Sie sind auf Seite 1von 34

Accountzng, Orgamzat~onsandSocwty, Vol 16, No 5/6, pp 405-438, 1991 0361-3682/91 $3 00+ O0

Printed m Great Brttam Pergamon Press plc

COST ACCOUNTING, CONTROl,LING LABOUR AND THE RISE OF


CONGLOMERATES

TREVOR HOPPER
Department o f Accounting and Financg University o f Manchester
and

PETER ARMSTRONG
School o f Management and Economic Studie~ Unitmrsity o f Sheffield

Abstract

Through a detailed crtttque ofJohnson & ~ ' s RelevanceLost, (Johnson, H. T. & Kaptan,R. S.,Relevance
Los~ TheRiseandFall of ManagenkontAccountDtg (Boston, MA Harvard BusinessSchool Press, 1987)),
based up¢~ labour htstorgs of control witlun North Americanfirms, this article identifiesmajor deficienctes
m conve~uonal histcmcal studms of cost and management accounting and offers possibihues for thetr
resoluuon. ARer n o e ~ the lunitatiom of ~ cost theory for the theorisation of ¢xgmummmsand
then- history, the paper argues that acommting controls were not a consequence of econonuc or
tedmclt~cal ~ lint rather were rooted m strugglesas firmsattempted to control laixaa, p r o c ~
m vinous epochs of capttalisucdeveaopmem Cost accounting developments are r~l~wdto the ~ of
internal subcgmtracung and craft control of ~ m early factories, the advent of '~cmntific"
Manasement and hcmmsenmedlabour and, post-1930, with an accord Ixtween prnnary sectors ~ ~ ~
O3tlmeati¢~, whtch led m an increased emphasis on ~ l y pnctr~ smoothing production and h ~
employnmnt patterns, and a shtR of eommmic l~mSUreSto secondary lalmur argl producer mark~ The
paper cotwdudesby m]gun~tlmt, in the cxmtext of today's g l ~ of capital,controls assooated wt~ ~
labour and capttal accord are being abandoned as corporauom expemnem with new ~ ~ ~
of control ~ are reflected m current fashtom m accounting research.

T r a d i t i o n a l m a n a g e m e n t a c c o u n t i n g h i s t o r y has a c c o u n t i n g d e v e l o p m e n t is s e e n as a n integral
b e e n fixated o n a s e a r c h for origins, o n the part o f thts e v o l u t i o n a r y process. J o h n s o n &
q u e s t i o n s o f w h o d i d w h a t first, a n d w h e n . Kaplan's Relevance Lost ( 1 9 8 7 ) is t h e m o s t
Preoccupied with invention, rather than with t h o r o u g h - g o i n g e x e m p l a r to date o f this n e w
diffusion a n d application, w r i t i n g s i n this g e n r e tradition. G i v e n t h e i m p a c t o f this w o r k i n
h a v e b e e n r i c h i n n a r r a t i v e t e r m s b u t t h e y have academic, c o n s u l t a n t a n d p r a c t i t i o n e r circles,
n e g l e c t e d to e x p l o r e t h e i m p o r t a n t linkages t h e r e are g o o d r e a s o n s for s u b j e c t i n g its
b e t w e e n phases of accounting development htstorical a n d t h e o r e t i c a l a d e q u a c y to t h e
and their socio-economic context. Given the closest s c r u t i n y , n o t least b e c a u s e t h e s e issues
b e l i e f that this p e r c e i v e d d e f i c i e n c y n e e d s to b e may bear tmportantly on the prescriptive
addressed, then the recent marriage b e t w e e n message w h t c h J o h n s o n a n d Kaplan d r a w from
a c c o u n t i n g a n t i q u a r i a n i s m a n d the d o c t r i n e s o f t h e i r v e r s t o n o f a c c o u n t i n g history.
liberal e c o n o m i c s c o n s t i t u t e s a defintte In c o n f o r m i t y w i t h their e v o l u t i o n a r y m o d e l ,
t h e o r e t i c a l advance. P r e m i s e d o n t h e n o t i o n J o h n s o n a n d Kaplan p o r t r a y t h e initial phases o f
that c h a n g e s i n t h e f o r m s o f b u s i n e s s organlsa- cost a c c o u n t i n g d e v e l o p m e n t as a steady accre-
t i o n a n d c o n t r o l s y s t e m s are d r i v e n b y s e a r c h e s tion of knowledge and technique achieved by
for efficiency i n c o m p e t i t i v e e n v i r o n m e n t s , practising engineers and managers in their

405
406 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

searches for efficmncy As a result of this argue the thesis of R e l e v a n c e L o s t a r e better


process, they argue, virtually all of the con- understood through a "labour process"
temporary techniques of management account- approach to e c o n o m i c and industrial history, as
ing w e r e in operational use by about 1920 exemplified by writers such as Clawson (1980),
Having reached this point, Johnson and Kaplan Gordon e t aL (1982), Littler (1982),
then depart from their basic evolutionary Montgomery ( 1 9 8 7 ) and Nelson ( 1 9 7 4 )
model to argue that many of the achievements Recognising the need for a broader, more
of this "Golden Age" have subsequently been critical, institutional analysis of capttahstic
stifled by the influences of financial reporting development, ~ the core presupposition of this
and academic teaching Thts theoretmal twist perspective is that social and economtc con-
enables the authors to launch a powerful attack, flicts arising from the modes of control which
from the historical ground of the 1920s, on the characterise particular phases o f capttalisttc
inefficiencies resulting from the contemporary development stimulate the creation of new
teaching and practice of management account- forms of control intended to ehmmate or
ancy Accountmg information systems of ques- accommodate resistance and to solve the
ttonable relevance are said to be used m a associated problems of profitability These new
mechanical fashion b y a generatton of American forms of control, in turn, decay, partly because
executives brought up to manage "by the their competitive advantage disappears as a
numbers" This, in turn, is held responsible for a consequence of their generalisatton and partly
decline in the international competitiveness of because they give rise to new contradictions
American businesses, especially in relatton to and forms of resistance. Thus a labour process
the Japanese. This message evidently strikes a approach, in contrast to one utilising trans-
c h o r d with many practising managers, perhaps action cost theory, stresses crisis rather than
because the inroads made by Japanese manufac- continuity; contradmtion rather than internal
turers are indisputable, perhaps because there consistency; social and political conflict rather
is some truth in the thesis of accounting than harmony; the m o n o p o l y p o w e r of corpora-
stagnation, but also, perhaps, because of the tions rather than serf-equilibrating competitive
implicit daemonisation of academics and financ- markets, patterns of class formatton in specific
tal accountants economtes rather than an atomised view of the
Despite the respect in which Johnson and individual; and human agency m its cultural and
Kaplan's w o r k must be held, the argument of mstatutlonal setting rather than economtstic
this paper is that their theory is flawed, their reductlomsm
history partial and some of their prescription A re-exammation, along these "labour pro-
neglectful of the socto-economic condinons on cess" lines, of Johnson and Kaplan's chosen
w h i c h the achievements of the 1920s exemplars of effficiency-driven development
depended. In contrast to the social harmony mdtcates that mid 19th century cost accounting
and Serf-equilibrating behaviour o f individuals, systems were employed to intensify labour in
firms and markets assumed in the transaction response to increased competition as well as to
cost framework employed by Johnson and stimulate searches for efficiency. It reveals
Kaplan, many of the historical events used to accountmg's tmplication in the tightening of

tThts article does not cla,m to be umque m thts respect Other pertinent attempts include Armstrong (1985, 1987),
Hopwood(1987), Hoskm& MacVe(1986), Loft(1986), Merino & Netmark(1982), Miller & O'Leary(1987) and Tinker &
Neimark (1987) Many of these employ a theorettcal perspecttve dertved from the work of Foucault Such work has
mlluenced our own, but thts arttcle ts motivated m part by the destre to locate accountingwtthin a more explicit theory of
interests
COST ACCOUNTING,LABOURAND CONGLOMERATES 407

managerial control through the destruction of TRANSACTION COSTS AND THE


subcontracting and craft controls later in the DEVELOPMENT OF MANAGEMENT
century, and it shows that a major feature of the ACCOUNTING: A CRITIQUE OF THE
General Motors system o f the 1920s was the THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK OF
insulation o f shareholders' dividends from "RELEVANCE LOST"
e c o n o m i c fluctuation by throwing the costs of
this o n t o the workforce. Because s o m e of these Relevance Lost ts not considered h e r e from
usages of accounting information d e p e n d e d the standpoint of managerial prescription; the
u p o n a lack o f resistance from organised labour, reader can find this elsewhere ( e g. Noreen,
it is b y no m e a n s accidental that Johnson and 1987) Rather, the c o n c e r n is with the partial
Kaplan's a p o g e e o f m a n a g e m e n t accounting nature of the interpretations of history which
d e v e l o p m e n t was also an age of anti-union underlie tts thesis Since this p r o b l e m stems, m
w o l e n c e and espionage. The c o n t e m p o r a r y part, from certain inadequacies in the transac-
implicatton is that certain o f the "relevances" of tion cost framework e m p l o y e d b y Johnson and
1920s' a c c o u n t m g control systems can only be Kaplan, it is necessary to review these before
r e s u r r e c t e d in c o n t e x t s w h e r e the resistance of p r o c e e d i n g to matters of histortcal substance.
labour is weakened. Most of the p r o b l e m s stem from the assump-
A labour process approach is also useful in tion in transactton cost theory that changes in
reassessmg J o h n s o n and Kaplan's thests of orgamsational forms and control systems are
accounting stagnation, according to which the universally driven by searches for efficiency,
influence o f financial accountants and academ- whereas it is an elementary feature of capitalist
ics was sufficient to arrest the d e v e l o p m e n t of e c o n o m i c life that there are also gains to be
m a n a g e m e n t a c c o u n t a n c y for o v e r sixty years made from the extension and intensification of
within the m o s t dynamic e c o n o m y in the labour and from the monopolisation o f p r o d u c t
capitalist world. Here, the historical record markets. In fact it ts only fair to point out that
suggests that the post-1930s' decline of inter- the fine detail of Johnson and Kaplan's history
est in accounting for process efficiencies was often does acknowledge issues of labour
actually the p r o d u c t of the N e w Deal era, in intensification and m o n o p o l y - - see, for exam-
w h i c h trade unions w e r e far m o r e able to resist ple, the DuPont case study (Johnson, 1975).
lay-offs and the speed-up, and o f increasing The critique which follows, therefore, is not a
industrial concentration which enabled wholesale challenge to their factual account
e m p l o y e r s to displace the costs o f welfarist but, rather, to their broadbrush interpretation
e m p l o y m e n t strategies o n t o semi-monopolised
p r o d u c t markets. In this n e w socio-economic The contract image o f organisation
context, the relevance o f budgetary controls Basically, transaction cost theory
m a y have changed, rather than declined Cost (Williamson, 1970, 1975) asserts that the
accounting c a m e to b e used as the instrument concentration of diverse e c o n o m i c activities
o f m o n o p o l y pricing policies designed to within large corporations is viable only w h e n
p r o t e c t a partial accord b e t w e e n capital and managerial c o o r d i n a t i o n of these achieves
certain sectors o f the labour force. H o w far this significant economies, as c o m p a r e d to the
a c c o r d will persist into the 199Os is an o p e n aggregate result w h e n the same operations are
question, but to the extent that tt does so, there separately managed and co-ordinated through
m a y b e resistance to Johnson and Kaplan's call market transactions. The costs of securing co-
for a reassertion of accounting for process ordinatton are called "transaction costs". The
efliciencies potential for gains from r e d u c e d transaction
408 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

costs m seen as c r e a t m g opportunities for both organisation and accounting are driven by
increased profits and r e d u c e d p r o d u c t costs. searches for efficiency Whilst still contentious,
Simultaneously, therefore, they explain the this at least has the virtue of intelligibility.
expansion of capitalist enterprises into func-
tionally related activities, and the success of The assumption o f competitive markets
those companies w h i c h do so. Moreover, they Transaction cost theory is based o n the idea
are held to explain innovattons in systems of that, m o r d e r to be successful, managertal co-
organisation and accounting which achieve ordination must compete with market coordina-
further i m p r o v e m e n t s in managerial co-ordina- tion. Tacitly this assumes competitive p r o d u c t
tion markets. O f all the areas of e c o n o m i c debate m
Transaction costs, evidently, bear a great which this assumptton mtght b e made, that on
weight of explanation in the theory. Yet as the formation of giant mtegrated corporations
P e r r o w ( 1 9 8 1 a ) has p o i n t e d out, it ts far from must be just about the least appropriate Using
clear w h a t they are. Whilst it is clear enough case material, P e r r o w ( 1 9 8 1 a ) has made the
that there are gains to be achieved from obvious point that acquisitions and mergers
combining single-activity enterprises, with the may b e carried out with m o n o p o l y profits in
object o f eliminating their separate profits, it is view, rather than gains from efficiency. In fact
clear that Williamson and his followers see the Nelson ( 1 9 5 9 ) has shown that the majority of
r e d u c t i o n of transaction costs in m u c h broader mergers m the great wave of 1 8 9 5 - 1 9 0 4 w e r e
terms, This is achieved b y visualising all horizontal, rather than vertical, and that m o s t
relationships of organisational co-ordination as resulted in corporations which dominated thetr
contracts. T h r o u g h this device, the act of p r o d u c t markets
settling the f o r m o f o n e of these "contracts" can Williamson & Ouchi ( 1 9 8 1 ) reject thts
b e seen as a transaction. O n this basis it ts argument on the dubious and irrelevant
claimed that there is potential for reduced grounds that any costs to the public arising
transaction costs in devising i m p r o v e d systems from "modest" increases in market power, are
of organisation and co-ordination. m o r e than offset b y the gains in efficiency
Setting aside the neglect of p o w e r relauon- possible in large monopolistic corporations.
ships implicit in the contract tmage of organis- Significantly, Chandler's c o m m e n t on the issue
ation, it is still not clear that even this extended ( 1 9 8 1 ) avotded a defence of transaction cost
definition o f a "transaction" can c o v e r all theory as such. Nevertheless, he sought to
i m p r o v e m e n t s in co-ordination, let alone all maintain the n a r r o w e r thesis that managerial
increases in efficiency. For example, h o w can co-ordination was vital to the competitive
clatms that c o r p o r a t e managers may achieve success of m e r g e d corporations on the grounds
i m p r o v e d investment decisions, as c o m p a r e d to that only those horizontally-merged companies
capital markets, b e described as a reduction in which w e n t on to achieve the additional
transaction costs~ e c o n o m i e s of vertical integration w e r e ulti-
Williamson & Ouchi's answer to these points mately successful. Logically speaking, even this
( 1 9 8 1 ) c o n c e d e d that transaction costs have argument is unconvincing, since one might
n e v e r b e e n formally defined but claimed that a construct a reverse chain of causality; namely
definition could b e adequately approached that managerial hierarchies and controls are a
through a series of illustrattons. This weak reply c o n s e q u e n c e of firms moving closer to mono-
reinforces the impression that the p r o b l e m ts poly and that m o n o p o l y profits are essential to
fundamental. Possibly for this reason, Johnson the success of managerial control in vertically
and Kaplan make no a t t e m p t to resolve the integrated enterprises
issue, and so transaction cost theory m their Whatever the eventual o u t c o m e of these
hands stmphfies to the " c o m m o n s e n s e " debates, tt is clear that they have m o v e d on
hypothesis that d e v e l o p m e n t s in forms of from blanket assumptions of competitive
COST ACCOUNTING,LABOURAND CONGLOMERATES 409

markets (Perrow, 1981b). It seems established c o n t e m p o r a r y dominant ideologies, sanitised of


that theories of the real-world d e v e l o p m e n t of discomforting explanations of capitalistic dev-
large organisations, and of the role of accoun- e l o p m e n t and the role of large corporations,
ting therein, n e e d to take account of monopoly. educational institutions and the state. By neg-
In this vein, this p a p e r will argue that the lecting an examination of alternatives foregone,
p u r p o s e of budgets in "core" corporations such history blinds rather than enlightens by
gradually changed after the 1930s, to b e c o m e portraying the status quo as inewtable.
an instrument of m o n o p o l y prtcing policies
w h i c h created the basis for an a c c o m m o d a t i o n Contro~ efficiency and effort
b e t w e e n e m p l o y e r s and certain sectors of the Transaction cost theory confuses gains from
labour force. increased effort with those from mcreased
efficiency In consequence, it confuses mana-
Microeconomics as social theory gerial controls aimed at increasing effort levels
The contract image of organlsational relation- with those directed towards increasing process
ships and the assumption of competitive mar- efficiencies This t e n d e n c y is at its m o s t visible
kets are special cases of a m o r e general in Williamson's (1975, 1980) treatment of the
intellectual m y o p i a in transaction cost theory. e m p l o y m e n t contract. In law, this is incomplete
As Robins (1987, p. 75) has argued. in the sense that the e m p l o y e r formally
receives, not a set amount and type of work, but
Although transaction~cost theory offers powerful tools the right to direct labour ("labour p o w e r " in
for understanding the tmphcattons of specific soctal Marxist terminology). Williamson attempts to
mstttuttons for economic acuwty, it is incapable of explain this form of contract, and the conse-
explaining historical tramformauons m those m s u m . quent apparatus of control o v e r the labour
Uons The transacuon-cost approach ulttmately is an
extenston and apphcauon of micro-econormc theory, process, as a minimisation of transaction costs,
and tts capactty to describe reahty is bounded by the from which b o t h parties benefit. In this manner
hmtts of the theory m that is, by the very mstituttonal a tacit assumption is imported into the theory,
constraints that [it] would attempt to explain. that managertal control is directed solely to-
wards t m p r o v e m e n t s in efficiency rather than
The transaction cost approach thus stands increases in effort levels.
accused o f trying to make history backwards by According to Williamson, variations in the
rationalising past events through the insti- precise task to be p e r f o r m e d and difficulties of
tutional lenses o f the present, particularly in its monitoring the possibility o f opportunist
assumption that all organisational relationships behaviour on the part o f workers make the
can be visualised as market transactions. By negotiation of contracts covering all possible
means o f this device, all is explained by the contingencies e x t r e m e l y costly. Thus a form
conventions o f m i c r o e c o n o m i c s to the exclu- o f contract in which employers have the
sion of social and political factors. But, to quote right, within limits, to allocate tasks and specify
Robins o n c e again, "the history o f nineteenth- effort levels is seen as a less costly alternative,
century d e v e l o p m e n t s is less a story of hier- from which b o t h parties can benefit. In part-
archy displacing markets than a tale of social icular, the individual worker's lost opportun-
and political centralisation creating the condit- ities for mtsappropriation and shirking are
ions for large-scale p r o d u c t i o n of goods clmmed to be m o r e than c o m p e n s a t e d by the
(Knowles, 1967)" (Robins, 1987, pp. 76-77). gains from preventing others from doing so.
The p r o b l e m with an inordinate reliance upon Thus authority relationships within the firm are
transaction cost theory is that important depicted as the o u t c o m e of a notional process
aspects o f history are excluded along with of rational e c o n o m i c exchange b e t w e e n work-
divergent e c o n o m i c perspectives. The danger is ers and the firm, in which output efficiency is
that history b e c o m e s written as an extension of maximised.
410 TBEVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

T h i s fanciful a n d i n d i v i d u a l i s t i c g e n e s i s ation. T h e r e i n it is s e e n as d a t a t o b e f e d i n t o a
n o t a b l y g l o s s e s o v e r t h e issue o f w h y t h e rational decision-making process Thus the
c l a i m e d e c o n o m i e s in t r a n s a c t i o n c o s t s s h o u l d quality of managerial decisions on production
b e a c h i e v e d b y a s s i g n i n g t h e r i g h t t o fill in t h e p r o c e s s e s a n d r e s o u r c e a l l o c a t i o n is s e e n as
g a p s in t h e e m p l o y m e n t c o n t r a c t t o capital d e p e n d i n g fairly s t r a i g h t f o r w a r d l y o n t h e u m e -
o w n e r s h i p , in t h e p e r s o n o f t h e e m p l o y e r , liness, a c c u r a c y a n d r e l e v a n c e o f c o s t inform.
r a t h e r than, say, t o e l e c t e d r e p r e s e n t a t i v e s o f ation. W i t h i n this s c h e m a , c o s t d a t a a r e s e e n in
t h e w o r k f o r c e . M o r e , it b u r i e s all o f t h e gains t o realist t e r m s . J o h n s o n a n d K a p l a n w r i t e fre-
capital from the right to direct labour within a q u e n t l y o f t h e " a c c u r a c y " o f c o s t s or, o n t h e
n e u t r a l - s o u n d i n g r e d u c t i o n o f t r a n s a c t i o n costs. n e g a u v e side, o f t h e i r " d i s t o r t i o n " . W h i l s t
M a r g i n s o n ( 1 9 8 6 , p. 5 ) has c o m m e n t e d : s t r e s s i n g t h a t c o s t d a t a n e e d to b e a p p r o p r i a t e
t o t h e d e c i s i o n s t o b e taken, t h e y n e v e r t h e l e s s
The concept of efftctency utthsed by Wtlharuson and b e l i e v e that, w i t h i n t h e p a r a m e t e r s o f rele-
Aoki ts not well specifietL An increase m eflictency can v a n c e , t h e q u a l i t y o f c o s t d a t a is i m p o r t a n t l y
be defined as an mcresse m output for given inputs d e t e r m i n e d b y its a c c u r a c y .
However there ts no certainty that m the case of labour
mput the last condition will hold A strengthening of If, o n t h e o t h e r h a n d , m a n a g e m e n t is t a k e n to
hterarchy can result in an increase of labour input, be about the control of labour and of junior
through the extracuon of labour effort, as well as an m a n a g e r s , t h e issue l o o k s different. F r o m this
mcrease m output. The eflictency tmphcauons of p e r s p e c t i v e , a c c o u n t i n g i n f o r m a t i o n is t o b e
strengthening hterarchy are indeterminate - - both
j u d g e d b y t h e r e s u l t s w h i c h it achieves, r a t h e r
inputs and outputs could have increased Hence the
argument (Williamson, 1980) that the existence of an t h a n its n o t i o n a l a c c u r a c y . T o t a k e a familiar
anthonty relatton can be taken as evtdence of enhanced e x a m p l e , t h e classical l i t e r a t u r e o n t h e b e .
efficiency m achtevmg common goals can be confronted h a v i o u r a l a s p e c t s o f b u d g e t s (e.g. Caplan, 1971 )
with a plausible alternative hypothesis luerarchy d i s c u s s e s t h e effects o f s e t t i n g t a r g e t s at v a r i o u s
reflects the abthty of those who own and control the
levels o f difficulty, n o t w h e t h e r t h e s e levels a r e
firm to ensure that their goals dominate the goals of
those employed m the firm Supporting evtdence for flits " c o r r e c t " in s o m e essential sense. O n this view,
alternaUve hypothesis can be drawn from the work of t h e a c c u r a c y o f b u d g e t s a n d i n t e r n a l attribu-
Marglm (1974), Pollard (1965) and Thompson (1967) t i o n s o f c o s t m i g h t b e r e g a r d e d as i r r e l e v a n t , s o
who tllustrate how the msttmtton of hierarchy through l o n g as t h e y s e r v e t o focus m a n a g e r i a l effort m
the factory system had tts origins m a search by
the directions desired by those who control the
employers for more effecttve means of coercing
workers to work. Factory orgamsauon was associated o r g a n i s a t i o n J o h n s o n a n d Kaplan d e p r e c a t e t h e
with worlang more days of the week, longer hours m a l l o c a u o n o f o v e r h e a d c o s t s o n t h e basis o f
the day, and more mtenstvely direct labour expended, on the grounds that
this p r a c u c e o v e r s t a t e s t h e c o s t s o f labour-
T h e s e c o m m e n t s i n d i c a t e t h a t an a d e q u a t e intensive processes, thus leading to unsound
history of capitalist forms of organisauon w s t r a t e g i c d e c i s t o n s . But this a s s u m e s that stra-
i n c l u d i n g t h e r o l e t h e r e i n o f a c c o u n t i n g inform- tegic decisions on the product mix are perma-
ation -- needs to take cognisance of their part e n t l y o n t h e agenda, w h e r e a s t h e r e m a y b e
in t h e e x t e n s i o n a n d i n t e n s i f i c a t i o n o f l a b o u r , as p h a s e s o f c a p i t a l i s t d e v e l o p m e n t w h e r e this is
w e l l as o f t h e i r a b i l i t y t o p r o m o t e t e c h n i c a l not the case Given the monopoly power of
p r o c e s s eflficiencies. c e r t a i n A m e r i c a n c o r p o r a t i o n s in t h e d a y s
b e f o r e t h e p a m c o v e r J a p a n e s e c o m p e t i t i o n , for
Accounting information and the rational example, product costings seem to have had
decision-making model of management m o r e significance for p r i c i n g p o l i c y t h a n for
T h e t r a n s a c t i o n c o s t v i e w o f m a n a g e m e n t as m a n u f a c t u r i n g strategy. M o r e o v e r , e v e n w h e r e
a s e a r c h for p r o c e s s efliciencies has c o n s e - competiuon places cost reduction on the
quences for Johnson and Kaplan's conception agenda, t h e r e is s o m e t h m g t o b e said for t h e
o f t h e m a n a g e r i a l r o l e o f a c c o u n t i n g inform- i n a c c u r a c y o f t r a d i t i o n a l furl-costing systems,
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOUR AND CONGLOMERATES 411

since these serve to direct managerial efforts to vet's (Berle & Means, 1933, p. 2 0 2 ) and m o d e r n
cut unit labour costs towards labour-intensive accounting historians (Merino & Neimark,
processes, which, as will appear in this paper, 1982). Speaking during the 1930s, Landis o f the
are precisely w h e r e resistance from labour is SEC had this to say:
likely to b e at its weakest.
The tmpact of almost dady uits with accountants, s o m e
Explaining accounting stagnation of them called leaders m thetr professton, oRen leaves
httle d o u b t that thetr loyalittes to m a n a g e m e n t are
Much of the rhetorical force of Johnson and stronger than thetr sense of responstbfltty to the
Kaplan's version of m a n a g e m e n t accounting investor (Carey, 1979, p 2 6 2 )
history derives f r o m the fact that it contains a
contradiction. If the search for gain from As against the questionable thesis o f financial
r e d u c e d transaction costs was sufficient to a c c o u n t m g dominance, it is important to con-
drive the evolution o f organisational forms and sider the possibility that the cost accounting
accounting systems u p to the mid-1920s, w h y systems which stand accused of f a i l i r l g
did this process cease thereafter? Necessarily American enterprise have actually persisted
answers have to b e i m p o r t e d from outside the because they have s o m e offseRing managerial
transaction costs framework. Johnson and advantage which lies b e y o n d the grasp of
Kaplan find t h e m in the imposition of financial transaction cost theory. By considering the
reporting conventions on management evolution o f accounting systems as an aspect of
accounting t e c h n i q u e b y professional account- overall changes in the pattern of control of the
ants and a takeover o f research by academics labour process, the present p a p e r attempts
interested only in abstract simplified problems. precisely this.
Thus Kaplan's diatribe against the shortcomings
of c u r r e n t m a n a g e m e n t accounting is recon- Social transformation and management
cried with Johnson's optimistic v i e w o f the accounting technology: towards a labour
a u t o n o m o u s evolution of c o r p o r a t e forms and process approach
accounting technique. Into the bargain, plaus- Johnson and Kaplan are not unaware of the
ible culprits are produced, since not even their relevance of the capital-labour relationship to
best friends could p r e t e n d that accountants are the operation of accounting information sys-
not p r e o c c u p i e d with financial reporting or that tems Noting that early cost accounts w e r e
academics are not academic. c o n c e r n e d with labour control, they remark
Whilst this m a y constitute a solution to the that "arguments about the causes, costs, and
logical p r o b l e m s created b y framing accounting possible benefits to workers o f surrendering
history within transaction cost theory, there control o v e r their labour in return for a fixed
remains an air o f unreality about it To reduce income have a b o u n d e d since Ricardo and
such accounting p r o b l e m s to accountants, be Marx" (Johnson & Kaplan, 1987, p. 22). But the
they academics or practitioners, seems to be a concerns of political e c o n o m y are cast aside
case of blaming the m o n k e y rather than the w h e n they self.consciously limit their remit to
organ-grinder. W e are asked to believe that the "the implications for accounting of the compli-
c o m p a r a t i v e l y m i n o r vested interests of cations that factory managers faced o n c e
accountants and academics have b e e n able to workers w e r e e m p l o y e d at a wage" (ibid. p.
i m p o s e their intellectual habits u p o n manage- 22) The implication appears to be that the
m e n t practice in America's giant corporations p r o b l e m s of securing compliance from the
for o v e r sixty years, to the considerable detri- workforce are sufficiently addressed through
m e n t o f their profitability. In fact, the indepen- the institution of the wage relationship, leaving
d e n t influence o f accounting professionalism on managers flee to search for process efficiencies.
c o r p o r a t e practice m a y well have b e e n mini- The notion that the p r o b l e m of extracting w o r k
real, b o t h in the v i e w o f c o n t e m p o r a r y obser- from the workforce cannot be solved on a
412 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

once-for-all basis, and that it actually lies at the (in this case, of management accounting sys-
root of many of the "comphcations" for tems) as the p r o d u c t of a continuous evolution-
accounting, is thus excluded from considera- ary selection of more efficient forms, rather
tion. than as discontinuous, and crisisMriven
It is this questionable intellectual procedure (Schumpeter, 1942). In this vein, Johnson and
which underlies Johnson and Kaplan's theorisa- Kaplan portray accounting developments up to
tion of changes in management control and the mid-1920s as a steady accretion of know-
capitalistic development through transactton ledge and practice spurred on by firms and
cost theory In this vein, it is stated as fact that individuals operating within competitive and
"the goal of the scientific management engin- self-equilibrating markets. Such assumptions are
eers, such as Frederick Taylor, was to improve called into question by the accumulating evi-
the efficiency and utilisation of labour and dence ( s o m e of which will be reviewed in this
materials" (Johnson & Kaplan, 1987, p. 10). This paper) that new technologies and orgamsa-
ts demonstrably partial, since Taylor himself tional forms are partly responses to problems of
stated that his system was a means of elimin- capital accumulation and labour control. Clear-
ating "systematic soldiering" (group output ly, a comprehenstve historical analysis of
restriction) on the part of the workforce management accounting along these lines is
(Taylor, 1903). More generally, the notion that beyond the remit of a single paper. What
searches for efficiency under the pressure of follows, therefore, ts an attempt to sketch out
competitive markets were the primary drtve the form of such a history, focusing upon h o w
behind the development of capitalistic organ- management accounting has developed in rela-
tsations and scientific management is tughly tion to the control of labour within increasingly
contenttous and has been strongly disputed by concentrated p r o d u c e r markets m North
historians and radical political economtsts, e.g America. 2
M o n t g o m e r y ( 1979, 1987), Braverman (1974),
Clawson (1980), Nelson (1974). I n t e r alia, all
of these writers reject technologmal determin- A LABOUR PROCESS APPROACH TO THE
tsm and e c o n o m i c imperatives as a satisfactory DEVELOPMENT OF SYSTEMS OF
basis for explaming changes in the modes of ORGANISATION AND ACCOUNTING
management control. In contrast to the assu-
med self-equtlibrating behaviour of firms and Johnson and Kaplan analyse a perceived crisis
markets and the social harmony trnplictt m in management accounting by examining its
transaction cost research, they describe h o w historical origins In a notable advance on the
social conflicts w e r e e m b e d d e d m histormal '~who did what first?" school of accounting
changes and h o w instttutions such as the state history (see Flamholz's 1983 c o m m e n t s on
and trades unions helped to shape controls at Johnson's earher work), they relate the early
the point of production. Transaction cost development of cost accounting to the evolu-
theory tends to deflect attention from such tton of orgamsational forms w h i c h took place in
tssues rather than shed light on them American industry between 1850 and 1930.
It also tends to portray technological change This development is analysed wtthin the frame-

2 Tilts paper ts dtrected at the issues rinsed m the opemng paragraph, namely how management accounting developments
have been related to the control of labour The paper dehberately concentrates upon manual labour m manufacturing
orgamsattons It does not exanune how costing was assoctated wtth the growth of management and tts control as a labour
process, or the role of accountingknowledgeand business schoolsm reproducmg and legttamatingmanagement The paper
also concentrates almost exelustvely on North Amertcanbusiness history It does not seek to deny that, Inter alia, due to
different cultures, state acttons and patterns of class forrnatton, accounting developments elsewhere (e g. Germany,Japan
and the U IC) have been stgndicanflydifferent Some dtscusston of these points can be found m Hopper (1990)
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOUR AND CONGLOMERATES 413

w o r k o f transaction cost theory (Williamson, been studied by labour historians, and these
1970, 1975) and is depicted as occurring in a studies provide an illuminating commentary on
n u m b e r of stages, each of which is illustrated Johnson and Kaplan's analysis.
from Johnson's studies of early organisations Essentially, the Lyman Mills accounting
and accounting systems. records consisted of records of operatives'
wages and other prime costs of production
The initial proletarianisation o f the labour which w e r e inspected weekly by the treasurer
force at company headquarters in Boston. Johnson
The first stage o f management accounting and Kaplan's interpretation is that this informa-
d e v e l o p m e n t described by Johnson and Kaplan, tion was used by the management to monitor
came with the end of putting out and other and compare the performance o f individuals
forms o f subcontracting in single-product firms. and of groups of workers with the object of
In their account, the driving force behind this increasing efficiency
d e v e l o p m e n t was a belief on the part of In contrast to Johnson and Kaplan's
entrepreneurs that gains in profitability could approach, writings in the labour process tradi-
be obtained by increasing the efficiency of the tion emphasise that much of the gain in
conversion process and from improvements in profitabfltty from the early factory organisation
labour productivity. In pursuit of these aims, of production came, not from increases in the
systems o f accounting for prime costs w e r e technical efficiency of the conversion process,
developed. These enabled owners and entre- but from the ability of owners/entrepreneurs to
preneurs to monitor and compare the perfor- mtensify labour through close disciplinary
mance of workers and their supervisors, to control and to extend the working day
encourage workers to achieve "company goals" (Clawson, 1980) Operatives in the Boston
and to root out "slack behaviour". In these Associates' factories, for example, worked 12
single activity organisations there was no hours per day, six days per week (Dublin, 1979,
d e v e l o p m e n t o f measures of efficiency with p 59), throughout the labour intensification
which capital was employed, since there w e r e process to be described presently. Similarly,
no decisions to be made on alternative uses of Marglin (1974), has noted that many early
capital. In any case, the rapid expansion of English factories employed precisely the same
American markets from 1820 to 1870 ensured production technology as the handicraft system
that a control o f operating costs was sufficmnt which they displaced, indicating that their
to achieve satisfactory long-run returns on initial competitive advantage stemmed not
capttal. from economies of scale, technological innova-
The key case-study used by Johnson and tion or some conjectural reduction o f transac-
Kaplan to substantiate this part o f their thesis is tion costs, but from an increased enhanced
that o f the accounting system of Lyman Mills ability of owner-managers to discipline and
(Johnson & Kaplan, 1987, p. 24 ft.). This was drive labour in the factory setting (see also
one of a n u m b e r of textile factories sited in the Gordon et aL 1982, p. 58).
N e w England towns o f Waltham, Lowell and In this phase of capitalist development,
Holyoak, which w e r e o w n e d by a close-knit which Gordon et aL ( 1 9 8 2 ) call initial
group o f financiers called the "Boston proletariamsation, labour processes remained
Associates". These employers shared technolo- for the most part untransformed. In the Marxist
gical information, used c o m m o n selling agents terminology of labour process writers, labour
and managed their factories along very similar had b e c o m e formally subordinated to capital
lines. Wage rates and working rules, for ex- in the sense that workers w e r e n o w employees,
ample, w e r e identical throughout the group but there was, as yet, little real subordlination in
(Dublin, 1979). As will shortly appear, a the sense that production processes w e r e
n u m b e r o f the Boston Associates' factories have designed and controlled by employers and their
414 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

agents. The major exception, in the American therefrom are credited to mechamsation and
context, was the New England textile industry integration.
( o f which Lyman Mills was, of course, a part). The facts certainly bear a different interpre-
From the outset, this employed the mechanised tation. The accounts in question date from the
p r o d u c t i o n methods pioneered in Great Britain mid-19th century, a period w h e n the Boston
(Lazonick, 1981; G o r d o n et aL, 1982, p. 69; Associates w e r e faced with failing prices and
Burawoy, 1985). rising inventories of unsold cloth as a result of
Since the workforces of the day w e r e accus- intensified c o m p e t i u o n from England. In 1834,
t o m e d to the rhythms of agricultural produc- acting in concert, they imposed a wage cut of
tion, the ability of early factory regtmes to about 1896 in all their factories, so precipitating
increase labour productivity d e p e n d e d on a an abortive strike. In 1836, there was a similarly
harsh discipline of time and task (Thompson, unsuccessful strike against an increase tn the
1967). Partly for this reason, factory work was price of board and lodgings. By the time further
unpopular and the supply of labour frequently wage cuts w e r e imposed m 1837 and 1840, the
d e p e n d e d upon a lack of alternative sources of "Yankee farm gtrls", having alternatave means of
livelihood. Some early American textile mills, survival, were beginning to leave the mills and,
for example, recruited whole famdies from the from 1840 onwards, their place was increas-
depressed agriculture o f New England on the mgly taken by Irish tmmigrants w h o had little
so-called "Rhode Island system" (Ware, 1931; choice but to accept the worsening conditions.
p. 199). The Boston Associates, on the other The factories themselves w e r e managed by
hand, o w e d much of their success to the on-site agents w h o reported weekly to a chief
provision of company dormitories for single executive and treasurer based in Boston. Whilst
'`yankee farm girls" willing to w o r k for a short the pressure to increase production or reduce
period in order to supplement the family costs came initially from the treasurer, agents
income before returning to marriage and the had substantial autonomy as to h o w this was
land (Ware, 1931; Dublin, 1979, p. 16, Gordon done, Though there w e r e some technical
et aL, 1982, pp. 6 8 - 6 9 ) . Besides serving to process improvements, their main responses
attract labour, this system also exhibited w e r e the stretch-out (an increase in the
some of the features of "total institutions" number of machines supervised by each oper-
(Goffman, 1968), creating the conditions for a ative), the speed-up (an increase in the oper-
disciplinary regime which extended deep into ating speed of the machines) and a premium
what w o u l d nowadays be considered to be the bonus system w h e r e b y the overseer whose
workers' private lives (Gersuny, 1976). workers p r o d u c e d at least unit cost received a
Whilst Johnson and Kaplan are too cash payment which could amount to as much
c o m p e t e n t as historians to be unaware of these as $100, compared to an annual salary of $600.
features of the organisation of Lyman Mills, or Indeed this latter incentive was blamed for a
to ignore the potential of the accounting p r o n o u n c e d deterioratton in the relationships
records for increasing effort levels, their inter- b e t w e e n overseers and the "girls".
pretation is distorted by their commttment to As a result of these measures, the workload of
transaction cost theory. They write: "The early the spinners and weavers more than doubled
cost accounts of Lyman Mills also offered between 1840 and 1854 whilst wages remained
incentives and controls to mitigate slack be- substantially the same. Indeed it was the
haviour that might otherwise disstpate the exphcit policy of the Boston Manufacturing
productivity gains inherent in mechanised, Company in Waltham (and probably of other
multiprocess systems" (Johnson & Kaplan, factories in the group) to adjust piece-rates so
1987, p. 31) Thus an intensification of labour is that earmngs remained steady whilst speed-up
represented as an implicitly costless reduction and stretch-outs w e r e imposed - - quite apart
of "slack behaviour" and the productivity gains from actual reductions in real wages. The
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOUR AND CONGLOMERATES 415

records used to achieve these results w e r e labour force upon which depended their ability
those o f the paymaster, to w h o m w e r e reported to act on the labour cost information generated
monthly figures for output, days w o r k e d and by their accounting records.
earnings o f each operative (Ware, 1931, pp
230-272; Dublin, 1979, pp. 100-109). Internal contract a n d the role o f a c c o u n t i n g
It is not clear from Johnson and Kaplan's in its d e m i s e
account w h e t h e r their interpretation of the The recruitment and control of sldlled labour
uses made o f accounting information in Lyman posed special problems for the early industria-
Mills is based o n records similar to these, or on fists, especially in America w h e r e it was scarce
others. W h a t / s clear, however, is that s o m e of (Habakkuk, 1967) To some extent, the supply,
the accounting information in the Boston as with semi-skilled labour, depended on a lack
Associates' factories o f the mid-19th century o f alternatives. Some industries w e r e able to
was clearly implicated in the intensified exploi- depend on a supply of ex-handicraft workers
ration of labour with which the employers driven out of business by the emergent
responded to increased competition. capitalist enterprises ( G o r d o n et aL, 1982, p.
O n c e it is established that accounting inform- 57). In the particular case of the New England
ation is used to redistribute the rewards from textile industry, w h e r e the production process
p r o d u c t i v e labour, rather than to increase the was an import or reinvention of English tech-
efficiency with which it is employed, it needs to nology (Lazonick, 1981 ), low wages in England
be seen in the c o n t e x t o f other labour process created a supply of skilled immigrant workers,
controls, since such a redistribution may well despite laws forbidding their exodus (Ware,
be resisted. For example, records which indi- 1931, p 203). For the employers, external
cate w h e r e piece-rates "should" be cut are of recruitment from these sources had the impor-
little use unless the possibility o f acting on the tant consequence that craft knowledge was
information has already b e e n established. initially possessed by the workers rather than
As has already b e e n pointed out, the Boston themselves, with skills passed on by senior
Associates' factories w e r e run as a unit, with workers to their junior counterparts through
identical wage structures, conditions and lists systems of apprenticeship.
of disciplinary rules. In order to solve the With this situation, the problems of delegated
p r o b l e m of labour stability, the "girls" w e r e control began. Whilst salaried managers and
required to sign yearly contracts, with defaul- foremen existed, they w e r e not the norm. With
ters blacklisted throughout the group. Depart- Adam Smith (and like contemporary agency
ments within the factories w e r e controlled by theorists), most 19th century owner--managers
( m a l e ) overseers w h o had absolute p o w e r to believed that the security of fixed salaries could
hire, fire and discipline the workers. Gersuny's only lead to "idleness, negligence and pro-
( 1 9 7 6 ) study o f the records of dismissals from fusion" (Smith, 1970; see also Clawson, 1980, p.
one factory in the group shows a pattern of 68). Instead, they preferred to rely on the profit
individual victimisation, sometimes for "combi- motive, in a variety of forms of internal
nation" (trade union activity), coupled with a subcontracting, some of which cast skilled
managerial c o n c e r n to establish their own craftsmen or heads of households in the role of
dominance and what they considered to be mternal contractors (Littler, 1982). Besides
p r o p e r standards of deference in the workforce, providing a clear motivation for contractors to
in the light o f the prevailing gender stereotypes extract the most out o f the labour they
o f the time. In the c o m p a n y dormitories "moral employed, the subcontracting relationship had
police" controlled out-of-work behaviour, several other advantages for employers: it
which, again, included a prohibition on "combi- largely eliminated the need for them to be
nation". By these means, the Boston Associates conversant with the production process
and their agents maintained the control o f the (important so long as craft workers still
416 TREVORHOPPER and PETERARMbiKOt~

possessed the "secret knowledge of produc- directly. According to a c o n t e m p o r a r y source,


tion"), it spread risk, and it avoided large what "looked like a very innocent and un-
administrative overheads, partly by acting "as a important c h a n g e . . , was really the thin edge of
substitute for accounting" (Littler, 1982, p. 6 7 ) the w e d g e which was ultimately to deprive the
T h o u g h internal contract began to disappear contractor of his profits" (Clawson, 1980, p.
in the latter half of the 19th century, tt cannot 117). Of necessity, the direct p a y m e n t of wages
b e assumed that thts was a c o n s e q u e n c e of the called for the creation of records, and these also
e c o n o m i c inefficiencies of an archaic system or enabled the c o m p a n y to obtain information on
a technological conservatism rooted in a mono- the wage cost of each item of p r o d u c t i o n and so
polisation of p r o d u c t i o n knowledge by the discover which contract prices w e r e high in
workforce. Clawson ( 1 9 8 0 ) points out that relation to the contractors' costs. This informa-
m a n y of the 19th century factories run on the tion was subsequently used to renegotiate
internal contract system (such as the contract prices and so reduce the contractors'
Winchester Repeating Arms C o m p a n y ) w e r e income. Eventually, contractors b e c a m e reluc-
large, c o m p l e x and technologically progressive, tant to bid on certam jobs wtth the result that,
with m a n y examples of technologtcal inno- over time, fewer and fewer of the c o m p a n y ' s
vation instigated b y the subcontractors. In fact workers w e r e e m p l o y e d through them.
the eventual displacement of internal contrac- Johnson and Kaplan have comparatively httle
tors from Winchester Arms resulted in in- to say on internal contract. However, they do
creased costs for a n u m b e r o f years, probably locate "the scientific quest for knowledge about
because the college-trained executives w h o efficiency" ( p 4 8 ) in the c o n t e x t of metal-
replaced t h e m lacked their practical produc- working firms w h i c h w e r e originally run on this
tion know-how. system. Whilst noting that internal contracting
Clawson suggests that the real reason for the meant that the beneficiaries of effictency
displacement of the internal contractors lay in i m p r o v e m e n t s tended to be contractors and
their ostentatious displays of wealth m times of their workers rather than ownership, Johnson
prosperity. Their tendency to turn up for w o r k and Kaplan nevertheless see the motive for
in horse-drawn carriages, for example, was improved record-keeping as a "desire for closer
greatly resented b y e m p l o y e r s b o t h as visible control o v e r increasingly c o m p l e x and special-
h a e m o r r h a g e of profit and as contrary to their tsed manufacturing tasks" rather than a redis-
ideas on social rank. Thus the employers' gut trtbution of the benefits from innovation.
response to e c o n o m m d o w n t u r n was a system- According to J o h n s o n and Kaplan, moreover,
atic a t t e m p t to squeeze their contractors' the t m p r o v e m e n t in record-keeping was
profits Clawson's account of events in a accomplished by encouraging workers to re-
n u m b e r of American companies in the last cord their o w n acttvities in return for a share in
quarter of the 19th century indicates that the the gains from t m p r o v e d efficiency. By contrast,
d e v e l o p m e n t of labour cost records was inte- Litterer's study ( 1 9 6 3 ) indicates that workers
gral to this process. w e r e not trusted in this respect and that
Until the 1870s, contractors in the metal- specialist time-keepers w e r e e m p l o y e d for the
w o r k i n g industries w e r e paid according to the purpose.
contract price and the n u m b e r of units The discrepancy in these accounts is marked.
dehvered. Compantes kept no record of the For Johnson and Kaplan, accounting develop-
hours w o r k e d b y the contractors' employees, ments appear as part of a drive for efficiency. To
or of h o w m u c h and on what basis they w e r e Clawson, the immediate stimulus was a desire
pard There was therefore no c h e c k on con- to approprtate the profits of internal contrac-
tractors' profits, either overall or on particular tors, at the expense, initially at least, of
tasks. Amongst others, the Singer c o m p a n y increased costs. To Johnson and Kaplan, the
decided to change all this b y paying employees d e v e l o p m e n t of w o r k records had relatively
LObVl ACCOUNTING,LABOURAND CONGLOMERATES 417

benign c o n s e q u e n c e s for the Workforce. To tO intensify the labour process took the form of
Litterer, o n the o t h e r hand, the result was the further assaults u p o n internal subcontracting
imposition of an additional system of activity and craft labour controls. At the same time,
surveillance, in w h i c h it is not too fanciful to companies sought to p r o t e c t themselves from
see the origin o f the future expansion of competition and the p r o s p e c t of bankruptcy
supervision. The suggestion is that the creation through a sertes of mergers, culminating in the
of internal cost records marks the beginning of great m e r g e r m o v e m e n t of 1898-1902. In the
a transfer of financial knowledge from the space of twenty years, the structure of
w o r k e r to the factory owner, which not only American industry was dramatically
p e r m i t t e d rewards from innovation to flow in transformed. The small, owner-managed and
the same direction, but also provided the essentially self-financing firms of the late 19th
potential for making visible w h e r e returns century w e r e swept u p into giant conglomer-
might best b e c r e a m e d off and labour b e ates, controlled by external financiers through
intensified and disciplined pyramid holding companies and the concen-
The question of the reasons for the decline of tration of voting rights into small proportions of
internal contract is important for Johnson and the total e q m t y (Berle & Means, 1933).
Kaplan's history. As they point out, it was the In a c o m m a n d i n g synthesis of labour histor-
establishment of costing systems specifically in ies of the period, M o n t g o m e r y ( 1987, pp. 4 5 -
the metal-working industries, w h e r e internal 4 6 ) describes b o t h of the above developments
c o n t r a c t had previously b e e n dominant, which in the American iron, steel and metal-working
laid the foundation for the later d e v e l o p m e n t of industries b e t w e e n 1870 and 1930:
standard costing systems b y the American
industrial engineers. If, as is suggested by By the turn of the century, the steelmasters' quest for
Clawson's work, the establishment of these greater and more secure profits had led them not only to
early costing systems had nothing to do with integrate 'q~ackward"for every operation from the non
the efficiency of the conversion process (and, in or coal mine to the rolling mill but also to attack the
menace of workers' control in any part of those
the event, actually reduced it), but was a means operattons and ulttmately to search for ways in whtch to
of redtstributing profits, the general applica- cut the taproot of nineteenth century workers' power
bility of J o h n s o n and Kaplan's historical model by dmpossessmg the craftsmen of thetr accumulated
is t h r o w n into question. If relatively p e r m a n e n t skdl and knowledge.
changes in systems of organisation and account-
ing can b e s h o w n to o c c u r which have nothing W h e r e Johnson and Kaplan follow the transac-
to d o with gains in efficiency ( o r reductions in tion costs o r t h o d o x y in arguing that the
transaction costs), it follows that the latter appearance of vertically integrated companies
cannot b e a sufficient explanation of the former. resulted from entrepreneurial perceptions of
possible efficiency gains, M o n t g o m e r y ( 1987, p.
Scientific Management and the 179) points out that it is difficult to point to
homogenisation of labour cost savings for the large metal.fabricating
The s e c o n d major phase of m a n a g e m e n t firms, since these enjoyed few e c o n o m i e s of
accounting d e v e l o p m e n t o c c u r r e d roughly be- scale, if any. Similarly, whilst Wells ( 1 9 7 8 )
t w e e n 1870 and 1920, as firms sought to concurs with Johnson and Kaplan that develop-
maintain profitability through a sertes of eco- ments in cost accounting w e r e closely associ-
n o m i c recessions. The period was also charac- ated with the efficiency m o v e m e n t centred on
terised b y intensified c o m p e t i t i o n m conse- the American Society of Mechanical Engineers,
q u e n c e of the geographical expansion of mar- he explicitly denies their p r e s u m e d imperative
kets, following the creation of a national rail of effictency as a cause, noting that, "Contrary
n e t w o r k offering c h e a p freight rates to the c o m m o n view that competition provided
Ftrms r e s p o n d e d in t w o basic ways. Attempts the stimulus to the introduction of costing
418 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

systems, a notable feature of the American social relations of production. The expansion of
mechanical engineers was a lack of the "foreman's empire" (Gordon et aL, 1982, p.
competition" (Wells, 1978, p 51). In parallel 135) created two such problems: that of how
with the theme of this paper Wells goes on to the foremen were to control the work of skilled
note that by the 1920s "With the advent of craftsmen, and that of how employers and their
efficiency experts, the emphasis [of costing senior managers were to monitor and control
systems] shifted to control" (Wells, 1978, p. the activities of the foremen themselves. In
53) both cases, the "solution" involved develop-
The increases in the size and complexity of ments in cost and management accounting.
industrial organisations following the merger The problem of controlling the "foreman's
movement, and employers' efforts to develop empire" grew quickly Partly because of the
systematic means of labour control, created a detailed controls of the labour process de-
need for complex managerial hierarchies to manded by the new methods of management
administer the paper bureaucracy which in- (to be discussed presently), the number of
creasingly replicated and controlled the foremen in manufacturing industry increased
productive processes (Braverman, 1974). How- by more than 300% between 1900 and 1920,
ever, these systems did not appear overnight. whilst total employment increased by only
Initially the labour process was managed 96%. At the beginning of the period, moreover,
through the agency of foremen, and efforts at foremen exercised virtually unlimited authority
intensification were relatively unsystematic. within the shop, controlling the administration
Later, however, this aspect of the foreman's role of payment systems as well as possessing the
was increasingly taken over by the industrial unfettered right to hire, fire and promote
engineers, who began to undermine craft workers (Gordon et aL, 1982, pp. 135-137).
controls through process redesign and the These wide and arbitrary powers were resented
creation of effort standards under the slogan of by workers and were a significant source of
"Scientific Management" These formalised disputes.
production methods and effort (cost) standards Part of the employers' response was a gradual
were to play a crucial role in the developing transfer of many of the foreman's functions to
bureaucratisation of industrial organisation centralised staff departments as the continued
(Littler, 1982). increase in the size of companies made these
economically feasible. Personnel offices took
The role o f accounting information in over payment systems and the hiring and firing
supplementing the control o f the labour of labour, whilst rate-fixers and quality control
process by foremen inspectors appeared on the shop floor (Jacoby,
The destruction of internal contract left "the 1985) The other aspect of the response
employer facing the solidity of his own depended upon accounting records. As has
Ignorance about shot>floor performance" (Littler, already been pointed out, earnings and produc-
1982, p. 84). This vacuum of managerial tion records at Lyman Mills were already being
knowledge was initially filled by salaried fore- used by the 1850s to allocate bonus payments
men, employed at a fraction of the costs of the to those supervisors whose workers produced
former subcontractors, though initially wield- at the lowest unit costs. The 1915 prime cost
ing much the same powers (Clawson, 1980, p reporting system a t the E.I. DuPont de Nemours
127). Fundamental to the labour process Powder Company was similarly used to stimu-
approach to organisational history, however, late competition between mill superintendants
is the notion that "solutions" to the organ- to produce a t the lowest direct cost (Johnson,
isational problems of capital accumulation 1975, Johnson & Kaplan, 1987, p. 72). These
inevitably generate further problems which instances indicate that the current concerns of
derive ultimately from contradictions in the agency theory are very venerable indeed: cost
COSTACCOUNTING,LABOURAND CONGLOMERATES 419

data seem to have been used from the outset to The element of rate-cutting stemmed from the
create a framework of monitoring informatton Fact that production over a basic level was paid
with the object o f containing the wide powers at a progressively lower rate. Eventually this
then delegated to foremen and superintendents system also stimulated opposition and output
by aligning their interests with those o f their restriction on the part of the workforce (Littler,
employers. 1982, p 84)
All of these systems failed as means of
Standard cost systons and the control o f craft combatting output restriction for one simple
labour reason: that the piece-rates and time allowances
Whilst historical costing systems, backed up themselves already contained an element of
by the disciplinary powers o f foremen, might output restriction because they could only be
suffice to speed up semi-skilled labour pro- set on the basis of observation, judgement or
cesses, the obstacles to the intensification of past experience. In two respects, however, the
labour posed by the craft control of skilled experiments with piece-rates laid the founda-
work w e r e of a different order. Ultimately, of tions for the future development o f Scmntific
course, they acted as the catalyst for funda- Management: they clarified the need for
mental changes in the nature o f capitahst management to understand and take control of
control o f the labour process. the labour process in order to speed it up,
In the first experiments, from the 1880s rather than relying on generalised economic
onwards, p i e c e w o r k began to supplant the time pressure, and they stimulated the creation of an
rates previously Favoured by internal contrac- infrastructure of systematic record-keeping on
tors (Clawson, 1980, p. 168; Littler, 1982, p. the activities o f the workforce (Clawson, 1980,
82), o n the supposition that a general economic p. 187).
incentive to increase output could bypass the The outlines of the "revolution in manage-
p r o b l e m o f detailed labour process controls. ment" built on these foundations by F. W.
In practice, however, managements invariably Taylor and other American industrial engineers
u n d e r m i n e d their o w n logic of incentives by are too familiar to need detailed rehearsal here.
cutting rates w h e n e v e r workers' earnings rose Because "Both the cost and intractability of
to a level which they considered unacceptable skilled labor posed special challenges to the
This tactic caused many industrial disputes owners of metal working firms", it was these
until workers learnt to defend themselves which provided the crucial "laboratory" for the
against rate cutting by restricting output (a original development o f Scientific Management
practice recognised as "systematic soldiering" by the American Society of Mechanical Engi-
by Taylor, but attributed to a "logic of senti- neers (Montgomery, 1987, p. 179), which both
ments" r o o t e d in anthropological mysteries m Johnson & Kaplan ( 1 9 8 7 ) and Wells ( 1 9 7 8 )
the supposedly m o r e sophisticated Hawthorne recognise as central to cost accounting
studies o f the 1920s (Rose, 1979)). For these developments.
reasons, the simple replacement of time-rates The means of removing the obstacle to
by piece-rates p r o v e d self-defeating. control presented by craft skills d e p e n d e d upon
From the 1890s until the First World War, a "homogenlsation o f labour" ( G o r d o n et aL,
time-saved bonus systems enjoyed a vogue with 1982) in which craft labour processes w e r e
employers in the British engineering industry, redesigned, fragmented and simplified so that
since these systems incorporated a kind of skill levels w e r e reduced and the mental
automatic and concealed rate-cutting. A bastc aspects of production incorporated mto
wage was guaranteed for a level o f productton management (Braverman, 1974). Technological
corresponding to pre-set time allowances, be- developments w e r e involved in this process as
y o n d which bonuses w e r e payable in propor- well as the mere redesign of labour processes.
tion to the "time saved" over these allowances G o r d o n et aL (1982, p. 115) give examples of
420 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMS'FRONG

technological changes in the metal-working costing systems of the Lyman Mill type (e.g.
industries which w e r e aimed at breaking the Garner, 1976). The labour process perspective
p o w e r of highly-paid and troublesome craft considerably illuminates such questions: whilst
workers rather than "quantitative reductions m historical cost systems permitted detailed and,
unit factor costs in the short run" (see also in prmciple, timely monitoring of performance,
Bruland, 1982, for British examples) and could well have been developed into full-
Like Taylor himself, Johnson and Kaplan blown systems of variance reportmg on the
represent Scientific Management as a search for basis of standards derived from experience, true
efficiencies. Whilst labour process writers are standard costs are based on the engineering
willing to c o n c e d e the positive contribution of redesign and analysis of the labour process, and
trained mechantcal engineers in this respect so are invulnerable to the influence o f the
(e.g Clawson, 1980, p. 237), it is important to workforce. It is this critical difference, a
recall that Taylor also saw his system as an difference in the source of standards rather than
assault upon "systematic soldiering", that is, the m accounting procedures, which has made
restriction of o u t p u t by skilled craftsmen based them such an effective instrument of manage-
on the m o n o p o l y of production know-how ment control and the intensification of labour
which they had hitherto possessed. Once "All
possible brain w o r k [was] removed from the Management accounting homogenised
shop and centred in the planning or laying-out labour a n d a n t i - u n i o n i s m in the 1920s
department" (Taylor, 1903), it became possible During the merger wave at the end of the
to take control of the pace of work m a manner 19th century, vertically integrated organ-
which had b e e n inconceivable under the isations began to appear, which incorpor-
reg~ne of craft control. Moreover, the clatm ated purchasing, transport and distribution
that effort standards could be "scientifically" within the same organisation as manufacturing.
determined, h o w e v e r nonsensical to the philo- This development was driven by the realisation
sophically inclined, provided a potent ideologi- of entrepreneurs that profits could be increased
cal warrant for the speed-up (Clawson, 1980, p by securing reliable supplies of raw materials
236). From the perspecttve of labour process and stable markets for mass production pro-
theory, the key feature of Scientific Manage- cesses, by economies of scale, and by acqui-
ment was not the increases in technical effic- sition of the profits of formerly independent
iency, but the creation of deskiUed and suppliers of materials and the commissions of
fragmented labour dependent upon the pro- former selling agents. In their early form, these
duction engineering and control n o w in- organisations developed functional structures
c o r p o r a t e d into management. Both to Marx and which enabled the experttse of specialist mana-
to Braverman (1974), thts real subordmation of gers to be brought to bear on each aspect of
labour to capital was one of the defining company operations. At this stage the account-
features of the fully developed capitalist mode ing measures of operational efficiency first
of p r o d u c t i o n developed in single activity organisations
As is by n o w well known, the first standard sufficed Top management, meanwhile, w e r e
cost systems w e r e closely associated with the faced with two new tasks which had not existed
scientific Management m o v e m e n t (Wells, 1977, in single-activity organisations: that of ensuring
1978; Epstein, 1978). However, the labour that the activities of specialist managers w e r e
process control and intensification aspects of aligned with the objective of company profit-
Scientific Management are not squarely recog- abihty and that of devising the optimum pattern
nised in most accounting histories and, in of investment of company resources These
consequence, these are not always clear on the problems ~ notably as encountered in the
respects in which standard cost systems rep- General Motors inventory crisis of 1920
resented an "advance" on detailed historical stimulated new developments in organisational
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOUR AND CONGLOMERATES 421

forms and management accounting technique. (cf. Chandler & Daems, 1979). The emphasis in
In the pioneering multidtvisional organisations, thLs account is on the control of operational
the problems of performance monitoring and management, firstly by the subjection of their
investment allocation w e r e tackled by the use claims on corporate investment resources to an
o f budgets to control and balance the internal apparently rational comparative appraisal, and
flow o f resources and by use of such measures secondly by the creation of measures of their
as return-on-investment (ILO.I.) and stock performance. Leaving to one side the consider-
turnover ratio to compare the productivity of able literature on the consequences of d~vi-
capital invested in different activities, as well as sional performance measures for intermanagerial
to measure the performance of their managers conflict and other org~dsational "dysfunctions",
(Chandler & Daems, 1979). In a kind of it is noticeable that the workforce simply does
bureaucratised revival of internal contract, not enter into Johnson and Kaplan's conception
these forms o f organisation linked managers' of the role of the new management accounting
career interests to accounting measures of techmques. The result is that they are insensi-
performance, so permitting a "decentralised tive to the historical specificity of the condv
centralisation" (Pfeffer, 1978), in which tions under which the new techniques emerged,
managerial initiative could be contained within and which may well have contributed to their
the imperative o f capital accumulatton. At the success.
same time, the proliferating flows of financial According to Gordon e t al. (1982), the years
information, along with the managerial records 1890 to 1920, which roughly correspond to the
o f performance and standards already gener- accounting innovations by Dupont and General
ated by industrial engineering, resulted in vast Motors, also saw the consolidation of a pattern
shadow paper organisations which mirrored o f employment which contemporary observers
the productive process, thus rendering it visible called the "drive system". This consisted of
and accessible to managerial intervention, but three dimensions: the reorganisation of work,
which, at the same time, called for expanded facilitated by mechanisation and job restruc-
cadres of managerial, technical and clertcal turing; increased plant size, which increased
labour which created control problems of their the impersonality o f work; and the continuing
OWn. expansion of the foreman's role. The major
Johnson and Kaplan describe these processes consequence for the workforce was the re-
through a discussion of the accounting inno- placement of locally specialised skills and
vations o f Dupont and General Motors from experience by mass labour markets in which
about 1900 to 1925. The nature of these the individual semi-skilled worker was highly
accounting innovations is n o w widely known vulnerable to substitution. From the outset, the
through the researches of business historians consequent threat represented by the "reserve
such as Chandler (1966, 1977), Dale ( 1 9 6 0 ) army of labour" was reinforced by employer
and Johnson himself (1975), and there can be campaigns to "extirpate unionism root and
no serious doubt that they w e r e crucial to the branch from the United States" ( G o r d o n e t aL,
success o f the giant, and otherwise unwieldly, 1982; see also Bendix, 1956, on the contem-
conglomerates o f m o n o p o l y capitalism. What is porary "ideology of the open shop"). Tactics
o p e n to dispute is the precise nature of their included the violent harassment and depor-
contribution. Johnson and Kaplan take the tation of trade union activists and the sponsor-
conventional line that accounting measures of ship of company "unions".
the performance o f operating units provided a The success of these campaigns varied with
rational basis for the allocation of corporate economic conditions. During the labour short-
investment resources, and also served to align ages of the First World War, craft unions, in
the interests o f middle management to those of particular, had achieved significant gains, partly
corporate management and capital ownership on the basis of the state's need to obtain the co-
422 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

operation of organised labour. By the mid- achieved, there was little s c o p e for corrective
1920s, however, trade union strength, as action either by compensating cuts m fixed
indexed b y strike activity and m e m b e r s h i p capital investment, since this had already b e e n
statistics, was at a low ebb. Under these determined, or through price increases, since
conditions, there was little trade union resis- the industry tradition was to hold prices
tance to w h a t o n e c o n t e m p o r a r y c o m m e n t a t o r throughout the model year. In any case, Sloan
called "fluctuating labour requirements", whilst believed that increasing prices at a time of
a n o t h e r o b s e r v e d that "physical output per falling d e m a n d would have the effect of de-
w o r k e r is e x t r e m e l y flexible and u n d e r favour- creasing revenue (Sloan, 1986, p 147). Nor was
able conditions can b e quickly and substantially it possible to achieve targets by arbitrary
increased" ( G o r d o n et al., 1982, p. 163). This manipulations of overhead costs, a m o d e r n
was the general state of the balance of advan- practice m u c h excoriated by Johnson and
tage b e t w e e n labour and capital at the time of Kaplan, since factory overhead was applied at a
the introduction of General Motors' pioneering fixed rate to all units produced. The system
m a n a g e m e n t accounting system. therefore encouraged divisional managers to
As outlined b y Johnson & Kaplan (1987, p. keep close control of inventories and to
102), this centred on the calculation of respond quickly to adverse changes in the
"standard prices" w h i c h w o u l d ensure a 20% competitive e n v i r o n m e n t or seasonal down-
return on capital for each p r o d u c t division at turns in d e m a n d b y reducing direct costs.
80% capacity. Fixed capital investment for each Johnson and Kaplan make it clear that the
diviston was adjusted so that the yearly volume system was used to provide a very positive
planned o n the basis of sales forecasts could be motivation in this respect: "[the data] enabled
achieved at an average 80% capacity. Selling top m a n a g e m e n t to swiftly r e m o v e a divisional
prices in the industry w e r e traditionally fixed manager w h o failed to perform as expected.
for a year in advance and w e r e largely dictated Obviously, such a reporting system put enor-
b y p r o d u c t markets. If the p r o p o s e d selling molls pressure on the division manager to
prices fell b e l o w the standard prices needed to r e m o v e slack and inefficiency at all levels
maintain 20% IZO.I., divisional managers w e r e within his division" (Johnson & Kaplan, 1987,
e x p e c t e d to r e d u c e p r o j e c t e d operating costs. p. 116). Again, however, Johnson and Kaplan
Similarly, if sales forecasts ( b y corporate see the situation through the distorting flame-
m a n a g e m e n t rather than the divisional mana- w o r k of transaction cost theory: the real-life
gers themselves in the mature system) mch- consequences for the workforce w e r e seasonal
cated that plant w o u l d run b e l o w 80% capacity, lay-offs and speed-ups of the production lines,
operating costs w o u l d again need to be reduced b o t h of w h i c h practices w e r e notorious
to compensate. throughout the American m o t o r industry of the
O n c e agreed, annual projections w e r e 1920s
b r o k e n d o w n into monthly forecasts according What Johnson and Kaplan d o not adequately
to past e x p e r i e n c e of seasonal sales fluctuations stress is that the American m o t o r industry of
These forecasts specifically included budgets the 1920s, besides being subject to the normal
for dtrect p r o d u c t i o n costs and earnings. Moni- instabilities of d e m a n d in a capitalist economy,
toring of p e r f o r m a n c e against targets was on a was highly seasonal, partly due to the employ-
m o n t h l y basis ( o r daily, in the case of s o m e ers' reliance on an annual spring model change
items), with an early form of flexible budgeting to stimulate sales. Douglas & Director (1931,
used to isolate cost variations which w e r e due pp. 75, 7 7 ) give the following figures for the
solely to short-term output fluctuations from seasonal variations in e m p l o y m e n t for the
"genuine" variations in p r o d u c t i o n costs. If, industry as a whole:
during the planning year, there w e r e signs that 1923 - - 50%
the target return-on-investment would not be 1924 - - 21%
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOUR AND CONGLOMERATES 423

1925- 19% Whilst the instability of 1920s' American


1926- 11% product markets certainly existed prior to
1927- 11% General Motors' accounting system, the latter
1928- 10% was clearly instrumental m throwing the costs
1930- 24%. onto the workforce. Indeed, that was the logical
As for longer-term fluctuations in employ- consequence o f a m e t h o d of accounting cal-
ment, McPherson ( 1 9 4 0 ) gives the following culation designed to p r o t e c t the shareholders'
figures for the peaks and troughs during the 20% return-on-investment in the face o f econ-
omic fluctuation. Providing headquarters man-
193Os:
agement with d e a r and prompt signals whenever
1929 -- 448,000 falls in demand threatened divisional contribu-
1932 ~ 244,OOO tions to this target, the system, as Johnson and
1937 ~ 517,0OO Kaplan point out (1987, p. 116), was used to
1938 ~ 306,000. put great pressure on divisional managers.
What distinguished General Motors from Whilst there may have been genuine long-run
other firms w h o s e e m p l o y m e n t practices are gains in efficiency as a result, the extent and
aggregated within these figures, was that it timescale of the market fluctuations ensured
had an accounting system which enabled it that the predominant managerial response
to b e m o r e responsive to market fluctuations would take the form of lay-offs and the speed-
In o r d e r to obtain a rounded picture of up It is arguable that the promptitude and
the operation o f this management accounting accuracy of these responses at General Motors
system, therefore, it is important to appreciate was the principle achievement of the system,
the costs which w e r e imposed upon the rather than the alchemy of efficiency claimed
workforce. by Johnson and Kaplan. In view o f this, it is not
In the recession years o f 1 9 3 3 - 1 9 3 4 nearly surprising that there was widespread resent-
40% o f General Motors workers w o r k e d fewer ment of budgeting during the 1920s and 1930s,
than 29 weeks. Even after switching to an due to its association with the casualisation of
autumn model change in response to Govern- labour (Loncar, 1956).
m e n t pressure to stabilise employment, only The important implication is that the success-
85% o f General Motors workers w o r k e d for a ful operation of the 1920s' General Motors
full year (Fine, 1969, p. 60). With hindsight, accounting system d e p e n d e d on the inability of
Alfred P. Sloan himself recognised "... the organlsed labour to contest speed-ups and
hardships caused by o u r cyclical production" seasonal lay-offs. Thus the anti-unionism of
(Sloan, 1986, p. 404). General Motors during the 1920s was not a
Besides these aggregate effects, seasonal lay- quirk of labour relations policy incidental to the
offs exposed workers to the arbitrary p o w e r of serious business of corporate control: it was
foremen, since, throughout the 192Os and integral to it. Only by neutralising union
193Os, it was largely they w h o decided w h o demands for employment security and a voice
would b e laid off and re-hired. This discretion- in the determination of workloads, could
ary p o w e r was routinely used to discriminate General Motors top management secure the
against trade unionists (Fine, 1963, p. 151). For freedom to act on the information provided
workers o v e r 50, annual lay-offs also brought by their accounting system. For this reason,
the fear o f p e r m a n e n t unemployment since it the company fought tooth and nail against
was widely believed by employers (with some the United Auto Workers' campaign for nego-
justification) that m e n of this age could not tiating rights, as this gathered m o m e n t u m
keep up with the demands o f the line speeds during the late 1920s and early 1930s (Bemstein,
(Fine, 1969, pp. 56, 60; Jacoby, 1985, pp. 218, 1970, p. 515). More details will be given
235; Montgomery, 1979, p. 141). presently.
424 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

A n e w c o n t e x t f o r m a n a g e m e n t accounting: trade unionism could raise purchasing p o w e r


the era o f s e g m e n t e d labour m a r k e t s and so set the economy in motion (Montgomery,
Like internal contract, the "drive system" 1979, p 164). Both views w e r e expressed in
contained the germs of its o w n decay. Exhaust- the National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933
ing and stressful conditions of w o r k gave rise to which contained provisions on collective bar-
high labour turnover. Despite the general gaining rights, to be adjudicated b y a National
success of the employers' anti-union drives and Labor Board under Wagner's chatrmanship.
the n e w transparency of the labour process, During an intervention in the automobile
there was still hidden resistance to the intensi- industry dispute of 1934, this set up the
fication of labour based on "informal" w o r k Automobile Labor Board, which imposed limited
groups. The c o n c e r n of employers o v e r this last seniority provisions for lay-offs on the industry
p h e n o m e n o n was evidenced by the e n o r m o u s and was e m p o w e r e d to hear clatms of anti-
publicity attracted b y the Hawthorne experi- union practices The following year, u m o n
m e n t s (Baritz, 1960). Moreover, the very growth and campaigns for recognition w e r e
homogenisation of labour on winch the drive further stimulated b y the passage of the Wagner
system was based, created c o m m o n conditions Act which granted e m p l o y e r recognition of
of w o r k amongst massive workforces, and thus single unions on a majority vote (Bernstein,
s o w e d the seeds of the 193Os' upsurge of 1970, p p 1 7 2 - 1 8 1 ; J a c o b y , 1985, p. 235; Fine,
industrial unionism ( G o r d o n et a l , 1982). Most 1963, p. 251).
fundamentally o f all, the growing gap b e t w e e n The initial response o f America's giant
wages and the productivity o f labour led to a corporations to this pressure for recognition
crisis, variously diagnosed as o n e of under- from the trade union m o v e m e n t and the state
c o n s u m p t i o n or over-production, which resul- varied in detail, but not in intent. W h e r e the
ted in the depression and mass u n e m p l o y m e n t Ford Motor C o m p a n y relied upon the thugs of
of the 1930s (Bernstein, 1970, p. 19). Harry Bennet's "Service Department" to con-
O u t of this crisis there arose a n u m b e r of duct a campaign of organised violence against
mutually reinforcing developments which trade union activists, General Motors o p t e d to
changed the socio-political environment of spend just short of $1 million on espionage
budgetary control in America's core corpora- o v e r the two-year period 1 9 3 4 - 1 9 3 6 m though
tions for several decades to c o m e Labour h o w this fitted into the corporate system of
unrest increased rapidly during the early 1930s, budgetary control was not clear (Fine, 1963, p.
with the issue of trade union bargaining rights 153; Fine 1969, p. 37; Bernstein, 1970, p. 739)
( r e c o g n i t i o n ) a t the head of the agenda, closely As has already b e e n indicated, there seems to
followed b y insecurity of employment, wage have b e e n a clear connection, in the mind of
cuts and speed-ups (Bernstein, 1970, p. 172; General Motors' Alfred P. Sloan, b e t w e e n this
G o r d o n et aL, 1982). After b o t t o m i n g out at the anti-union campaign and the maintenance of
height of the slump, trade u m o n m e m b e r s h i p the freedom of actton d e m a n d e d by the Slomn-
m o r e than doubled b e t w e e n 1933 and 1941 DuPont system of decentralised financial con-
(Fine, 1969; G o r d o n et al., 1982). These trol (cf. Bernstein, 1970, p. 515):
d e v e l o p m e n t s w e r e linked with the pattern of
state intervention during the period, which We knew that some political ra(hcalsregarded unions as
appears to have b e e n driven by a conviction instruments for the attainment of power But even
that the stability of the capitalist system ttself orthodox "business umomsm" seemed to us a potenttal
was in question. W h e r e Roosevelt beheved that threat to the prerogattves of management What
recognition strikes w e r e endangering the pros- made the prospect seem especially grtmm those early
years was the persistent umon attempt to invade basic
p e c t of e c o n o m i c r e c o v e r y (Bernstein, 1970, p management prerogatives. Our rights to determine
172), Keyserling, a p r o m i n e n t atde of Senator productton schedules, to set work standards and to
Robert F. Wagner, thought that only strong chsctplme workers were all suddenly called mto
COST ACCOUNTING,LABOURAND CONGLOMERATES 425

questton Add to tlus the recurrent tendency of the w h o guaranteed 1200 hours o f w o r k p e r year to
umon to tnject ttself mto prmmg pohcy, and it ts easy to b e e x e m p t from a 3% payroll tax. This was
understand why tt seemed to some corporate oflicmlsas considered b y General Motors in 1938, but
though the unton might one day be vtrtuaUym control
of our operattons (Sloan, 1986, pp 405--406) rejected on the grounds that such a guarantee
could only b e e x t e n d e d to a minority of
Recall that General Motors' divisional budgets employees, whereas there w o u l d be union
w e r e issued in the f o r m o f " t a r g e t prices" and it pressure to extend it to all (Sloan, 1986, p.
can b e s e e n that any trade union d e m a n d with a 404). The Federal G o v e r n m e n t also persuaded
non-zero cost w o u l d be likely to appear to the automobile industry to s m o o t h d e m a n d by
Sloan as an e n c r o a c h m e n t on "pricing policy". introducing an autumn m o d e l change (Fine,
State intervention to p r o m o t e union recogni- 1969, p. 27, Jacoby, 1985, p. 236).
tion was no m o r e w e l c o m e than the unions' In summary, as the 1930s progressed,
o w n efforts. Both DuPonts and General Motors Amertca's core corporations found themselves
played a p r o m i n e n t part in the sponsorshtp of u n d e r increasing pressure to a c c o m m o d a t e to
the American Liberty League, which organised a the demands of trade umonism and to provide
declaration b y a g r o u p o f p r o m i n e n t lawyers s o m e security of e m p l o y m e n t for at least a
that the Wagner Act was unconstituttonal, thus section o f their workforces. To s o m e extent,
furnishing their paymasters with a p r e t e x t for the e c o n o m i c basis for such an a c c o m m o d a t i o n
ignoring it (Berustein, 1970, p. 515). On the already existed. Anti-trust legislation notwith-
whole, h o w e v e r , these campaigns w e r e standing, a n u m b e r of large companies had
unsuccessful: General Motors was forced to enjoyed dominant positions in their p r o d u c t
recognise the United Auto Workers in 1937 and markets from as far back as the great m e r g e r
Fords followed in 1941. Both companies accep- wave of 1895--1904. The second m e r g e r wave
ted seniority rights in lay-offs as part of the deal, o f 1 9 2 6 - 1 9 3 0 added m o r e (Nelson, 1959, p. 5).
with the additional provision at Fords that During the early 1930s, indeed, a n u m b e r of
w e e k l y h o u r s w o u l d b e r e d u c e d to 32 before employers' organisations lobbied for a
any lay.offs t o o k place. In response to the relaxation of the anti-trust laws on the grounds
changed climate o f opinion, though not as a that reduced c o m p e t i t i o n w o u l d both end over-
result o f direct union or governmental p r o d u c t i o n and enable prices, and therefore
demands, General Motors, in 1939, introduced wages, to be ratsed, so stimulating demand
a w a g e guarantee plan w h e r e b y workers with (Bernstein, 1970, p. 19). Douglas & Director
five years' seniority w h o w e r e laid off or on (1931, p. 109 ft.) saw additional connections
short.time could b o r r o w the difference be- b e t w e e n m o n o p o l y and e m p l o y m e n t stabili-
t w e e n their actual w e e k l y p a y and 24 hours' sation, in the possibilities of production plan-
worth, against their future earnings - - though tung and the avoidance of "unnecessary" style
this s c h e m e was quietly d r o p p e d in 1942, w h e n changes.
the industry was working at full capacity (Sloan, In response to demands for stabilisation, and
1986, p. 404; Jacoby, 1985, p. 248). w h e r e there was a c o n t e x t o f limited p r o d u c t
As well as encouraging union recognition, market competition, corporate welfare
the Federal G o v e r n m e n t sought to p r o m o t e the schemes k n o w n as the "American Plan" w e r e
"stabilisation" o f e m p l o y m e n t by sponsoring introduced in p r o s p e r o u s and oligopolistic
research o n the topic (e.g. Douglas & Director, mdustries such as autos, rubber, chemicals and
1931 ) and b y direct pressure on employers. In electrical machinery. For strongly u m o m s e d
an a t t e m p t to spread e m p l o y m e n t , the Natmnal workers, or those with s c a r c e skills, this
Industrial R e c o v e r y Act placed an u p p e r limit involved job security and o t h e r benefits deter-
o n the p e r m i t t e d hours of w o r k in each mined by seniority. On the o t h e r s~de of the
industry (Fine, 1963, p. 35), whilst the Social coin, these privileges w e r e p r o t e c t e d from
Security Act o f 1935 p r o v i d e d for employers e c o n o m i c fluctuations b y the e m p l o y m e n t of
426 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

flexible reserves of black and Mexican labour at w o m e n w e r e assumed to possess characteris-


the lowest w a g e grades (Montgomery, 1979, p. tics ( s u c h as unreliability and lack of ambition)
160) Whatever the arguments for stabilisation which peculiarly suited t h e m to secondary
in c o r e areas of employment, there was little sector e m p l o y m e n t (Barron & Norris, 1976).
e c o n o m i c logic in unnecessarily offering secur- For these, m a n a g e m e n t accounting systems
ity of e m p l o y m e n t or welfare benefits to which pressured managers to adjust direct
unskilled w o r k e r s w h o could readily be costs in response to market fluctuations con-
replaced from the labour market and w h o tinued to b e relevant. For processes on w h i c h
lacked the organisation to press their claims for primary sector w o r k e r s w e r e employed, this
themselves. Moreover, the costs might be particular relevance was lost, and there are
prohibitive if the workers c o n c e r n e d w e r e indications that the use m a d e of budgetary
engaged o n labour intensive processes for controls changed. The precise nature of these
w h i c h there was a fluctuating demand. changes will be discussed after a brief con-
Thus the n e w liberal approach to the control sideration o f Johnson and Kaplan's views on the
o f labour was specific to core workers m core loss of relevance o f m a n a g e m e n t accounting
corporations w h i c h possessed the market systems.
p o w e r to stabilise d e m a n d for their products
Elsewhere, the earlier drive system persisted, Relevance Lost. Johnson and Kaplan's analysis
and this, in turn, b e c a m e specific to smaller In Johnson and Kaplan's view, the third and
firms, unstable or competitive p r o d u c t markets, latest period of m a n a g e m e n t accounting history
and weakly organised labour forces. Labour has b e e n o n e of stagnation and decadence
markets thus b e c a m e segmented into primary They deplore the retreat in m o d e r n manage-
and secondary sectors (Doeringer & Piore, ment accounting systems from the unambiguous
1971). E m p l o y m e n t in the primary sector was focus on p r i m e costs w h i c h characterised the
characterised b y stability, relatively high wages, pioneering systems of DuPont and General
career structures and relatively skilled w o r k Motors. By the 1920s, the efforts of managers
(for w h i c h training, often of a company-specific and engineers to solve real-life p r o b l e m s had, in
nature, w o u l d b e provided), and b y compara- their view, p i o n e e r e d m o s t of the current
tively strong trade unions ( w h e r e these exis- techniques of m a n a g e m e n t accounting. Whilst
ted). Within limits, labour in this sector was they acknowledge some later innovations, such
treated as a valuable corporate resource, to b e as discounted cash flow, residual income and
c o n s e r v e d in the face of (short-run) e c o n o m i c m o r e refined m a n a g e m e n t controls, they argue
fluctuations. In the secondary sector, w o r k was that the teaching and practice of m a n a g e m e n t
unskilled ( o r treated as such), wages w e r e low, accounting has generally stagnated or regressed
trade unionism w e a k or non-existent and since the mid-1920s, with the result that these
e m p l o y m e n t was either unstable or explicitly are n o w out of t o u c h with the n e w competttive
o n a casual basis. Besides this basra segmen- and manufacturing environment.
tation, subsidiary patterns of differentiation This is attributed largely to the displacement
emerged. According to G o r d o n et aL (1982), of engineers b y financial accountants as the
the p r i m a r y sector b e c a m e further segmented custodians of m a n a g e m e n t accounting exper-
into an " i n d e p e n d e n t primary" sector of pro- tise. The c o n s e q u e n c e is that cost accounting
fessionals and managers and a "subordtnate has b e c o m e less relevant to managerial
primary" sector of skilled manual workers. As decision-making through its subservience to
has already b e e n hinted, the segmentation of external financial reporting. This is reflected in
labour markets, from the beginning, tended to the current emphasis u p o n inventory valuation
coincide with g e n d e r and ethnic differences. and integrated accounts and the widespread
O v e r time, these patterns b e c a m e mstituttonal- adoption of arbitrary overhead allocations with-
ised, w i t h the result that ethnic minoriues and m p r o d u c t costings. Academic accountants are
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOUR AND CONGLOMERATES 427

implicated in this state of a~irs, notably through early as 1916, the Federal Trade Commission
their adherence to over-simplified normative had sponsored the d e v e l o p m e n t o f guides to
e c o n o m i c m o d e l s divorced from practice. the i m p r o v e m e n t of cost accounting practice in
The emphasis o n these concerns in account- a n u m b e r of industries, in the belief that this
ing education has, it is alleged, p r o d u c e d a would both lessen the incidence of small
b r e e d of managers w h o "manage b y the business failure and provide a means of con-
numbers", on the basis of obsolescent cost trolling price inflation (Miranti, 1986, pp. 451,
systems w h i c h are at odds with the n e w 452). Some of the early literature on budgeting
operations management, with its stress u p o n reveals that the adoption o f budgeting in m a n y
quality, minimal set-up times and broader, American companies followed from their
longer-run p e r f o r m a n c e criteria. Johnson and involvement with g o v e r n m e n t in the two
Kaplan c o n c l u d e with a plea for the recon- World Wars, and from the debates o v e r Munici-
sideration o f detailed p r o d u c t costings through pal and Federal budgeting (Coonley, 1925;
tracer studies o f overheads as originally attemp- Theiss, 1937; Fiske, 1947). For example, Rogers
ted b y engineers It is argued that information ( 1 9 3 2 ) notes h o w budgeting and costing w e r e
t e c h n o l o g y can n o w o v e r c o m e the calculative p r o m o t e d b y joint industry and g o v e r n m e n t
c o m p l e x i t y that defeated the early efforts o f commissions on standardisation and the re-
engineers to d o this. quirement for i m p r o v e d record-keeping w h e n
As has b e e n indicated in the previous section, contracts w e r e negotiated with state bodies.
this a r g u m e n t ignores the changed context of The c o m m o n thread running through these
m a n a g e m e n t accounting systems in American state-sponsored initiatives was the use of bud-
corporations from the 1930s onwards. Because geting and cost accounting data to plan and
J o h n s o n and Kaplan do not recognise that control the rate o f return on investment.
systems o f the General Motors type were, in Having b e e n p u s h e d into budgeting b y the
part, administrative devices for matching cap- requirements of state bureaucracy, business-
acity to d e m a n d b y imposing speed-ups and lay- m e n soon recognised its potential for planning
offs o n the workforce, they are unable to o n their o w n account, as the c o m m e n t s of Vieh
appreciate the significance of changes in the (1925, p. 174) bear out:
balance o f advantage b e t w e e n labour and
m a n a g e m e n t w h i c h m a d e these courses of Until we discover practical means of overcomm8 the
action less possible. More, because they follow evils of booms and depre,sions which are inherent in
the line of the transaction costs literature in our present economic structure, years of poor business
and even unprofitable years are inevitable The
failing to acknowledge monopoly profits as a budget looks to the future with the hope of averting or,
drtving force behind acquisition and merger, they at least, o f r e d u c m 8 t h e effects o f t h e storm w h e n it
rmss its significance in creating the economic breaks.
leeway which allowed the possibility of an
accommodation with primary sector workforces. This use of budgetin 8 to anticipate and d a m p e n
Rather than assuming that budgetary controls the effects o f trade cycles on c o m p a n y profit-
w e r e driven off course by the requirements of ability is a recurring t h e m e o f its early advo-
external financial reporting= post-1920s' develop- cates. In contrast, the 1930s' advocates of
ments need to be seen in the context of the " e m p l o y m e n t stabtlisation" advocated the use
labour and capital accord in the primary sector o f budgetary forecasts to plan a steady rate o f
pi'oduction which would build u p inventories
Budgetary controls in primary sector so as to a c c o m m o d a t e seasonal variations in
employment., cost accounting f o r a labour- d e m a n d (Douglas & Director, 1931, p. 85), a
capital accord means of preserving the accord with primary
T h e r e w e r e p r e c e d e n t s for budgets to b e sector labour which b e c a m e widespread in the
used for planning rather than cost control. As years after the Second World War (Lewis et a t ,
428 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

1984). Progress appears to have b e e n uneven, COSTS of e c o n o m i c fluctuation onto smaller


however. According to Loncar (1956) the competitors (Chandler & Salsbury, 1971, p.
potential of budgets for planning was not fully 155), which, in s o m e respects, might be viewed
appreciated b y m a n y firms until they encoun- as an alternative to "smoothing" p r o d u c t i o n b y
tered matertal shortages during the war. budgetary forecasTS. As will be s h o w n in m o r e
The literature so far lacks a systematic detail presendy, the DuPont strategy was to
a c c o u n t of the use of accounting reformation in monopolise only the stable base of a seasonal
formulating policies designed to preserve the market, rather than the w h o l e o f it, in accord-
accord w i t h primary sector labour. Indeed, ance with Pierre S. DuPont's 1903 dictum that
there appears to b e a dearth of historical studies "the essence of manufacture is a full and steady
of management accounting post-1930. 3 p r o d u c t " (Chandler & Salsbury, 1971, p 93).
Clearly, however, a key policy decision in This d e p e n d e d o n the c o m p a n y producing at a
m o n o p o l i s e d markets is that of price The case cost lower than iTS smaller competitors.
of U.S. steel illustrates h o w cost accounting data DuPonts estimated their c o m p e t i t o r s ' costs (p.
w e r e used to formulate placing policies with 157), using this information to set prices low
the object of insulating profits from the con- enough to discourage n e w competition and the
sequences o f the a c c o m m o d a t i o n with primary expansion o f existing competitors, but not low
sector labour, from the m o m e n t this b e c a m e enough to drive the m o r e efficient of these out
necessary. T h e c o m p a n y recognised the United of business. These w e r e allowed to survive so
Steel Workers in 1937, conceding a wage that they could absorb seasonal and other peaks
increase in the process. Immediately a policy of in d e m a n d (see also Johnson & Kaplan, 1987).
building all future wage increases into the price Clearly this business strategy creates the con-
structure was instituted (Bernstem, 1970, p. ditions u n d e r which a large c o m p a n y might
417; see also Baran & Sweezy, 1966, p. 77). The offer a degree of e m p l o y m e n t security to a
aim was to maintain margins m the face of sales primary sector workforce w at the expense of
fluctuations. Cross-plant average standard costs, insecurity in its secondary-sector competitors.
assuming p r o d u c t i o n at 80% capacity, w e r e Unfortunately direct confirmation of the place
c o m p u t e d on the basts of the anticipated wage of labour relations in the DuPont strategy is
settlement for the coming year. Overhead was fragmentary, since the major historians of the
then assigned to every p r o d u c t on the c o m p a n y (Chandler & Salsbury, 1971; Johnson
"traditional" assumption that each cent per & Kaplan, 1987; Dutton, 1947) have paid little
h o u r on direct w a g e costs w o u l d add one cent attention to the workforce.
p e r ton to non-wage cosTS. The result was that Budgeting is also involved in o t h e r elements
the anticipated wage settlement was roughly of planning w h i c h relate to the a c c o m m o d a t i o n
doubled, then multiplied by a "traditional" 20 with primary sector labour. In expanding
man-hours to yield the n e w cost of a ton of steel markets, monopolistic firms which r e d u c e pro-
(Kaplan et aL, 1958, pp. 15, 1 6 ) . S i m i l a r duction costs through process innovation may
policies exist, or existed, in Alcoa and American use the p r o c e e d s to fund an increased sales
Can, the Oil Companies and DuPont (Kaplan et effort with the object of capturing the bulk of
aL, 1958, pp. 27, 150, 208, 256). the enlarged market and to c o m p e n s a t e the
The case of the latter c o m p a n y also illustrates workforce for their acceptance of the n e w
the m a n n e r in which market domtnance en- methods, rather than to c o m p e t e through prtce
ables pricing policy to be used to t h r o w the reductions (Baran & Sweezy, 1966, p. 66;

~he authors were led to speculate whether the "stagnatton" thesis of post-193Os' cost accounting owes more to the
stagnation of emptrtcal research relatmg to this pertod and to the questaons asked, rather than any real stagnation of
managerial practices assoctated wtth accounting.
COST ACCOUNTING,LABOURAND CONGLOMERATES 429

Aghetta, 1979, p. 305). The idea of preserving resources of the company consisted of m o r e
relationships by compensating the workforce than forty geographically dispersed mills, manu-
for revised working arrangements probably facturing three broad classes of product Verti-
reached its apogee in the 1948 General Motors/ cal integration consisted of the incorporation of
United Auto Workers settlement which incor- the selling function within the company, rather
porated an "escalator clause" w h e r e b y wages than relying on agents as was then the custom,
w e r e related to the cost of living, and an and of headquarters control of purchasmg"
additional " i m p r o v e m e n t clause" intended to rather than the devolution of this function to
reflect the long-term prospects for improved individual mills
productivity, even though Sloan believed that According to Johnson and Kaplan, the return-
productivity increases had little to do with the on-investment formula devised by DuPont "Is
efforts o f the workforce (Sloan, 1986, p. 397). an ideal tool for controlling, with accounting
In o r d e r to show the detailed connections numbers, any vertically integrated company's
b e t w e e n budgetary controls and primary sector operations" By providing information on the
e m p l o y m e n t practice, it would be desirable to "mternal efficiency of capital across the three
study both in the context of a single monopolis- functional departments", the system enabled
tic corporation from the 1930s onwards. At the "the Powder Company's top management to
moment, unfortunately, published material of effectively supplant capital markets m dectding
this type seems to be lackmg. However, h o w to allocate resources within the American
Johnson and Kaplan ( 1 9 8 7 ) offer a detailed explosives industry" (all quotes from Johnson
study of the accounting system of the E.I. & Kaplan, 1987, p. 84). Fascinating as is
DuPont de Nemours P o w d e r Company as it Johnson and Kaplan's case material, it scarcely
existed in 1915, and, in view o f the success of bears this interpretation.
this system, it is not unreasonable to suppose The DuPont company was formed during the
that it continued unchanged in essentials for great American merger wave of the turn o f the
some decades thereafter. As for the company's century, during which "almost one-half of firm
e m p l o y m e n t practices, these have not been disappearances, and seven-tenths of merger
extensively studied, possibly because DuPonts capitalisations w e r e accounted for by mergers
have n e v e r e x p e r i e n c e d large.scale industrial that gained a leading position in the market"
conflict. Nevertheless, the studms of Weber (Nelson, 1959, pp. 102, 103). By 1907, the
( 1 9 5 9 ) and Rezler ( 1 9 6 3 ) enable at least the company controlled between 64% and 100%
outlines o f the company's labour relations o f the entire American market for the various
policies to b e discerned. Despite its limitations, types of explosive. An anti-trust action of 1911
this evidence gives some indication of h o w the resulted in a division of the corporation mto
use o f accounting systems for prtcing pohcy three parts, but DuPonts still dommated the
and planning related to welfarism as an aspect p o w d e r business and continued to acquire
o f labour relataons policy in the monopoly more companies (Laidler, 1931, p. 306) This
sector, from the 1930s onwards. was quite typical o f the period, the over-
whelming majority o f mergers at the tame w e r e
Pricing policy, planning and welfarism in hortzontal rather than vertical, with the latter
monopoly capitalism predominating only in the primary metals
Johnson and Kaplan intend the study of the industries, " ( w h i c h ) suggests that the econo-
1915 management accountang system at E.I. mies of vertical integration, upon whmh many
DuPont d e Nemours P o w d e r Company to be an merger students have placed great stress,
illustration of h o w entrepreneurs developed played a relatively small role in the merger
accounting systems to realise the profit poten- m o v e m e n t " (Nelson, 1959, pp. 102, 103).
tial o f vertical integration. The records studied The data provided by Johnson and Kaplan sit
date from a time w h e n the manufacturing more comfortably with Nelson's mterpretataon
430 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

than their own. To describe as "vertically tecting profits by explicitly building wage costs
integrated", a c o m p a n y of forty or so basically into their price structures.
s i m i l a r tlnillg, i n w h i c h vertical integration Decisions on actual prices, subject to this
consists only of the internal administration of c o m p a n y minimum, w e r e devolved, so as to
sales and the p r o d u c t i o n of one of the two take advantage of local market conditions. The
major r a w materials is a very partial view. strategy of branch sales managers was to set the
N o r does J o h n s o n and Kaplan's detailed study general level nf district prices as high as they
o f the accounting system support the notion could without encouraging the entry of n e w
that it was primarily used to decide the competitors. Individual salesmen w e r e paid on
allocation of resources b e t w e e n the three an incentive system which encouraged t h e m to
major vertically Integrated activities (purchas- maximise total revenue ( t h r o u g h adjusting
ing, manufacture and sales). Only the purchas- prices), rather than sales volume, thus insulat-
ing system seems to have b e e n used in this ing the company's manufacturing operations, to
manner, the information being used to evaluate s o m e degree, from market fluctuations. This too
the likely return from takang a financial interest could be regarded as an anticipation of the later
in raw material supplies. The sales system advocacy of seasonal price changes to smooth
appears to have b e e n used as a tool for setting d e m a n d b y the " e m p l o y m e n t stahilisation"
prices and motivating the sales force, rather m o v e m e n t of the 1930s (Douglas & Director,
than as a m e a n s o f assessing the resources to 1931, p. 85), though the aim in DuPont's case
invest in the sales effort. The manufacturing was to operate the mills at full capacity rather
system was used to c o m p a r e the performance than to stabilise e m p l o y m e n t as such.
of the p o w d e r mills, with a view to deciding The c o m p a n y ' s policy on competition exhibt-
w h i c h of these to expand and which to close ted the same priorities. Rather than attempting
during phases of rationalisation. In other words, to gain a c o m p l e t e monopoly, DuPonts toler-
the major decisions o f allocation made on the ated smaller, higher cost competitors since
basis of DuPont's accounting system seem to these served to insulate the production
have b e e n b e t w e e n similar, manufacturing facilities of the c o m p a n y from market fluctua-
establishments. Such a system ts m o r e properly tions. To this end the company's prices w e r e
described as an instrument of the rationalisa- increased to the point w h e r e it was estimated
tion of horizontally m e r g e d p r o d u c t i o n resour- that the m o r e efficient competitors could make
ces than as a means of allocating investment an adequate return, though not to the point
b e t w e e n vertically integrated activitms. w h e r e n e w c o m p e t i t i o n was encouraged
T h e detail of the sales accounting system (Chandler & Salsbury, 1971, p. 155). This
given b y J o h n s o n ( 1 9 7 5 ) suggests that it was policy can b e seen as an early version of a
used as an instrument of planning, so as to similar pricing policy (ironically) forced o n t o
c o u n t e r trade fluctuations and control competi- the American aluminium ingot and fabrication
tion. Data o n the capital invested in each m o n o p o l y Alcoa, by a district court judgement
p r o d u c t line w e r e used to calculate the aggre- of the 1930s. Alcoa w e r e forced to sell ingot to
gate desired earnings for that p r o d u c t in c o m p e t i t o r fabrication companies at prices
a c c o r d a n c e with the c o m p a n y ' s return-on- which would allow these a reasonable profit at
investment target. This earnings target was then the Alcoa prices for fabrications (Kaplan et aL,
used to calculate the mark-up per u m t at 1958, p. 30), thus providing the c o m p a n y with
normal and m a m m u m capacity, which was a warrant for setting prices on the basis of their
added to unit p r o d u c t i o n costs to ymld a smaller competitors' costs rather than their
c o m p a n y - w i d e m i n i m u m price for each pro- own.
duct. This p r o c e d u r e might be regarded as an This aspect of the DuPont m o n o p o l y pricing
early p r o t o t y p e of the later practace of policy, of course, d e p e n d e d o n keeping the
monopolistic American corporations, of pro- company's p r o d u c t i o n costs b e l o w those of its
COST ACCOUNTING,LABOURAND CONGLOMERATES 431

c o m p e t i t o r s (Chandler & Salshury, 1971, p. d e v e l o p m e n t of independent local unions


155). To this end, as is stressed b y Johnson and (plant level unions, not affiliated to national
Kaplan, the p r i m e costs o f p r o d u c t i o n w e r e organisatlons). By 1940, about 9096 of the
r e p o r t e d b o t h to mill superintendants and to DuPont workforce was organised in this fash-
c o m p a n y headquarters, so providing the f o r m e r ion, partly as a result o f the c o m p a n y ' s policy of
with p o w e r f u l incentives to minimise these bargaining only on a plant-by-plant basis. By
costs. The p o i n t h e r e is that the maintenance of 1960, however, the p r o p o r t i o n of the work-
p r o d u c t i o n costs b e l o w those of competitors force organised by independent locals had
was only o n e aspect of the DuPont c o m p a n y d r o p p e d to u n d e r 60%, with nationally organ-
strategy. The o t h e r aspects, namely the allo- ised trade unions gaining a beachhead of 6%
cation of resources b e t w e e n horizontally and the rest unorganised. Meanwhile the real
m e r g e d p r o d u c t i o n facilities and a m o n o p o l y influence of trade unionism in the c o m p a n y
pricing policy w h i c h aimed at securing a steady and thus the a c c o m m o d a t i o n with the demands
long-run r e t u r n - o n - m v e s t m e n t whilst insulating of primary sector labour w c a m e about through
manufacturing operations from market fluc- the c o m p a n y ' s policy of outflanking trade
tuations, w e r e equally important and equally unionism b y r e m o v i n g the apparent need for it.
d e p e n d e d u p o n the c o m p a n y ' s internal accoun- On the basis of survey information, the
ting system. Whereas J o h n s o n and Kaplan argue m a n a g e m e n t of each plant ensured that wages
that the information relevant to the contain- w e r e at least as high as those prevailing in the
merit o f p r o d u c t i o n costs should not contain locality. In the process, a careful eye was kept
arbitrary allocations of overhead, it is clear that on the advances achieved b y trade unions. In
decisions o n pricing policy must include s o m e 1956, for example, DuPont's president stated
allocation o f overhead. To the extent that that the average wage at C o m p a n y # a n t s was
decisions o f the latter type c a m e to p r e d o m - $2.46 p e r h o u r c o m p a r e d with $2.05 p e r h o u r
inate m the m o n o p o l y sector o f the American at comparable unionised plants (Weber, 1959).
e c o n o m y f r o m the 1930s onwards, the inclu- Welfare benefits formed an important part of
sion o f o v e r h e a d allocations in p r o d u c t costings the strategy. Apart from the intrinsic welfare
( o n w h a t basis is a separate question) need not utility of stable e m p l o y m e n t , partly m a d e
b e s y m p t o m a t i c o f "relevance lost" at all. possible by the insulation o f manufacture from
To w h a t e x t e n t was DuPont's pricing policy market fluctuations through the agency of the
the i n s t r u m e n t o f an a c c o m m o d a t i o n with sales accounting system, benefits included
p r i m a r y s e c t o r labour~ As has b e e n indicated, g r o u p life insurance, accident and health insur-
the paucity o f information on labour relations at ance, pensions and a vacation plan. The inten-
the c o m p a n y m e a n s that any answer must tion was to p r o v i d e a substantial measure of
involve s o m e e l e m e n t of conjecture. It is clear e c o n o m i c security for xhe workers, at least
f r o m the w o r k o f Rezler (1963), however, that whilst they remained e m p l o y e e s of the com-
t h e r e has n e v e r b e e n a policy of a c c o m m o - pany. By the 1960s, the costs o f these welfare
dation with trade unionism as such at the p r o g r a m m e s was claimed by a c o m p a n y spokes-
DuPont company. The 1960s' philosophy o f the man to c o n s u m e 26% of the total wage bill
e m p l o y m e n t relationship remained as individ- (Rezler, 1963). In o r d e r to ensure that these
ualistic and anti-union as that of the c o m p a n y ' s welfare benefits w o u l d b e effective as a means
founders. Until the National Labor Relations Act of combating trade unionism, the c o m p a n y also
of 1935, the company, like others in the U.S. needed to ensure that trade unions could not
chemical industry, cultivated " e m p l o y e e repre- claim any of the credit. To this end, trade union
sentation plans" as a means of deflecting influence on welfare benefits was excluded b y
d e m a n d s for genuine trade unionism (Weber, deciding these issues at headquarters, whiisr
1959). Following the N e w Deal, however, these restricting bargaining to plant level. To the
served as the organisational basis for the later DuPont company, the unionisation o f any plant,
432 TREVORHOPPERand PETERARMSTRONG

even by an independent local, represented a labour-intensive processes appear more costly


managerial failure, and was followed by an than they should, with consequent distortions
investigation aimed at "putting things right" m firm's manufacturmg policies. Leaving aside
The post-1940s' fall in union membership the question of h o w indirect costs should be
within the c o m p a n y was testimony to the allocated, it can be argued that present practice
success of these measures fits well with another feature of core corpora-
Thus, from the time trade unionism became a tions m the era of labour segmentation. As
force to be reckoned with in the U.S. chemical noted above, a segmentation of labour markets
industry m say from the 1930s onwards has taken place w i t h i n some of these, with
(Weber, 1959) - - the determination of wages primary and secondary sector conditions coin-
and benefit levels within the DuPont company ciding roughly with capital and labour-intensive
started from the requirements of labour policy, processes On the whole, workers on m o d e r n
rather than those of p r o d u c t markets. Whilst labour-intensive processes tend to be unskilled
unit labour costs were mininused through (or defined as such), are easily substitutable
productivity increases (see Rezler, 1963, p. from external labour markets and, in conse-
189, for the 1950s' record in this respect), quence, are weakly unionised. The bargainmg
wage rates and benefits w e r e set on the basis of position of workers on capital-intensive pro-
what was required to sustain the accommo- cesses, on the other hand, is much stronger,
dation with labour on which the anti-union either because of their extensive training or
policy depended. Assuming that the sales because of their responsibility for expensive
accounting system remained essentially stmilar plant. In consequence the latter are less
to that of 1915, c o m p a n y minimum prices vulnerable to managerial attempts to intensify
could then be set, within semi-monopolised their labour and downgrade their employment
markets, so as to maintain the planned level of conditions (Rubery, 1978; Armstrong, 1982).
return-on-investment. In this situation, there may be a lot of
What this evidence indicates is that, in the capitalistic sense in incorrect allocations of
DuPont c o m p a n y from the 1930s onwards, costs w h i c h t h r o w the pressure to minimise
there was a m o n o p o l y pricing policy, based dtrect costs disproportionately on the managers
u p o n the sales accounting system, which of labour-intensive processes - - for these are
c o v e r e d the costs o f a welfarist employment where the resistance of labour to further
strategy and w h i c h insulated the manufacturing intensification and casualisation is likely to be at
function from market fluctuations, with a conse- its weakest. Information on the true costs of
q u e n t stabilisation of employment levels. capttal-intensive process, on the other hand,
Whilst the stabilisation of employment may may be relatively useless, since there may be
have been a by-product of a p o h c y destgned in little scope for the reduction of costs by
the first instance to maximise plant utilisatton, technical means in an up-and-running system
and whilst the overt aim of the employment and primary sector labour, in any case, is likely
strategy may have been the excluston of trade to be highly resistant to any attempt at
unionism rather than welfarism for tts own sake, intensification.
the resultant e m p l o y m e n t policy still adds up to In other words, ff cost reformation is regar-
one of r a p p r o c h e m e n t voth primary sector ded prtmarily as a means of directing effort,
labour. rather than as a representation of reality, it can
be argued that the distortions of contemporary
Overhead allocation a n d the targetmg o f cost accounting systems serve to focus that of
secondary sector labour costs managers precisely w h e r e it is most likely to
J o h n s o n and Kaplan argue that the practice of ymld results. True to their realist conception of
allocating redirect costs on the basis of dtrect cost information as a basis for rational econo-
labour costs is arbitrary and tends to make mtc deciston-making, however, Johnson and
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOURAND CONGLOMERATES 433

Kaplan argue that overestimates of the true ship b e t w e e n systems of accounting informa-
costs o f labour intensive operations m a y lead tion and phases in the evolution of capitalist
managers to abandon these unnecessarily in the control of the labour process. Systems of
face o f overseas competition. Whilst this m a y control b o t h entail costs and p r o v o k e charac-
b e true, it is equally possible tlmt the threat of teristic forms of resistance which, under com-
doing so m a y enable these same managers to petitive conditions, r e n d e r them increasingly
drive s e c o n d a r y s e c t o r labour costs even l o w e r ineffective as means of capital accumulation..
than they really n e e d to b e in o r d e r to m e e t the These contradictions build into crises o f con-
competition. W h e r e initiatives of this type are trol, especially in times of e c o n o m i c recession,
successful, c o r p o r a t e m a n a g e m e n t cannot b e and this leads to a search for n e w systems of
e x p e c t e d to b e greatly c o n c e r n e d if the in- controlling the labour process, either directly
formation o n w h i c h they are based is inaccu- or through its immediate management. This
rate, or if the c o n s e q u e n t increase in overall p a p e r has sought to establish that s o m e o f the
profit ts incorrectly attributed to capital-inten- key phases of innovation in cost and manage-
sive operations. As for the effect on p r o d u c t m e n t accounting can be understood as part of
pricing policy, given the relative absence of this search for n e w methods o f control.
c o m p e t i t i o n in m a n y American p r o d u c t Thus d e v e l o p m e n t s in accounting for direct
markets b e t w e e n a b o u t 1930 and 1960, finely- labour costs w e r e implicated b o t h in the
t u n e d p r o d u c t costs for strategic decision- employers' liquidation of internal contract and
making p u r p o s e s m a y have b e e n a secondary in the curbing and focusing of the p o w e r of the
consideration in p r i m a r y sector corporations. salaried f o r e m e n w h o replaced them. Standard
O f course, this situation has changed with the costing systems w e r e p i o n e e r e d as an aspect of
rapid g r o w t h of Japanese and o t h e r Far-Eastern the fragmentation and deskilling o f craft labour,
competition, and m u c h of the present-day which had hitherto resisted employers'
relevance o f Relevance Lost derives precisely attempts at intensification through p i e c e w o r k
from that fact. p a y m e n t systems. O n c e the American industrial
engineers had gained control o v e r working
methods, it b e c a m e possible for t h e m to make
CONCLUSION AND POSTSCRIPT: SOCIAL "scientific" decisions on the p a c e of work, and
TRANSFORMATION AND COST to issue these in the form o f standard costs.
ACCOUNTING TODAY As organisations g r e w in size and complexity,
the p r o b l e m of securing middle m a n a g e m e n t
Relevance Lost seeks to inform current c o m m i t m e n t to the demands of capital owner-
a c c o u n t i n g p r o b l e m s through historical analy. ship for secure dividends was addressed b y the
sis. Whilst the i m p o r t a n c e o f this is undeniable, d e v e l o p m e n t o f the return-on-investment
it is questionable w h e t h e r transaction cost measure. A re.examination o f the General
theory is an adequate theoretical tool for the Motors case r e p o r t e d b y Johnson and Kaplan
purpose. indicates that the effectiveness of this measure
The intention o f this p a p e r has b e e n to depended, at least in part, on the "drive system"
establish that there is a p r i m a - f a d e case for of e m p l o y m e n t and anti-union campaigns
considering accounting d e v e l o p m e n t s in the which secured the freedom of middle managers
light o f labour process histories of capitahst to t h r o w the costs of e c o n o m i c fluctuation and
organisation. The potential of this b o d y of w o r k recession directly o n t o the worlcforce.
for accounting research has b e e n argued else- Subsequently, the drive system ran into, and
w h e r e ( H o p p e r et aL, 1986; H o p p e r et aL, partially created, the American recession of the
1987). 1930s, from w h i c h there e m e r g e d a resurgent
Following G o r d o n et aL (1982), the p a p e r labour m o v e m e n t and a government committed
has sought to establish that there is a relation- to s o m e measure o f legislative support for trade
434 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

unionism and e m p l o y m e n t stability. In these dinate primary sector of skilled manual workers
circumstances, the relevance of the accounting are increasingly u n d e r attaclc Anti-union drives
systems o f the 1920s was indeed lost. Manage- and threats o f plant closure have enabled
merits b e c a m e less able to a c t on accounting employers to claw back previous trade union
information w h i c h told t h e m where, and by gains on wages and e m p l o y m e n t security.
h o w much, to cut direct labour costs. Instead, Edwards (1979, p. 157) argues that the accord
large corporations, aided by the m o n o p o l y with subordinate primary sector labour c a m e
positions w h i c h they increasingly enjoyed, u n d e r pressure in the early 1970s w h e n the oil
b e g a n to e m p l o y budgets for the very different crisis precipitated a series of e c o n o m i c and
p u r p o s e of preserving an accord with their core social crises. Under these conditions, "For the
labour forces b y means of m o n o p o l y pricing firm, bureaucratic control threatens to b e c o m e
policies. J o h n s o n and Kaplan describe an early a pact with the devil thaL while offering
p r o t o t y p e of this strategy in their case study temporary respite from trouble, spells long-term
of DuPont, though the purpose there was disaster. The reason ts simple: bureaucratic
apparently to k e e p manufacturing plant fully control speeds up the process of converting the
o c c u p i e d rather than to provide stable employ- wage bill from a variable to a fixed cost."
m e n t as such. W h e n used as an instrument of For these reasons, the present may well turn
m o n o p o l y pricing policies, apportioned in- out to be a period of exploration from which
dtrect costs b e c a m e relevant in cost accounting n e w forms of control of the labour process and
systems, as o p p o s e d to the p r i m e costs relevant its immediate m a n a g e m e n t may emerge. T h e r e
to m a n a g e m e n t decisions on manufacturing are parallels with the British context, in w h i c h
methods. debates o n "Japanisation" (IndustrtalRelations
In the phase o f capitalist d e v e l o p m e n t des- Journal, 1988) and "flexibility" (Pollert, 1991),
cribed b y G o r d o n et aL ( 1 9 8 2 ) as one of b o t h tacitly predicated u p o n the destruction of
"segmentation", this a c c o m m o d a t i o n with lab- current trade union rights, n o w clog the
o u r was restricted to a p r i m a r y sector of core academic and practitioner journals. In this
operations within core corporations. context, current accounting research obsess-
Elsewhere, In the competitive sector o f the ions with agency theory, downscaling and
e c o n o m y and in the small suppliers to core financial rewards, far from being irrelevant to
corporations, secondary sector e m p l o y m e n t real-life p r o b l e m s as Johnson and Kaplan be-
conditions continued. Indeed, by throwing the lieve, make a good deal of sense. Agency theory,
effect o f e c o n o m i c fluctuations and d o w n t u r n m particular, offers a n e w "scientific" rattonale,
o n t o s e c o n d a r y sector firms, core corporations and s o m e practical guidance, for tying the
w e r e able, in effect, to use the insecurity and rewards of managers to their success in rolling
l o w wages o f secondary sector e m p l o y m e n t as a back the previous gains made b y labour and
m e a n s of subsidising their a c c o m m o d a t i o n with treating it as a variable and expendable cost
their o w n labour forces. (see Metcalf, 1989, on the effects of such
T h e r e are signs that the boundaries of this initiatives on macro-measures of British labour
a c c o r d are n o w being redrawn. Whilst parts of productivity). Likewise, the attraction to firms
the i n d e p e n d e n t primary sector of managers of activity costing may lie in its potential for
and professionals remain protected, the bureau- questioning the continued need for
cratic and costly apparatus of control m large bureaucracies and bureaucrats w h o s e functions
c o r e conglomerates, w h i c h had e m e r g e d in originated not in the quest for corporate
m o r e benign e c o n o m i c conditions than the past efficiency but in the search for a labour/capital
fifteen years or so, is increasingly being ques- accord and associated m o d e s of control which
tioned w i t h c o n s e q u e n c e s for the control and are n o w perceived as redundant.
e m p l o y m e n t p r o s p e c t s of lower levels of In the American context, the mroads of
management. Similarly, condttions m the subor- Japanese manufacturers have b e e n such that
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOUR AND CONGLOMERATES 435

Harvard Business School itself, so long the high the level of operating subsidiaries. Thus plant-
temple of strategic management, is now the level accommodations with primary sector
headquarters of a sect which reasserts the labour (regimes of "factory hegemony" in
centrality of manufacturing policy (Hayes & Burawoy's terminology) may be preserved
Abernathy, 1980; Skinner, 1985) The work of through the common interest of plant-level
Johnson and Kaplan, with its concern to adapt management and labour in preventing the flight
management accounting to new manufacturing of capital At the same time, these may be
technologies and Japanese systems of organisa- subjected, through financial accounting reports,
tion, needs to be seen as part of this intellectual to the discipline of internal capital markets. If
ferment. It is likely that Relevance Lost, w i t h its Burawoy is correct, and this hegemonic despoosm
resonant assertion that management accounting is indeed the map of the future, corporate-level
systems are to be judged solely by their relevance management accounting may continue to pay
to managerial decisions on man-f~cturing pro- little attention to the prime costs of production
cesses, however historically inadequate (as and regard these as an internal matter for
this paper has hopefully demonstrated), may establishment-level managements in their com-
turn out to be an important moment in the petition for investment capital If this per-
search for a leading role for accounting in new petuates the games of financial entreprenenrship
forms of control of the labour process. currently played with overhead allocation by
On the other hand, there are reasons for the managers of operating subsidiaries (and
expecting the influence of financial reporting much decried by Johnson & Kaplan), the result
on management accounting systems to increase may be a continuation of the loss of relevance
rather than decrease. Burawoy (1985) sees the to manufacturing policy of management accoun-
present intensification of internatzonal com- tancy. However, because individual companies
petition and the potential mobility of capital in may be able to evade the consequences by
multinational conglomerates as creating the astute policies of acquisition and divestment,
conditions for new regimes of corporate con- the costs may ultimately appear in the U.S.
trol in which financial reports are used to balance of payments figures rather than in the
reassert the primacy of capital accumulation at balance sheets of the companies concerned.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Aghetta, M, A Theory o f Capitalist RegulatlorL the US Experience (London New Left Books, 1979)
Armstrong, P, If tt's Only Women zt Doesn't Mauer So Much, in West, J (ed.), Work, Women and the
Labour Market pp 27--43 (London Routledge, 1982)
Armstrong, P, Changing Managerial Control Strategies The Role of Competition Between Accountancy
and Other Orgamsattonal Pfofesstons, Accountin~ Organizations a n d Society (1985) pp 129-148
Armstrong, P, The Rtse of Accounting Controls in British Capttalist Enterprtses, Accountin&
Organizations andSociety (1987) pp 415--436
Baran, P A. & Sweezy, P M, Monopoly Capital an Essay on the American Economic and Sociai Order
(New York Monthly Revtew Press, 1966)
Baritz, L., The Servants o f P o w e r ( N e w York: Wilof, 1960)
Barron, R. D & Norrts, G M, Sexual DlVlStort$ and the Dual laff~ur Market, m Barker, D L. & Allen, S,
Dependence a n d Exploitation in Work a n d Marriage (London Longmans, 1976)
Bendix, IL, Work a n d Authority in Industry Ideologies o f Management in the Course o f
Industrialisatlon (New York Harper & Row, 1956)
Berle, A. A. & Means, G C, The Modern Cot~0orat/on and Pr/vate Property (New York Macmillan,
1933).
Bernstein, I, Turbulent Year£ a History o f the American Worker 1933-1941 (Boston: Houghton
MttBin, 1970)
436 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

Bravetmat% H., Labor a n d Monopoly CapitaL. the Degradation o f Work in the Twentieth Century
(New York Monthly Revtew Press, 1974)
Bmland, T, Industrial Confltct as a Source of Techmcal Innovation Three Cases, Economy a n d Society
(1982) pp 91-121
Burawoy, M, The Politics o f Production~ Factory Regimes under Capitalism and Socialism (London
Verso, 1985)
Caplan, E H, Manasement Accounting and Behavioural Science (Reading, MA Adchson-Wesley,
1971)
Carey, J L, The Origins of Modern Fmanctal Reporting, m Ice, T. A. & Parker, R. H (eds), The
Evolution o f Corporate Financial Reporting pp 241-264 (Sunbury-on-Thames Nelson, 1979)
Chandler, A. D, Jr, Strategy a n d S t r u c t u ~ Chapters in the History o f the American Industrial
Enterprise (Boston M I.T Press, 1966)
Chandler, A. M, Jr, The Visible Hana the Managerial Revolution in American Business (Cambrtdge,
MA Harvard Umverstty Press, 1977)
Chandler, A. D, Htstortcal determinants of Managerial Hterarchtes a Response to Perrow, m Van de
Ven, A H & Joyce, W F (eds), Perspectives on Organisation Design a n d Behaviour pp 391-402
(New York Wdey, 1981)
Chandler, A.D & Daems, H, Admtmstrattve Co-ordinatton, Allocatton and Momtormg. a Comparauve
Analysts of the Emergence of Accounting and Orgamsation m the USA and Europe, Accounting
Organ/zations and Society (1979) pp, 3-20
Chandler, A. D & Salsbury, S, Pierre X DuPont and the Making o f the Modern Corporat:on (New York
Harper & Row, 1971)
Ciawson, D, Bureaucracy and the Labor Proves& The Transformation o f US Industry, 1860-1920
(New York. Monthly Review Press, 1980).
Coonley, H., The Development of Industrtal Budgeting, The Annals o f the American Academy o f
Political a n d Social Science (1925) pp 64-79.
Dale, I~, The Great Organizers (New York McC_n'aw-Hdl, 1960)
Doennger, P & Piore, M, Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Studies (Lexmgton, MA Heath,
1971)
Douglas, P H & Director, A , TheProblem o f Unempioyment (New York Macmtllan, 1931)
Dublin, T , Women at Work the Transformation o f Work and Community in Lowell Massachusettg
1826--1860 (New York. Columbta Universtty Press, 1979)
Dutton, W S, DuPOn£ One Hundred a n d Forty Years (New York Scrthner, 1947).
Edwards, IL, Contested Terraitt the Transformation o f the Workplace in the Twentieth Century
(London Hememann, 1979)
Epstein, M J , A Btbhography on the Relattonshtp Between Scmntific Management and Standard Costing
(Working Paper, Califorma State Umverstty, Los Angeles, 1978)
Free, S, The Automobile under the Blue Eagle: Labor, Management and the Automobile
Manufacturing Code (Ann Arbor Umverstty of Mtchigan Press, 1963)
Free, S, Sit.Dowrg The General Motors Strike o f 1936-1937 (Arm Arbor Umverstty of Mtchtgan Press,
1969)
Fiske, W P, Developments m Cost Control, NACA Bulletin (September 1947) pp 65--73
Flamholtz, D T, The Markets and Hmrarcbaes Framework a Crittque of the Model's Apphcabdtty to
Accounting and Econormc Development, Accounting Organizations and Society (1983) pp 147-
151
Garner, S P, Evolution o f Cost Accounting to 1925 (Alabama Umversity of Alabama Press, 1976
(1954))
Gersuny, C, '% Devil m Petttcoats" and Just Cause Patterns of Pumshment in Two New England Textile
Factortes, Business History Rev/ew (1976) pp 131-152.
Goffman, E, On the Charactertsttcs of Total Institutaons, m Asylums pp 11-47 (Harmondsworth
Pelican, 1968)
Gordon, D M., Edwards, R. & Reich, M, Segmented Work, Divided Workers (Cambridge Cambrtdge
Untverstty Press, 1982)
Habakkuk, H J , American and British Technology in the Nineteenth Century. the Search f o r Labour.
Saving Inventions (Cambrtdge Cambrtdgc Umverstty Press, 1967)
Hayes, R. H & Abernathy, W J, Managing Our Way to Economic Dechne, Harvard Business Review
(July-August 1980) pp 67-77
COST ACCOUNTING, LABOUR AND CONGLOMERATES 437

HOpl~r, T M, Cooper, D, Lowe, E A., C~o~, T & Mourlt.~n, J., Fn~noxl Control m the Labour
Process. Managertal Strategies and Worker Reststance m the NCB, m Kraghts, D & Wtllmott, H (eds),
Managing the Labour Process (Aldershot Cower, 1986).
Hopper, T M, Storey, J & Wdimott, H, Accounting for Accounting. Towards the Development of a
Dtalecttcal View, Accounting. Organizations a n d Society (1987) pp. 437--456
Hopper, T. M, Soctal Transformation and Management Accounting Ftnchng the Relevance m Hmtory, m
Gustafsson, C & Lassel, H (eds), Accounting a n d Organtzational Action (Abo/Turku Abo Umvermty
Press, 1990)
Hopwood, A. G., Towards an Archaeology of Accounting Systems, Accounting Organizations a n d
Society (1987) pp 207-234
Hoskm, K. W & Macve, IL H, Accounting and the Exammauon A Genealogy of Dtsctphnary Power,
Accounting Organizations a n d Society (1986) pp 105-136
Industrial Relation, Journal, Spectal Issue on the Japanese Employment Relattonshlp (1988).
Jacoby, S M., Employing Bureaucracy Managerg Unions and the Transformatzon o f Work in
American Industry 1900-1945 ( N e w York Columbta Universtty Press, 1985).
Johnson, H T, Management Accountmg m an Early Integrated Industrial. F_ I Dupont Nemours Powder
Company 1930--1912, Business History Review (1975) pp 184-204
Johnson, H T & Kaplan, IL S, Relevance Lost The Rise and Fall o f Manageraent Accounting (Boston,
MA Harvard Busmess School Press, 1987)
Kaplan, A D H, Dtrlam, J B & Lanzdlottt, IL F, Pricing in Big Bustnes~ a Case Approach (Washington
DC. The Brookings Instttute, 1958)
Knowles, L C, Economic Development :n the Nineteenth Century France, Germany, Russia a n d the
United States (New York. A. M Kelly, 1967).
Latdler, H W, Concentration o f Control in American lndusWy (New York Thomas Y Comwell
Company, 1931 )
Lazomck, W H, Productton Relattons, Lalx~ productivity and Chotce of Techmque Brmsh and U S
Cotton Spinning Journal o f Economic History (1981) pp 491-516
Lewis, N I L , Parker, L D & Sutchffe, P, Fmanctal Reporung to Employees: the Pattern of Development
1919-1979 (Worlong Paper, Monash Umversity, Melbourne, 1984)
Lttterer, J A., Systemauc Management Destgn for Organizanonal Decoupling m American Manufacturing
Ftrms, Business History Review (1963) pp 369-391
lattler, C IL, The Development o f the Labour Process in Capitalist Societies~ a Comparative Study o f the
Transformation o f Work Orgamsatzon :n Brita#~ Japan and the USA (London. Heinemann,
1982)
Loft, A., Towards a Crmcal Understanding of Accounting The Case of Cost Accounting m the U K., 1914-
1925, Accounting. Organization5 a n d Society (1986) pp 137--170
Loncar, F E, Budgetary Plarming--Yesterday and Today, NACA Bulletin (April 1956) pp 949-955
McPherson, W H, Labor Relations in the Motor Industry (Washington DC The Brookmgs Institute,
1940)
Margmson, P, Labour a n d the Modern Corpomtio~ M u t u a l Interest or Control?. (Coventry Warv~ck
Paper m Industrial Relanons No 9, Industrial Relauons Research Umt, Umverstty of Warwtcig 1986)
Marglm, S A., What Do Bosses Do~ The Ortgms and Funcnons of Hterarchy m Capitalist Productton,
Review o f Radtcal Political Economics (1974) pp 60-112
Merino, B D & Netmark, M. D., Dtsclosure Regulauon and Poblic Policy A Socto-lustoncal Reappraisal,
Journal o f Accounting a n d Public Policy (1982) pp 33-57
Metcal~ D., Water Notes Dry Up the Impact of the Donovan Reform Proposals and Thatchertsm at Work
on Labour Productivity m Bfltlsh Manufacturing Industry, B r t t l ~ Journal o f Industrial RelatRms
(1989) pp 1-32
Mdler, P & O'Leary, T, Accounting and the Construction of the Governable Person, Accounttn~
Organizations a n d Society (1987) pp 235-265
Mtrantt, P J , Jr, Assoctatlonahsm, Stattsm and Professtonal Regulatton. Public Accountants and the Reform
of the Fmanctal Markets, 1896-1940, Business History Review (1986) pp 438---468
Montgomery, D, Workers" Control ~n Americ~ Studies in the History o f Worlg Technology, a n d Labor
Struggles (Cambrtdge Carnbrtdge Umverstty Press, 1979
Montgomery, D, The Fall o f the House o f Labour The Workplace, the State, and American Labor
Activism (Cambridge Cambridge Umverstty Press, 1987)
Nelson, D, Scmntttic Management, Systemaoc Management and Labor, 1880-1915, Business History
R e v i e w ( 1 9 7 4 ) pp 479-500
438 TREVOR HOPPER and PETER ARMSTRONG

Nelson, P~ I., Merger Movements in American Industry 1895--1956 (Prmceton Prmceton Umversity
Press, 1959)
Noreen, E, Commentary on Relevance Lost Accounting Horizons (1987) pp 110-116
Perrow, C, Markets, Hierarchies and Hegemony, m Van de Ven, A. H & Joyce, W F (eds), Perspectives on
Organisation Design and Behavtour pp 3 7 1 - 3 8 6 (New York Wiley, 1981 )
P~, C, Postcrtpt, in Van de Ven, A. H & Joyce, W F (eds), Perspectives on Organisation Design and
Behat,/our pp 403--404 (New York: Wiley, 1981b)
Pfeffer, J, Organizational Design (Arlington Heights, IL. M-IM Pubhshmg 1978)
Pollard, S, The Genesis o f Modern Management a Study o f the Industrial Revolution in Great Britain
(London Edward Arnold, 1965)
Pollert, A., Farewell to Flexibility (London. Routledge, 1991)
Rezler, J , Labor Orgamsatton at DuPont a Study in Independent Local Untomsm, Labor HisRmy (1963)
pp 178--195
Robins, J A, Orgamzattonal Economics Notes on the Use of Transaction Cost Theory m the Study of
Orgamzattons, Administrative Science Quarterly (1987) pp 68-86
Rogers, D M, Development of the Modern Business Budget, The Journal of Accountancy (1932) pp
186-205
Rose, M, Industrial Bebavtour (Harmondsworth Penguin, 1979)
Rubery, J , Structured Labour Markets, Worker Orgamzauon and Low Pay, Cambridge Journal of
Economics (1978) pp 17-36
Schumpeter, J A, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (C,ambrtdge, M ~ Harvard University Press,
1942)
Skinner, W , Manufacturing - - the Formidable Competitive Weapon (New York. Wiley, 1985)
Sloan, A. P, My Years with General Motors (London Penguin, 1986)
Smith, ~ , The Wealth o f Nations (Harmondsworth Penguin, 1970)
Taylor, F W , Shop Management (1903), re-published in Scientific Management (New York- Harper &
Row, 1947)
Theiss, E. L, The Beginning of Business Budgetin~ The Accounting Review (1937) pp 43-55
Thompson, E P, Tune, Work DtscipUne and Industrial Capitalism, Past and Present (1967)pp 56-97
Tinker, T & Neimark M, The Role of Annual Reports in Gender and Class Contradicttons at General
Motors 1917-1976, Accountin~ Organizations and Society (1987) pp 71-88.
Vteh, V/ F, Why the Budget~Journal of Accountancy (1925) pp 173-179
Ware, C F, The Early New England Cotton Manufactur~ a Study in Industrial Beginnings (Boston
Houghton-Mtt]~Lq, 1931 )
Weber, A. It., Competittve Umomsm m the Chemical Industry, Industrial and Labor Relations Review
(1959) pp 16-37
Wells, M C, Some Influences on the Development of Cost Accounting, The Accounting Historians
Journal (1977) pp 4 7 - 5 9
Wells, M C, Accounting for Common Costs (lllmots Umversity of Ilhnois press, 1978)
WilliatllSon, O E, Corporate Control and Business Behaviour An Inquiry into the Effects of
Organizational Form on Enterprise Behaviour (Englewood Cliffs, NJ Prentice-Hall, 1970).
Wdltarrtson, 0 E, Markets arid Hierarchie~ Analysis and Antitrust Implications (New York Free Press,
1975)
WtlliatTlfion, O E, The Orgarnzatton of Work A Comparattve lnstttutional Assessment, Journal of
Economic BOJaviour and Organization (1980) pp 5--38
Willianlson, O E & Oucht, W G, A Rejoinder, m Van de Ven, A. H & Joyce, W. F (eds), Perspectives on
Organ/sat/on Design a n d Behavtour pp 387--390 (New York Wiley, 1981 ).

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen