Sie sind auf Seite 1von 12

Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w. e l s ev i e r. c o m / l o c a t e / e c m o d

The choice of foreign market entry mode: An analysis of the dynamic probit model
Ming-Yuan Chen a,⁎, Jing-Yun Chang b
a
Graduate Institute of Human Resource Management, National Central University, No. 300, Jhongda Rd., Jhongli City, Taoyuan County 32001, Taiwan
b
Department of Industrial Economics, Tamkang University, No.151, Ying-Chuan Road, Tamshui, Taipei County 25137, Taiwan

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Based on the official survey data of Taiwanese FDI in China, this study investigates the transaction cost
Accepted 11 August 2010 determinants of foreign market entry mode choice. In contrast to the existing literature, this paper constructs
a panel data set and makes a dynamic probit analysis on the mode choice between wholly-owned
JEL classification:
subsidiaries and joint ventures. Empirical results indicate that state dependence between current and past
L23
modes plays an important role in determining entry mode choice. However, the impact of state dependence
M21
will be reduced significantly if the mode adopted in the previous period is associated with poor performance
Keywords: of the parent firm. There is strong linkage between mode performance and future mode choice. Evidence also
Entry mode choice shows that the hypothesized influences of transaction cost factors on entry mode choice gain support in the
Dynamic probit model dynamic choice process.
Transaction cost theory © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction Other models are also developed to explain the phenomena


associated with entry mode choice. The eclectic framework intro-
One of the most critical decisions faced by multinational enter- duced and developed by Dunning (1980, 1988, 1998, 2000) is a model
prises (MNEs) intending to undertake foreign direct investment (FDI) commonly applied. This approach states that the entry mode
is the choice of foreign market entry mode. A large number of studies decisions are determined by three sets of advantages as perceived
analyze the determinants of entry mode choice within the transaction by enterprises, namely, ownership advantages, location advantages,
cost framework proposed by Anderson and Gatignon (1986). Based on and internalization advantages. The more advantages a firm has the
the transaction cost economics initiated by Williamson (1975, 1985), greater the tendency of adopting the mode with a high level of
the underlying theory claims that the organizational structure and control. The resource-based view is also among the most frequently
design are determined by the trade-off between market transaction applied perspectives. This view, including knowledge-based and
costs and hierarchical control costs. Depending on the factors organizational capabilities theories, regards a firm as a bundle of
pertaining to transaction specific assets, external and internal capabilities and knowledge, where individual skill, organization and
uncertainty, and the potential for opportunistic behavior, MNEs technology are linked together (Aulakh and Kotabe, 1997; Madhok,
choose a specific mode of entry in order to minimize transaction 1998; Nelson and Winter, 1982). Entry mode decisions are made
costs. Transaction cost analysis has been extended by many research- under the consideration related to the development and acquisition of
ers by integrating several factors into the given framework, such as firm-specific resources and capabilities. Brouthers et al. (2008b)
environmental and strategic factors, network relationship, and further argue that resource-based advantages have different levels of
institutional and cultural factors (i.e., Brouthers, 2002; Coviello and applicability in different national institutional environment. The entry
Munro, 1997; Hennart, 1991; Hill, et al., 1990; Lu, 2002; Yiu and mode predicted by a model that incorporates both resource-based
Makino, 2002). In a recent study, Brouthers et al. (2008a) combine advantages and external institutional factors yields better subsidiary
transaction cost economics with insights from the real option theory performance. A survey article by Brouthers and Hennart (2007)
and suggest that this model effectively improves decision-making provides a review of issues and various approaches for the interna-
outcomes. The firms choose the entry mode predicted by this tional entry mode research.
combined model have significantly satisfactory performance. This paper examines the transaction cost determinants of entry
mode choice between wholly-owned subsidiaries (WOSs) and joint
ventures (JVs) for Taiwanese FDI in China. Taiwan has been one of the
main contributors of FDI flows in the East Asian area since 1990,
⁎ Corresponding author. Tel.: + 886 3 422 7151x66153; fax: + 886 3 422 7492. particularly for the investment into the Chinese market. People in
E-mail address: mychen@mgt.ncu.edu.tw (M.-Y. Chen). Taiwan share common language, ethnic links, and cultural traits with

0264-9993/$ – see front matter © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.econmod.2010.08.004
440 M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450

Chinese. A lot of Taiwanese have strong affection for their original agreements or export to China prior to establishing plants there. This
home in China and have strong commitment to their family. Shared feature makes it less necessary to consider contracts as an alternative
culture and family relations produce more mutual trust and less mode of servicing the Chinese market. Besides, according to the
uncertainty between Taiwanese investors and Chinese local firms perspective articulated by Hennart (1988, 1989, 2000), the remuner-
(Wei et al., 2005). The influence of cultural distance between home ation to input suppliers in the equity modes, either WOSs or JVs, is
and host countries on entry mode choice is widely recognized in the paid ex post from the profit of the venture, which is different from
literature. Large cultural distance, implying high transaction costs for contracts with payments being specified ex ante. The variables that
MNEs investing overseas, may lead them to adopting JVs as the entry determine the choice between contracts and equity modes are thus
mode (Hennart and Larimo, 1998). Foreign investors can share risk not necessarily the same as those affecting the choice between WOSs
with local partners and avoid costly mistakes in an environment with and JVs (Brouthers and Hennart, 2007). Gatignon and Anderson
unfamiliar culture. Cultural advantages for Taiwanese firms' entry into (1988) and Brouthers et al. (2003) also emphasize that the role of
China suggest that they inherently prefer WOSs to JVs as they are transaction cost variables in predicting entry mode choice when a
more acquainted with local conditions and hence are less reliant on contractual partnership has been chosen is not as clear as for the
local firms. Strategically, Taiwanese firms tend to enter this culturally decision as to whether to set up a WOS or JV. Therefore, while
similar market with wholly-owned modes in order to obtain a high classifying entry modes in a binary way may reduce the variability of
return (Brouthers, 2002; Kim and Hwang, 1992). It is thus interesting mode choice, it allows for a more explicit and precise test of
to know whether the transaction cost arguments gain support in transaction cost arguments. Examining the binary choice between
explaining the mode choice when WOSs seem to be a MNE's natural WOSs and JVs has been the methodology adopted by many entry
choice. mode studies, e.g., Brouthers (2002), Chen and Hennart (2002),
The main feature of this paper is that we construct a panel data set Cleeve (1997), Hennart (1991), Hennart and Larimo (1998), Makino
to make a dynamic binary choice analysis on mode choice. Previous and Neupert (2000), and Padmanabhan and Cho (1996).
studies generally regard entry mode choice as a one-stage static This paper also distinguishes the entry mode, i.e., WOSs vs. JVs,
decision-making problem. However, the choice may be a multiple- from the establishment mode, i.e., greenfields vs. acquisitions, and
stage dynamic process in the sense that firms having started to enter focuses on the former. In the literature, some researchers have mixed
into a foreign market may change their original strategy due to these two dimensions by considering the choice among, say, wholly-
learning effects or unanticipated developments and results. There are owned greenfields, wholly-owned acquisitions, and JV greenfields.
two merits in the panel data dynamic choice analysis. First, although However, in the survey article of international entry mode research,
cross-sectional studies can test the relation between observed firm Brouthers and Hennart (2007) do not include the studies as to the
characteristics and entry mode choice, they overlook that the choice choice between greenfield and acquisition entry. They argue that in
might be affected by unobserved heterogeneity across firms. The view of the theoretical reasons and the empirical evidence, the
panel data model has greater flexibility in modeling behavior decision of entry mode and the decision of establishment mode are
differences among individuals. Second, a dynamic specification, separate and independently made. This distinction is also recognized
where the effect of the lagged dependent variable is considered in by several studies, e.g., Dikova and van Witteloostuijn (2007),
the binary choice model, is necessary since state dependence (or Hennart (2000), Hennart and Park (1993), and Padmanabhan and
habit-persistence) is important for a firm's entry mode decision. Some Cho (1996).
firms may remain more likely to choose JVs than others in every Based on the official survey data conducted by the Department of
period due to firm heterogeneity. However, having JVs in one period Statistics of Taiwan, this paper shows that state dependence, which
may also lower the probability of choosing WOSs in the next period suggests the persistence between current and previous entry modes,
because of large adjustment costs in changing the organizational form is important in explaining an MNE's entry mode choice. It is also
in relatively short periods. This reflects the effect of state dependence. evidenced that the transaction cost arguments of entry mode choice
Heckman (1981a) has shown that state dependence is particularly gain support when state dependence has been controlled in a
important in a panel that has only a few observations for each dynamic probit model, provided that this model is appropriately
individual, which, we believe, is a usual case for most of entry mode estimated by assuming the endogeneity of initial conditions. Trans-
data. By modeling the dynamic effect in the binary choice model, the action cost economics predict the choice of entry modes satisfactorily
transaction cost influences (i.e., the impact of firm heterogeneity) on even if the MNEs inherently have greater propensity of using WOSs
entry mode choice can be tested in a more precise way that controls because of common cultural traits, at least for Taiwanese FDI in China.
for state dependence of mode choice. Furthermore, there is evidence supporting an intriguing dynamic
Furthermore, as indicated by Brouthers and Hennart (2007), phenomenon that poor mode performance lowers the degree of state
although entry mode studies have made experience a standard dependence. The possibility of continuing adoption of WOSs in the
variable in mode choice models to consider the effect of learning from current period due to mode dependence will be reduced significantly
past choices, they fail to distinguish between favorable and unfavor- if WOSs used in the previous period produces poor performance in the
able experience. A firm that has tried JVs and has not performed well MNE's parent firm.
will consider whether continue using JVs or try another mode type. As The next section presents the empirical models, including static
performance reflects the success and failure of the selected mode, the and dynamic binary choice models. Section 3 reviews the literature
dynamic setting is able to identify the link between previous mode and discusses the transaction cost determinants of entry mode
performance and future mode choices. It allows us to examine how choice. Section 4 describes data and variable measurement. The
mode performance affects state dependence of mode choice. In sum, a empirical results are presented in Section 5, and finally Section 6
dynamic binary choice analysis, with its capability of dealing with the concludes.
persistence effect of mode use and the impact of past performance on
mode choice dynamics, might help us obtain additional insights not 2. Static and dynamic models of entry mode choice
available from the cross-sectional techniques.
The dichotomous specification of WOSs and JVs used in this paper Previous studies generally use cross-sectional data for probit or
deserves more notice. In the entry mode literature, three commonly logit models to analyze the choice of foreign entry mode. In this study,
explored modes are wholly-owned mode, joint venture mode, and since longitudinal data from official surveys are available to track a
non-equity contractual mode such as licensing, franchising, and firm's mode choices, the binary choice models and their estimation
exporting. In the Chinese market, few Taiwanese firms use licensing are extended to the panel data format.
M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450 441

The structure of the static random effects probit model for entry observations belong to all periods except period 1, and fit = 0 other-
mode choice is specified as wise (Arulampalam and Stewart, 2007). This is also the procedure
adopted in LIMDEP program (version 9.0, 2007). The encompassing
 
Prob ½ MODEit = 1j xit ; ui  = Φ α + β ′ xit + ηt + σu ui ðfor t = 1; …; Ti Þ model is thus
ð1Þ h i
Prob MODEit = 1jMODEi;t1 ; xit ; xi1 ; ui
where the subscript i indexes individual firms and t indexes time
period (year). The panel is unbalanced in this study. MODEit is a
½
= Φ γMODEi;t1 + β′ xit + δ′ xi1 + ηt + ðα + σ u ui Þfit ð4Þ

binary variable for entry mode choice. MODEit = 1 indicating WOSs 


+ ðξ + τ u ui Þdit ðfor t = 1; …; Ti Þ
and MODEit = 0 for JVs. The xit represents explanatory variables that
are hypothesized to determine mode choice. ηt is a set of year
dummies to filter macro-economic shocks that are common across The coefficients on fit and dit are viewed as random coefficients
firms. ui ~ N(0,1) accounts for firm-specific unobserved heterogene- that share the common random component, ui, as both σuui and τuui
ity and is assumed to be independent of the model's random error appear in the equation. The contribution of observations from firm i to
term. Φ is the cumulative density function of the standard normal the likelihood is the joint density
distribution. As the variance of the random error term is normalized
to 1, the underlying variance of the model's disturbance is thus equal Li ðΛ jMODEi ; xi ; ui Þ
to 1 + σu2. For the same individual firm, the disturbances in different
two periods are correlated because of their common component, ui,
T
½
= ∏t i = 1 Φ γMODEi;t1 + β′ xit ð5Þ
and their correlation (ρ) is a constant given by ρ = σu2 /1+σu2. The
parameters for estimation in this model include the coefficient vector

+ δ xi1 + ηt + ðα + σu ui Þfit + ðξ + τu ui Þdit 
β and the parameter ρ. The parameters will be fitted by maximum
likelihood estimation. A statistically significant estimate of ρ would where Λ represents the full set of structural parameters, including
suggest the importance of controlling for unobserved heterogeneity, nonrandom slope parameters and random parameters. Since ui is
and imply that the random effects probit model is a better unobserved, it is necessary to operate the unconditional likelihood,
specification than the pooled probit model where ρ is assumed to i.e., ui must be integrated out. The contribution of firm i to the
be zero. unconditional likelihood is thus given by
The dynamic version (or habit-persistence version) of the random
effects probit model can be written as Li ðΛ jMODEi ; xi Þ

h
Prob MODEit = 1 jMODE i;t−1 ; xit ; ui
i ð T
½
= ∫ui ∏t i = 1 Φ γMODEi;t1 + β′ xit + δ′ xi1 ð6Þ
 
= Φ α + γMODEi;t−1 + β′ xit + ηt + σu ui ðfor t = 2; …; Ti Þ
ð2Þ + ηt + ðα + σu ui Þfit + ðξ + τu ui Þdit Þ gðu Þdu
i i

where g(⋅) is the probability density function of the standard normal


where the observed entry mode in the previous period, MODEi,t − 1, is distribution. The integrals will not exist in closed form, but since they
included. The coefficient γ represents the degree of state dependence. are of the form of expectation, they can be estimated by simulation.
Correlation between ui (time-invariant term) and MODEi,t − 1 makes The simulated log-likelihood is
the latter endogenous in (2). Estimation requires an assumption about
the relation between the first period observations (initial conditions),
MODEi1, and ui. If the initial conditions are assumed to be exogenous,
n 1 R
R
T
½
logLs = ∑i = 1 log ∑r = 1 ∏t i = 1 Φ γMODEi;t1 + β′ xit + δ′ xi1
    ð7Þ
i.e., MODEi1 and ui are not correlated, which may be appropriate if the
start of the process is the start of the observation period for each firm,
+ ηt + α + σu ui;r fit + ξ + τ u ui;r dit 
the maximum likelihood random effects probit estimation mentioned
above can be used. If the initial conditions are correlated with ui, as The simulation is over R draws on ui for each firm i. The maximum
would be expected in the current study, this estimation method will simulated likelihood (MSL) estimator can be obtained by maximizing
be inconsistent and overstate state dependence. Eq. (7) over the full set of structural parameters. We use LIMDEP
Heckman (1981b) suggests an approximation to the process program, with the simulation over 500 draws (R = 500), to estimate
generating the first period observations using the same form of the model. The relevant theory of simulation based estimation can be
equation as for the rest of the observations but with some restrictions. referred to Greene's (2007) textbook.
Heckman's approach has been used in the studies of dynamic
(intertemporal) labor force participation (e.g., Hyslop, 1999; Stewart, 3. Determinants of entry mode choice
2007). In the current context, a suggested equation for the first period
observations is In this section, by reviewing the literature we discuss the
hypothesized relations between transaction cost factors and entry
  mode choice. Besides, since this paper emphasizes state dependence
Prob ½ MODEi1 = 1jxi1 ; ui  = Φ ξ + δ′ xi1 + τu ui ðfor t = 1Þ ð3Þ
of mode choice in a dynamic framework, previous mode performance
is also a key factor to determine the current mode choice.
The model of Eq. (2) is retained for t ≥ 2. The same random effect,
ui, appears in both Eqs. (2) and (3) but has different scaling 3.1. Scale of the firm
parameters, σu and τu, respectively. Exogeneity of the initial
conditions corresponds to su = 0 and can be tested accordingly. Relative to large MNEs, smaller ones suffer from fewer productive
Eqs. (2) and (3) specify a complete model for the dynamic process. resources such as managerial skills, human resources, or financial
A simplified procedure to implement Heckman's estimator involves resources, and have limited complementary assets. They are also
the creation of two dummy variables: dit = 1 if the observations exposed to more risks and uncertainty as a failure of foreign
belong to period 1, and dit = 0 otherwise; fit = 1–dit = 1 if the investment could possibly lead the entire enterprise to bankruptcy.
442 M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450

These inherent weaknesses may encourage small MNEs to make JV holding key positions. Over time, when the firms have gained local
agreements with local firms that have close relationship with local knowledge and have adapted to local conditions, they are more
environment and have easier access to information channels and willing to delegate control and to use JV modes. Davidson and
assets (Asiedu and Esfahani, 2001; Kogut and Singh, 1988; Mutinelli McFetridge (1984, 1985) also argue that experience encourages JVs
and Piscitello, 1998). In addition, large MNEs with large worldwide because experienced firms are able to enforce, monitor, and control
networks of subsidiaries are more capable of exploiting global the JV agreements more effectively after acquiring that kind of
economics of scale than small ones. Global strategies may cause experience by running an integrated operation.
global profit maximization by MNEs to diverge from local profit
maximization by their JV partners. The action of the partners will 3.4. Technological capability and sources of the subsidiary's technology
affect MNEs' operation in other countries, while having no such
external effect on local partners' operation (Gomes-Casseres, 1989). The transaction cost theory traditionally explains the association
This spillover effect of JVs is more likely to appear in large MNEs that between technological capability and entry mode choice by focusing
operate subsidiaries in more than one host countries and have more on the tacit knowledge transfers among firms. MNEs with high R&D
cross-border transactions within the firm. WOSs will thus be a capability tend to transfer proprietary technology of products or
preferred entry mode for large MNEs that tend to have goal conflicts processes to their subsidiaries. They should prefer a complete control
with local firms. of subsidiaries. One reason is that it is difficult to obtain a fair return
for the technology contributed by the parent to the JVs (Hennart,
3.2. Relative size of the subsidiary 1982). Another reason is the fear of leaking proprietary technology
beyond the JVs and losing technological advantages to their rivals
The entry mode decision can be determined by the trade-off (Anderson and Gatignon, 1986; Bhaumik and Gelb, 2005; Hennart,
between risks and returns and by resource availability and need for 1982, 1991; Hill et al., 1990; Mutinelli and Piscitello, 1998). For
control (Agarwal and Ramaswami, 1992). A large investment is Taiwanese FDI in China, while the main objective of Taiwanese firms is
usually associated with high risks and returns and requires the ability to learn more about the local business conditions, their venturing
of MNEs to secure financial resources. When the size of the subsidiary partners' objective usually is to access proprietary technology that
relative to the parent (or to the entire enterprise) is large, MNEs have gives them competitive advantages. Thus, the threat of proprietary
more resources committed to the local subsidiaries. They will have technology leakage encourages Taiwanese MNEs having higher R&D
greater incentives to choose WOSs with tight control because the capability to choose WOSs in China.
subsidiary's performance has more significant impact on the overall It can be further argued that the entry mode decision is related to
performance of the firm (Bhaumik and Gelb, 2005). However, this the sources of the subsidiary's technology. An MNE will have strong
propensity of favoring WOSs tends to diminish as the MNE's scale incentives to choose WOSs if the technology of its subsidiary is
increases. For a given relative size of the subsidiary, the absolute size proprietarily sourced from the parent, because it will especially
rises as the MNEs grows larger. The incentives for firms to use JV concern about the risk of dissemination of technological know-how.
modes become stronger so as to acquire local partners' expertise of On the other hand, JVs will be appropriate for an MNE whose
running a large organization in the host country (Gatignon and subsidiary's technology is outsourced to third-party providers. The
Anderson, 1988). subsidiary can benefit from the opportunity of learning in cooperation
and from the creation of its own capability via interfirm knowledge
3.3. International experience transfers.

Many studies have argued that the more international experience 3.5. Product markets and sources of materials
a firm possesses the more efficient it is to gain full control of
subsidiaries (Anderson and Gatignon, 1986; Chang and Rosenzweig, When the products of foreign subsidiaries are sold to the local
2001; Delios and Beamish, 1999; Gatignon and Anderson, 1988; market, rather than exported to the home market or other
Gomes-Casseres, 1989; Hennart, 1991; Mutinelli and Piscitello, 1998). countries, MNEs will desire more local market knowledge in
The firms with less experience in managing foreign production lack order to deal with uncertainty in the product market, such as the
the knowledge of dealing with local economic and environmental unexpected changes in product demand and customer's preferences
conditions. That knowledge, which is tacit and subject to high and the availability of substitute or complementary products
transaction costs, usually accrues to local firms. Less-experienced (Brouthers et al., 2002). That knowledge can be readily obtained
firms are thus not willing to make significant resource commitments through venturing with local firms. Therefore, MNEs tend to choose
and tend to have recourse to local firms. The tendency of using WOSs JVs if their subsidiaries primarily sell to the local market. Hennart
increases as the parent accumulates experience and develops (1991) and Hennart and Zeng (2005) also indicate that the export
expertise and knowledge in managing international operations. of the subsidiary's products may compete with domestic or third
Also, from the view of internal uncertainty in Williamson's (1975, country's sales of the parent and cause the conflict between global
1985) transaction cost framework, unlike experienced MNEs that may and local profit maximization pursued by MNEs and their venturing
have developed strong internal control mechanisms to reduce partners respectively. When the subsidiary's products are sold
internal uncertainty, inexperienced MNEs are less capable of knowing locally, the goal conflict is expected to be smaller and JVs are likely
how to monitor and evaluate inputs appropriately and will make to be chosen.
considerable errors to depress efficiency if they try to exercise higher The tangible nature of products for manufacturing MNEs makes
control (Anderson and Gatignon, 1986; Gatignon and Anderson, them perceptive to the variations in quality, quantity, and timing of
1988). Low-control modes such as JVs become more attractive for raw materials and intermediate inputs (Brouthers et al., 2002;
inexperienced MNEs that cannot manage a wholly-owned integrated Richardson, 1993). When subsidiaries have to obtain materials from
structure efficiently. local suppliers, uncertainty implied in such transactions will motivate
On the contrary, Anderson and Gatignon (1986) indicate that MNEs to engage in JVs so as to rely on local partners that already
based on the ethnocentric orientation of international neophytes, possess reliable and constant provision of materials or have developed
international experience would be negatively related to the level of networks of outside suppliers. Apparently, if the materials of
ownership control. Ethnocentrism leads inexperienced firms to subsidiaries are directly provided by parent firms, the secured source
demand high ownership first to develop their own advantages by should lead to use of WOSs.
M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450 443

3.6. Resource-intensive industries resources. However, the structural problems faced by JVs (Hennart
and Zeng, 2005) are more likely to emerge when MNEs enter into an
MNEs are likely to venture with local firms if their products are unfamiliar industry. Venturing with local firms that have tacit
intensive in the resources that make a host country attractive as a knowledge specific to the new industry implies greater asymmetric
location of foreign investment. Entering into a country in the form of dependence on local partners. This allows local firms to expropriate
JVs can reduce transaction costs of acquiring local resources via the quasi-rent stream of foreign investors by taking advantage of
developing the business relation with local firms controlling the unspecified and unenforceable elements of the contract. Anticipating
access to resources. This will be the case in the industries where local this potential costly redistribution, MNEs may not choose JV modes.
backward integration into natural resource is important. The higher Thus, because of two opposite influences, the relation between
tendency towards JVs in resource-intensive industries may be due to diversified investment and mode choice may be ambiguous.
that local firms have exclusive or privileged access to domestic supply Nevertheless, the consideration of avoiding the threat of expro-
of agricultural or mineral resources which can be vertically integrated priation will play a more significant role in the FDI activities of small
with processing, and that there may not be well-functioning and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs). Contrast to large enterprises,
competitive markets for these resources because local institutions, SMEs are generally less-experienced internationally and do not have
business regulations, and government policies discourage or prohibit well-developed systems and processes for information access and
wholly-owned foreign investment in resource industries, particularly capital availability. Since SMEs spend most of their resources in a
in emerging economies (Chen and Hennart, 2002; Gomes-Casseres, unique foreign market, they may be most concerned with the
1989; Hennart, 1991; Mutinelli and Piscitello, 1998). Besides, unforeseen opportunistic behavior by the local partners when joint
resources-intensive industries are less dependent on a firm's venturing into a new industry. Thus, adoption of WOSs in diversified
complicated R&D and marketing capabilities so that the experience investment is likely to appear in small SMEs. However, this tendency
of local firms is relatively important in such basic industries than in decreases as firms grow and have greater abilities to solve holdup
more advanced industries (Gomes-Casseres, 1989). This also predicts problems in JV contracts.
the higher possibility that JVs are chosen in resource-intensive
sectors.
3.9. Relational network
3.7. Production relations between the subsidiary and the parent firm
The social relational network is important for SMEs' internation-
alization process (Bell, 1995; Chen and Chen, 1998; Coviello and
In the production system the parent firm and its subsidiaries can
Munro, 1997). The relational network, which is built on the
be linked vertically or horizontally. Vertically linkages are normally at
relationship among relatives, friends, alumni, and religious beliefs,
a stage of the production process that comes either before or after the
establishes trust norms and creates highly elastic external linkages.
main activity of the parent firm. Subsidiaries either turn raw materials
These linkages encompass non-contractual transaction based on
into semi-manufactured products or turn semi-manufactured pro-
inter-personal links and trust beyond pure business relations, and
ducts into final products. Horizontal linkages involve use of the same
provide technology, entrepreneurial know-how and market access to
or modified technology to produce more or less the same product.
support cross-border operations (Chen and Chen, 1998). Members of
Brouthers and Hennart (2007) point out that Williamson's concept of
the relational network value relationship rather than discrete
asset specificity is more appropriately applicable to vertical invest-
transactions so that opportunistic behavior is expected to be
ments although many entry mode studies have used it to explain
controlled and minimized (Coviello and Munro, 1997). A firm short
horizontal expansions. Asset specificity implies bilateral dependence
of firm-specific assets might still succeed in making foreign
between transacting partners. Coordinated efforts are required to
investment because the relational network helps it overcome entry
solve opportunism and self-interested bargaining. Due to the
barriers of foreign markets, enables it to access into local comple-
increased costs associated with the coordinated efforts, transaction
mentary resources markets, and facilitates rapid acquisition of capital
cost economics suggests a positive relation between the degree of
and trade connections.
asset specificity and the likelihood that WOSs are chosen (Yiu and
The relational network is important for Taiwanese FDI activities. As
Makino, 2002). Therefore, vertical linkages between foreign subsid-
in the footwear industry exemplified by Chen and Chen (1998), the
iaries and their parent firms, implying more attributes of asset
network that creates mutual trust and understanding facilitates SMEs
specificity, should encourage the use of WOSs.
to maintain business by following Taiwanese or foreign clients to host
The propensity of choosing WOSs when the parent firm and its
countries in response to rising of wage and manufacturing costs. The
subsidiary are vertically connected may differ across industries.
relational network gives assistance akin to that from local partners,
Relative to less-advanced industries, such as resource-intensive
and allows foreign investors to be less reliant on local firms. Thus, the
industries, advanced industries have more complicated vertical
stronger are the relational network connections, the more likely an
transactions for material and intermediate goods or for marketing
MNE will choose WOSs.
and distribution, and hence are likely confronted with the contractual
holdup problems. One can argue that the vertically-linked production
relationship in motivating MNEs to choose WOSs tends to appear in 3.10. Previous mode performance
non-resource-intensive industries.
MNEs can learn from the previous mode and determine current
3.8. Diversification mode choice depending on whether previous mode performance is
favorable or unfavorable (Brouthers and Hennart, 2007). In the
Several studies have shown that MNEs will enter a foreign market dynamic choice process, as current mode choice is assumed to be
through JVs when they are diversified into a different industry affected by the previous mode, it is expected that previous mode
(Asiedu and Esfahani, 2001; Gomes-Casseres, 1989; Hennart, 1991; performance will influence the dependence between current and
Mutinelli and Piscitello, 1998). The parent firm may find that the previous mode choices. Poor performance should reduce the degree of
product-specific knowledge and distribution access needed to enter state dependence, in the sense that the likelihood of choosing WOSs in
into a new industry are subject to high transaction costs and are the current period is reduced if the wholly-owned mode used in the
difficult to acquire in the market. Joint venturing with local firms in previous period produced poor performance. Such firms might think
the new industry is the most efficient way to obtain relevant that changing the mode to JVs will improve performance.
444 M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450

Table 1
The number of FDI firms in 2004–2007 annual surveys.

2004 survey 2005 survey 2006 survey 2007 survey

Number of FDI firms in the survey 1880 1711 1677 1770


Number of manufacturing FDI firms in the survey 1741 1434 1367 1485
Number of manufacturing FDI firms with China being the major FDI country 1307 1145 1106 1198
Number of manufacturing FDI firms with China being the major FDI country as 75.07% 79.85% 80.38% 80.67%
a percentage of number of manufacturing FDI firms

Source: Department of Statistics, Ministry of Economic Affairs of Taiwan.

4. Data and variable measurement (0.903 vs. 0.264). The remaining rows suggest that state dependence
appears in all subgroups distinguished by the factors that are
Many of studies for Taiwanese FDI in China put focus on the effect hypothesized to influence entry mode choice. The propensity of
of investment towards China on Taiwanese domestic industries. choosing WOSs can also be due to heterogeneity across firms. As can be
Relatively fewer academic studies in Taiwan address entry mode seen, the unconditional proportion of using WOSs is higher for the
choice in the Chinese market, and they are generally based on MNEs investing in other countries besides China, having more
questionnaires sent by researchers themselves to a selected number employees and sales, and possessing less experience and high
of firms with a low recovery rate. In this paper, the sample is taken technology capability. It is also higher for the subsidiaries with the
from annual survey data on Taiwanese FDI conducted by Department technology source being the Taiwanese parent, with a smaller
of Statistics, Ministry of Economic Affairs of Taiwan. The survey is percentage of products sold to the local market and more reliance on
based on the questionnaires sent to all firms that are approved to Taiwanese material supplies, and vertically linked to the parent's
make foreign investment by the Investment Commission of Ministry production. The subsidiaries that operate in non-resource-intensive
of Economic Affairs. It is implemented annually during May and June industries or in different industries from the parent, or have an
and published in August the following year. The firms that have been intensive relational network are more likely to choose WOSs.
approved to make foreign investment may not be the ones recorded in However, it seems that the heterogeneity-induced difference in
each year's survey because of closure, moving out of business, or choosing WOSs within all subgroups is more evident when the mode
withdrawing the capital from the investing regions. Although the at t − 1 is JVs. That difference conditional on WOSs at t − 1 is trivial for
official survey is not designed for the investigation of entry modes, several subgroups. This might be due to that the effect of state
careful consideration on its questionnaire certainly provides us a dependence causes the firms to maintain WOSs and mitigates the role
reliable source to analyze the choice of entry mode between WOSs of firm heterogeneity in influencing mode choice.
and JVs. Table 4 reports the means and standard deviations of the variables
Table 1 reports the total number of FDI firms, the number of for all observations and for observations classified by the entry mode.
manufacturing FDI firms, and the number of manufacturing FDI firms Consistent with the implications of Table 3, the test for the equality of
of which China (including Hong Kong) is the major investing country means between WOS and JV observations suggests that on the
for the 2004–2007 surveys (2003–2006 FDI activities). As can be seen, average the firms choosing WOSs tend to be larger in either the scale
China undoubtedly is the main country for Taiwanese FDI. We use the of multinational operations, total number of employees, or total sales.
manufacturing firms with the major FDI country being China from These firms possess higher technology capability, have the subsidi-
2004 to 2007 surveys to construct the panel data set.1 Furthermore, in ary's technology directly transferred from Taiwanese parent, sell
order to implement the estimation of the dynamic probit mode, the fewer products to the local market, and obtain more materials from
final sample firms are restricted to those appearing in the surveys for Taiwan. They also have vertical parent–subsidiary production rela-
at least two consecutive years. Accordingly, there are 1240 FDI firms tion, operate in non-resource-intensive industries, and have more
with 3841 observations in an unbalanced panel. Among them, 568 relational network connections.
firms have full observations for 4 consecutive surveys (2004–2007),
225 firms have observations for 3 consecutive surveys (either 2004–
2006 or 2005–2007), and 447 firms have observations for 2 5.2. Regression results
consecutive surveys (2004–2005, 2005–2006, or 2006–2007). The
detailed descriptions for the measurement of entry mode and all We firstly report in Table 5 the results of static probit regressions
variables proxy for the determinants hypothesized in Section 3 are that focus on the impact of firm characteristics and do not consider the
presented in Table 2. dependence between past and current entry modes. In column (1),
results from the pooled probit model are presented since a static
5. Empirical results model can also be estimated by pooling the data and ignoring the
correlation structure to obtain consistent parameter estimates
5.1. Descriptive statistics (Maddala, 1987). Column (2) contains the results from the probit
model that allows for individual-specific random effects. The
The proportion of observations that choose WOSs as the entry estimated value of ρ is 0.798, which is significantly greater than
mode, either unconditional or conditional on mode at t − 1, is zero, suggesting that the random effects probit model controlling for
presented in Table 3. The first row of the table shows that there is unobserved heterogeneity is a better specification and that 79.8% of
considerable state dependence in entry mode choice. The proportion the latent disturbance variance is due to unobserved heterogeneity. In
of observations choosing WOSs at t for those having chosen WOSs at column (3), three interaction terms are included into the regression to
t−1 is much higher than that for those having chosen JVs at t − 1 consider specific arguments mentioned earlier. The similar value of ρ
is found in column (3).
It must be noted that random effects probit and pooled probit
1
There are a lot of changes in the questions of the questionnaire since 2004 so that models have different normalizations in LIMDEP program to facilitate
the panel data set starts from 2004 and does not include the surveys prior to 2004. easy estimation. In the random effects probit model, the estimates of β
M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450 445

Table 2
Variable measurement.

Variable name Description

Entry mode:
MODE MODE is a dummy variable for entry mode choice. It is equal to 1 for WOSs and 0 for JVs. In the survey, MNEs are asked to identify the organizational form of
the foreign subsidiaries in their major FDI countries from the following items: (1) WOSs; (2) JVs with Taiwanese firms; (3) JVs with local Taiwanese firms; (4)
JVs with local non-Taiwanese firms; (5) JVs with local governments; (6) JVs with foreign firms; (7) JVs with Taiwanese individuals; (8) JVs with local
individuals. In this study, the MNEs checking (1) is defined as having WOSs (MODE = 1) and those checking (3), (4), (5), (8) are categorized to have JVs
(MODE = 0). Some MNEs check (2) or (7) only and do not check either one of (1), (3), (4), (5), or (8). For these samples, since the hypotheses of entry mode
choice in the literature are largely based on the benefits and costs of venturing with local entities, we classify them to have WOSs, i.e., we include the cases of
multiple parents as Hennart (1991) has done. Finally, few samples checking (6) only are classified to have a JV mode because one can reasonably conjecture
that the foreign firms might have already established their relationships with local entities.
Scale of the firm:
LMNE, lnEMP The MNE's scale is measured by three variables. LMNE is a dummy variable, which is equal to 1 if the MNE makes investment in other foreign countries in
and lnSALE addition to China (including Hong Kong), and 0 if it invests in China only. This variable is proxy for the scope of an MNE's worldwide network. In the survey,
MNEs are asked to report the major, second major, and third major FDI countries. Most MNEs have only one FDI country. Thus we divide the sample firms, of
which the major FDI country is China, into two groups: one has other FDI countries in addition to China and the other does not. lnEMP is the log of total
number of employees of the MNE. lnSALE is the log of total sales (thousand Taiwan dollars) of the MNE. In response to the survey, MNEs report their total
number of employees and total sales.
Relative size of the subsidiary:
SUBSIZE SUBSIZE is the ratio of the subsidiary's sales to total sales of the MNE. Previous studies usually use assets to measure the relative size. Unfortunately, data for
the assets are not reported in the survey. Also, we do not use the ratio of the subsidiary's sales to the parent's sales in measuring the relative size. Some MNEs,
particularly traditional manufacturing firms, report very low parent's sales in the survey primarily because the focus of the entire enterprise has been moved
to China. This situation will make variable values using the ratio of the subsidiary's sales to the parent's sales fall into a very wide range and cause the model
estimation to be difficult and untraceable. Therefore, we use the ratio of the subsidiary's sales to total sales so that its values can be confined to the range
between 0 and 1.
International experience:
lnEXPER lnEXPER is the log of the number of years since the MNE has engaged in FDI. In the survey, MNEs are asked to fill in the beginning years of investing in major,
second major, and third major FDI countries. The beginning year of FDI is thus defined as the earliest one among them, and it is defined as the year of entering
into the major country for MNEs that report the major FDI country only. It might be possible that an MNE has completely exited from a specific country that is
its first foreign market. But such information is unavailable from the survey.
Technological capability:
RDLOW and RDLOW is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the MNE's R&D intensity, defined as the R&D expenditure as a percentage of annual sales, is less than 0.03 and greater
RDHIGH than zero. RDHIGH is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the MNE's R&D intensity is greater than 0.03. The omitted group is for zero R&D intensity. MNEs report
their annual R&D expenditure in the survey. Using 0.03 as the turning point seems an arbitrary choice; however, it produces better results to distinguish the
effects between low and high R&D intensity while other turning points also show a similar pattern of the R&D effect.
Sources of the subsidiary's technology:
TECHTW and TECHTW is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the subsidiary's technology is transferred directly from Taiwanese parent firm. TECHOS is a dummy variable equal to
TECHOS 1 if the subsidiary outsources its technology. The omitted group is for the subsidiaries that internalize technology development. In the survey, MNEs are asked
to identify the sources of the subsidiary's technology in the major FDI country from the following items: (1) provided by Taiwanese parent; (2) provided by
cooperative firms; (3) learned in the counseling process; (4) jointly developed with other firms; (5) developed by the subsidiary itself; (6) recruited from
other firms; (7) commissioned to outsiders; (8) purchased from outsiders; (9) learned from other firms. According to MNEs' responses, we define TECHTW as
the category of firms that check (1) as the technology source, and TECHOS as the category of firms that check (2), (6), (7), (8) as the technology source.
Internalization of technology development (the omitted group) is for the firms checking (3), (4), (5), (9).
Product markets and sources of materials:
LOCMKT and LOCMKT is a dummy variable equal to 1 if more than 50% of the subsidiary's products are sold to the local market, i.e., the Chinese market. MATTW is a dummy
MATTW variable equal to 1 if more than 50% of the subsidiary's raw materials or intermediate goods are provided by Taiwanese parent firm. In the survey, for the
subsidiary's product sales, MNEs are asked to write down the percentage sold to the local markets, the percentage sold back to Taiwan, and the percentage
exported to other countries. For either sources of materials or sources of intermediate goods, MNEs report the percentage provided by Taiwanese parent firm,
by local Taiwanese businesses, by local non-Taiwanese businesses, and by other countries.
Resource-intensive industries:
RESOURCE RESOURCE is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the subsidiary's main product in China belongs to a resource-intensive manufacturing industry defined by the
Standard Industrial Classification System of Taiwan, i.e., SIC 08 (food and beverages), 09 (tobacco), 10 (textiles mills), 11 (apparel, clothing accessories and
other textile product), 12 (leather, fur and allied product), 13 (wood and bamboo products), 14 (furniture and fixtures), 15 (pulp, paper and paper products),
19 (petroleum and coal products), 20 (rubber products), 21 (plastic products), 22 (non-metallic mineral products), 23 (basic metal industries), 24 (fabricated
metal products). In the survey, MNEs are required to indicate the industries of major, second major, and third major products in the FDI countries.
Production relations between the subsidiary and the parent firm:
VERTLINK VERTLINK is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the subsidiary's production is vertically linked to the parent's production. In the survey, MNEs are asked to identify
the production relation between the subsidiary and the parent firm from 13 items of the descriptions. We categorize the MNEs that identify the relation as one
of the following four items to have the vertical linkages: (1) Taiwanese parent does not have the production sector and is responsible only for selling the
foreign subsidiary's products; (2) The foreign subsidiary does not have the production sector and is responsible only for selling the products of Taiwanese
parent; (3) Taiwanese parent produces components and semi-manufactured products, and the foreign subsidiary assembles and produces final products; (4)
the foreign subsidiary produces components and semi-manufactured products, and Taiwanese parent assembles and produces final products.
Diversification:
DIVERSE DIVERSE is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the subsidiary's main product in China belongs to a different industry from Taiwanese parent, according to the
Standard Industrial Classification System of Taiwan.
Relational network:
RELCUST and Two variables are proxy for the relational network connections. RELCUST is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the MNE follows Taiwanese or foreign clients to
RELFIRM make FDI in China. An MNE is defined to have this kind of network if in the survey it identifies the motivation of FDI in China as “to make investment along
with Taiwanese customers” or “to meet the request of foreign customers”. The second variable, RELFIRM, is the log of the number of Taiwanese MNEs that
make FDI in China in the same industry defined by the Standard Industrial Classification System of Taiwan. A large number of firms from Taiwan may imply
that relational network connections are more likely to be established.
Previous mode performance:
PERF-SUB and Previous mode performance is an explanatory variable interacted with the previous mode in the dynamic model to examine whether MNEs adjust the mode in
PERF-PAR response to unfavorable previous performance. In the survey, MNEs are asked to subjectively evaluate the profitability of their parent firm and foreign
subsidiaries. We consider the subsidiary's performance (PERF-SUB) and the parent's performance (PERF-PAR) respectively. Both PERF-SUB and PERF-PAR are
dummy variables equal to 1 if MNEs identify the performance as having loss or breakeven, and equal to 0 for having surplus.
446 M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450

Table 3 Table 4
Unconditional and conditional proportions of observations choosing WOSs. Means and standard deviations of variables.

Number of Unconditional Conditional Conditional Variable All observations Observations Observations


observations on WOSs on JVs at for WOSs for JVs
at t − 1 t−1
(N = 3841) (N = 2673) (N = 1168)
All observations 2601 0.705 0.903 0.264
Mean Standard Mean Standard Mean Standard
LMNE = 1 698 0.739 0.885 0.335
deviation deviation deviation
LMNE = 0 1903 0.693 0.910 0.242
lnEMP ≥ 5.298a 1524 0.760 0.912 0.306 MODE 0.696 0.460
lnEMP b 5.298 1077 0.629 0.889 0.225 LMNE 0.268 0.443 0.283⁎ 0.451 0.232 0.422
lnSALE ≥ 13.816b 1095 0.752 0.907 0.309 lnEMP 5.627 1.588 5.777⁎ 1.562 5.283 1.592
lnSALE b 13.816 1506 0.672 0.900 0.239 lnSALE 13.291 2.029 13.416⁎ 1.996 13.005 2.075
SUBSIZE ≥ 0.3 1356 0.703 0.892 0.284 SUBSIZE 0.375 0.307 0.375 0.309 0.375 0.303
SUBSIZE b 0.3 1245 0.708 0.915 0.241 lnEXPER 1.915 0.638 1.912 0.633 1.922 0.650
lnEXPER ≥ 2.015c 1380 0.695 0.895 0.255 RDHIGH 0.207 0.405 0.230⁎ 0.421 0.155 0.362
lnEXPER b 2.015 1221 0.717 0.913 0.273 RDLOW 0.507 0.500 0.516 0.500 0.485 0.500
RDHIGH = 1 527 0.776 0.936 0.246 TECHTW 0.558 0.497 0.624⁎ 0.485 0.408 0.492
RDLOW = 1 1370 0.716 0.900 0.275 TECHOS 0.115 0.319 0.082⁎ 0.274 0.191 0.393
RDLOW = RDHIGH = 0 704 0.632 0.880 0.254 LOCMKT 0.452 0.498 0.436⁎ 0.496 0.491 0.500
TECHTW = 1 1428 0.785 0.926 0.309 MATTW 0.278 0.448 0.297⁎ 0.457 0.234 0.423
TECHOS = 1 311 0.534 0.832 0.188 RESOURCE 0.386 0.487 0.350⁎ 0.477 0.469 0.499
TECHTW = TECHOS = 0 862 0.636 0.877 0.252 VERTLINK 0.316 0.465 0.342⁎ 0.474 0.259 0.438
LOCMKT = 1 1203 0.679 0.900 0.232 DIVERSE 0.451 0.498 0.461 0.499 0.430 0.495
LOCMKT = 0 1398 0.728 0.906 0.295 RELCUST 0.615 0.487 0.634⁎ 0.482 0.573 0.495
MATTW = 1 676 0.747 0.910 0.276 RELFIRM 4.557 1.092 4.647⁎ 1.103 4.352 1.037
MATTW = 0 1925 0.691 0.900 0.260
⁎ Represents that the difference in mean between observations for WOSs and
RESOURCE = 1 1000 0.649 0.901 0.241
observations for JVs is statistically significant at the 0.01 level.
RESOURCE = 0 1601 0.741 0.904 0.284
VERTLINK = 1 842 0.757 0.902 0.309
VERTLINK = 0 1759 0.681 0.904 0.248
DIVERSE = 1 1170 0.724 0.912 0.289
International experience (lnEXPER) is negatively related to the
DIVERSE = 0 1431 0.690 0.896 0.244
RELCUST = 1 939 0.724 0.914 0.288 propensity of using WOSs in both columns (2) and (3). However, the
RELCUST = 0 1662 0.695 0.897 0.250 opposite implications of experience, as stated in Section 3, offset each
RELFIRM ≥ 4.605d 1258 0.746 0.906 0.303 other so that its impact is not very strong. The finding is more
RELFIRM b 4.605 1343 0.667 0.900 0.236 consistent with the argument of ethnocentrism. It also suggests that
Total number of observations is 2601, which is pooled data for period 2 to period Ti. for Taiwanese investment in China, experience is imperative for firms
a
The number of employees ≥ 200. to efficiently enforce JV agreements with Chinese local firms.
b
The value of sales ≥1 billion Taiwan dollars.
c Higher R&D intensity encourages Taiwanese firms to use WOSs in
The international experience ≥ 7.5 years.
d
The number of firms in the same industry ≥100. China. Compared with the group of firms without R&D investments,
the positive effect is significant for the group of RDHIGH but not
for RDLOW.2 This implies that the fear of local partners' access to
proprietary technology is evident when the MNE's technology
returned by the program is normalized by the standard deviation of capability is above a certain level. For an MNE only having low
the random error term, which is assumed to be 1 here. But parameter technology levels, the need of obtaining complementary technology
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
estimates of β = 1 þ σ u2 are obtained in the pooled probit model. To
from JVs becomes stronger and lowers the tendency of complete
control over the subsidiary. Consistent with these notions, it is found
make valid comparisons in coefficient estimates, it is necessary toffi
qffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi that relative to those internalizing technology developments, MNEs
convert the random effects probit coefficients from β to β 1 þ σ 2u , = having the subsidiary technology proprietarily transferred from
that is, the random effects probit coefficients need to be multiplied by Taiwanese parent (TECHTW) are more likely to fully control their
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

the estimate of 1−ρ(Arulampalam, 1999), which is 0.449 in column subsidiaries. In contrast, MNEs outsourcing the subsidiary technology
(2). Consequently, compared with the pooled probit coefficients in (TECHOS) tend to choose JVs probably for the benefits from learning
column (1), as the random effect term captures the impact of and interfirm knowledge transfers.
unobserved heterogeneity, almost all “scaled” coefficients in the The coefficient on LOCMKT is negative. MNEs selling fewer
random effects probit of column (2) are reduced, except those of products to the local market are found to more likely choose WOSs.
SUBSIZE, lnEXPER and MATTW. In this case, JVs are not a preferred choice because MNEs are less
Regression results in Table 5 generally are consistent with the dependent on local partners to deal with the uncertainty in the local
predictions of the transaction cost theory. Let us focus on the results product market, or because they want to avoid the goal conflict with
from the random effects probit model. Column (2) shows that MNEs local partners when the subsidiary has more exports that might
operating subsidiaries in the countries besides China (LMNE = 1), compete with the sales of the parent firm. The positive coefficient on
hiring more employees (lnEMP), or having greater sales (lnSALE) tend MATTW shows that a more secured source of materials from
to choose WOSs. However, only the coefficient on lnEMP is significant Taiwanese parent will lead to use of WOSs due to less reliance on
at the 12% level. The coefficient on SUBSIZE is significantly positive, local firms' assistance for an assured provision of materials.
supporting the hypothesis that MNEs desire a higher level of control
over their subsidiaries when they have larger resources committed to
the subsidiaries. In column (3) where the interaction between
2
SUBSIZE and lnSALE is included, the positive effect of lnSALE turns The purpose of using two dummies for three levels of R&D intensity is to consider
to be significant and the interaction term has a significantly negative that the effect of R&D intensity may not be strictly linear. In unreported regressions,
we keep R&D intensity a continuous variable in running regressions and also include
coefficient. The positive effect of the relative size of the subsidiary on
its squared term. However, the results are not satisfactory. The significantly positive
the likelihood of choosing WOSs is shown to decrease as the scale of coefficient on RDHIGH suggests a threshold effect of R&D expenditures on entry mode
the firm (in total sales) becomes large. choice.
M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450 447

Table 5 Finally, it is evidenced that the variables RELCUST and RELFIRM,


Static probit estimation of entry mode choice. proxy for relational network connections, are positively related to the
Variable Pooled probit Random effects probit probability of choosing WOSs. The existence of Taiwanese or foreign
customers that are followed by MNEs when investing in China and
(1) (2) (3)
more number of Taiwanese MNEs that make foreign investment in the
Constant −0.629 −1.071 (0.576)⁎ −2.772
same industry are shown to provide the relational network similar to
(0.232)⁎⁎⁎ (0.698)⁎⁎⁎
LMNE 0.029 (0.057) 0.004 (0.131) 0.224 (0.161) assistance from local partners of the JVs, and hence facilitate
lnEMP 0.121 (0.022)⁎⁎⁎ 0.075 (0.048) 0.059 (0.049) Taiwanese investors to choose complete control of their subsidiaries
lnSALE 0.028 (0.019) 0.043 (0.045) 0.176 (0.059)⁎⁎⁎ as an entry mode.
SUBSIZE 0.078 (0.082) 0.342 (0.174)⁎⁎ 4.250 (1.057)⁎⁎⁎ Table 6 presents the results of dynamic probit estimation that
SUBSIZE × lnSALE −0.300
(0.080)⁎⁎⁎
includes previous entry mode (MODEt − 1) in the model. Column (1)
lnEXPER −0.008 (0.040) −0.135 (0.087) −0.164 (0.088)⁎ reports the results from the random effects probit model when the
RDHIGH 0.237 (0.069)⁎⁎⁎ 0.387 (0.151)⁎⁎⁎ 0.345 (0.154)⁎⁎ initial conditions are assumed to be exogenous. Since the estimated
RDLOW 0.071 (0.057) 0.079 (0.119) 0.066 (0.121) value of ρ is very small (b0.001), the regression results are almost
TECHTW 0.475 (0.049)⁎⁎⁎ 0.585 (0.092)⁎⁎⁎ 0.580 (0.092)⁎⁎⁎
identical to those of the pooled probit model. The results of the
TECHOS −0.255 −0.441 −0.474
(0.072)⁎⁎⁎ (0.134)⁎⁎⁎ (0.135)⁎⁎⁎ Heckman approach estimated by MSL are given in columns (2) and (3).
LOCMKT −0.103 −0.190 (0.101)⁎ −0.198 (0.102)⁎ The estimated value of τu is 1.734 in column (2) and 1.805 in column
(0.047)⁎⁎ (3). Both are significantly greater than zero, implying the rejection of
MATTW 0.120 (0.051)⁎⁎ 0.278 (0.107)⁎⁎⁎ 0.268 (0.107)⁎⁎ the exogeneity of the initial conditions. The coefficient on MODEt − 1 is
RESOURCE −0.121 −0.194 (0.133) −0.085 (0.141)
(0.051)⁎⁎
significantly positive, apparently suggesting positive state dependence
VERTLINK 0.143 (0.050)⁎⁎⁎ 0.152 (0.092)⁎ 0.308 (0.112)⁎⁎⁎ in entry mode choice. Compared to column (1), the Heckman
VERTLINK × RESOURCE −0.449 estimator shows a fall in the coefficient on MODEt − 1 of about a half.
(0.192)⁎⁎ Let us focus on column (3) which includes the interaction terms.
DIVERSE 0.084 (0.045)⁎ 0.152 (0.098) 0.293 (0.113)⁎⁎⁎
Similar to the results obtained from Table 5, all coefficient estimates
DIVERSE × LMNE −0.465
(0.203)⁎⁎ are as expected and most of them are statistically significant. The
RELCUST 0.115 (0.048)⁎⁎ 0.200 (0.100)⁎⁎ 0.211 (0.101)⁎⁎ predictions for the influences of firm heterogeneity on entry mode
RELFIRM 0.071 (0.023)⁎⁎⁎ 0.132 (0.055)⁎⁎ 0.131 (0.055)⁎⁎ choice based on transaction cost economics are robust even if the
ρ (= σ2u /1+σ2u) 0.798 (0.018)⁎⁎⁎ 0.799 (0.018)⁎⁎⁎ cross-period dependence of mode choice is taken into account in the
Log-likelihood −2179.569 −1707.242 −1695.117
dynamic model. In columns (4) and (5) of Table 6, the impact of
Number of firms 1240 1240 1240
Number of observations 3841 3841 3841 previous mode performance on the state dependence of mode choice
⁎⁎⁎, ⁎⁎ and ⁎ represent that the coefficients are statistically significant at 0.01, 0.05 and is considered by including the interactions of previous mode choice
0.1 levels respectively. The year dummies are included in the regressions. with subsidiary's performance (MODEt − 1 × PERF-SUBt − 1) and with
parent firm's performance (MODEt − 1 × PERF-PARt − 1) respectively.3
As indicated earlier, MNEs will learn from previous mode performance
to determine the current mode by looking into whether performance
As expected, the negative coefficient on RESOURCE means that is favorable or unfavorable. It is our purpose to know whether the
MNEs would not like to choose WOSs if their subsidiaries operate in parent firm's performance, which is likely affected by the MNE's global
the resource-intensive industries. But the importance of this effect is plans and strategies, or the subsidiary's performance itself determines
captured by the firm-specific term as its significance drops substan- the dynamic mode adjustments. Regression results show that both
tially when compared to that appeared in the pooled probit model. MODEt − 1 × PERF-SUBt − 1 and MODEt − 1 × PERF-PARt − 1 have nega-
Consistent with transaction cost arguments, the vertical production tive coefficients, but the former is not significant. The likelihood of
link between the subsidiary and the parent (VERTLINK), which has choosing WOSs in the current period decreases significantly if WOSs
more attributes of asset specificity, causes the likelihood of choosing used in the previous period were associated with poor parent firm's
WOSs to increase for the saving of coordination costs. In column (3), performance (PERF-PARt − 1 = 1). That is, if the previous mode is
the interaction between VERTLINK and RESOURCE has a significantly WOSs, poor parent's performance will cause the degree of state
negative coefficient, supporting the prediction that asset specificity is dependence on WOSs to be reduced and encourage MNEs to change
more likely to be a factor in favor of WOSs in non-resource-intensive the mode in the current period. The subsidiary's performance itself
industries. seems not an important consideration for an MNE to adjust the
The significance for the positive effect of DIVERSE is weak in organizational form of that subsidiary.
column (2) (only at the 12% level), but turns to be strong after the One can also interpret the above findings as that the marginal
interaction with LMNE is included in column (3). The coefficient on effect of MODEt − 1, i.e., the effect for a change of MODEt − 1 from 0 to 1,
the interaction term is significantly negative. These results have depends on the parent firm's previous performance (PERF-PARt − 1).
particular implications for Taiwanese foreign investment. The Using the estimated coefficients in column (5), the magnitude of the
Taiwanese firms investing in China only (LMNE = 0) are usually impact of PERF-PARt − 1 on the marginal effect of MODEt − 1 can be
SMEs. As stated earlier, because of their inherent disadvantages in calculated. It is important to note that the estimated coefficients in a
managerial resources and asymmetric dependence on local firms probit model are not the marginal effects we are accustomed to
when entering a new industry, SMEs are likely to be expropriated by analyzing. Like those of any nonlinear regression, the marginal effects
local firms if they choose JVs. This consideration motivates them to vary with the values of explanatory variables. For the purpose of
use WOSs. The structural problems in JVs can be alleviated for large demonstration, consider an exemplified firm in 2004 that has
MNEs that also make foreign investment in other countries
(LMNE = 1) since they may have more expertise learned from
3
multinational operation to deal with holdup problems. The negative As described in Table 2, one may notice that PERF-SUB and PERF-PAR are
relationship between diversification and WOSs, a result frequently dichotomous measure of performance. Only subjective measures (managerial
evaluations) of performance are available in the survey. This is common in the
found in the literature, tends to appear in the MNEs that operate in literature. As indicated by Brouthers (2002), previous survey-based studies have found
multiple countries and is reflected in the coefficient of the interaction that firms are reluctant to provide objective measures of performance for their foreign
term. subsidiaries. Subjective measures are usually employed.
448 M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450

Table 6
Dynamic probit estimation of entry mode choice.

Variable MSL Heckman estimation of random effects probit

Random effects probit Considering the impact of previous performance


(pooled probit)a
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Constant −0.910 (0.344)⁎⁎⁎


LMNE −0.025 (0.082) 0.003 (0.092) 0.151 (0.118) 0.152 (0.118) 0.145 (0.119)
lnEMP 0.077 (0.032)⁎⁎ 0.083 (0.036)⁎⁎ 0.076 (0.037)⁎⁎ 0.075 (0.037)⁎⁎ 0.073 (0.037)⁎
lnSALE −0.018 (0.028) 0.011 (0.031) 0.067 (0.043) 0.065 (0.043) 0.059 (0.043)
SUBSIZE −0.016 (0.115) 0.097 (0.129) 1.775 (0.767)⁎⁎ 1.795 (0.770)⁎⁎ 1.979 (0.784)⁎⁎
SUBSIZE × lnSALE −0.127 (0.058)⁎⁎ −0.129 (0.058)⁎⁎ −0.138 (0.059)⁎⁎
lnEXPER −0.044 (0.062) −0.099 (0.064) −0.109 (0.065)⁎ −0.109 (0.065)⁎ −0.097 (0.066)
RDHIGH 0.115 (0.101) 0.238 (0.117)⁎⁎ 0.244 (0.119)⁎⁎ 0.244 (0.119)⁎⁎ 0.241 (0.120)⁎⁎
RDLOW 0.009 (0.084) 0.031 (0.094) 0.035 (0.096) 0.034 (0.096) 0.027 (0.097)
TECHTW 0.265 (0.070)⁎⁎⁎ 0.373 (0.076)⁎⁎⁎ 0.380 (0.077)⁎⁎⁎ 0.381 (0.077)⁎⁎⁎ 0.392 (0.078)⁎⁎⁎
TECHOS −0.153 (0.101) −0.299 (0.110)⁎⁎⁎ −0.327 (0.113)⁎⁎⁎ −0.327 (0.113)⁎⁎⁎ −0.326 (0.114)⁎⁎⁎
LOCMKT −0.104 (0.067) −0.157(0.074) ⁎⁎ −0.173(0.075)⁎⁎ −0.173 (0.076)⁎⁎ −0.190 (0.077)⁎⁎
MATTW 0.002 (0.075) 0.089 (0.089) 0.091 (0.091) 0.094 (0.091) 0.101 (0.091)
RESOURCE 0.009 (0.073) −0.017 (0.082) 0.070 (0.093) 0.070 (0.093) 0.071 (0.094)
VERTLINK 0.057 (0.071) 0.069 (0.077) 0.192 (0.095)⁎⁎ 0.193 (0.096)⁎⁎ 0.214 (0.098)⁎⁎
VERTLINK × RESOURCE −0.344 (0.162)⁎⁎ −0.344 (0.163)⁎⁎ −0.370 (0.164)⁎⁎
DIVERSE 0.122 (0.065)⁎ 0.131 (0.072)⁎ 0.233 (0.086)⁎⁎⁎ 0.234 (0.086)⁎⁎⁎ 0.239 (0.086)⁎⁎⁎
DIVERSE × LMNE −0.332 (0.158)⁎⁎ −0.332 (0.158)⁎⁎ −0.334 (0.159)⁎⁎
RELCUST 0.143 (0.069)⁎⁎ 0.203 (0.077)⁎⁎⁎ 0.222 (0.079)⁎⁎⁎ 0.222 (0.079)⁎⁎⁎ 0.242 (0.080)⁎⁎⁎
RELFIRM 0.020 (0.033) 0.077 (0.038)⁎⁎ 0.077 (0.039)⁎⁎ 0.076 (0.039)⁎ 0.074 (0.039)⁎
MODEt − 1 1.860 (0.065)⁎⁎⁎ 0.975 (0.080)⁎⁎⁎ 0.899 (0.082)⁎⁎⁎ 0.932 (0.099)⁎⁎⁎ 1.015 (0.098)⁎⁎⁎
MODEt − 1 × PERF-SUBt − 1 −0.062 (0.101)
MODEt − 1 × PERF-PARt − 1 −0.317 (0.107) ⁎⁎⁎

Coefficients for fit:


α −1.371 (0.378)⁎⁎⁎ −2.053 (0.495)⁎⁎⁎ −2.023 (0.497)⁎⁎⁎ −1.920 (0.501)⁎⁎⁎
σu 0.976 (0.057)⁎⁎⁎ 1.073 (0.061)⁎⁎⁎ 1.072 (0.061)⁎⁎⁎ 1.116 (0.062)⁎⁎⁎

Coefficients for dit:


ξ −1.771 (0.525)⁎⁎⁎ −4.355 (0.741)⁎⁎⁎ −4.361 (0.742)⁎⁎⁎ −4.228 (0.736)⁎⁎⁎
τu 1.734 (0.098)⁎⁎⁎ 1.805 (0.103)⁎⁎⁎ 1.809 (0.104)⁎⁎⁎ 1.777 (0.102)⁎⁎⁎
ρ (= σ2u /1+σ2u) b0.001 0.488 0.535 0.535 0.555
Log-likelihood −1007.219 −1683.281 −1670.105 −1669.950 −1666.487
Number of firms 1240 1240 1240 1240 1240
Number of observations 2601b 3841 3841 3841 3841
⁎⁎⁎, ⁎⁎ and ⁎ represent that the coefficients are statistically significant at 0.01, 0.05 and 0.1 levels respectively. The year dummies are included in the regressions.
a
Random effects probit estimation assuming exogenous initial conditions has results almost identical to those of pooled probit estimation, as can be seen that the estimate of ρ is very
small and insignificant.
b
Observations for each sample firm are from period 2 to period Ti.

following characteristics: investing in China only, possessing moder- calculation for parent firms having poor previous performance (PERF-
ate R&D intensity, outsourcing its subsidiary's technology, having high PARt − 1 = 1) suggests that the marginal effect of MODEt − 1 is 0.270.
proportion of raw materials provided by the parent firm and high Apparently, poor previous performance in the parent firm reduces the
proportion of products sold to the local market, entering into degree of state dependence on WOSs by 0.118. In other words, for the
resource-intensive industries, having the subsidiary vertically linked previous mode being WOSs, the probability of continuing adoption of
to the parent firm, making diversified investment, investing in China WOSs in the current year will decrease by around 12% if the parent
following foreign clients, and having the number of employees, total firm experiences poor previous performance. This confirms the
sales, the years of experience, and the number of same-industry firms importance of mode performance in affecting a firm's future mode
at the sample means. The marginal effect of MODEt − 1 can be decisions.
calculated as the difference in the expected probability of adopting Finally, in order to provide a descriptive assessment of the fit of the
WOSs for previous modes (modes in 2003) being WOSs and JVs, models, following Heckman (1981a), Table 7 presents the observed
i.e.,Φ(α + γ + β′xit) − Φ(α + β′xit).4 We then compare the marginal frequency of mode choice patterns for period 2 to period Ti, together
effect of MODEt − 1 for PERF-PARt − 1 equal to 0 and 1 respectively. with the frequencies predicted by the models shown in columns (1),
The result shows that for parent firms having superior previous (2), (3) and (5) of Table 6. The bottom row of the table records the χ2
performance (PERF-PARt − 1 = 0), the expected probability of choos- Pearson goodness-of-fit statistics for each model. The statistic is
ing WOSs as the previous mode being WOSs is 0.695 and the calculated as
corresponding probability as the previous mode being JVs is 0.307.
 2
This implies that the marginal effect of MODEt − 1 on the probability of 14 ns − n̂s
choosing WOSs, or the effect of state dependence, is 0.388. Similar Goodness of fit = ∑s = 1
n̂s

4
That is, the marginal effect, Φ(α + γ + β′xit) − Φ(α + β′xit), is computed when the where ns and n̂s are respectively the observed and predicted
values of variables in x are as the following: LMNE = 0, RDLOW = 1, RDHIGH = 0,
TECHTW = 0, TECHOS = 1, MATTW = 1, LOCMKT = 1, RESOURCE = 1, VERTLINK = 1,
frequencies of the sth pattern, and there totally are 14 choice patterns.
DIVERSE = 1, RELCUST = 1, and lnEMP, lnSALE, lnEXPER, and RELFIRM equal to the A lower value of the χ2 statistic implies a better fit for a model. As can be
sample mean. Time dummies are also assigned to represent year 2004. seen, the goodness-of-fit statistics indicate a poor fit to the observed
M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450 449

Table 7 production relationship, diversification of foreign investment, and


Comparisons of predicted with observed entry mode choice frequencies. relational network connections. On the other hand, the probability of
Choice Observed Predicted frequency choosing WOSs decreases with an MNE's international experience and
patterna frequency the proportion of the subsidiary's products sold to the local market.
Random Heckman estimation of random
(number Accordingly, this study provides a more comprehensive picture of
effects effects probit
of firms)
probit foreign market entry mode choice of Taiwanese manufacturing firms
Column (1) Column (2) Column (3) Column (5) than has been available to date in Taiwan.
Table 6 Table 6 Table 6 Table 6

Firms with Ti = 4 Acknowledgments


0, 0, 0 113 52.59 82.80 86.51 88.15
1, 0, 0 15 34.14 23.28 22.44 21.75 This research is financially supported by the Taiwan National
0, 1, 0 8 26.70 21.93 20.57 20.14
0, 0, 1 20 29.36 22.66 21.87 21.50
Science Council (NSC-98-2410-H-032-034). We would like to thank
1, 1, 0 30 53.21 30.47 28.52 27.60 two anonymous referees and the Editor for their valuable comments
1, 0, 1 24 51.71 30.02 28.32 27.40 and insights that help us improve this paper.
0, 1, 1 22 48.89 29.18 27.53 27.08
1, 1, 1 336 271.40 327.67 332.24 334.37
Total 568 568 568 568 568 References
Firms with Ti = 3
Agarwal, S., Ramaswami, S., 1992. Choice of foreign market entry mode: impact of
0, 0 45 35.82 43.32 43.85 43.99
ownership, location, and internalization factors. Journal of International Business
0, 1 22 36.64 25.10 24.34 23.97
Studies 23, 1–27.
1, 0 17 32.70 22.31 20.85 20.46
Anderson, E., Gatignon, H., 1986. Modes of foreign entry: a transaction cost analysis and
1, 1 141 119.84 134.28 135.96 136.57 propositions. Journal of International Business Studies 17, 1–26.
Total 225 225 225 225 225 Arulampalam, W., 1999. A note on estimated effects in random effect probit models.
Firms with Ti = 2 Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 6, 597–602.
1 311 313.67 319.49 319.98 319.47 Arulampalam, W., Stewart, M.B., 2007. Simplified implementation of the Heckman
0 136 133.33 127.51 127.02 127.53 estimator of the dynamic probit model and a comparison with alternative
Total 447 447 447 447 447 estimators. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) Discussion Paper No. 3039. .
Pearson 170.89 29.15 22.36 19.83 Asiedu, E., Esfahani, H.S., 2001. Ownership structure in foreign direct investment
goodness-of-fit projects. The Review of Economics 83, 647–662.
statistic Aulakh, P.S., Kotabe, M., 1997. Antecedents and performance implications of channel
(χ2 statistic) integration in foreign markets. Journal of International Business Studies 28, 145–175.
Bell, J., 1995. The internationalization of small computer software firms: a further
a
The choice pattern is for period 2 to period Ti. “1” corresponds to WOSs and “0” challenge to stage theories. European Journal of Marketing 29, 60–75.
corresponds to JVs. Thus “1, 1, 0” corresponds to a firm that chooses WOSs in periods 2 Bhaumik, S.K., Gelb, S., 2005. Determinants of entry mode choice of MNEs in emerging
and 3 and JVs in period 4. markets. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 41, 5–24.
Brouthers, K.D., 2002. Institutional, cultural and transaction cost influences on entry mode
choice and performance. Journal of International Business Studies 33, 203–221.
Brouthers, K.D., Hennart, J.F., 2007. Boundaries of the firm: insight from international
frequency for the random effects probit assuming exogenous initial entry mode research. Journal of Management 33, 395–425.
conditions (or pooled probit model) (column (1) of Table 6), but a much Brouthers, K.D., Brouthers, L.E., Werner, S., 2002. Industrial sector, perceived
environmental uncertainty and entry mode strategy. Journal of Business Research
improved fit for the Heckman estimation of the random effects probit. 55, 495–507.
Particularly, the statistic indicates the best fit for the model taking Brouthers, K.D., Brouthers, L.E., Werner, S., 2003. Transaction cost-enhanced entry mode
account the impact of previous parent firm's performance on state choices and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal 24, 1239–1248.
Brouthers, K.D., Brouthers, L.E., Werner, S., 2008a. Real options, international entry
dependence of mode choice (column (5) of Table 6). mode choice and performance. Journal of Management Studies 45, 936–960.
Brouthers, K.D., Brouthers, L.E., Werner, S., 2008b. Resource-based advantages in an
6. Conclusions international context. Journal of Management 34, 189–217.
Chang, S.J., Rosenzweig, P.M., 2001. The choice of entry mode in sequential foreign
direct investment. Strategic Management Journal 22, 747–776.
Using the official survey data of Taiwanese FDI in China, this study Chen, H., Chen, T.J., 1998. Network linkages and location choice in foreign direct
examines the transaction cost determinants of entry mode choice investment. Journal of International Business Studies 29, 445–467.
Chen, S.S., Hennart, J.F., 2002. Japanese investors' choice of joint ventures versus
between WOSs and JVs. This study departs from previous researches
wholly-owned subsidiaries in the US: the role of market barriers and firm
in that it constructs a panel data set and focuses on an analysis of the capabilities. Journal of International Business Studies 33, 1–18.
dynamic binary choice model that controls for state dependence of Cleeve, E., 1997. The motives for joint ventures: a transaction costs analysis of Japanese
mode choice. The dynamic probit model is formulated according to MNEs in the UK. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 44, 31–43.
Coviello, N., Munro, H., 1997. Network relationships and the internationalization
Heckman's (1981b) approach and is estimated by the MSL method process of small software firms. International Business Review 6, 361–386.
under the assumption of endogenous initial conditions. Davidson, W.H., McFetridge, D.G., 1984. International technology transaction and the
Empirical results suggest the existence of state dependence theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics 32, 253–264.
Davidson, W.H., McFetridge, D.G., 1985. Key characteristics in the choice of international
between current and previous entry modes. Having WOSs in the technology transfer mode. Journal of International Business Studies 16, 5–21.
previous period increases the probability that WOSs will be chosen in Delios, A., Beamish, P.W., 1999. Ownership strategy of Japanese firms: transactional,
the current period. However, there is also evidence to show that the institutional, and experience influences. Strategic Management Journal 20, 915–933.
Dikova, D., van Witteloostuijn, A., 2007. Foreign direct investment mode choice: entry
degree of state dependence decreases if the entry mode in the and establishment modes in transition economies. Journal of International Business
previous period did not produce good parent firm's performance. Studies 38, 1013–1033.
Echoing the argument of Brouthers and Hennart (2007), we find Dunning, J.H., 1980. Toward an eclectic theory of international production: some
empirical tests. Journal of International Business Studies 11, 9–31.
strong linkage between mode performance and future mode choice. Dunning, J.H., 1988. The eclectic paradigm of international production: a restatement
The hypothesized effects of transaction cost factors on entry mode and some possible extensions. Journal of International Business Studies 19, 1–31.
choice gain support even if Taiwanese MNEs inherently have greater Dunning, J.H., 1998. Location and the multinational enterprise: a neglected factor?
Journal of International Business Studies 29, 45–66.
propensity of using WOSs in investing China because of cultural
Dunning, J.H., 2000. The eclectic paradigm as an envelope for economic and business
similarity. Specifically, empirical findings indicate that the probability theories of MNE activity. International Business Review 9, 163–190.
of an MNE's choice of WOSs is positively associated with the MNE's total Gatignon, H., Anderson, E., 1988. The multinational corporation's degree of control over
number of employees, relative size of the subsidiary, and technological foreign subsidiaries: an empirical test of a transaction cost explanation. Journal of
Law, Economics and Organization 4, 305–336.
capability of the business. It also increases when there are proprietary Gomes-Casseres, B., 1989. Ownership structures of foreign subsidiaries. Journal of
technology transfer from parent to subsidiary, vertical parent–subsidiary Economic Behavior and Organizations 11, 1–25.
450 M.-Y. Chen, J.-Y. Chang / Economic Modelling 28 (2011) 439–450

Greene, W., 2007. Econometric analysis, 6th edition. Prentice Hall, New York. Kim, W.C., Hwang, P., 1992. Global strategy and multinationals' entry mode choice.
Heckman, J.J., 1981. Heterogeneity and state dependence. In: Rosen, S. (Ed.), Studies in Journal of International Business Studies 23, 29–54.
Labor Markets. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Kogut, B., Singh, H., 1988. The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode.
Heckman, J.J., 1981. In: Manski, C.F., McFadden, D. (Eds.), The incidental parameters Journal of International Business Studies 18, 411–432.
problem and the problem of initial conditions in estimating a discrete time–discrete Lu, J.W., 2002. Intra- and inter-organizational imitative behavior: institutional influences on
data stochastic process. : Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with Econometric Japanese firms' entry mode choice. Journal of International Business Studies 33, 19–37.
Applications. Cambridge: MIT Press. Maddala, G., 1987. Limited dependent variable models using panel data. Journal of
Hennart, J.F., 1982. A Theory of Multinational Enterprise. University of Michigan Press, Human Resources 22, 307–338.
Ann Arbor. Madhok, A., 1998. The nature of multinational firm boundaries: transaction cost, firm
Hennart, J.F., 1988. A transaction costs theory of joint ventures. Strategic Management capabilities and foreign market entry mode. International Business Review 7, 259–290.
Journal 9, 361–374. Makino, S., Neupert, K.E., 2000. National culture, transaction costs, and the choice
Hennart, J.F., 1989. Can the “New Forms of Investment” substitute for the “Old Forms?” A between joint venture and wholly owned subsidiary. Journal of International
transaction costs perspective. Journal of International Business Studies 20, 211–234. Business Studies 31, 705–713.
Hennart, J.F., 1991. The transaction cost theory of joint ventures: an empirical study of Mutinelli, M., Piscitello, L., 1998. The entry mode choice of MNEs: an evolutionary
Japanese subsidiaries in the United States. Management Science 37, 483–497. approach. Research Policy 27, 491–506.
Hennart, J.F., 2000. In: Pitelis, C., Sugden, R. (Eds.), The transaction cost theory of the Nelson, R.R., Winter, S.G., 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Belknap
multinational enterprise, 2nd ed. : The Nature of the Transnational Firm. Routledge, Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge.
London. Padmanabhan, P., Cho, R.K., 1996. Ownership Strategy for a foreign affiliate: an empirical
Hennart, J.F., Larimo, J., 1998. The impact of culture on the strategy of multinational investigation of Japanese firms. Management International Review 36, 45–65.
enterprise: does national origin affect ownership decisions? Journal of Interna- Richardson, J., 1993. Restructuring supplier relationships in U.S. manufacturing for
tional Business Studies 29, 515–538. improved quality. Management International Review 33, 53–67.
Hennart, J.F., Park, Y., 1993. Greenfield vs. acquisition: the strategy of Japanese investors Stewart, M.B., 2007. The interrelated dynamics of unemployment and low-wage
in the United States. Management Science 39, 1054–1070. employment. Journal of Applied Econometrics 22, 511–531.
Hennart, J.F., Zeng, M., 2005. Structural determinants of joint venture performance. Wei, Y., Liu, B., Liu, X., 2005. Entry modes of foreign direct investment in China: a
European Management Review 2, 105–115. multinomial logit approach. Journal of Business Research 58, 1495–1505.
Hill, C.W.L., Hwang, P., Kim, W.C., 1990. An eclectic theory of the choice of international Williamson, O.E., 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. Free Press, New York.
entry mode. Strategic Management Journal 11, 117–128. Williamson, O.E., 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Free Press, New York.
Hyslop, D.R., 1999. State dependence, serial correlation and heterogeneity in intertemporal Yiu, D., Makino, S., 2002. The choice between joint venture and wholly owned
labor force participation of married women. Econometrica 67, 1255–1294. subsidiary: an institutional perspective. Organization Science 13, 667–683.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen