Sie sind auf Seite 1von 19

DESIGNING 401(K) PLANS THAT ENCOURAGE RETIREMENT SAVINGS:

ISSUE BRIEF

LESSONS FROM BEHAVIORAL FINANCE

Introduction
The most common type of employer-
The United States has a voluntary pension provided defined contribution plan is the
system: employers are not required to 401(k) plan. These plans are largely
provide pensions. 1 With this approach, the participant-directed. In 401(k) plans,
amount of responsibility placed on employee participation is typically
workers differs considerably between voluntary. Employees can choose within
defined benefit and defined contribution limits what percentage of salary to
pensions. Defined benefit plans base contribute. They can choose investments
benefits on a formula, while defined from the options offered by the plan. Plans
contribution plans base benefits on the similar to 401(k) plans are available to
accumulation of funds in an individual employees who work for non-profit
account. With a defined benefit plan, if the organizations (e.g., 403(b) plans) or for
employer provides a pension to a worker, government (e.g., 457 plans, the Thrift
the worker automatically participates. Savings Plan). This Issue Brief refers to
With a defined contribution plan, however, these types of pensions generically as
participation often depends on whether the 401(k) plans.
worker chooses to contribute.
Only about half of all workers participate
When the landmark Employee Retirement in any type of pension plan in any given
Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA) was year. Some workers do not contribute to a
passed, pension coverage was primarily 401(k) plan even though their employer
provided through defined benefit plans. offers a matching contribution. Often
Since then, pension participation has workers who do contribute do not
shifted away from defined benefit plans contribute sufficiently to assure
and toward defined contribution plans. themselves a comfortable retirement.
According to Department of Labor data, Workers in 401(k) plans frequently exhibit
for more than 20 years – since 1984 – inertia, sometimes called “status quo bias,”
more workers have been active not adjusting their portfolio mix as
participants in defined contribution plans changing circumstances warrant. A small
than in defined benefit plans. Now number of workers turn over their pension
considerably more than twice as many investments too aggressively, resulting in
workers are active participants in defined high trading costs. Some workers switch
contribution plans as in defined benefit investments following financial market
plans (U.S. Department of Labor 2005). trends, which results in their buying high
The shift from defined benefit to defined and selling low. Many workers take
contribution plans has meant the shift of benefits as lump sums, incurring the risk
investment risk from employers to of running out of money during retirement
employees. if they live longer than expected. In short,
there are a number of problems with the
1I have received helpful comments from Jon way workers manage their 401(k) plans.
Dauphine, John Gist, Jules Lichtenstein, Evelyn
Morton, Lisa Southworth, and Theresa Varner.

IB Number 80
Research in behavioral finance has Behavioral Economics and Behavioral
provided some lessons for 401(k) plan Finance
design that may help workers better
manage their 401(k) plans. Behavioral An assumption underlying the system of
finance considers psychological issues voluntary employee participation in
affecting how workers make financial defined contribution plans is that
decisions. This Issue Brief analyzes the individuals make good financial decisions
401(k) plan decisions workers make, the that they are able to implement. A
reasons why workers make poor decisions weakness of this approach is that many
concerning their 401(k) pensions, and individuals make poor choices, resulting in
policy options to deal with those problems. retirement income that is insufficient to
maintain their preretirement living
The paper focuses on an insight from standards. Behavioral finance has
behavioral finance – the importance of documented these choices and how they
defaults. Judicious choice of defaults by result in outcomes that are unfavorable to
pension plan sponsors may have the result workers in the long-run. Behavioral
that workers are more likely to have finance theorists have used their insight
pension coverage, are more likely to have into the roles that inertia and
well-diversified portfolios for their procrastination play in worker behavior to
pension funds, and are less likely to spend propose solutions that preserve worker
their pension money before retirement. choice while arguably achieving better
Changing the default options to make long-run outcomes for many workers.
sound savings and investment decisions
the norm could promote better retirement Behavioral finance and behavioral
income for many workers (Munnell and economics focus on psychological factors
Sundén 2004; Mitchell and Utkus 2004; affecting individuals’ decision making,
Gale, Iwry, and Orszag 2005). including how individuals deal with
problems arising from the quantity and
This paper considers policies that quality of information available to them.
encourage participation among workers This approach expands on the
offered a 401(k) pension, encourage methodology of traditional finance and
higher contribution rates, influence economics, which focuses on the behavior
choices concerning investment decisions, of well-informed persons who are
and influence choices concerning the form psychologically capable of implementing
in which benefits are received. It the decisions they make.
discusses the motivation behind the choice
of defaults and the limited empirical The following sections address policy
evidence that indicates effects of the issues related to workers’ choices
choice of defaults. The paper summarizes concerning (1) pension participation, (2)
what the economics literature on these contribution rates, (3) investments, and (4)
topics has found, and it discusses policy benefit receipt. Each section contains an
prescriptions suggested by that literature. introduction that provides background, a
discussion of information problems, and
an analysis of policy options.

2
(1) Encouraging Participation Economic studies of pension participation
(Hinz, Fernandez, and Turner 1994)
Background. While the United States has indicate characteristics of workers who do
legislated numerous pension policy not participate when offered a pension
innovations over the past twenty years in plan, but generally do not examine
an effort to raise pension participation, the specifically the workers’ reasons why they
participation rate has remained stagnant at do not participate. For example, it is
roughly 50 percent of private sector unclear whether workers’ nonparticipation
workers (U.S. BLS 2003). The reflects an affirmative choice made by
participation rate varies across groups of them or it reflects inertia that has caused
workers classified by income. The them not to make an active choice.
participation rate was higher than 75 Further, inertia could be caused by
percent for groups with income higher indecisiveness, lack of interest, or inability
than $80,000 a year in 1997, while it was to act on a decision.
only 22 percent for those workers with
annual income under $20,000 The Survey of Income and Program
(Congressional Budget Office 2003). Participation (SIPP) for 2003 asked non-
participating workers who were offered a
The most commonly used arrangement for pension why they did not participate
enrolling workers in 401(k) plans, called (Table 1). More than 40 percent of men
“standard enrollment,” is that workers and nearly 40 percent of women replied
must sign-up to participate. The default if that they could not afford to contribute.
the worker takes no action is non- Roughly 20 percent of men and nearly 30
participation. The worker must choose percent of women indicated that they did
how much to contribute, whether to not want to tie up the money. The next
change the contribution rate over time, and most common reason given by both men
the asset allocation for his or her account. and women (more than 14 percent of each
not participating) was that they hadn’t
Some workers whose employer offers a thought about it. Other responses included
401(k) plan may not participate in it that the worker did not need the plan, or
because they are ineligible or because they that the worker or spouse had other
do not choose to participate. Data from the pension coverage. With this set of
Survey of Income and Program questions, most participants gave
Participation (SIPP) for 2003 indicate that economic reasons for not participating—
those who are eligible but do not they couldn’t afford to, they didn’t want to
participate constitute 22 percent of private tie up their money, or they didn’t need the
sector workers eligible to participate in coverage.
defined contribution plans (Turner and
Verma 2005). Workers in firms that offer Because workers could give multiple
401(k) plans and who do not participate in responses, there is some overlap in the
any plan offered by their employer tend to answers. For example, 15 percent of those
be younger than participants, to be female, who said they could not afford to
and to have lower education, earnings, and contribute also answered that they did not
tenure (Hinz and Turner 1998, Turner and want to tie up the money.
Verma 2005).

3
Table 1. Reasons Why Workers Who Are Most (81 percent) of the workers in the
Eligible to Participate in a Pension Plan lowest income quartile did not give that
Do Not Participate response, while a few (7 percent) of the
Reasons for not Men Women workers in the highest quartile did give
contributing that response.
Cannot afford to 43.6% 39.7%
contribute While the SIPP data give two possible
Do not want to tie 21.6 28.8 responses for not contributing that may
up money relate to non-economic reasons (“Haven’t
Haven’t thought 14.4 14.5 thought about it” and “Some other
about it reason”), the data used in the Hinz and
Do not plan to be 7.2 4.6 Turner (1998) study provide a number of
on job long non-economic reasons as options. Nearly
enough one in six men and women (16 percent of
Have an IRA or 4.6 4.6 each) did not contribute to the Thrift
other pension
coverage Table 2. Reasons for Not Contributing to
Spouse has a 4.2 1.4 the Federal Thrift Savings Plan
pension plan Reasons for not Men Women
Employer doesn’t 3.7 4.2 contributing
contribute or Can’t spare the money 28.7 34.2
doesn’t contribute Prefer other 24.2 19.7
enough investments
Do not need it 3.6 3.5 Too close to 16.7 13.1
Started job too 2.3 1.2 retirement
close to Don’t understand the 13.7 16.0
retirement Thrift Savings Plan
Some other 23.2 25.6 Don’t want money 14.2 14.2
reason tied up
Note: percent of non-contributing eligible workers. Don’t have enough 12.0 14.5
Percentages sum to more than 100 because workers information
can provide multiple answers. No confidence in the 10.3 5.8
Source: SIPP 2003
plan
Haven’t considered 10.1 9.6
These responses can be compared to those
the Thrift Savings
from an earlier study of federal
Plan
government workers who did not choose
Never got around to it 7.3 13.7
to participate in the Thrift Savings Plan,
which was designed to be similar to 401(k) May not stay in 3.9 3.8
plans (Hinz and Turner 1998). The most federal government
common answer, given by more than a Note: percent of non-contributing eligible workers.
fourth of men (29 percent) and a third of Multiple responses were possible.
Source: Hinz and Turner (1998), computations
women (34 percent), was that they could from 1990 Federal Retirement Thrift Investment
not afford to contribute (Table 2). Board data.
.
Factors other than income were clearly
among the determinants of that response.
4
Savings Plan because they reported they how quickly life expectancy is improving,
did not understand the plan, and nearly as basing their own life expectancy on that of
many (12 percent of men and 15 percent their older relatives. Thus, “demographic
of women) did not contribute because they literacy” as well as “financial literacy”
reported they did not have enough may be a source of problems in
information. A tenth of the non- individuals’ planning for retirement.
contributors (10 percent each of men and
women) did not contribute because they A study by the Society of Actuaries (2004)
had not considered whether to do so. More found that a majority (67 percent of pre-
than one-eighth of women (14 percent), retirees) of the male respondents
but fewer men (7 percent), did not underestimated the life expectancy of the
contribute because, as they reported, they average 65-year-old man. Of that group,
had not bothered to sign up to do so. 42 percent underestimated average life
expectancy by 5 years or more. Roughly
Information Problems. How much workers half (54 percent) of pre-retiree females
and their spouses should save for underestimated the life expectancy of the
retirement is a complex problem. The average 65-year-old woman. A British
answer depends on a number of factors, study found that on average people over a
including the age at which they start range of ages underestimated their life
saving for retirement, their expected age at expectancy by 4.6 years for males and 6.0
retirement and what they anticipate their years for females. Males ages 30 to 39, an
life expectancy to be at that age, the age range where they may be considering
expected rate of return from and risk seeking employment providing pension
associated with their investments, whether coverage, underestimated their life
they have employer-provided retiree expectancy by 6.3 years, while females in
health insurance, and whether they own that age range underestimated their life
their home and expect to have paid off the expectancy by 6.5 years (O’Brien, Fenn,
mortgage by retirement. Some workers and Diacon 2005). These findings suggest
may not participate in a pension plan that a substantial portion of the population
because they do not understand how much may considerably underestimate its life
they need to save for retirement or the expectancy.
consequences of saving inadequately.
Some may not participate in a pension Policy Options. U.S. employers have used
plan because they find pensions too at least five different policy options to
complex to feel comfortable making that encourage workers to participate in 401(k)
decision, especially since it involves plans. First, employers can encourage
substantial sums of money. Some high- workers to participate in 401(k) plans by
income workers may not participate offering a match for employee
because they believe, rightly or wrongly, contributions. The match, for example,
that they have sufficient savings in other could be dollar-for-dollar up to a certain
forms. level of employee contributions, with a
lower match rate, or no match, beyond
An important reason for undersaving for that. A number of empirical studies have
retirement may be that some workers found that employer matching
underestimate their life expectancy. They contributions increase employee
may do so because they are unaware of participation (Papke and Poterba 1995;

5
Munnell, Sundén, and Taylor 2001; and do not allow loans (GAO 1997). Another
Clark and Schieber 1998). feature of plan design affecting
participation may be the complexity of the
Second, with automatic enrollment, also investment decision, which may
called “negative election,” workers are discourage some workers from enrolling in
automatically enrolled in 401(k) plans as a 401(k) plan.
the default option; however, workers may
choose to not participate. The Internal One study found a strong negative
Revenue Service (IRS) has issued rulings relationship between the number of funds
indicating that it is permissible for offered by a 401(k) plan and the
employers to automatically enroll participation rate. Increasing by 10 the
participants in 401(k) plans provided that number of funds offered led to a 1.5 to 2.0
the employee is notified in advance and is percentage point decline in the average
permitted to leave the plan if he or she participation rate (Huberman, Iyengar, and
chooses to do so (Purcell 2004). With Jiang 2003). However, a study in the
automatic enrollment, a portion of the United Kingdom found that simplifying
participant’s pay is contributed to a 401(k) the application form, in some cases so that
plan and invested in a default investment all the worker had to do was to sign a form
option without any action required by the that contained information the employer
worker. Automatic enrollment has been already had from payroll records, had little
adopted by only a minority of plans. As of effect on the percentage of people
2004, only 11 percent of all 401(k) plans, participating in employer-provided defined
and 31 percent of plans with more than contribution plans (Horack and Wood
5,000 participants, had adopted automatic 2005). This approach may have had little
enrollment (Profit Sharing/401(k) Council effect because workers still faced the
of America 2005). Plans with automatic problem of how to invest their pension
enrollment tend to be large plans, but not money.
much else is known about their
characteristics. Fifth, employers can encourage workers to
participate by providing them financial
Third, participation in 401(k) plans may be education about the need for adequate
encouraged by requiring an active decision retirement savings (McCarthy and Turner
in a given time frame whether to enroll in 2000). While providing workers with
the plan. For example, workers may be additional information, financial education
required to make a decision within the first raises the costs of their plan, which
couple of months of work on a new job workers may bear through added fees,
(Horack and Wood 2005). unless paid for directly by the employer.

Fourth, employers can encourage Choice of Defaults. If all workers


participation by offering attractive features actively made wise decisions concerning
in their 401(k) plan. The availability of the various aspects of their pension
loans from a 401(k) plan may encourage participation, the issue of defaults in
participation. The General Accounting designing 401(k) plans would be
Office (GAO) found that participation irrelevant. However, some workers do not
rates in plans that allow loans are 6 make a choice and are automatically
percentage points higher than in plans that placed in the status determined by the

6
default. Defaults may have a socially Table 3. Participation Rates by Tenure
desirable function when they can be Tenure Participation
structured so that workers end up in a Rate (%)
situation that increases their retirement New employees, 86
savings. automatic enrollment
Before automatic
Evidence from U.S. studies suggests that enrollment
automatic enrollment may be a more 3-5 years tenure 64
successful way to increase pension 5-10 years tenure 77
coverage than employer matching 10-15 years tenure 80
contributions. For example, Madrian and 15-20 years tenure 82
Shea (2001) found that automatic 20+ years tenure 83
enrollment led to substantially higher Note: data from one firm
enrollment among new employees in one Source: Madrian and Shea (2001)
firm than under a system that relied solely
on offering a match (Table 3). Choi et al. Some changes in federal law may be
(2004), using data for three firms, found needed to encourage automatic enrollment.
that automatic enrollment had its largest Federal law could be clarified in this area
effect on participation at short job tenure; to indicate that it preempts state law. In
but after three years of tenure, the addition, federal law could be changed so
participation rate among employees hired that employees who were automatically
under automatic enrollment was still 30 enrolled but accumulated only small
percentage points higher than among amounts and wished to withdraw the funds
employees hired under standard from their account could do so without
enrollment with the same tenure. penalty. Congress could clarify the limits
on fiduciary liability for employers who
Automatic enrollment has the advantage offer automatic enrollment programs. To
for workers who are uncertain about increase the incentive for firms to offer
investments that the investment choice is automatic enrollment, Congress could
made for the worker. A British study has limit the current safe harbor rules
suggested that automatic enrollment is concerning anti-discrimination to only
successful in part because some workers those plans that offer automatic enrollment
who do not choose to participate are and automatic escalation of contributions
intimidated by the choice of investment so as to assure that workers taking the
option (Horack and Wood 2005). default are contributing a sufficient
amount (Gale, Iwry, and Orszag 2005).
These studies have been based on a small
number of large firms that have been Automatic Enrollment. While
benefits innovators. The experience in automatic enrollment has been
these firms may not be typical of that demonstrated to raise participation rates, it
across the U.S. labor market, especially in may create problems in some firms. While
smaller firms and in firms with the problem of former employees failing
predominantly low-wage workforces. The to claim pensions is most commonly
extent to which the results can be associated with firms that have gone out of
generalized to the entire private sector business rather than with stable, ongoing
workforce has not been assessed. firms, that problem may arise in some

7
firms with automatic enrollment (Blake decisions are best used as the approach to
and Turner 2002). In firms with young enrolling workers in the pension plan
workers and high job turnover, workers when workers have differing needs and
may quit without informing the firm, preferences and have a strong propensity
leaving behind small pension amounts in to procrastinate. Under standard
defined contribution plans. In firms where enrollment, enrollment tends to increase
automatic enrollment occurs at the time of with employee tenure. Active enrollment
hire, workers with short tenure who leave leads to workers enrolling more quickly
may not be aware that they have a defined and to higher enrollment levels (Table 4).
contribution account. These small After three months with active enrollment,
accounts can be expensive for employers the percentage of workers enrolled equaled
to maintain. Employers may roll over that which had been achieved previously
small amounts to an IRA, but these after three years of standard enrollment.
benefits may ultimately never be claimed Even after 30 months, for the one firm in
by the workers because they are unaware the study (Choi et al. 2005), participation
of their existence. Lost pensions and lost for employees required to choose still
pensioners are often an information exceeded that of those under the standard
problem, with pension participants not enrollment regime, by 83 percent to 69
having sufficient information to claim the percent.
pensions that are theirs. No good data are
available on the magnitude of this problem Table 4. Active Enrollment Compared to
with respect to 401(k) plans. Standard Enrollment
Participation Active Standard
A British study interviewed employers at rate after enrollment enrollment
14 firms that had considered implementing three months
automatic enrollment but had rejected the of tenure
idea (Horack and Wood 2005). It found January 66% 45%
that employers were concerned about February 71 42
enrolling workers in plans without their March 70 43
prior knowledge or consent, especially April 70 40
when the workers were required to May 63 35
contribute. They were concerned that such Note: The active decision enrollment was for new
a move would be disadvantageous to some hires in 1997. The standard enrollment was for new
employees. They were also concerned hires in 1998.
about their increased costs due to the need Source: Choi et al. (2005) using data for one firm.
to make matching contributions for more
workers, some of whom would not Other factors affect workers’ decisions to
appreciate the expense to the employer. participate. For example, several studies
have found that workers covered by a
Active Decisions. An alternative defined benefit plan provided by their
approach to automatic enrollment, which employer are less likely to participate in a
is called “active decisions,” allows 401(k) plan the employer provides than
workers to choose whether to participate workers who are not covered by a defined
by having the employer set a deadline for benefit plan (Andrews 1992, Bernheim
the workers’ decision rather than having and Garrett 2003). Since the early 1980s,
no time limit (Choi et al. 2005). Active roughly 15 percent of the private sector
wage and salary workforce has been
8
covered by both a defined benefit and a of encouraging employees to participate.
defined contribution plan (U.S. A match also can be used to encourage
Department of Labor 2005). employees to increase their contributions.
Economic studies have generally shown
(2) Encouraging Contributions that offering an employer match for
employee contributions increases
Background. It is important that workers participant contributions. One study found
contribute towards their retirement income that a one percent increase in the employer
security. Once a worker has decided to match rate led to a 0.25 percent increase in
participate in a 401(k) plan, the factor that employee contributions (Engelhardt and
has the largest effect on the amount of Kumar 2003).
assets accumulated is how much is
contributed to the plan (Choi, Laibson, and Loans. Other research indicates
Madrian 2004). In 2001, the median that certain defined contribution plan
balance in 401(k) accounts among features besides the match rate may affect
households headed by 50- to 55-year olds the amount participants contribute. One
who had positive balances was only study found that the ability of plan
$50,000 (Goodman and Orszag 2005). In participants to borrow from the plan
2004, the the typical defined contribution increased their contributions by about one
plan participant investing with Vanguard percentage point (Munnell, Sundén, and
was 44 years old and had a plan account Taylor 2001). Another study found that
balance of $24,000 (Vanguard 2005). participants in plans that allow borrowing
When low- and middle-income workers do contribute, on average, 35 percent more to
participate in 401(k) plans, their their pension accounts than participants in
contributions are generally low (Hinz and plans that do not allow borrowing (GAO
Turner 1998). 1997).

Information Problems. As discussed, Active Enrollment. A study of one


workers and their families may have a firm found that active enrollment with no
difficult time determining their retirement default option improved participation but
income needs and how those needs led to lower average contribution rates
translate into a savings rate. Workers who (Choi et al. 2005). Active enrollment
underestimate their life expectancy will participants had lower contribution rates
save insufficiently even if they are saving than standard enrollment participants until
adequately for their perceived life the fourth year of participation. The
expectancy. Even for workers with explanation for the lower average
unbiased estimates of their life contribution rates among active enrollment
expectancy, there is no simple answer to participants may be that active decisions
the question, “How much do I need to save bring employees with weaker savings
for retirement?” motives into participation earlier in their
tenure.
Policy Options. There are several policy
options for encouraging contributions. Auto Escalation. One approach to
encourage workers to contribute more
Match. The effects of an employer automatically over time has been given the
match were discussed earlier in the context acronym SMarT – Save More Tomorrow

9
(Thaler and Benartzi 2004). The Save are eligible to participate in the pension
More Tomorrow plan is designed to make plan.
it easier for workers to commit to
participating in a 401(k) plan, to keep the In the firms that have implemented it, the
commitment, and to increase their savings SMarT approach has been highly
rate over time. Under this plan, workers successful in encouraging workers to
voluntarily agree to save part of their participate in 401(k) plans and to increase
future wage increases—the first payroll their contribution rate over time. In its
deduction occurs the year following the first implementation, 78 percent of the
date when the commitment is made. In the people who were offered the option chose
future, today’s workers generally will have it, 98 percent of the people who took the
higher wages than currently as they gain option remained in it through two annual
more experience, as productivity increases pay raises, and 80 percent remained in it
in the economy, and as the price level through three annual pay raises (Benartzi
rises. Therefore, workers will face no and Thaler 2004).
absolute reduction in their take home pay
in order to save more, as long as they (3) Investment Choices
receive wage increases that exceed the
payroll deduction. Normally, wages Background. With the growth of 401(k)
increase in both nominal and real terms plans, because the investment risk is
over time. This plan, however, is not shifted from employers to workers,
dependent on real wage increases – it workers’ investment decisions play an
incorporates an assumption that workers increasingly important role in determining
are subject to “wage illusion,” meaning their retirement income. While traditional
that they are fooled by inflation and defined benefit plans are generally
misperceive nominal wage increases as managed professionally, workers have
real wage increases that raise their wages responsibility for managing the
above the amount necessary to keep pace investments in their 401(k) plans.
with inflation. Workers commit to save
part of their nominal wage increase Information Problems. Workers as
through their pension. Alternatively, auto- investors may be their own worst enemy.
escalation can occur as an increase in the While traditional economic theory
percentage of wages contributed, assumes that investors are rational wealth
regardless of whether future wages maximizers and do not make systematic
increase. errors, more recent economic theory and
empirical studies increasingly suggest
There are five essential aspects of the otherwise. Many workers are uninformed
SMarT approach: 1) the increased about financial markets and lack interest in
contribution occurs the year following the spending their time learning about them.
decision to participate, 2) the increased Consequently, they may have biased or
contribution is taken out of increased otherwise inaccurate information about
income, 3) the increased income of the them.
worker is measured in nominal terms, 4)
participation is voluntary, and 5) These information deficiencies can be
participation is open to all workers who addressed by participant education
(McCarthy and Turner 2000). However,

10
information provided by financial service The question arises as to how many
providers may be affected by the self- options workers should be given in
interest of the provider, with, for example, deciding how to invest their pension
little or no discussion of the amount of assets. If too many options are provided,
fees the provider charges and the role fees many workers may feel they are unable to
play in reducing account balances. decide and take the default fund if one is
offered (Agnew and Szykman 2004). An
A different information problem is that example of many choices leading workers
economists do not agree on what workers to take the default is provided by
should do concerning the management of experience with the mandatory account
their pension portfolios. A leading scholar system in Sweden. Workers have a choice
in the field writes, “There is currently no of more than 600 mutual funds. Yet only
consensus on the optimal asset allocation 18 percent of new entrants into the system
strategy for investors” (Poterba 2001). For in 2001 made an active choice, the rest
example, most financial planners allowing their contributions to be placed in
encourage workers to hold less risky the default fund, which is primarily
portfolios as they approach retirement, but invested in equities (Turner 2004).
Bodie (1995) challenges that view.
Types of Investment Errors Pension
Information may be so complex that, even Participants Make. While the preceding
if supplied, pension investors are unable to section discussed reasons why investors
make rational choices (Barr 2001). This make errors, this section discusses the
failure may occur in part because the long types of investment errors pension
time horizon for young workers makes it participants make. Pension investor errors
difficult for them to understand the include insufficient diversification and
consequences of their choices. inappropriate portfolio adjustments
Having a larger number of choices may (Turner 2003).
seem to be desirable because that would
allow workers to find the options that fit Insufficient Diversification. Failure
their tastes or needs. However, the to understand the basic principles of
paradox of choice is that too many choices diversification may lead to investor errors.
may immobilize some workers, with the This lack of understanding leads to
increased number of choices making it insufficient diversification between stocks
difficult for them to decide. One possible and other instruments such as bonds, and
explanation is information overload also to lack of diversification within the
(Agnew and Szykman 2004). With stock portion of the portfolio. Lucas
information overload, workers find the (2000), examining the portfolios of
problem too complex, with too much 250,000 401(k) participants, found that,
information to try to understand, and they typically, participants’ portfolios are
take no action. Studies in psychology have poorly diversified, focusing mainly on
shown that having more choices may stable value funds, large capitalization
render people worse off by hampering the stock, and stock of their own company.
ability to identify the option that best suits
them (Iyengar and Lepper 2000). A particular aspect of problems
participants may have with portfolio
diversification is naïve diversification.

11
This occurs when participants attempt to (Benartzi 2001). This pattern is the reverse
diversify by dividing their investment of what diversification would indicate.
portfolios equally among all available
investment options offered by a pension Inappropriate Portfolio
provider. Thus, if a pension plan offers Adjustments. Overconfidence in one’s
three options, participants attempting to own abilities as an investor or, at the
diversify would split their contributions in opposite extreme, inertia, may lead to
thirds. This results in an asset allocation inappropriate portfolio adjustments.
to stocks and bonds that depends on the Overconfidence may cause some investors
number and composition of stock and to trade aggressively, while inertia may
bond funds offered by the sponsoring result in some investors not revising their
employer (Benartzi and Thaler 2001). initial investment allocation when their
One study explored this pattern and found pension plan offers further options.
that only a small percentage of workers
appear to manage their pension portfolios Inertia may result from workers’ not being
this way (Holden and VanDerhei 2001). willing to invest the time to learn how to
make portfolio allocation changes. The
Over-investment in the stock of the perception that it is a time-consuming
sponsoring employer has occurred in some process to make changes may be a factor.
pension plans, and is another form of Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988) found
insufficient diversification. When workers that most pension participants in TIAA-
invest their pension plans in company CREF never made any adjustments to their
stock, if the company goes bankrupt they asset allocation over their entire career.
lose both their jobs and their pensions. In Ameriks and Zeldes (2000) found that
plans that allow employer stock as an nearly half of TIAA-CREF participants
investment option, 46 percent of made no changes over a ten-year period.
participants (about 11 million employees) Failing to adjust one’s portfolio as one
hold more than 20 percent of their account ages is another possible manifestation of
balance in employer stock (VanDerhei inertia. Lucas (2000) found that pension
2002). This sometimes occurs because the participants typically do not adjust their
company provides the contribution match portfolios as their time horizon shortens.
in company stock. Providing the match in Portfolios are clustered at similar risk
company stock encourages workers to levels across age groups from ages 25 to
over-weight their portfolios in company 50. Equity exposure only decreases
stock. Men and lower-paid employees materially for the portfolio of the typical
tend to invest a higher percentage of their participant aged 60 and older.
portfolios in company stock than women
and higher-paid employees (Lucas 2000, Overconfidence may cause investor errors.
Holden and VanDerhei 2001). One study Barber and Odean (2001) define
reports that when the employer match is in overconfident investors as those who
company stock, employees invest 29 ultimately lower their returns because of
percent of their own contributions in excessive trading. Males, and in particular
company stock. When the match is in young adult males, tend to suffer from
cash, employees invest 18 percent of their overconfidence in their ability as
own contributions in company stock investors. This may arise from a feeling
by some of superior knowledge

12
concerning the mathematics and concepts employers to provide better default options
of finance (Barber and Odean 2001). for pension investments. Congress could
Overconfidence tends to increase the designate some standard investment
amount of trading by individual investors, portfolios that would be granted safe
raising their transaction costs (Odean harbor exemption from issues of fiduciary
1998). Barber and Odean’s (2001) study liability (Gale, Iwry, and Orszag 2005).
of trading at a discount brokerage found
that single men traded 67 percent more An approach to improving asset allocation
than single women, thereby lowering their in 401(k) plans would be to grant plan
returns net of trading costs by 1.4 sponsors relief from some fiduciary
percentage points per year compared to liability if they offer participants
single women. alternatives to self-direction of investment
choices. This could be done by offering
Policy Options. There are several possible diversified funds that would meet certain
alternatives to employees managing their standards or by having professionally
own 401(k) plans. First, the employer managed accounts (Gale et al. 2004).
could manage the investments of the
401(k) plan. The convenience store chain Many workers take the default fund in a
7-Eleven, Inc. provides a 401(k) plan for situation of automatic enrollment. Because
its employees with a trustee-investment of inertia, they then stay with that fund.
structure, where all participants’ accounts Thus, the financial characteristics of the
are aggregated and invested as one pool, default fund in terms of risk and expected
and investment earnings are distributed to return warrant careful consideration.
participants’ accounts proportionate to Some employers have chosen a low-risk
their account balances (Demby 2002). money market portfolio as the default fund
This approach may be desirable in firms because they were afraid of lawsuits if
with lower-paid employees who may have participants lost money. That portfolio,
less experience with and knowledge about however, may be too conservative for
investing. Almost 70 percent of 401(k) participants over the long run. It may be
participants direct the investment of their desirable to amend ERISA to clarify
entire account balances, and an additional fiduciary responsibilities for employers
17 percent are able to direct the investment when investment losses result from a
of a portion of the assets in their account default investment that includes stocks and
(U.S. Department of Labor 2004). bonds. Legislation has been proposed that
would provide employers that establish a
Second, some plan sponsors have offered plan with automatic enrollment the same
automatically managed 401(k) plans, protection from liability for investment
where employees can pay a fee based on losses as is provided to plans in which the
their assets to have professional employee exercises control over the
management of their investments (Maas investment of plan assets (Purcell 2004).
2005).
As employees age and approach
Third, employers can offer a default retirement, some financial market experts
option, so that workers do not need to advise they should change their investment
make an investment choice. One possible portfolios to include more bonds, reducing
change in pension law would encourage the risk of losses at ages near retirement.

13
This type of portfolio change can be made 401(k) plans, are not required to provide
automatically by investing in a lifecycle survivor benefits.
fund. A lifecycle fund changes the
portfolio mix over time, with larger shares Often when workers change jobs before
of the fund invested in bonds as the retirement, they take the money out of
worker ages. their pension plans. At retirement,
annuities provide insurance that workers
This discussion of common errors that will not outlive their resources. Many
individual pension investors make workers in defined contribution plans do
suggests a number of possible pension not have the option of annuitizing their
policy options. These options would account balance. Moreover, when that
restrict the range of investment choices, option is available, workers generally do
but such restriction in choice could reduce not take it. One reason for their failure to
investor errors. do so is that many workers have a strong
preference for current consumption
1. Limit investment in individual relative to saving for future consumption.
stocks, including employer stocks.
2. Limit investment in mutual funds Information Problems. If workers
with narrow market focus. underestimate their life expectancy, as
3. Limit investment in highly risky well as the probability that they will live
assets such as high tech stocks. longer than their life expectancy, they will
4. Offer professional management of likely underestimate their retirement
pension investments as an option. income needs and may undervalue the
5. Educate workers on common benefits provided by annuities (Drinkwater
investment mistakes. and Sondergeld 2004; O’Brien, Fenn, and
6. Limit the frequency of investment Diacon 2005).
changes.
7. Provide well-chosen default Policy Options. The federal government
options that participants can use if has changed the default so that when a
they do not want to make an active worker leaves a job with a small amount in
choice. his pension account – between $1,000 and
$5,000 — the employer rolls it over into
(4) Benefit Receipt an Individual Retirement Account (IRA)
rather than the worker cashing it out. This
Background. Three issues concerning policy is designed to discourage workers
benefit receipt are (1) What happens to from cashing out their 401(k) accounts and
workers’ accounts when they change jobs to encourage them to keep their
before retirement? (2) Are workers’ accumulated pension assets in the
accounts annuitized, taken as a lump sum, retirement income system. When a worker
or taken as a phased withdrawal at leaves a job with a larger amount, it might
retirement? And (3) are survivor benefits be desirable for pension plan sponsors to
provided? While defined benefit pension make automatic rollover into an IRA the
plans are required to provide survivor default to discourage workers from taking
benefits, 401(k) plans that do not provide the account balance as a lump sum.
annuities as an option, which are most With the options of annuitization or partial
annuitization, questions arise as to whether

14
some form of annuitization should be contribution rate that starts low, but
mandatory, or whether that should be the gradually increases over a period of years.
default option. The market for individual Some firms have made the default
annuities, however, is quite small in the investment a life cycle fund, where the
United States. The market may be small default investment is more heavily
because these annuities typically are not weighted to stocks for younger workers,
protected against inflation or because life but gradually shifts towards bonds as
annuities are priced on the assumption that workers’ expected retirement approaches.
the person taking them has a higher life If workers change jobs, the default in
expectancy than the average life some 401(k) plans is that the plan assets
expectancy in the U.S. population. are rolled over into an IRA. At retirement,
the default may be that part or all of the
Conclusion account balance is annuitized, possibly
with survivor benefits provided
Several 401(k) policy options could
encourage workers to participate, to While these defaults may not be optimal
contribute more, to invest wisely, and to for all workers, they help assure that many
make informed choices when it comes to workers will accumulate assets in a 401(k)
receiving benefits. plan that are available to finance
retirement consumption. The effects of the
Many of the ideas discussed here have defaults on women, minorities, and low-
resulted from developments in behavioral wage workers, in particular, deserve
finance and relate to the choice of defaults. further attention.
Studies have shown that the choice of
defaults can have a large effect on While defined benefit plan investments are
workers’ behavior, and may ultimately generally made by investment
lead to workers having larger 401(k) plan professionals, defined contribution plan
account balances at retirement. investments are generally made by the
workers themselves. Workers tend to
Traditionally, the default for workers make predictable investment errors. Some
unable to decide whether to participate in a workers invest too heavily in the stock of
401(k) plan has been nonparticipation. their employer. Some workers never
However, some plan sponsors have change their portfolio to adjust to their
established defaults that preserve freedom approaching retirement. The design
of choice for workers wishing to make a features of 401(k) plans discussed here
choice, but that result in good decisions may be of substantial help in preventing
for workers who are uncertain as to what workers from making such errors.
to do. These defaults start with automatic
enrollment in the plan unless workers
affirmatively decide to not participate. References

Automatic enrollment creates problems of Agnew, Julie and Szykman, Lisa R. “Asset
inadequate build-up of assets if the default Allocation and Information Overload: The
contribution rate is low and the default Influence of Information Display, Asset
investment is highly conservative. Thus, Choice and Investor Experience.” Boston
some firms have established a default

15
Center for Retirement Research Working Quarterly 18(3) Third Quarter 2002, pp.
Paper 2004-15, 2004. 51-64.

Ameriks, John and Zeldes, Stephen. Bodie, Zvi. “An Analysis of Investment
“How Do Household Portfolio Shares Advice to Retirement Plan Participants.”
Vary with Age?” Working Paper, In The Pension Challenge: Risk Transfers
Columbia University, 2000. and Retirement Income Security, edited by
Olivia S. Mitchell and Kent Smetters.
Andrews, Emily S. “The Growth and Philadelphia: Pension Research Council
Distribution of 401(k) Plans.” In Trends in Press, 2003, pp. 19-32.
Pensions 1992, edited by John Turner and
Daniel Beller. Washington, DC: U.S. Bodie, Zvi. “On the Risk of Stocks in the
Department of Labor, Pension and Long Run.” Financial Analysts Journal
Welfare Benefits Administration, 1992, 51(3) 1995: 18-22.
pp. 149-176.
Choi, James J.; Laibson, David; and
Barber, Brad and Odean, Terrance. “Boys Madrian, Brigitte. “Plan Design and
Will be Boys: Gender, Overconfidence, 401(k) Savings Outcomes,” National Tax
and Common Stock Investment.” Journal 52(2) June 2004: 275-298.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 116
(February 2001): 261-292. Choi, James J.; Laibson, David; Madrian,
Brigitte; and Metrick, Andrew. “Optimal
Barr, Nicholas. The Welfare State as Defaults and Active Decisions.” National
Piggy Bank. Oxford, England: Oxford Bureau of Economic Research Working
University Press, 2001. Paper 11074, January 2005.
Benartzi, Shlomo. “Excessive
Extrapolation and the Allocation of 401(k) Clark, Robert L. and Schieber, Sylvester.
Accounts to Company Stock.” The “Factors Affecting Participation Levels in
Journal of Finance LVL (October 2001): 401(k) Plans.” In Living with Defined
1747-1764. Contribution Plans: Remaking
Responsibility for Retirement, edited by
Benartzi, Shlomo and Thaler, Richard S. Olivia S. Mitchell and Sylvester J.
“Naïve Diversification Strategies in Schieber. Philadelphia, PA: University of
Defined Contribution Savings Plans.” Pennsylvania Press, 1998, pp. 69-97.
American Economic Review 91: (March
2001): 79-98. Congressional Budget Office. “Utilization
of Tax Incentives for Retirement Saving.”
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Garret, Daniel August 2003.
M. “The Effects of Financial Education in
the Workplace: Evidence from a Survey of Demby, Elayne Robertson. “Leave It to
Households.” Journal of Public Economics the Boss.” Plan Sponsor. September
87 (August 2003): 1487-1519. 2002, pp. 60-61.

Blake, David and Turner, John. ”Lost Drinkwater, Mathew and Sondergeld, Eric
Pensions and Lost Pensioners.” Benefits T. “Perceptions of Mortality Risk:
Implications for Annuities.” In Pension

16
Design and Structure: New Lessons From Hinz, Richard P.; Fernandez, Phyllis; and
Behavioral Finance, edited by Olivia S. Turner, John (editors). Pension Coverage
Mitchell and Stephen P. Utkus. New York: Issues for the '90s. Washington, DC:
Oxford University Press, 2004, pp. 275- USGPO, 1994
286.
Holden, Sarah and VanDerhei, Jack.
Elton, Edward J.; Gruber, Martin J.; and “401(k) Plan Asset Allocation, Account
Blake, Christopher R. “The Adequacy of Balances, and Loan Activity in 2000.”
Investment Choices Offered by 401(k) EBRI Issue Brief November 2001.
Plans.” Unpublished paper, New York
University, December 2004. Horack, Sarah and Wood, Andrew. “An
http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~mgruber/worki Evaluation of Scheme Joining Techniques
ng%20papers/adequacy_investment_choic in workplace Pension Schemes with an
es_offered_401k.pdf Employer Contribution.” UK Department
for Work and Pensions, research Report
Engelhardt, Gary V. and Kumar, A. No. 292, 2005.
“’Understanding the Impact of Employer http://www.dwp.gov.uk/asd/asd5/rports20
Matching on 401(k) Saving.” TIAA- 05-2006/rrep292.pdf . Downloaded
CREF Research Institute Research Dialog November 4, 2005.
76, June 2003.
Gale, William G.; Iwry, J. Mark; Munnell, Huberman, Gur; Iyengar, Sheena; and
Alicia H. and Thaler, Richard H. Jiang, Wei. “Defined Contribution Pension
“Improving 401(k) Investment Plans: Determinants of Participation and
Performance.” Issue Brief No. 26, Center Contribution Rates.” Columbia University
for Retirement Research at Boston Working Paper. New York, NY: Columbia
College, December 2004. University, 2003.

Gale, William G.; Iwry, J. Mark, and Iyengar, Sheena S. and Lepper, M. R.
Orszag, Peter R. “The Automatic 401(k): “When Choice is Demotivating: Can One
A Simple Way to Strengthen Retirement Desire Too Much of a Good Thing.”
Savings.” The Retirement Security Journal of Personality and Social
Project, March 2005. Psychology 79 (2000): 995-1006.

Goodman, John C. and Orszag, Peter R. Lucas, Lori. “Under the Microscope: A
“Common Sense Reforms to Promote Closer Look at the Diversification and
Retirement Security.” The Retirement Risk Taking Behavior of 401(k)
Security Project, May 2005. Participants and How Plan Sponsors Can
Address Key Investing Issues.” Benefits
Hinz, Richard P. and Turner, John. Quarterly (Fourth Quarter 2000): 24-30.
“Pension Coverage Initiatives: Why Don’t
Workers Participate?” In Living With Madrian, Brigitte C and Shea, Dennis, F.
Defined Contribution Pensions, edited by “The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in
Olivia S. Mitchell and Sylvester J. 401(k) Participation and Savings
Schieber. Philadelphia: University of Behavior.” Quarterly Journal of
Pennsylvania Press, 1998, pp. 17-37. Economics 116( 4) (November 2001):
1149-1187.

17
/papers/crisresearchreport2005-
Maas, Angela. “Managing Retirement-- 1(summary).pdf.
Automatically managed 401(k) plans
appeal to employers and employees alike.” Odean, Terrance. “Volume, Volatility,
Employee Benefit News March 2005. Price, and Profit When All Traders Are
Downloaded March 14, 2005. Above Average.” Journal of Finance 53
http://www.benefitnews.com/detail.cfm?id (1998): 1887-1934.
=7183
Papke, Leslie E. “Choice and Other
McCarthy, David and Turner, John. Determinants of Employee Contributions
"Pension Education: Does It Help? Does to Defined Contribution Plans.” Social
It Matter?" Benefits Quarterly (16) 2000: Security Bulletin 65 No. 2 (2003/2004):
pp. 64-72. 59-68.

Mitchell, Olivia S. and Utkus, Stephen P. Papke, Leslie E. “Individual Financial


“Lessons from Behavioral Finance for Decisions in Retirement Plans: The Role
Retirement Plan Design.” In Pension of Participant Direction.” Journal of
Design and Structure: New Lessons From Public Economics 88 (2003): 39-61.
Behavioral Finance, edited by Olivia S.
Mitchell and Stephen P. Utkus. Oxford, Papke, Leslie E. and Poterba, James M.
U.K.: Oxford University Press, 2004, pp. “Survey Evidence on Employer Match
3-41. Rates and Employee Saving Behavior in
401(k) Plans.” Economic Letters 49 No. 3
Munnell, Alicia H. and Lee, James G. (September 1995): 311-325.
“Changing 401(k) Defaults on Cashing
out: Another Step in the Right Direction.” Poterba, James M. “Taxation and
Just the Facts on Retirement Issues, No. Portfolio Structure: Issues and
12, September 2004. Implications.” NBER Working Paper
8223, 2001
Munnell, Alicia H. and Sundén, Annika. (http://www.nber.org/papers/w8223).
Coming Up Short: The Challenge of
401(k) Plans. Washington, DC: The Profit Sharing/401(k) Council of America.
Brookings Press, 2004. 48th Annual Survey of Profit Sharing and
401(k) Plans, 2005.
Munnell, Alicia H., Sundén, Annika and
Taylor, C. “What Determines 401(k) Purcell, Patrick. “Automatic Enrollment
Participation and Contributions?” in Section 401(k) Plans.” CRS Report for
Unpublished paper. Boston College, 2001 Congress, October 14, 2004.

O’Brien, Chris; Fenn, Paul; and Diacon, Samuelson, William and Zeckhauser,
Stephen. “How Long Do People Expect to Richard J. “Status Quo Bias in Decision
Live? Results and Implications.” Centre Making.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty
for Risk & Insurance Studies, CFIS 1 (1988): 7-59.
Research report 2005-1, April 2005.
Downloaded November 1, 2005 Society of Actuaries. “2003 Risks and
http://www.nottingham.ac.uk/business/cris Process of Retirement Survey: Report of

18
Findings.” January 2004. U.S. General Accounting Office. “401(k)
http://www.soa.org/ccm/content/areas-of- Pension Plans: Loan Provisions Enhance
practice/special-interest- Participation, but May Affect Income
sections/pension/post-retirement/ Security for Some.” GAO/HEHS-97-5.
Downloaded November 10, 2005. Washington, DC, October 1997.

Thaler, Richard H. and Benartzi, Shlomo. VanDerhei, Jack. “Retirement Security


“Save More Tomorrow: Using Behavioral and Defined Contribution Pension Plans:
Economics to Increase Employee Saving.” The Role of Company Stock in 401(k)
In Developments in Decision-Making Plans,” written testimony for the U.S.
Under Uncertainty: Implications for Senate, Committee on Finance, February
Pensions, edited by Olivia S. Mitchell and 27, 2002.
Stephen P. Utkus. Philadelphia:
University of Pennsylvania Press, 2004. Vanguard. “How America Saves 2005: A
Report on Vanguard 2004 Defined
Turner, John. “Errors Workers Make in Contribution Plan Data.” The Vanguard
Managing their 401(k) Investments,” Center for Retirement Research.
Benefits Quarterly 19(4) Winter 2003: 75- December 6, 2005.
82.
Turner, John. “Individual Accounts:
Lessons from Sweden.” International
Social Security Review 57 No. 1 (2004):

ISSUE BRIEF
65-84.

Turner, John and Verma, Satyendra.


“Extending Pension Participation: The Written by John Turner
AARP Public Policy Institute
Behavioral Economics of Why Some 601 E St., NW
Workers Choose to Not Participate.” Washington, DC 20049
Unpublished AARP document, November 202-434-3870; E-Mail: ppi@aarp.org
2005. March 2006
© 2006, AARP http://www.aarp.org/ppi
Reprinting with permission only.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (US BLS).
“Retirement Plans in 2003.” MLR: The
Editor’s Desk, October 3, 2003.

U.S. Department of Labor, Employee


benefits Security Administration. “Private
Pension Plan Bulletin, Abstract of 1999
Form 5500 Annual Reports.” Summer
2004.

U.S. Department of Labor, Employee


Benefits Security Agency. “Private
Pension Plan Bulletin: Abstract of 2000
Form 5500 Annual Reports,” July 2005.

19

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen