1999; for a critique seejarstad, 2001: 42-Q4).
Nilsson, 2008: 215) . Lijphart's work has inspired several research fields. One is the fie ld of constitutional
Power-sharing becomes a platform for building new, more inclusive state institutions. But engineering, a term coined by Giovanni Sartori, which aum to design constitutions with the
stacebuilding is an arduous task anywhere, and it is even more difficult in societies shattered by purpose of changing the political behavior of elites (Sartori, 1994, ix). The main debate in thi'
civil war. One re>-<on is that even after a peace deal is signed, former enemies have to learn how field has evolved around the choice between majoritarian and proportional electoral systems.
to live side by side and cooperate in building a conunon state willie the country often remains Three of the most prominent works on tltis matter are Comparative Comtitutional Engineering: An
divided along the conflict lines. Under such circumstances power-sharing can ease the way by Inquiry into Struct11res, Incentives ami 0111comes (Sartori, 1994), Seats and Votes: Tire Effects and
guaranteeing all parties a share in the new or refonned state institutions. Some of the most pressing Deten11inant if Electoral Systems (Taagepera and Shugart, 1989), and Electoral Laws and 71reir Politiml
issues for statebuilding after civil war involve creating new or reformed institutions for political Consequcrrces (Grofinan and Lijphart, 1977). These works primarily discuss various techniques
governance, territorial control , the security sector, and economic development. Such institutions from a democratic point of view. However, in a divided society, elections reflect demographic
are not developed from scratch. Rather peace agreements often include provisions fnr different relations. Political parties representing ntinorities have no chance of ever forming a majority.
types of power-sharing, most commonly political, territorial, military, and economic power- Shifting majorities in parliament - a healthy sign of democracy- are thercfnre unlikely in divided
sharing. These arrangements can [onn the basis of the new institutions and thereby shape the societies. Instead, minorities are in practice excluded from political influence. Under such
new state. How docs power-sharing influence statebuilding? Is it a constraint or does it facilitate circumstances, there is a risk tl>at minority groups see secession as their only option to survive as
statebuilding? a distinct group, whereas the majority believes that oppression is the only way to prevent such
separatist tendencies. Robert Dahl has captured the dilemma in divided societies as follows: 'the
price of polyarchy may be the break-up of the country. And the price of territorial unity may
Consociational democracy: the background to contemporary research be a hegemonic regime' (Dahl, 1971: 11). Comociationalism is put foruiard as a way to avoid
on power-sharing these two undesirable outcomes.
Arend Lijphan coined the concept 'consociational democracy' in 1968 to denote an institu- In addition to Lijphart's consociational model, Donald Horowitz, Tim D. Sisk, Benjamin
tionalized form of democratic con.A.ict management for divided societies, which he found in the Reilly, and Andrew Reynolds have developed integrative models for constitutional engineering
Netherlands. At that time the country was deeply divided along religious and class lines which in divided societies (Horowitz, 1985; Reilly, 2001; Reynolds, 2002; Sisk, 1996). Horowitz
separated the population into distinct, isolated, and self-contained groups. There was minimal suggests a system that makes 'moderation rewarding by making politicians reciprocally dependent
communication across these groups and each group had its own newspapers and radio and
2,&65
26216
Silariug power to build states

j<llstad
as a threat to some political actors. The opening up of political space and liberalization of media
al~o introduce new actors and new motives for violence. During election campaigns candidates
on the votes of members other than their own' (Horowitz, 1991: 196). He has suggested the
are more visible than usual, and voters may become targets of violence from actors who seek to
alternative vote (AV) or the single transferable vote (SVT) as methods for conflict management.
affect the electoral outcome. Hence, violence often peaks around election times and can even
However, there are few empirical cases of success of these systems. Wl1ile the integrative models
trigger a rerum to war. Under such circumstances, a period of political power-sharing- inclusion
seek to prevent the emergence of ethruc parties, Lijphart suggest that rccugn.ition of existing
. of vital parties in a broad coalition government- can ease the transition from war to democracy.
ethruc cleavages, and political representation of such groups, better provide for moderate politics.
Such power-sharing is identi cal to Lijphart's grand coalition. The main fi.mction of power-sharing
In New Zealand, a system has developed to allow voters to change ethnopolitical affiliation.
is here to reduce the uncertainty of actors who fear losing power when democracy is introduced.
ln 1993, a referendum was held to change the voting system from fust-past- the-post to mixed
Second, power-sharing bas also been described as a school in demo cracy (TocqueviUe, 2000) by
member proportional representation (MMP) . Each voter has two votes: a party vote and an
socializing new political actors into the game of democracy. This can be particularly useful when
electoral vote (depending o n where you live). Ahead of each election, every voter enrolls on
warring actors ate transfonned into political parties. Third, under th e best circumstances power-
either the indigenous Maori roll or the General roll. The Maori quota depends on the share of
sharing buys rime to build strong institutions which can sustain the dangers of el ections. In this
registered voters on the Maori roll. In addition, because it is in the interest of all parries to attract
way, it is believed that power-sharing can contribute to statebuilding.
Maori voters, all main political parti es include Maori among their top candidates. This means
However, the track record of political power-sharing is poor; there is no statistical evidence
that some Maori members of parliament hold a general seat as a result of the party votes, whereas
that it provides for durable peace. Despite the fact that half of the political power-sharing
others hold a Maori electoral seat Qarstad, 2001). agreements have failed and resulted in resumed conflict, such power-sharing is still very conunon.
Since 1989 political power-sharing agreements have been signed in 19 states: Mghanistan, Angola,
Power-sharing after civil war Bangladesh, Bosnia-Herzegovina, Burundi, Cambodia, Comoros, Democratic Republic of
Congo, Guinea Bissau, Ivory Coast, Liberia, Mali, Mexi co, Rwanda, Sierra Leone, Somalia,
Another research field that builds on Lijphart's work centers around the question of how to
Sudan, Tajikistan, and Uganda Uarstad, 2009).
promote democratization, statebuilding, and peacebuilding after civil war. In quantitative research
In Rwanda in 1994, genocide took place after a power-sharing agreement was signed. Th e
o n conflict management it has become common to talk about four types of power-sharing:
Hutu extremiSts in government feared that they would be excluded from power and misused
political, territorial, military, and economic. Political power-sharing is similar to Lijphart's grand
the new rights of infonnation for propaganda where T ursi and moderate Hutus were labeled as
coalition, while territorial power-sharing corresponds to Lijphart's autonomy criteria. Military
cockroaches that should be extenninated . Mter three mo nths, when Tursi rebels overpowered
and economic power-shari ng builds on Lijphart's proportionality principle for allocation for
the government forces, more than 500,000 people had been killed. This exampl e points to th e
positions in the state administration and distribution offunds. In conflict management research,
danger in excluding heavily am1ed groups from a power-sharing arrangement. Barbara Walter
the main function of power-sharing is to end violence. To lay down amJS, warring groups often
argues that third-parry security guarantees are vital for successful settlements of civil wars. She
demand a share of power. suggests that it was the lack of credible commitment of the UN that caused the settl ement to
Barbara Walter fi.mh er understands power-sharing as a mecharusm for solving the conunim1ent
break down: 'a false hope of international intervention is worse than no hope at aU' (Walter,
problem in a context of severe distrust and vulnerability (Walter, 1999). The concession involved
2002: 159). However, there are cases where agreement on political power-sharing has bee n
in peace agreements leaves the parties vulnerable to each other. The parties may fear that the
followed by elections and peace was kept the year after the election without third-party
other party will take advantage of them and exclude them from power. Under this condition,
guarantees. Such agreements include Burundi 2003 and Comoros 2003 Qarstad, 2009}. This
guaranteed shares of power can reduce distrust and vulnerability. Consequently, Walter also finds
means that third- party security guarantees are not always necessary for political power-sharing
that warring parties are much more likely to sign an agreement if it includes guaranteed positions
to enable peace. One oftl1e cases that are considered to be most successful is South Africa, where
in d1e new government (Walter, 2002: 80). Caroline Hartzell and Matthew Hoddie (2003) found
political power-sharing was agreed upon and carried out without any third-party guarantee. This
that settlements thar include several forms of sharing or dividing political, territorial, military,
example points to the importance of local ownership of the peace prncess. Despite the many
and economic power are more likely to see peace prevail. However, when including the
predictions in the 1970s and 1980s of inevitable racial war in South Africa, th e many local
implementation of the power-sharing provision , Anna Jars tad and Desiree Nilsson find no
initiatives to unite the country after apartheid and years of violent conflicts were successful.
evidence that more power-sharing is better. It is also found that both implemented territorial
and military power-sharing increase the chances of peace, while political power-sharing has no
effect on peace Qarstad and Nilsson, 2008). Territorial power-sharing: devolution and decentralization
Lijphart suggest that 'no state can exist without some degree of consensus on matters of
Political power-sharing: Former enemies in joint government fundamental concern ... [namely) the desire to preserve the existing system.' This minimal
consensus is based on 'the feeling ofbelonging to a common nation as well as to one's own block'
Democracy is a system for managing conflicts peacefully. There is also strong empirical evidence
(Lijphart, 1968a: 78- 79). In many countries undergoing simultaneous statebuilding and
for the so-called 'democratic peace,' which means that democratic states do not engage in warfare
peacebuilding, the political structure is constructed while the question of who constitutes the
against each other (Oneal and Russett, 1999). To promote democracy has therefore become a
demos (the people) is still a source of conflict. This is what Juan J. Linz and Alfred Stepan have
central task for international organizations. But the road to democracy - democratization - is
cal.led the 'statencss problem' (Linz and Stepan, 1996: 29). Territorial power-sharing seeks to
often paved with gross human right violations and violent conflicts. One reason is that democracy
builds on the notion of free political competition and uncertain electoral outcome, whi ch is seen
2Jg67
?4~6
Sliariug power to build states
Jars tad
show that territorial power-sharing is conducive to durable peace and that such power-sharing
solve this issue, by devolving some power to local govemment or by autonomy for a certain is almost as common as political power-sharing Qarst.1d and Nilsson, 2008). But does it contribute
region. Tllis can provide for separate education systems and separate laws in parts of the country to statebuilding?
to enable cultural diversity. Malaysia applies a dual justice system with sharia law limited to In Bosnia a.nd Herzegovina, the territorial power-sharing arrangement keeps the state formally
Muslims and secular criminal and civil law for the rest of the population. Also in Nigeria and in together. However, the state is divided and the institutions are weak. According to David
. Chandler, the 1995 Dayton agreement created a high degree of international dependence .
Sudan, sharia is the law in parts of the country.
The majority in the country may fear that territorial power-sharing is a stepping-stone toward Democracy was further undennined by the extended mandate for the Office of the High
partition. Historically, there are such cases. In Cyprus, before independence 1960, the Greek Representative, which granted him the right to enact laws and to remove elected politicians
Cypriots wanted to unite the island with Greece while the Turkish Cypriots favored a division (Chandler, 1999; Knaus and Martin, 2003). However, few other autonomy arrangements have
of the island. Tl:Us is a typical case where power-sharing was applied in an attempt to solve the attracted such international involvement. A more common problem is that the new entities have
stateness problem. The 1960 constitution for the newly independent country provided for few resources to develop strong local institutions. In many cases the national government is still
consociational democracy. Defore agreement was reached, there was an intense debate on the in conrrol of collection ofraxes. Economic power-sharing could assist in achieving a more even
criteria for belonging to the respective Greek and Turkish conununities. While the Turkish side distribution of resources.
srressed language as the most important criterion, the Greek side insisted that religion should
define which community individuals belonged to. Each conmmnity was then to enroll on separate Economic power-sharing: distributing incomes of natural resources
electoral rolls. Turkish Cypriots were to be overrepresented in govenunent posts as well as in
the bureaucracy, the judiciary, the police, and the army Qarstad, 2001: 133-137). The relationship between economic inequality and violent conAict is at the cen ter of a large
In addition, the Turkish Cypriots had extensive autonomy. While Greek and Turkish Cypriots discourse. Statistically, income inequality does not contribute to the probability of civil war
had lived intern:Ungled all over the island, at least since the millet system under the Ottoman era (Collier, 2000). However, great inequalities between regions or groups can create tensions and
there was a tradition that each community attended to its own business. During colonial rule, have negative consequences for statebuilding. Sometimes the richer region wants to secede. This
separate Turkish Cypriot municipalities had existed de facto since 1958. However, the decision was the case in Yugoslavia, where the wealthiest republic, Slovenia, was the first to proclaim its
to formally accept these mtn:llcipalities as provided in th e constitution was blocked. Turkish independence. Perceived economic discnmination often gives rise to grievances and can ftlel
Cypriots became increasingly isolated as they were not allowed to enter Greek Cypriot areas. In riots (Gurr, 2000). Issues related to economic inequality, such as land distribution and control
December 1963 interethnic violence broke out, and UNlFICYP was deployed in March 1964. over natural resources, often contribute to the conflict. In an effort to settle such issues, economic
Many positions reserved for Turkish Cypriots were taken over by Greek Cypriots, and Turkish power-sharing is part of several peace agreements, for instance in the Philippines, where the
Cypriots became more and more isolated and forced into ghettos. Under these harsh conditions regional government was granted control over fmance and a share of the profits from mining.
Turkish Cypriots had to rely on their own administrative system for registration of births etc. Other cases include Colombia, Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Nicaragua, Mali, Moldova,
They also became gradually dependent on the UN and Turkey for supply of food. In 1974 Rwanda, and Zimbabwe (Hartzell and Hoddie, 2007: 47-49, 128) .
Turkey invaded the island, and since then Cyprus is divided into a northern Turkish Cypriot In Sudan there have been several conflicts between the Arabs in the north and the black
part (recognized as a state only by Turkey) and the Republic of Cyprus, with territorial control Africans in the south. In Sudan between 2002 and 2004, the parties agreed on provisions for
over the southern Greek Cypriot part. The Kofi Annan plan on a new power-sharing agreement political, territorial, n:Ulitary, and economic power-sharing during a rransitional period of six
was put tO a referendum in 2004, but Greek Cypriots rejected it, and the island remains divided. years. The political power-sharing agreement stipulated two governments: a Government of
Hence, the stateness problem is still not solved and no peace agreement has been signed. National Un.ity at tl1e cenrrallevel and a Government of Southern Sudan. The territorial power-
Also in a few other cases, referenda have been stipulated for the purpose of setding the slate- sharing was an agreement on some parts of the south/north boundary and provisions for a
ness problem. ln Papua New Guinea in 2001 an agreement created autonomy for the island referendum on secession after the end of the transition period. Militarily power-sharing took the
Douga.inville. At a later stage a referendum on independence is supposed to be held. In Sudan, form of creation of some Joint Integrated Units in southern Sudan, Khartoum, the Nuba
the Machakos process included peace agreements on political power-sharing as well as territorial Mountains, and the Blue Nile during the intenm period, while the rest of the army remained
power-sharing by autonomy for Southern Sudan. It was also agreed that a referendum on inde- divided (Sriram, 2008).
pendence was to be held. In July 2011 the new state was proclaimed, but the violence did not Econon:Uc power-shanng was provided for by an agreement on wealth sharing. The oil
end. This indicates that referenda do not seem to promote reconciliation and cooperation for a revenues from sou them Sudan should be shared on a 50-50 basis between the two governments
joint state, but rather strengrhen the perception of vulnerability and insecurity. A planned during the interim period. In addition, the revenues from the Abyei area should be shared, with
referendum also tends to put statebuilding on hold. It is difficult to build institutions when no one 50 per cent to the National Goverrunent, 42 per cent to the Govenunent of Southern Sudan,
knows where the future borders will be and who will fall under the jurisdiction of the future state. and the rest to the local population (Brosche, 2009, 17- 19). The agreements also included
However, referenda on independence are unusual and division after a period of territorial provisions for non-oil revenues, stipulating that 50 per cent of aU taxes collected in South Sudan
power-sharing is rare. Rather, many groups striving for autonomy seem to settle for rather minor by the National Government would be allocated back to the Government of Southern Sudan
fonns of self-government. Territorial power-shanng has contributed to ending large-scale violent (Rogier, 2005: 40).
conflict in countries such as Angola, Croatia (Serbian Republic ofKrajina), Bosnia-Herzegovina, After the independence ofSouth Sudan, there are a lot of unsettled issues regarding the border
Comoros, Djibouti, Georgia (Abkhazia), India (Bodoland), Indonesia (Aceh), Maced01lia, Mali, and tl1e bnd allocation for the returned refugees. In addition, new arrangements need to settle
Mexico, Moldova, Papua New Guinea, and the UK (Northem lrdand). Statistical studies also
2~69
268 250
~

Jarstad
I Sfwn·t~g poll!er to hHild states

than regular govenunent forces and were denied the ra nks that they had when lighting for th e
the issues of oil revenues, as the two counni es depend on each other if they are to reap continued
benefits of the oil. About three-quarters of the old oil reserves are located in the South, while ANC. Other fighters were not allowed to join the n ew force and remained unoccupied in c ororps
the infnsm1cture to exploit it, such as pipelines, «fineries, and export temrinals, is in tbe North during long periods without training or education to ena ble reintegration into the pmt- apmhcid
(lCG, 2011). This shows that continued negotiations are necessary. society. Some of them retained their 'profession' by j oining mercenary companies (Spe:ll", 200/.:
147-148). O ther former fighters have been employed as body guards. Th e le vel ofpn litic:II
. violence is still rather high in some areas in South Mrica, especially around electi on tiorw;
Military power-sharing: integrating armed forces (Hoglund andJarstad, 20 11). This is partly a legacy of the conflict and points to th e consct.rucoocn
of inadequate DDR.
Military power is at the heart of security relations, as it provides security for its group at the same
time as it poses the greatest threat to its adversaries. Agreements regarding nrilitary power are
very painful for the parties, as they risk leaving them vulnerable. For this reason, agreements
How can power-sharing facilitate state building?
often include security guarantees or a share of the military power. Military power-sharing usually
meam integrating the warring parties into a joint anuy. An example is the Bosnian case where, Power-sharing freezes the power balance and thereby reduces uncertainty. This creates a space
following the Dayton peace agreement in 1995, the Bos1rian and Croat forces completed a merger that can be used to build strong institutions and plan for efficient statebuilding, give n that th e
in 1997. Military power-sharing was also an important part of the peace agreement reached fanner warring parties can coop erate. It is noteworthy that many peace processes enta il several
by the Philippines government and the M o ro lslanric Liberation Front in 1'>96. Four years after peace agreements before peace eventually ho lds. There is reason to expect that the parties
the signing, a large number of the soldiers called for in the agreement had been integrated into gradually leam what can be aclrieved during negotiations. But negotiations must also contin ue
special and auxiliary uorits of the armed forces and the national police. As stipulated in the 1992 during and after power-sharing in order for peace to be maintain ed.
peace agreement in M ozambique , the government and Renamo merged their am1ed forces Previous experience of power-sharing points to many directions, and no idea l type of power-
and fo m1cd a new national am1y with equal numbers of troops from each side . In all of these sharing emerges. M any states that have implemented power-sharing after civil war are facing
three cases, nrilitary power- sharing has contributed to peace (Hartzell and Hoddie, 2007: hu ge challenges including weak institutions, fragile peace, and poor econonric development. We
129-135). know more of what does not work with regard to power-sharing than what is working in order
In N epal in 20 ll, an agreement was made to integrate the Maoist rebel fo rces into the national to £1cilitate statebuilding. Power-sharing not only may fail to end the violent conflict, but it can
am1y. Military power-sharing agreements have also been struck in countries such as Angola, also work contrary to statebuilding. Does tlris mean that power-sharing should be removed from
Bosnia, Cambodia, Chad, El Salvador, Lebanon, Nicaragua, Rwanda, Sierra Leone, and South th e toolbox of statebuilders?
Africa. In addition, Matthew Hod die and Caroline Hartzell in clude division of military forc es,
In reality, after civil war there are few alternatives to power-sharing. Power over political,
or pemrission for antagonists to remain am1ed or retain their own anned forces, in a study on
territorial, military, and ccononric issues is at tl1e heart of many armed conflicts. A precondition
implementation of agreements on nrilitary provisions. Among the 16 agreements on military
for warring parties to sign an agreement is that they believe that they no longer can win militarily
power that they identify during the period 1980-1996, there are only three agreements that do
and that they have more to gain from a peace ab>reernent. The promise of guaranteed shares of
not require any integration of the militari es. These cases ofnrilitary power division are Azerbaijan,
pow er may be necessary to end such civil wars. Thus, the main fun ction of power-sharing is
C hechnya, and Georgia-South Ossetia (Hartzell and Hoddie, 2003: 308, 312). In addition there
short-·tenn peace, not statebuilding. At the same time, when power-sharing is deemed necessary
are cases where some parties are allowed to retain their own am1ed forces; for instance, the 19ll9
to end the war, it should be designed in such a way that longer processes such as st:Itebuilding
Taif Accord which allowed Hezbollah to retain its military wing, wllile all other militias integrated
are facilitated. Policymakers are advised to acknowledge tradeoff.> involved in diflerent solutions.
into the Lebanese reformed security force (Hartzell and Hoddie, 2007: 175). In their article,
It is vital that the power-sharing agreement be designed in such a way th at the worst pitf.1lls and
Hoddie and H artzell demonstrate that implementation of agreements on dividing or sharing
risks are reduced. Power-sharing should at least no t undem1ine .ltatebuilding; at best it can even
nrilitary power is important C or durable peace. They suggest that the reason is that implementation
contribute to building functional institutions. This meons that policymakcrs must look ahead and
involves great costs for the parties, and the fa ct that they do implement agreements sends a signal
analyze the long-term consequences of different power-sharing arrangements and also make use
of their genuine comnritment to peace (H artzell and Hoddie, 2003). T his hypothesis was of innovative ideas to improve power-sharing.
statistically tested in a study including the implementation of other types of power-sharing
arrangements, spanning a longer time period and induding agreement after less dearlly conflicts.
In line with H artzell and Hoddie, it was found that most integrative nrilitary power-sharing lncludillg extremists. Peace is made bet\veen enenries, not fri ends_ Warring parties that arc
agreements are at least partially implemented and that complete implementation of su ch excluded from a power-sharing arrangement have an incentive to continue fighting. Therefore
agreements improves the prospects for lasting peace Oarstad and Nilsson, 200H). power-sharing should aim to include all strong actors, including the most harrlline extrcnrists.
Military power- sharing is often paired with broader security sector refonns as well as This choice entails certain tradeoffs. Including warring parties always involves the risk that
demobiliZdtion, disarmament, and reintegratio n (DDR) programs. In South Africa, a number of they continue to use violent tactics in parallel to politics. In addition, such inclusion can be
the anned forces associated with the ANC and lnkatha were integrated into the new national viewed as rewarding violence. However, transiti onal power-shari ng arra nge ments ca n buy
defense iorcc. A British Advisory T raining Team assisted in tlris relatively successful integration. time to integrate former fighters into society. Ideally, during the period o f political power-
Nevertheless, there were some problems. For imtance discontented fonuer fighters left their bases sharing the former encnries should be exposed to dernocrJtic methods of solving confljcts and
socialized into democrats.
and complained to President Nelson M andela about their poor treannent. They were paid less

27~);z 771
253
.
Jarstad

Iucluding non-violent parties. h is important to make use of the local capacity for peace. Aim to
include non-violent representatives in the power-sharing goverrunent, for instance existing
political parties and civil society representatives. This can provide for a broader form oflocal
ownership of the peace process. The challenge in this regard involves identifYing local actors
1.
r
'
Slzt~ring po11'er to build states

continuing difficult negotiations to solve remaining conflict issues and preclude n ew conflicts.
finally, conflict sensitivity is always essentia.l during peace operations. It is particularly
important to assess how assistance afFects the power relations in society and to prevent new
tensions from mrning violent.

that are seen as legitimate representatives who want elections.


Cotztitzued dialogue. Several rounds of peace agreements are often needed before lasting peace References
is achieved. Even when a power-sharing agreement is reached there is a need for continued
Brosche,J. (2009). Sharing power - Enab~ng peace? Evaluating Sudan's Comprehensive Peace Agreement
dialogue and negotiation to solve remaining issues. International mediators and local religious 2005. Uppsala, Sweden: Uppsala Unive"ity and New York, NY: Mediation Support Unit, Department
leaders can play a pivotal role to facilitate such talks. of Political Aflai", United Nations.
A mouopoly '!l violctuc. The state must seize a monopoly of violence. In exchange for inclusion, Chandler, D. (1999). Bosnia: Faking democracy after Dayton. London, UK: Pluto Press.
the warring parties must refrain from illegal violence. A period of power-sharing allows time Collier, P. (2000). Doing well out of war: An economic pe"pective. In M. Berdal and D. M. Malone (Eds.),
Greed tmd gn'evmue: Eco11omic age11das ;, dv;J 1/lars. Boulder, CO: Lyrwe Rienner.
for DDR and security sector reform (SSR) ro develop rule of law and respect for human
Dalil, R. A. (1971 ). Polyarchy: Participation and opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
rights. Military power-sharing can provide for reform and incOiporation of the warring forces Grofinan, B., and Lijphart, A. (Eds.). (1977). Electomllmus attd their politir<tl co11sequences. New York, NY:
into a united national anny and training to abide by international conventions. Agaton Press.
• Decetttralization aud devolution. ln conflicts where territorial control is contested, territori al Gurr, T. R. (2000). Peoples 11ersus states: Minorities at risk itt t/,. 11ew CC/Itury. Washington, DC: United St:Jtes
Institute of Peace Press.
power-sharing can be appropriate. To avoid the risks involved in secessions, territorial power-
HJitzell, C., and Hoddie, M. (2003). lmtit11tionalizing peace: Power sharing and post-civil war conflict
sharing can relieve the central government from some contested issues and devolve power to management. Ameriamjouma/ ~(Po/itiml Sdence, 47(2), 318-332.
more or less autonomous local governments. A tradeoff is that new minorities may emerge HameU, C., and Hoddie, M. (2007). Crafting peace: Powcr-slwn·ng imtitutinus mtd the ~~~~otiated settlemc/JI q(
in the new entity and if they feel discriminated against, a new conflict may rise. This is a citJil wmr. University Park, PA: Pennsylva nia St:Jte University Press.
particularly .important point to consider if the new entity is allowed to have separate laws. In Hoglund, K., andja"tad, A. (2011). TowJrds electoral security: Experiences from KwaZulu-Naltl. Afriw
Spectmm, 1: 33- 59.
addition, local leaders do not always enjoy greater legitimacy than national ones.
Horowitz, D. L. (1985). Etlmic .~ronps i11 conflict. Berkeley, CA: Unive"ity of California Press.
• Ecot1omic power-slwri11g. Economic power-sharing can reduce uneven development in th e Horowitz, D. L. (1991). A democratic Soutlt /lfrica' Constitutional cnginccrit(~ in a dil•ided society. Berkeley, CA:
country by ensuring that all parties share revenues from natural resources such as oil and mines. University of California Press.
Economic power-sharing can also entail land refonm. An overlooked issue in peace agree- ICG. (2011). Politics Jnd transition in the new South Sudan. Afn"ca Report, 172, April4.Juba, South SlHbn:
International Crisis Group.
ments is often how to improve the tax base and the institutions for tax collection. As resources
Jarstad, A. (2001). Chat~gitJg the game: Consodational theory and ctlmic quotas i11 Cypnu aud Nr.u• Zealand. Upp~·Ila,
are essential in order to build strong instimtions, this is an issue that needs to be addressed in
Sweden: Department of Peace and Conflict Research, Uppsala Unive"ity.
fumre peace agreements. Jarmd, A. K. (2009). The prevalence ofpower-sl.,ring: Exploring the patterns of post-election peace. Africa
A trat~sitiollalmeasure. It is important that the transitional period allows sufficient time ro begin Spectnwt, 44(3), 41-62.
building capable state institutions (not least rule oflaw), carry out DDR and SSR, and prepare Jarstad, A. K., and Nilsson, D. {2008). From word< to deed<: The implementation of power-sharing pacts
in peace Jccords. Conflict Mmragcmcnt and Peace Science, 25(3) , 206-223.
for democratic elections. Power-sharing arrangements tend to be based on the power relations
Knaus, G., and Martin, F. (2003). Trnvails of the European Raj.joumal of Democmcy, 14(3).
at the end of the war. Over time, there are changes in power relations, demography, and
LUphatt, A. (l968a). Tite politics of aaommodation: Pluralism a11d democrat)' in lire Nct!tcrlcmds. Berkeley, CA:
economy. Willie power-sharing ensures inclusion for the parties to the agreement, the political University of California Press.
space needs to open up to include also other political parties. In addition, power-sharing docs Lijphart, A. (1968b). Typologies of democrntic systems. Comparati11c Political Studies, I(Aptil): 3-44.
not allow for accountability and replacement of the government. Therefore power-sharing Lijphart, A. (1969). Consociational democracy. World Politics, 21(2), 207-225.
Lijphart, A. (1977). Democracy i11 plural societic<. New Haven, CT: Yale Unive"ity Press.
should be a temporary provision, and ideally be followed by elections within a five-year
Lijpharr. A. (19RS). Powcr-slrarinR i11 South A(n"ca. Berkeley, CA: Institute oflmematiorul Studie<, University
period. of California.
l11tegmtive electoral system. If power-sharing need' to be re tained afier the transitional period to Lijphart, A. (1993). Consocianonal democracy. In]. Krieger (Ed.), 71rc Oxford compmriotr to politics oftltc
secure the peace, design a system that allows for existing moderate groups and new actors to rvorld. Oxford, UK: OxCord Unive"ity Press.
stand for elections. Tlus can be done by reserving only part of the seats in parliament and Lijphart, A. (1996). The puzzle oflndian democrncy: A consociational interpret:Jtion. Americmr Political
Sdeucc Revierv, 90(2), 258-268.
leaving some open for electoral contestation outside of the quotas. Ensure that voters have a
Lijphart, A. (1998). Consensus and consensus democracy: Cu ltural, structural, functional, and rational-
choice of candidates in each election, also for d1c quota seats. Reserve seats for political parties, choice explanations. &atrditravimr Political Studies, 21(2). 99-108.
not for individual candidates. Lijphart, A. (1 999). Pattems of democracy: Govcmmeutfonns and peifonnat~ccs iu thirty-~ix cormtries. New Haven,
CT: Yale Unive"ity Press.
Cot!fiict-sensitive i11tematio11al etlgagcmcllt. It is not certain that international assistance provides
for more successfUl power-sharing arrangements. Rather, there is a risk of international Linz,J., and Stepan, A. (1996). Problems ofdemocratic trmrsitiotr and comolidatiott. Baltimore. MD:Johns Hopkins
University Press.
dependency and a lack of!ocal ownerslup. However, some conflicts cannot be ended without
Oneal, ]. R., and Russett, B. (1999). The Kantian peace: The pacific benefits of democracy,
international involvement. Under such circumstances, it is important that third parties do not interdependence, and international organizations, 1885-1992. World Politics, 52(1), 1-37.
pronusc to act as guarantors unless they can follow through on their promise. Equally Reilly, B. (200 1). Democracy itt divided socirlies: Electoral etrgineeritzJ?.for coujlict lllfliii'._(!Cmetrt. Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
important is that the developments are closely monitored, and that mediation facilitates

~li 2~73
Jarstad

Reynolds, A. (Ed.) . (2002). Tllf arcliiteaurc of democracy: Cou>titutioual desigu, co•iflict u<all<(getiiCIII, aud demo<r<1cy.

Desiguiu,~
Oxford, UK: Oxford Universiry Press.
Rogier, E. (2005). "" iutcgratcd srmtcgy for petue, sewriry aud dc<•clopmcut iu posr-agreemcur Sudau. The
Hague: The Nctherl:mds: Netherbnds Institute oflntcnmional Rela tions Clingembel.
Sartori, G . (1994). Cowpamtit'e constitutiot~al eu,Rillcen'tJg. At~ ituJiliry into stmctures, iuccHtivcs aud outcomes.
London, UK: Macmillan.
Sisk, T. D. (1996). Power s/iariug aud iutcm<llioualmediatiou i11 etli11ic cotiflicts. Washington, DC: United States
Institute of Peace Press.
Spear, J. (2002). Disarmament and demobili>ation. InS. J. Stedman, D. Rothchild, and E. M. Cousens
(£ds.), Ertdiug dr,il wars: ·nre imJJfemcutatiou of p~::ace agn:CIIICII(S. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Sriram, C. L. (2008). Pe<1ce "' gwcnl<liiCc: Power-slwri11g, armed groups , all(/ coutemporary pe<~cc uegoriatious.
Basingstoke, UK: Palgr.we Maonillan.
Taagepera, R., and Shugart, M .S. (1989). SealS ,,d votes: Tile <ffccts """ detcnuiuaulS of clcaoral systems. Yale,
CT: Yale universiry Press.
Tocqueville, A. De (2000). Dcmocmcy iu A merica. N ew York, NY: Perennial Classics. (Original title Dr Ia
democratic ell Amlriquc, London, UK: Saunders and Otley, 1H3B.)
Walter, B. (1999). Building rcputotion: Why governmentS f•ghr some separatistS bur not others. Amcri""'
Joumal of l'olitic.>l &icucc, 50(2), 313-330.
Wa lt er. B. F. (2002). Commi tliug Ill peace: The succcsiful sculewe11t of civil war$. Princeton, NJ: Princeton

UniverSity Press.

275
274 256

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen