Sie sind auf Seite 1von 9

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/238797941

The OM triangle

Article · January 2005

CITATIONS READS

2 1,916

1 author:

Glen M. Schmidt
University of Utah
31 PUBLICATIONS   702 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Glen M. Schmidt on 04 July 2017.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


The OM Triangle in Health Care
by Glen Schmidt
Adapted from Nosokinetics News, 3(5), Oct 2006

If you are a pilot, you know about the Bermuda triangle. If you study relationships, you have heard
of a love triangle. If you enjoy recreational mathematics, you are probably intrigued by Pascal’s
triangle. But if you study health care operations, the triangle you should definitely know about is
the OM triangle!

Before describing the OM triangle, let me briefly describe what Operations Management (OM) is
and how it relates to the field of health care. OM is a field within business and engineering that
addresses the flow of materials through production processes. OM has strong roots in
manufacturing, but services, such as the treatment of patients, are also effectively production
processes.

The manufacturing plant takes raw materials (RM) and performs certain process steps to transform
these raw materials into finished goods (FG). While being processed, the unfinished products are
called work-in-process, or WIP. The firm’s inventory is comprised of these three components, the
RM, WIP, and FG. Analogously, the patients waiting for treatment in a medical facility effectively
represent RM, patients being “worked on” represent WIP, and discharged patients are FG. The
medical facility has inventory (of patents) just as the factory has inventory (of products) – the only
real difference is that in a medical facility you can’t store FG to sell to new arriving customers
(wouldn’t it be great if you could store a “cured patient” on the shelf and hold it as an immediate
cure for a new arriving patient!).

Both the manufacturing plant and the medical facility need to determine the type and number of
resources needed in order to transform the RM into FG. For the factory, the resources might
consist of presses or machining centers, along with workers. For the medical facility, the resources
might be beds, MRI machines, and of course doctors and nurses. The more resources the
manufacturer acquires, the more capacity it has. For example, a Toyota plant may have the capacity
to produce 500 cars per day. Similarly, the more resources the medical facility has, the more
patients it can treat. Analogously, it may have the capacity to treat 500 patients per day.

Factories and medical facilities are also similar in that they must deal with what I call “the curse of
variability.” There are two keys types of variability; namely, variability in the arrivals of customers
(e.g., the arrival of patients to the hospital), and the variability in processes (e.g., it may take longer
to diagnose one patient as compared to another). Both of these types of variability wreak havoc in
a production process. How can you keep your doctors and nurses busy, but not overworked, if you
don’t know how many patients will arrive that day, or don’t know how long a patient will take to be
diagnosed? What each firm would like, is information as to the extent of this variability and how to
reduce it.

Thus a medical facility is similar to a factory in many respects, and the notions of “inventory,”
“capacity” and “variability (or information)” can be analogously defined in both settings.
Furthermore, we find that much of the theory that developed from the study of manufacturing can
also be applied to services such as health care. Just one example of this is the way some hospitals
are beginning to implementing the Toyota Production System (Connolly 2005).

1
Another similarity between manufacturing and services is that they both experience tradeoffs
depicted in the “OM triangle” (Lovejoy 1998, Schmidt 2005). See Figure 1. The OM triangle
depicts the tradeoff between the three factors described above, namely, inventory, capacity, and
information. The theory behind the OM triangle is rigorously grounded in queueing theory – see the
Appendix for a somewhat more formal development.

To illustrate the tradeoff, consider the following example. Say you are in charge of running a small
hospital. You are currently looking at buying the hospital its first and only MRI machine. Assume
you know that on average a patient will arrive every hour or so, but not necessarily with perfect
regularity. A less expensive MRI machine can examine a patient in 50 minutes on average, while a
more expensive one only takes 30 minutes (but again, there is some variability in the processing
times, as not all patients need the same scans). You can only buy only one – which one should it
be?

Inventory

Information Capacity
Figure 1. The OM Triangle Portrays the Substitutability of Inventory, Capacity, &
Information.

Here you are making a decision on how much to capacity to acquire. The expensive machine has the
capacity to examine two patients per hour, while the less expensive one can examine one every 50
minutes which is equivalent to a lower processing rate of only 1.2 per hour.

Recall that patients arrive at 1 per hour, on average. Say you buy the higher-capacity machine; the
one that can process 2 patients per hour. Even though you will be using the machine only half the
time (i.e., its capacity utilization will be 30 min. / 60 min. = 0.5 since it can treat a patient in 30 min.
and a new patient arrives every 60 min. on average), a patient will sometimes have to wait –
sometimes the next patient will arrive before the current patient is done.

A second option is to buy the lower-capacity machine. You will still have more capacity than the
minimum needed (its capacity utilization will be 50 min. / 60 min. = 0.83). However, in this case
the patients’ average waiting time will increase significantly over the wait time experienced with the
faster machine. The average number of patients waiting, i.e., the RM inventory, will also increase
significantly. This dramatic increase is due to “the curse of variability” – if the capacity or rate at
which patients can be treated is not much greater than the rate at which they arrive, variability in the
system drives the inventory “sky-high” (and the more variability there is, the worse this relationship
gets). See Figure 2.

2
The above discussion implies there is a relationship between capacity and inventory. Thus you can
think of your decision as one of how much inventory to hold, rather than how much capacity to
acquire. Just as buying the machine with more capacity costs you more money, holding more
inventory also costs you more. The cost of holding more raw materials (that is, of having
customers wait) is not an out-of-pocket cost, but instead it is the less tangible cost of having
disgruntled customers. You need to think about the degree of dissatisfaction that customers will
experience from having to wait, and whether this is tolerable.

High Inventory
b
Lead time
Inventory

2
and

M
or 1
eV
ar 0.5
ia b 0.1
“Extra” i li
Capacity ty 0.01
a c
Low Variability
0
0.0 1.0
Capacity Utilization

Figure 2. Inventory Skyrockets as Capacity Utilization Approaches One, and as Variability


Increases, Due to the “Curse of Variability”

A third alternative is to buy the less expensive machine while also spending some money on
information. For example, you might invest in an information system that tells you exactly what
medical tests every patient in the hospital needs at every point in time. With this information, you
might be able to develop a scheduling and tracking system that minimizes each customer’s wait, and
thereby effectively reduce the variability in arrivals to the MRI machine. In turn, reducing variability
in arrivals would reduce the RM inventory (the average number of people waiting).

In the above discussion we described three alternatives on how to “spend your money.” To
reiterate, option one is to pay the high cost of the fast machine, which minimizes waiting lines and
waiting costs. Option two is to reduce machine cost by buying the slow machine, but this will cost
you in terms of customer dissatisfaction. Option three is to buy the slow machine but
simultaneously buy the information system, thereby again minimizing waiting times and avoiding
the cost of dissatisfaction. As this discussion suggests, each option has its costs – it is your job to
determine which alternative has the lowest total cost. The option with the lowest total cost would
be your best choice (assuming these are the only relevant considerations).

Said another way, capacity and inventory and information are substitutes. If you acquire more
capacity you can get by with less information or drive inventory (and customer dissatisfaction)
down. If you hold more inventory, you can get by with less capacity or information. If you acquire
more information you can get by with less capacity or drive inventory down.

3
Different types of health care facilities call for different strategies in managing the tradeoffs
depicted by the OM triangle. For example, consider the following three facilities: an emergency
room, a hospital that focuses solely on hernia surgeries, and a free clinic. One of these facilities
might best operate at the “capacity” point of the triangle, that is, its money is probably best spent
on capacity. Another of these might best operate at the “inventory” point, since the “price it pays”
(the “cost it incurs”) by running with higher inventory levels is probably relatively lower. And the
strategy of the third of these facilities might best be described as one of acquiring information.
Before reading further, can you match up these three facilities with the three points on the OM
triangle?

The emergency room simply cannot tolerate a high level of inventory (at least not if the customers
truly come in because of real emergencies – patients will die if they have to wait too long for
service). Furthermore, for practical purposes, the emergency room cannot obtain advance
information regarding customer arrival times and treatment requirements. Thus the emergency
room’s only real option is to acquire “extra” capacity – some of its resources may go unused for
periods of time (or be used for care that is less time critical) because these resources must be
available just in case of an emergency. (One might argue that the extra capacity that an emergency
room acquires isn’t really extra – it is optimal to have some capacity that frequently sits idle). The
same argument holds for a fire station, for example. When you drive by a fire station, you often see
the trucks setting there idle. These idle trucks represent unused capacity – but these extra resources
are necessary, because the system simply cannot tolerate an inventory of raw materials (fires waiting
to be put out represent RM in this system). The emergency room’s position is reflected by point (a)
in Figure 2.

The situation for a free clinic is very different. It typically has a somewhat captive audience, while
possibly facing extreme pressures to keep costs down. Thus while the non-paying patients certainly
can become disgruntled by having to wait, such waits may not be all that “costly” to the clinic (the
patients have no acceptable alternatives for their health care – they can’t go elsewhere). Because of
the cost pressures, the free clinic may have no money to spend on extra capacity or on sophisticated
information systems. Thus such a facility might choose to operate at the “inventory” point on the
OM triangle (operating with a high level of inventory, but with relatively lower levels of capacity and
information). This is denoted as point (b) in Figure 2.

Finally, consider the hospital that caters to customers who need hernia operations. Shouldice
Hospital (Heskett 2003) is such a facility. Shouldice has a very regimented surgical procedure, called
the “Shouldice method.” Shouldice additionally sends surveys to its patients prior to their arrival
asking for information that helps insure that the patients are good candidates for the treatment
Shouldice offers (this further helps reduce variability in process time). And Shouldice of course
schedules the surgeries, such that variability in the arrivals of customers is virtually nonexistent.
Thus Shouldice can operate its facility almost like clockwork, and it can keep nearly all its beds full
without creating customer waits (virtually no customer has to wait for a bed). It has information
that allows it to virtually eliminate variability – it operates at the “information” point on the OM
triangle. This firm effectively operates at point (c) in Figure 2.

Thus the triangle formed by points (a), (b), and (c) in Figure 2 effectively depict the OM triangle.
You must decide what is best for your facility – should you operate at the capacity point (a), the
inventory point (b), or the information point (c) – or is your best position somewhere in-between?
Some questions to ask in determining your best position are: What are the consequences of
inventory (long wait times)? Are there ways to mitigate the effect of wait times (e.g., can you

4
entertain the customers while they wait)? Are your resources prohibitively expensive or relatively
inexpensive? Are customers willing to pay a premium for immediate service? Is it cost-effective or
even possible to get information as to customer arrival times and process times? And importantly,
can you find an operating point that differentiates you from your competitors and makes your
service a high-value proposition for customers?

If you ignore the tradeoffs described by the OM triangle, it will ensnare you more surely than the
Bermuda Triangle might ensnarl a pilot. But if you manage these tradeoffs wisely, and in concert
with your overarching firm strategy, it is a prescription for improving the health of your firm;
increasing its performance and profitability.

References

Connolly, Ceci (2005). “Toyota Assembly Line Inspires Improvements at Hospital,” Washington
Post, June 3, 2005.
Heskett, James L. (2003), “Shouldice Hospital Limited”, Harvard Business Publishing Case 9-683-
068
Lovejoy, William (1998), “Integrated Operations: A Proposal for Operations Management Teaching
and Research”, Production and Operations Management, 7(2).
Schmidt, Glen (2005), “The OM Triangle”, Operations Management Education Review, 1(1), 87-104

APPENDIX: Theoretical Basis for the OM Triangle

The tradeoffs as described by the OM triangle are grounded in a sound analytical framework, the
G/G/1 queueing model. In this section we derive the OM triangle using this model. (If a more
qualitative approach is desired, this section may be omitted.)

A brief description of the G/G/1 and the notation used herein is depicted in Figure 3. A more
comprehensive description of the G/G/1 is given in many Operations textbooks.

Queue Server (resource)

3 2 1

Figure 3. The G/G/1 Model.

Arrivals Services
Arrival rate (or flow rate) = R Capacity, or processing rate = c
Mean interarrival time = a = 1 / R Mean service (processing) time = p = 1 / c
Standard deviation in interarrival time = sa Standard deviation in processing time = sp
Coefficient of variation in interarrival time Coefficient of variation in processing time
= CVa = sa / a = R sa = CVp = sp / p = c sp
Average waiting time in queue = Tq Utilization = u = R / c = p / a
Average number in queue = Iq Average number in service = u
Average total waiting time in the system (in the queue and in service) = T = Tq + p
Average total number in the system (in the queue and in service) = I = Iq + u

5
In this model, customers (or jobs) arrive individually and join a queue, to be processed by a single
resource (called a “server”). For example, the model can be applied to the dunking booth
mentioned earlier. A customer arrives, she joins the queue, and when she gets to the front of the
line and the previous customer finishes his turn, she is “served” (meaning she takes her turn at
trying to dunk the celebrity).

The expected rate at which customers arrive will be denoted by R, such that the expected time
between arrivals, denoted by a, is a = 1/R (if 15 customers arrive every hour, then customers arrive
every 1/15 hour or every four minutes on average). The times between customer arrivals (i.e., the
interarrival times) are not always the same, but vary, with a standard deviation of sa. The coefficient
of variation in interarrival times, CVa, is the standard deviation divided by the mean, or CVa = sa / a
= sa R. The expected time that a customer waits in the queue before her turn is Tq, while the
expected number of customers in the queue is Iq.

The maximum number of customers that can get served per unit of time is the capacity c, which is
the inverse of the time that the processing time it takes for each service, p = 1/c (in the dunking
booth example, if each person spends two minutes throwing baseballs, then the maximum service
rate is ½ = 0.5 customers per minute). The service times are not always the same (in the dunking
booth example, some pick up the baseballs and throw quickly without buying another set, while
others may joke around in-between throws and may buy multiple rounds). The standard deviation
in processing times is denoted by sp, yielding a coefficient of variation of CVp = sp / p = sp R.

The fraction of time that the service is busy is denoted by u (for utilization), and u is calculated as
the time it takes for a service divided by the interarrival time, u = p / a = R/c (if a person
spends two minutes at the dunking booth, and a person arrives every four minutes, then there is a
person at the booth 2/4 = 50% of the time).

The expected time it takes for a customer (or job) to get through the system, denoted by T, is the
expected time spent waiting in the queue, Tq, plus the expected time spent being served, p. That is,
T = Tq + p.

In this system, the items waiting in the queue (if any) are effectively raw materials, and the item in
service (if any) represents work-in-process (WIP). There are no finished goods – an item leaves the
system when service is completed. (This is typical of a service operation, where the item in service
is a person. For example, if the service is a psychological counseling session, you don’t find
psychologists that have a finished counseling session ready on the shelf to give to a customer – it is
infeasible to hold an inventory of finished goods.)

Thus the total expected inventory in the system (i.e., the total expected number of items in the
system), I, is equal to the expected number in the queue, Iq, plus the expected number in service, u.
To show that u is the expected number of items in service, the following logic is applied. There is
always either one item in service or none (e.g., in the dunking booth, there is either someone
throwing balls at the target, or nobody). When somebody is throwing baseballs, the server is
utilized, and when there is no item in the server it is unutilized. Thus the fraction of time the server
is busy, u, is also the expected number of items in service. This leads us to the formula I = Iq + u.

6
In deriving the OM triangle from this model, we will make use of a simple formula know as Little’s
Law. This Law applies to any queueing system in steady state, meaning that it applies if the number
of arrivals into the system is, over the long run, equal to the number of departures from the system.
Dr. Little showed that in such a system, the expected number of items in the system is equal to the
rate of arrivals to the system multiplied by the expected time spent in the system. In the context of
our model, this means that Iq = R Tq. This means that we can now write our previous formula I = Iq
+ u as I = R Tq + u. (We simply substituted R Tq for Iq.)

Another useful formula gives the expected time that a customer (or job) must wait in the queue
before being served. This is known as the modified Pollaczek-Khinchine (PK) formula:
 u   CVa + CVp 
2 2

Tq = p     .
 1 − u   2 

  u   CVa 2 + CVp 2  
Thus, again proceeding by substitution: I = R Tq + u = R  p     + u .
  1 − u   2  

  u   CVa 2 + CVp 2  
Simplifying algebraically, we find: I = u 1 +     .
  1 − u   2  

CVa 2 + CVp 2   u  
Next define V as a variability factor, V = , such that I = u 1 +  V  .
2   1− u  

Notice in the preceding equation that the inventory, I, is a function of only two variables, the
utilization u and the variability factor, V. Thus we can generate a plot of I versus u, where u ranges
from zero to one (utilization is greater than zero, and can’t exceed one), making individual curves
(isoquants) for specific levels of variability. Figure 3 shows the results for V = 2, V = 1, V = 0.5,
V = 0.1, and V = 0.01.

Figure 4 effectively portrays the tradeoffs between utilization, inventory, and variability. In the
upcoming section we will discuss these tradeoffs in the context of points (a), (b), and (c): point (a)
is associated with u = 0.5, I = 1, and V = 1; point (b) is associated with u = 0.9, I = 9, and V = 1;
and point (c) is associated with u = 0.9, I = 1, and V = 0.01.

Another equation following directly from Little’s Law is I = R T, which can be written as
T = I (1 / R ). Thus holding R constant, the expected waiting time is simply some multiple of the
expected number of items in the systems. This means that the curves for T versus u would look
similar to (have the same shape as) those for I versus u. In other words, increasing variability and
increasing utilization have the same detrimental effect on lead-time as they have on inventory level.
(Here we think of lead-time as the expected total time is takes an item to get through the system –
in other contexts, we may attach a slightly different meaning to lead-time, such as the time the firm
quotes between receipt and delivery of an order, which may be different from the average time it
actually takes.)

7
10 (b)
8
(CVa2 + CVp2) / 2 = 2
Inventory, I 6 1
0.5
4
0.1
2 0.01

0 (a) (c)
0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

Utilization, u

Figure 4. The Tradeoffs as Determined by the G/G/1

View publication stats

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen