Sie sind auf Seite 1von 137

THREE ESSAYS ON FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND

ECONOMIC GROWTH

DISSERTATION

Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for


the Degree Doctor of Philosophy in the

Graduate School of The Ohio State University

By

Pilhyun Kim, M.A.

*****

The Ohio State University

2006

Dissertation Committee: Approved by


Dr. Paul Evans, Adviser
Dr. Masao Ogaki
Adviser
Dr. Pok-sang Lam Graduate Program in
Economics




ProQuest Number: 10835706




All rights reserved

INFORMATION TO ALL USERS
The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted.

In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript
and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed,
a note will indicate the deletion.






ProQuest 10835706

Published by ProQuest LLC (2018 ). Copyright of the Dissertation is held by the Author.


All rights reserved.
This work is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code
Microform Edition © ProQuest LLC.


ProQuest LLC.
789 East Eisenhower Parkway
P.O. Box 1346
Ann Arbor, MI 48106 - 1346
ABSTRACT

The primary part of my dissertation investigates the potential effects of financial

sector development on economic growth. In order to reveal the nature of these effects,

I focus on the potential channels of influence from the financial to the real sector.

I investigate the link between the financial sector and economic growth focusing on

the role of the financial sector in funding innovative activities. To this aim, I construct

a model where the economy is driven by innovative activities that require both human

capital and external funding. My analysis shows that when certain conditions are

satisfied, there exists a unique equilibrium where the growth rate of the economy

is jointly determined by the levels of human capital and financial development. An

implication of this is that financial liberalization policies that do not adequately

address the fundamentals of the economy can cause bank failures and possibly a

financial crisis. Furthermore, the model suggests that, depending on the parameter

values of the economy, there may be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small

number of bankers and the other with a large number of bankers.

Also, I examine empirically whether financial development has any effect on the

rate of technological innovation using patent applications as a proxy for innovative

output. For a sample of twenty eight countries from 1970 to 2000, my analysis shows

that financial development is indeed significant in raising the growth rate of innovative

output.

ii
In addition, I investigate whether financial development enhances investment ef-

ficiency. The efficiency channel hypothesis states that financial development may

increase the efficiency of investment by directing the funds to the most productive

uses. I examine if there is any evidence of financial development positively affect-

ing the efficiency of aggregate investment using developing countries as a sample.

Compared to the volume channel, the efficiency channel has received relatively little

attention until recently. I address the issue of the efficiency channel using two alterna-

tive measures of aggregate investment efficiency. I find that, for developing countries,

financial development significantly and positively affects productivity of investment.

iii
To my parents and my family

iv
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I am indebted to Dr. Paul Evans, my advisor, for his valuable and expert guidance,

insightful comments and encouragement during the course of this study. Without his

patient guidance my dissertation would have been impossible.

Special gratitude is extended to Dr. Masao Ogaki and Dr. Pok-sang Lam for their

comments and valuable help to improve my study.

Financial support from the PEGS Research Grant is greatly acknowledged as well

as the Graduate Teaching Assistantship the Department of Economics have offered

me throughout my residence at the Ohio State University.

In addition, my special thanks go to my wife Jihee and my family who have been

always supporting and praying for me.

Most of all, I would like to express my deepest appreciation to my father and

mother for their belief in my abilities and undying support throughout my life.

v
VITA

January 9, 1969 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Born - Gwanju, Korea

1991 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . B.A. Economics, University of Wiscon-


sin, Madison
1998 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . M.A. Economics, The Ohio State Uni-
versity
2001 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Ph.D Candidate, The Ohio State Uni-
versity
1998 - 2004 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Graduate Teaching Associate, The
Ohio State University
2004 - 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Lecturer, The Western Washington
University

FIELDS OF STUDY

Major Field: Economics

Studies in:
Money Macroeconomics
Applied Econometrics
Economic Growth

vi
TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

Abstract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii

Dedication . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iv

Acknowledgments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v

Vita . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi

List of Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . x

List of Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xi

Chapters:

1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

2. Literature Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

2.1 Models of the finance-led growth theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6


2.2 Empirics of the finance-led growth theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

3. A Finance-led Growth Hypothesis: Revisited . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
3.2 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
3.2.1 Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
3.2.2 A formal model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
3.3 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27
3.4 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

vii
4. How Does Financial Development Promote Growth? . . . . . . . . . . . 35

4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35
4.2 Related Literature . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
4.2.1 Theories of the finance-led growth hypothesis . . . . . . . . 37
4.2.2 Empirical studies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39
4.3 Theoretical background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
4.3.1 Final goods sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
4.3.2 Intermediate goods sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42
4.3.3 The research sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
4.3.4 The growth of the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
4.4 Empirical analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
4.4.1 Patents as a proxy for technological innovation . . . . . . . 47
4.4.2 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50
4.4.3 Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54
4.4.4 Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61
4.5 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63

5. Investment Efficiency and Financial Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

5.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71
5.2 Investment, output growth, and financial development . . . . . . . 74
5.2.1 Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77
5.2.2 Estimation strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79
5.2.3 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81
5.3 Investment efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
5.3.1 Measures of investment efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84
5.3.2 Investment efficiency estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87
5.3.3 Determinants of investment efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90
5.3.4 Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92
5.3.5 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 93
5.3.6 The effects of political stability and legal environment . . . 94
5.3.7 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95
5.4 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96

6. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111

Appendices:

viii
A. Data Sources for Chapter 5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

B. Countries Used in Chapter 5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

Bibliography . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118

ix
LIST OF TABLES

Table Page

4.1 Sample Countries Used for Patent Regression . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67

4.2 Fixed Effects Estimation I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

4.3 Fixed Effects Estimation II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69

4.4 Fixed Effects Estimation with Selected Independent Variables . . . . 70

5.1 Investment Regression I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100

5.2 Investment Regression II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101

5.3 Investment Regression III . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102

5.4 Investment Efficiency Estimates using GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103

5.5 Investment Efficiency Estimates Using IVA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105

5.6 Investment Efficiency Regression I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107

5.7 Investment Efficiency Regression II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

5.8 Investment Efficiency Regression III . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

5.9 Investment Efficiency Regression IV . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110

x
LIST OF FIGURES

Figure Page

3.1 Screening Costs of Competing Bankers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

3.2 Equilibrium When α + θ < 1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

3.3 Effects of Deterioration in Education . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

4.1 Long Run GDP Growth vs. Long Run Patent Growth . . . . . . . . . 65

4.2 Movements of Financial Development Indicators for Selected Countries 66

5.1 Output Growth and Investment in Cambodia . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98

5.2 The Share of Industry Value Added in GDP in Developing Countries 99

xi
CHAPTER 1

Introduction

The primary part of my dissertation investigates the potential effects of financial

sector development on economic growth. In order to reveal the nature of these effects,

I focus on the potential channels of influence from the financial to the real sector.

The nature of the interaction between the real and the financial sectors has been

hotly debated among researchers. Those who favor the finance-led growth hypothesis

argue that the existence of a vibrant financial sector has growth-enhancing effects. In

this literature, an economy can grow faster due to an efficient allocation of resources

by the financial sector, mainly banks. A number of channels of influence have been

proposed in the literature, which include increased savings, increased investment, in-

creased efficiency thereof, increased human capital accumulation, and positive effects

of the financial sector on innovation processes. Investigations of the validity of these

channels as true agents of long-run growth, so far, have yielded mixed empirical re-

sults. In chapter 2, I review the vast literatue on this subject to examine how the

literature has evolved over time.

In chapter 3, I investigate the link between the financial sector and economic

growth focusing on the role of the financial sector in funding innovative activities. My

1
motivation is based on the research by Easterly and Levine (2001) in that it is the

residual that accounts for most of the income and growth differences across nations.

Broadly speaking, innovative activities require both human and financial capital.

They act as complements in the production function of ideas. However, the interaction

between the two has been largely ignored in the literature. In order to improve our

understanding of how the financial sector interacts with the real sector, the nature

of interactions between two major components of innovative activities needs to be

examined more closely. In this chapter, I pursue this goal by constructing a model

where the economy is driven by innovative activities that require both human capital

and external funding from the financial sector. Similar to King and Levine (1993), it is

assumed that the role of the financial sector in this model is to screen the innovators for

their probabilities of success. In formalizing the model, I depart from the conventional

literature in four important ways. Firstly, I define innovation as a success not when

it is realized but when it is commercially successful. This distinction is motivated by

observations that not all innovations are implemented in the production processes.

Secondly, I assume that the magnitude of technological change an innovator comes

up with is a function of that innovator’s human capital. Thirdly, it is assumed in

this model that external finance is needed not for R&D activities but for utilization

of innovations. Finally, it is assumed that the financial sector pays no setup costs.

My analysis shows that when certain conditions are satisfied, there exists a unique

equilibrium where the growth rate of the economy is jointly determined by the levels

of human capital and financial development. An interesting implication of this is that

financial liberalization policies that do not adequately address the fundamentals of the

economy can bring about bank failures and possibly a financial crisis. Furthermore,

2
in addition to showing that poverty traps can be explained without introducing setup

costs, the model suggests that, depending on the parameter values of the economy,

there may be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small number of bankers and

the other with a large number of bankers.

In chapter 4, I examine empirically whether financial development has any effect

on the rate of technological innovation. A flood of empirical studies began to appear

in the 1990s to test the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis. A typical

test strategy involves regressing some indicator of financial development on some

aggregate growth measures such as investment growth, GDP growth or total factor

productivity growth. By and large, the current empirical literature lacks one crucial

element in that it does not consider the channels of influence suggested by theoretical

models and fails to show how financial development affects economic growth. In

order to examine the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis, I depart from the

conventional literature. Instead of estimating a relationship between aggregate growth

measures and financial development indicators, I test the validity of the finance-led

growth hypothesis by focusing on the innovation channel of influence, using patent

applications as a proxy for innovative output. Under the framework of ideas-driven

growth, the hypothesis I test is that financial development enhances innovation, which

is the main engine of economic growth. If the finance-led growth hypothesis is right,

as the financial sector develops over time in a certain country, the growth rate of

innovation should be higher, which would, then, lead to faster economic growth due

to a rising level of productivity. Using panel data on twenty eight countries from 1970

to 2000, my analysis shows that financial development is indeed significant in raising

the growth rate of innovative output.

3
According to the finance-led growth hypothesis, financial development affects in-

vestment in two ways. Firstly, a better developed financial sector may raise the

investment rate by pooling and risk sharing. This is the so-called volume channel.

Secondly, the efficiency channel hypothesis states that financial development may in-

crease the efficiency of investment by directing the funds to the most productive uses.

In chapter 5, I examine if there is any evidence of financial development positively af-

fecting the efficiency of aggregate investment using developing countries as a sample.

Compared to the volume channel, the efficiency channel has received relatively little

attention until recently. In this chapter, I address the issue of the efficiency channel

using two alternative measures of aggregate investment efficiency. I find that, for

developing countries, financial development significantly and positively affects pro-

ductivity of investment. Further, I depart from the existing studies by focusing on

the banking sector to measure the degree of financial development. In chapter 6, I

conclude.

4
CHAPTER 2

Literature Review

The literature on the finance-led growth hypothesis is vast. Accordingly, a few

survey papers have been written on this subject. See, for example, Levine (1997) and

Tsuru (2000). The focus of this review is, therefore, not to present an exhaustive

review of the literature as it would be rather redundant, but to assess critically how

the literature has evolved over time and to identify the remaining issues that need to

be resolved.

Theoretical models of the finance-led growth hypothesis are, in general, modified

versions of endogenous growth theories with risky investment opportunities. Due

to uncertainty about the outcome of investment, the allocation of resources is sub-

optimal. The financial sector enters this world to reduce welfare loss resulting from

this uncertainty by providing information, risk-pooling, and liquidity. As the financial

sector develops, possibly as a result of feedback from economic growth, the provision

of these services becomes more efficient so that a faster rate of economic growth is

realized.

The overriding research theme that came out of the theoretical models and that has

occupied the attention of the empirical researchers for the past decade is a question of

5
whether growth rate of an economy is positively correlated with the level of financial

development. A typical method employed to test this theory has been to regress

some aggregate growth variables on financial development indicators that are based

on some ratio of monetary aggregates to GDP. Simple as it may be in its approach,

this line of research has produced an impressive amount of evidence for the finance-led

growth theory. In what follows, I examine more closely how the literature has evolved

over time both theoretically and empirically.

2.1 Models of the finance-led growth theory

An initial theoretical interest lay in the effects of financial development on the

efficiency of capital accumulation. Greenwood and Jovanovich (1990) is among the

frontiers of this approach. They assume an economy where growth is driven by capi-

tal accumulation, and the risky nature of investment prevents agents from allocating

resources in an efficient manner, resulting in welfare loss in the absence of the finan-

cial sector. However, as the economy grows, it becomes able to pay the setup costs

to establish the financial sector of which the role is to collect and process information

and to pool risks across investors/savers. Once the financial sector is established, it

allows a higher rate of return to be earned on capital, promoting economic growth.

Bencivenga and Smith (1991) pursue a similar vein and present a model where ran-

dom liqudity shocks raise the fraction of savings invested in liquid but unproductive

assets. The financial sector enters this world exogenously, contrary to Greenwood

and Jovanovich, to provide liquidity to economic agents and makes it possible for

them to invest a larger portion of their savings in productive and illiquid assets. Al-

though the specific types of risk assumed in these models are different, the nature of

6
the fundamental role the financial sector plays is essentially the same. By processing

information and reducing risks, the financial sector reduces uncertainty associated

with investment and directs funds to their most productive uses, and consequently,

enhances the rate of economic growth.

As doubts about the effectiveness of capital accumulation in promoting long-term

growth arose, researchers shifted their focus to potential positive effects financial

development may have on productivity growth. The main sources of productivity

growth considered in this literature are purposeful innovative activities and market

specialization that are risky. Uncertain nature of the outcomes of innovative activi-

ties (Fuente and Marin, 1996) and market specialization characterized by increasing

number of firms (Galetovic, 1996; Greenwood and Smith, 1997) make monitoring

necessary. Since monitoring is assumed to be costly, there is an incentive for the

financial sector to endogenously emerge to economize on the monitoring costs as in

Diamond (1983). The provision of monitoring services by the financial sector then

leads to increased levels of innovative activities and market specialization, which re-

sult in enhanced economic growth. The main weakness of this type of model is that

there seems to be no empirical evidence of the financial sector conducting active

monitoring (Allen and Gale, 2001). Furthermore, the proposition that the financial

sector actively monitors the outcome of investment may have a weaker ground in

those countries where the banking sector provides a large share of external finance

with debt contracts.. Since debt contracts require the investor/borrower to repay a

fixed amount after a certain period independent of the outcome of investment, the

banking sector does not have an incentive to actively monitor the activities of the

investor/borrower except ascertaining the state of the outcome of such activities at

7
maturity. As such, the models above may not be applicable to the experiences of

many, especially developing, countries.

King and Levine (1993) and Harrison et al (1999) explore different possibilities.

Instead of the monitoring role, King and Levine (1993) focuses on the screening role

of the financial sector. Again, innovation that drives economic growth is assumed

to be risky. Each innovator has a different ability to innovate and hence different

probability of success. The financial sector in this case enhances growth by weeding

out those innovators with low probability of success by screening and improving the

aggregate probability of success. Harrison et al (1999) departs from the assumption

of asymmetric information and considers the effects of agency costs. In their model,

the economy grows by investment aimed at promoting productivity growth. Higher

agency costs due to a poorly developed financial sector hinders growth by reducing

the portion of savings that is channeled into investment. Financial development

reduces the costs of intermediation and promotes growth by allowing productivity

improvement. In turn, economic growth raises bank profits and induces more entry

of banks. As more banks enter, more specialization of banks occurs that reduces costs

of intermediation further, which, in turn, raises the investment rate feeding back to

still higher economic growth.

In general, the models described so far suffer from three drawbacks. Firstly, as

mentioned above, the assumption of setup costs, needed to introduce poverty traps,

seems empirically unjustified. Secondly, and related to the first point, is the fact that

finance-growth relationship is likely to be nonlinear. That is to say that the effects of

financial development on economic growth seems to get weaker as the level of financial

8
development rises, possibly suggesting diminishing marginal returns. This evidence

directly contradicts the existing theories where economic growth is a (monotonically)

increasing function of the level of financial development. Finally, the models where

the financial sector actively monitors do not seem to accurately reflect the experiences

of many countries.

2.2 Empirics of the finance-led growth theory

First systematic investigation of the relationship between finance and growth was

conducted by King and Levine (1993). In their study, it was found that the level of

financial development was positively correlated with growth variables such as GDP

per capita growth, investment rate, and total factor productivity growth. Notwith-

standing the rigorous statistical analysis they conducted to reveal the relationship,

their study was more significant in that it brought the issue of simultaneity up to the

center stage. It was pointed out that the use of lagged values of financial development

indicators, as King and Levine did in their study, does not resolve the simultaneity

bias if the agents behaved in forward-looking manner, which would make their results

hard to interpret. By contrast, De Gregorio and Guidotti (1995) argued that the

use of lagged levels of financial development indicators is justified in cross-sectional

studies by noting that "the theories suggest that economic growth induces growth in

the financial system but this has no implications regarding the size of the financial

system with respect to GDP." Further, their Barro-type cross-sectional estimation

found that the positive effects of financial development on growth vary over time

periods, regions, and income levels, which suggested that the relationship might be

nonlinear.

9
As the issues of simultaneity and nonlinearity persisted, it was suggested that a

time-series study focusing on a small group of countries would prove to be beneficial.

The results from the early attempts in this direction cast doubt on the validity of

the finance-led growth hypothesis. For example, Demetriades and Hussein (1996),

who were among the first researchers to employ time-series approach, found, using

cointegration tests, that the relationship between finance and growth is bidirectional

and that this relationship is country-specific. Similar results were obtained by Arestis

and Demetriades (1997), Luintel and Khan (1999), and Shan et al (2001) using VAR

estimation. However, more recent studies have reestablished finance as an important

source of economic growth. To cite a few, Xu (2000) found evidence for the finance-led

growth hypothesis using multivariate VAR, directly contradicting the findings of the

previous time-series studies. Calderon and Lie (2003) agree with Xu, after conducting

Geweke decomposition test on pooled data of 109 countries, and conclude that finance

generally leads growth albeit some evidence of bidirectional Granger-causality. More

recently, Christopoulos and Tsionas (2004) applied panel unit root and cointegration

tests, threshold cointegration test, and panel VECM to find support for unidirectional

causality from finance to growth.

Another strand of research that has been pursued is the use of panel studies.

Compared to the approaches mentioned above, panel study was generally regarded as

more advantageous (Temple, 1999). Using dynamic GMM to control for simultaneity

and unobserved country-specific effects, Beck et al (2000) found that financial devel-

opment promotes growth by improving productivity. Rioja and Valev (2004) adapt

a similar method to investigate whether financial development affects growth differ-

ently according to the income levels. While they concede that developed countries’

10
growth is enhanced by finance-stimulated productivity growth as in Beck et al, they

argue that the effects of financial development on growth of developing countries are

via capital accumulation.

Overall, the current trend in this area can be summarized as the following. First,

the consensus on the bidirectional causality seems to be gaining an increasing support.

This may be a natural course of work since the financial sector is, after all, a part of

an economic system. Second, there is an increasing emphasis on the need to employ a

time-series approach when considering the relationship between financial development

and growth. Third, along with the second trend, researchers are increasingly putting

an effort to incorporate infrastructural environments into the analysis. Fourth, the

importance of incorporating microeconomic mechanism in modelling the behavior of

the financial markets is gaining acceptance among researchers in this area. Given

that there has been an increased emphasis on the microeconomic environment in

macroeconomic topics, this seems rather late. At least, the research in this area

seems to be going in the right direction. Finally, since 1996, there has been more

attention on the channels of influence from financial development to economic growth

11
CHAPTER 3

A Finance-led Growth Hypothesis: Revisited

3.1 Introduction

Ever since Schumpeter highlighted a potentially growth-enhancing role of banks as

efficient allocators of funds in 1911, the relationship between financial sector and real

sector has been a subject of heated debates. In his argument, banks help an economy

achieve first-best outcome by providing efficient markets for funds. In contrast to

this argument, there are also a group of economists who view the financial sector as

something that merely mirrors the real sector. Most notably, Robinson (1952) argued

that "...finance does not lead growth. Growth leads finance..." The main argument

of those who oppose finance-led growth theories is that, simply put, financial markets

evolve in response to increased demands for better services from a growing economy.

Therefore, the development of financial markets only mirrors that of real sectors. This

led Lucas to state that economists badly over-stress the role of financial sectors. These

two polar positions on the role of financial sectors have led economists to consider

the issue of causality extensively.

The approach I take to investigate the link between the financial sector and eco-

nomic growth focuses on the role of the financial sector in financing innovative activ-

ities. Our motivation is based on the research by Easterly and Levine (2001) in that

12
it is the residual that accounts for most of the income and growth differences across

nations. Further, the idea that innovative activities need financial assistance is quite

intuitive. We can easily imagine what might have happened to IT companies if there

had been no venture capital. It clearly illustrates the possibility of positive effects

the financial sector may have on the real sector activities.

Broadly speaking, innovative activities require both human and financial capital.

They act as complements in the production function of ideas. However, the interaction

between the two has been largely ignored in the literature. An exception is the study

by Outreville (1999) where he shows empirically that there is a positive relationship

between human capital and financial development, although no formal theory was

offered to explain the finding. In order to improve our understanding of how the

financial sector interacts with the real sector, the nature of interactions between two

major components of innovative activities needs to be examined more closely. In this

chapter, I pursue this goal by constructing a model where the economy is driven by

innovative activities that require both human capital and external funding from the

financial sector. Similar to King and Levine (1993), it is assumed that the role of

the financial sector in this model is to screen the innovators for their probabilities

of success. However, unlike King and Levine’s version of the financial sector that

plays an active screening role of weeding out bad entrepreneurs, the financial sector I

consider is a more passive one. Specifically, it is assumed that the role of the financial

sector is to assess and convey the probability of success to the innovators so that the

latter can make optimal borrowing decisions. It is passive in a sense that it does not

refuse to lend to those innovators with low probability of success. Rather, it penalizes

them by imposing higher repayment requirements. Therefore, contrary to King and

13
Levine, the financial sector does not improve the aggregate probability of success by

screening.

In formalizing the model, I depart from the conventional literature in four impor-

tant ways. Firstly, I define innovation as a success not when it is realized but when

it is commercially successful. This distinction is motivated by observations that not

all innovations are implemented in the production processes. For example, we know

from history that the steam engine was invented in Ancient Greece two-thousand

years ago. However, it obviously did not ignite the industrial revolution at that time

as it did in England millenniums later. A similar example can be found in the United

States at the turn of the 20th century. Around the time when mass production of

automobiles was about to be started, an automobile that could run on electricity was

invented. It drove quietly, emitted less pollution and was technologically superior

to gasoline-driven automobiles. However, we all know how the electric-automobile

industry fared in the end. Although it was technologically superior to other competi-

tors, it did not survive the forces of the market because it lacked commercial appeals.

Gasoline-driven cars were simply much faster and more powerful than electric ones,

and hence were more attractive to automobile buyers. In a sense that the aim of

innovation is to improve the welfare, in terms of higher incomes or more convenience,

of economic agents, a steam engine in Ancient Greece or electric cars in the early 20th

century can hardly be regarded as a success. This is especially true if one regards the

purpose of innovation to be improvements of production technology. To put it rather

bluntly, a technology that is not used commercially is the same as a technology that

is not invented as far as its effects on output production is concerned. Accordingly,

in the model considered here, it is assumed that innovators invent new technologies

14
with certainty. What is uncertain is whether the new technology would be successful

commercially. Then, the job of assessing the probability of commercial success is

left to the financial sector. Secondly, I assume that the magnitude of technological

change an innovator comes up with is a function of that innovator’s human capital.

The idea is simply that the smarter the innovator is, the bigger the improvements

over the existing technology will be. It should be noted in advance that although

the magnitude of technological change is endogenized, the resulting implication in

terms of economic growth remains similar to the existing literature. Thirdly, it is

assumed in this model that external finance is needed not for R&D activities but for

utilization of innovations. Venture capital markets justify this assumption. Finally,

it is assumed that the financial sector pays no setup costs. The assumption of fixed

setup costs has been used in the literature to explain poverty traps and bidirectional

causality between finance and growth. However, historical experiences of developed

countries do not support this assumption (Galetovic, 1996). My analysis shows that

one does not need the assumption of setup costs to establish bi-causality or to explain

poverty traps.

My analysis shows that when certain conditions are satisfied, there exists a unique

equilibrium where the growth rate of the economy is jointly determined by the levels

of human capital and financial development. An interesting implication of this is that

financial liberalization policies that do not adequately address the fundamentals of the

economy can bring about bank failures and possibly a financial crisis. Furthermore,

in addition to showing that poverty traps can be explained without introducing setup

costs, the model suggests that, depending on the parameter values of the economy,

15
there may be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small number of bankers and

the other with a large number of bankers.

The rest of the chapter is organized as follows. In section 2, a formal model

preceded by a sketch is presented. In section 3, the model’s implications are discussed.

In section 4, I conclude.

3.2 Model

3.2.1 Environment

Imagine a small island populated by groups of workers and bankers who are risk-

neutral. While bankers move freely to and from other islands, workers are assumed

not to be mobile. People on this island live infinitely, but their planning horizon

is on a daily basis. In particular, there are L number of identical workers with a

zero population growth rate. The worker’s daily routine consists of three events in

the morning, afternoon, and evening. At every morning, he is endowed with one

unit of manna for the day. Notice that the manna depreciates completely in one

day so that there is no saving for tomorrow. The worker can use the manna for two

things. He can use some fraction of it to accumulate human capital which will enable

him to become an innovator in the afternoon. With what remains, he produces the

consumption good using the old technology. After obtaining education, the worker

innovates over the existing technology. At this time, the worker/innovator does not

know the likelihood of commercial success of his invention. Once he comes up with

an idea as to how to improve the old technology, he goes to the banker to finance

his production of consumption goods. Notice that the magnitude of improvement

depends on the fraction of the manna he spent to receive education. That is to say,

16
the smarter the worker/innovator is, the bigger the improvement will be. When he

meets with the banker, the probability of commercial success is revealed through

the screening of the banker. Then the worker/innovator borrows from the banker to

finance his production activity. In return he promises to pay a certain fraction of

the consumption goods he expects to produce in the afternoon as a repayment to the

banker. In the afternoon, the state of his innovation’s commercial success is revealed.

If it is a success, the worker uses the new technology to produce consumption goods

of which some fraction is paid back to the banker as a repayment. If it is a failure,

the worker returns what was borrowed, instead of the agreed amount of repayment,

to the banker. In the evening, the innovator/worker consumes what is left, and goes

to sleep to start a new day tomorrow.

There is an arbitrarily large number of identical bankers on this island. Since

they can move freely across different islands unlike the workers, exactly how many

bankers are on the island at any particular time is not relevant. What is relevant in

this economy is how many bankers decide to finance the innovators. In the morning,

the banker is endowed with the capital good. He is also endowed with a technology

that can transform his endowment to the consumption good at the rate of r, and

this process is assumed to take a day. With the endowment, the banker must figure

out whether he should open a bank or use the endowed technology to transform it

to consumption goods for his own use in the evening. Once he decides to open a

bank, he does so without paying setup costs. Then, he waits for the innovators to

come and ask for loans. When the innovator comes in for a loan to implement his

innovation, the banker screens him to gauge the likelihood of the commercial success

of the innovator’s idea. Based upon the probability of commercial success, which is

17
different across the innovators, the banker decides on the amount of repayment, in

terms of the consumption goods that he must receive for lending a given amount of

capital to the innovator. In the afternoon, he receives the proceeds from investing in

the worker/innovator. In the evening, he consumes what he received in the afternoon.

In the next morning, the whole cycle starts anew. With this description in mind, we

move to formalize the model in the next section.

3.2.2 A formal model


Workers

Initially, the island is endowed with a certain level of technology denoted by A0

at time 0. In each day t, there exists L number of workers who live infinitely. It

is assumed that there is no population growth and that L is some arbitrarily large

number less than infinity. As mentioned above, the worker i’s daily routine consists

of three events. In the morning, he is endowed with one unit of manna. He can use

the manna for two activities: innovation and/or production with an old technology.

His problem is to figure out how to allocate the manna between these two activities.

If he decides to innovate, he spends a fraction vi of the manna to receive education

that will enable him to become an innovator in the afternoon. The interpretation of

vi is that it measures the amount of sacrifice the worker needs to make to make an

innovation as it could have been used to produce the consumption goods with the

old technology. Notice that the education process is assumed to be instantaneous for

simplicity.

18
The worker i improves upon the old technology that is available for everyone based

upon the following:

Ait = γ it At−1 . (3.1)

where γ it = (δvit )θ . The parameter δ stands for the effectiveness of education process

and is greater than zero. θ is an idea production parameter between 0 and 1. This

specification of γ implies that the magnitude of the technological change is an increas-

ing function of human capital acquired through education. In essence, it is similar to

Aghion and Howitt’s model (1999) where the economy is driven by innovation and

creative destruction. In their model, the magnitude of technological change is a func-

tion of some exogenous parameter (their γ) and the number of people working in the

research sector. The difference is that I model γ to be solely a function of human cap-

ital and leave out the exogenous component. In terms of model implications, nothing

is lost by the explicit modelling of γ in this fashion. An attractive feature, on the

other hand, of specifying γ this way is that it allows for the possibility of diminishing

marginal returns. R&D literature shows that as research efforts increase, captured

implicitly by v here, the number of innovations that results grows at a decreasing

rate. Aghion and Howitt’s specification does not coincide with this empirical finding.

Admittedly, the specification of γ in my model is based on observations only and

rather ad-hoc. However, I argue that specifying γ explicitly rather than taking it

as exogenous is a step in the right direction toward understanding the impacts that

innovations have on the economy.

Recall that the fact the worker comes up with a new technology does not mean

that the innovation is successful commercially. As discussed in the previous section,

19
whether the innovation is a success is judged by its commercial usefulness. After com-

ing up with a new technology, the worker/innovator is randomly and uniformly put

into a location around the circumference of the island. The circumference of the island

is assumed to be equal to 1. In this model, I posit that the probability of commercial

success, p, is a function of the distance between the worker/innovator and the banker

who finances him, and that this distance is not known to the worker/innovator until

he is screened by the banker. This idea is motivated by observations from the venture

capital market. In the case of venture capital, it is accepted that the likelihood of

success for a new idea, business plan, and/or product is critically dependent upon

how close relationship the innovator has with those who provide funds. In this model,

the nature of the relationship between the borrower and the lender is captured by

the distance between the two. An exact specification of the probability of commercial

success will be given in the next section.

Afterwards, the worker/innovator goes to the banker to borrow capital to finance

his production activity using the new technology, after which the probability of com-

mercial success is revealed through the screening of the banker. Given the now-

revealed probability of the commercial success for his innovation, the worker/innovator

decides the optimal amount of capital, xit , to borrow and promises to repay Iit to the

banker if the innovation is commercially successful. Note that the capital is borrowed

after the innovation occurred as described in the previous section.

In the afternoon, the probability of the innovation’s commercial success is realized

to everyone. If the innovation is commercially successful, the worker uses the new

20
technology, Ait , and the capital, xit , borrowed from the banker to produce consump-

tion goods according to a production function:

yitH = Ait xαit = (δvit )θ At−1 xαit (3.2)

where α is between 0 and 1. H stands for the production sector that employs a

new technology. Note that after one day, the new technology becomes available

to everyone. If the innovation is unsuccessful, then the worker/innovator returns the

borrowed capital/consumption good, x, instead of I, to the banker. At the same time,

he spends 1 − vit to produce consumption goods with the old technology according

to the production function:

yitL = At−1 (1 − vit ) (3.3)

where L designates the production sector with the old technology. In the evening,

the day is complete with the worker consuming what is left.

Bankers

In this model, the bankers are assumed to be symmetrical and to maximize prof-

its. Similar to the workers, each banker’s daily routine consists of three events. In

the morning, the representative banker is endowed with arbitrarily large units of cap-

ital/consumption goods less than infinity.1 It should be pointed out that the exact

amounts of endowments do not need to be specified for the same reason that the

number of the bankers present on the island need not be specified. It is implicitly

assumed in this model that the bankers can potentially finance as many workers as

possible as long as it is profitable. Considering that in the real world, the amount
1
This endowment will be designated as a capital good from now on for the sake of convenience.

21
of funds that can be potentially available to the innovator is significantly large espe-

cially when there is a relatively free flow of funds across countries, I believe that this

assumption is reasonable. In addition, making this assumption allows us to abstain

from having to deal with the effects of inter-island transfer of capital/consumption

goods.

In the morning, he has to decide what to do with the endowment. He can use it

to invest in the worker/innovator or have it transformed at a rate of r. To use an

analogy, his decision can be described as having to choose between risk-free bonds

that pay an interest of r and risky bonds with a higher rate of return than r. Notice

that opening up a bank does not cost the banker anything. Once he opens the bank,

he meets and screens the worker/innovator to assess the probability of commercial

success of the innovation which is defined as:

p(zit ) = e−zit , 0 < zit < dt (3.4)

where zit is the distance between the banker and the worker/innovator i at time t.dt

is the maximum distance the worker/innovator can be located from the banker.

The screening is assumed to be costly. Intuitively, the further away the worker/innovator

is from the banker, the more costly it would be for the banker to assess the probability

of commercial success. Hence, the screening costs would be a function of z. Another

way to think about it is to imagine that, in practice, it would cost more for the banker

to find out the likelihood of success if the borrower is of a somewhat dubious nature,

which z represents. To capture this, I define the screening cost to be:

SC(zit ) = βezit , 0 < zit < dt (3.5)

22
where β is a exogenous policy variable that measures the stringency of the government

policies regarding the screening processes. A higher level of β implies that more

strict policies are in place, and hence the banker incurs higher costs for screening.

Figure (3.1) illustrates the relationship between two neighboring banks in terms of

the screening costs. It can be seen that for those innovators whose distances z are

between −dt and dt , the banker A has a monopoly power over them since it has a cost

advantage over all other banks and in particular over its adjacent bankers B and B’.

It can be seen that since the circumference of the island is equal to 1, and the bankers
1
will open their banks along the circumference, 2dt
= Nt , where Nt is the number of

bankers open for business at time t.

Once the screening is done, the banker informs the worker/innovator of the prob-

ability of commercial success so that the latter can make a optimal decision on how

much to borrow. Then the banker meets the worker/innovator’s demand by supplying

him with xit . In return, it is promised to the banker that he would receive I from the

worker/innovator if the innovation is commercially successful, and xit if it is not.

In the afternoon, the probability of success is realized and the banker receives

either I or xit depending on the state of the worker/innovator. In the evening, he

consumes what he has received from the worker/innovator along with the rest of the

endowments.

Equilibrium

In order to solve the model, we start with the worker. Given the setup above, the

problem the worker i faces at time t is to choose vit to maximize his consumption in

23
the evening. Formally, in the morning, he maximizes

pit (Ait xαit − Iit ) − (1 − pit )xit + At−1 (1 − vit )

by choosing v. Since zit is not yet known at the time of decision, the problem above

becomes in effect

E{pit (Ait xαit − Iit ) − (1 − pit )xit } + At−1 (1 − vit ). (3.6)

Before solving the worker’s problem, it will be convenient to specify I at this

point. When lending xit , the banker charges Iit to hedge against the potential loss in

case the innovation is a failure so that

(1 + r)xit = pit Iit + (1 − pit )xit , (3.7)

where r is the world interest rate and exogenous.

Solving Eq. (3.7) gives Iit as:


µ ¶
r
Iit = 1 + xit . (3.8)
pit

One can see from Eq. (3.8) that the banker needs to be compensated for the

risk he takes by financing the worker/innovator. As long as pit is less than one, the

return he gets from investing in the worker/innovator is greater than what he would

get from the endowed technology. If pit is equal to 1, then there is no uncertainty in

this world, and therefore the banker does not need to be compensated for investing

in the worker/innovator, which is as safe as the endowed transformation technology.

Also, note that those innovators with low probabilities of success are imposed higher

repayment requirements. In this world, the bankers do not weed out the bad innova-

tors as in King and Levine (1993). Instead, they impose higher penalties and let the

borrowers make the optimal decision.

24
Going back to the worker’s problem, When z is revealed in the afternoon, the

probability of success is now known to the worker/innovator. Then, the worker’s

problem after z is revealed is

pit (Ait xαit − Iit ) − (1 − pit )xit . (3.9)

Differentiating Eq. (3.9) with respect to xit gives:


µ ¶
αAit pit
xit = . (3.10)
1+r

Using Eq. (3.10) and Eq. (3.6), the worker’s problem before z is revealed can be

described as:
n 1
o
max CE (Ait pit ) 1−α (3.11)
v
¡ α
¢ 1−α
1 ¡
1−α
¢
where C ≡ Rα α
. Since the innovators are randomly and uniformly located

around the circumference of the island,


Z dt
1
1−α
1 −zit
E(pit )= e 1−α dzit . (3.12)
dt 0

Noting that Ait = (δvit )θ At−1 , Eq. (3.11) becomes:


µ ¶
θ 1
1−α
1−α −dt
max(δvit ) 1−α At−1 (1 − e 1−α )C, (3.13)
v dt

where C is as defined above. Differentiating Eq. (3.13) with respect to v gives:


à −dt ! α+θ−1
α−1

1 − e 1−α
vit∗ = D (3.14)
dt

© ª 1
where D ≡ δ −θ A−α
t−1 (1 − α)
α−1 −1 −α(α−1) α+θ−1
α R . Eq. (3.14) shows that the opti-

mal fraction of manna to be spent on receiving education depends on d. Note that by

symmetry, vit∗ = vjt



for i 6= j.

25
Next, we examine the behavior of the banker. Given the setup from the previous

section, the banker will decide to enter and finance the worker/innovator only if the

expected average profit from financing is greater than expected average screening

costs. Hence, the entry condition for the representative banker is

E {pit Iit + (1 − pit )xit } = E(βez ). (3.15)

It follows then that the decision rule for the banker is given by:
µ ¶ 1−α µ ¶ θ1 ( ) 1−α
θ
β θ Rα edt − 1
vit = (3.16)
αδθ A
−dt
1−α 1 − e 1−α

where R = 1 + r.

1
On this island, the equilibrium values of vit and Nt (= 2dt
) are jointly determined

by the decisions of the worker/innovator and the banker, represented by Eq. (3.14)

and Eq. (3.16) respectively. Differentiating Eq. (3.14) with respect to d, we find

that how v responds to changes in d depends on the values of two parameters, α and

θ. Specifically, if α + θ 6 1, the optimal level of education, v, rises as more bankers

enter since ∂v/∂d 6 0. In other words, the workers would devote a larger fraction of

the manna to obtain education if there is a larger number of bankers in the economy.

If α + θ > 1, the opposite situation occurs. By contrast, Eq. (3.16) shows that

the banker’s optimal level of d rises as the workers increase their efforts to receive

education.

In the steady state, vit = v ∗ and dt = d∗ (or Nt = N ∗ ) by symmetry. These

relations imply that pit = pi and xit = xi because zit = zi . Then, since the average

output per worker that’s produced using a new technology is At E(pi xαi ), the total

26
output produced by using new technologies is given by:

ytH = L(δv∗ )θ At−1 E(pi xαi ). (3.17)

Total output produced using old technologies is given by:

ytL = LAt−1 (1 − v ∗ ). (3.18)

Then the total aggregate output in equilibrium at time t is given by

£ ¤
yt = At−1 L (δv∗ )θ E(pi xαi ) + (1 − v ∗ ) . (3.19)

Finally, the growth rate of the economy at the steady state is:
µ ¶ µ ¶
yt+1 At
log = log
yt At−1
= θ log(δv) (3.20)

Hence, the growth of the economy is driven by the level of efforts the workers exert

to receive education (v), which is jointly determined by the bankers and the workers,

the idea production parameter, θ, and effectiveness of the educational system, δ.

3.3 Discussion

As noted above, the behavior of the economy in equilibrium is dependent upon

the summed values of two parameters, α and θ. Evidence from economic growth

literature tells us that the value of α is typically estimated to be roughly between

0.3 and 0.4. As for the value of θ, there is no practical way to measure θ as its

estimation essentially requires, among other things, separating out and measuring

the technological changes that results from human capital accumulation. However,

it is reasonable to argue that since there is no reason to believe that the value of θ,a

27
parameter that governs the degree of diminishing marginal returns to human capital,

would be much different from that of α, the sum of α and θ is likely to be less than

1. Accordingly, the model has an implication that for a given value of v, there exists

a unique value of d that is optimal, and vice versa for reasonable parameter values

(Figure 3.2).

The model presented in this chapter has some interesting policy implications.

Firstly, the tougher the government toward the financial sector, the better it is for

the economy. A rise in the stringency of policy rules, β, shifts graph B in Figure

(3.2) to the left, inducing a higher level of human capital accumulation and a faster

rate of economic growth. Another implication is that the economy of this island

will not benefit from those financial policies that aim to raise the number of banks

without paying attention to the fundamentals of the economy. When d is artificially

lowered, say, by the government, the value of v that is optimal to the workers becomes

greater than that of v optimal to the bankers. Hence, over time, the bankers will

begin to suffer losses, and, as a consequence, some bankers have to exit in order

for the economy to restore its equilibrium. This is in line with experiences of Latin

American and Asian countries. Beginning around the mid-1980s, these countries have

implemented financial policies that aimed to encourage competition by inducing more

entry, but often failed to address the issue of whether and how the fundamentals of

their economies would adapt to such policy changes. One of the results of these

policies was, as we know, rather catastrophic. In some instances, the failure of the

banking sector was so severe as to cause an economy-wide financial crisis. This

model provides an explanation for how financial liberalization policies that ignore the

fundamentals of the economy can lead to bank failures, and ultimately financial crisis.

28
Secondly, the model is able to explain the existence of poverty trap without in-

troducing setup costs. Furthermore, it suggests that two kinds of poverty traps may

exist. Firstly, deterioration in the effectiveness of the education system induces the

workers to receive less education, pushing graph W to the left, while shifting graph

B in the same direction. On net, the deterioration of the education system leads to a

lower equilibrium level of d. On the other hand, its effect on v is uncertain. However,

if the workers are more susceptible to deterioration of the education system than the

bankers are, the economy would be stuck in the poverty trap despite the presence

of a large number of banks (Figure 3.3). Therefore, it is possible that a large finan-

cial sector coexists with slow growth of the economy. Secondly, in contrast to the

preceding case, there can be a poverty trap with only a small number of bankers in

the economy as well. This happens when the financial regulations become lax. For

instance, if the regulations regarding the screening processes become relaxed, perhaps

as part of ill-designed liberalization policies, it causes a drop in the equilibrium values

of the number of bankers present in the economy and human capital accumulated,

leading to a slower growth.

Another possibility that has been ignored so far is the case of α+θ > 1. If this were

the case, then the bankers and the workers on this island live in a strange world. Since

it is not possible to analytically examine this case because of the number of parameters

involved, only a qualitative discussion is provided. First of all, depending on the

parameter values, indeterminacy could arise. Secondly, if the parameter values are

such that the bankers are more inelastic than the workers, a rise in β actually reduces

the human capital accumulation and, thus, hinders economic growth. However, it

should be reminded again that this scenario is an unlikely depiction of the real world

29
given the commonly accepted idea of what the values of these two parameters ,α and

θ, should be.

3.4 Conclusion

The exact nature of the relationship between finance and growth has been the

subject of heated debates for many years. Consequently, many models have been

proposed to shed light on this issue. One strand of this literature investigates the role

of the financial sector in promoting innovative activities. This chapter is part that

literature.

The approach I take to investigate the link between the financial sector and eco-

nomic growth focuses on the role of the financial sector in financing innovative activi-

ties. It is motivated by increasing empirical evidence that technological advancement

is a key to economic growth. To study this link, I start with the proposition that

human and financial capital act as complements in the production function of ideas.

Similar to King and Levine (1993), it is assumed that the role of the financial sector

in this model is to screen the innovators for their probabilities of success. However,

unlike King and Levine’s version of the financial sector that plays an active screening

role of weeding out bad entrepreneurs, the financial sector I consider plays a passive

role of assessing and conveying the probability of success to the innovators so that

the latter can make optimal borrowing decisions.

In formalizing the model, I depart from the conventional literature in four impor-

tant ways. Firstly, I define innovation as a success not when it is realized but when

it is commercially successful. This distinction is motivated by observations that not

all innovations are implemented in the production processes. Secondly, I assume that

30
the magnitude of technological change an innovator comes up with is a function of

that innovator’s human capital. Thirdly, it is assumed in this model that external

finance is needed not for R&D activities but for utilization of innovations. Finally, it

is assumed that the financial sector pays no setup costs.

My analysis shows that when certain conditions are satisfied, there exists a unique

equilibrium where the growth rate of the economy is jointly determined by the levels

of human capital and financial development. An interesting implication of this is that

financial liberalization policies that do not adequately address the fundamentals of the

economy can bring about bank failures and possibly a financial crisis. Furthermore,

in addition to showing that poverty traps can be explained without introducing setup

costs, the model suggests that, depending on the parameter values of the economy,

there may be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small number of bankers and

the other with a large number of bankers.

31
Screening costs for Screening costs for
Banker B’ Banker B

A B’ B A

β β β

Screening costs for


Banker A

-2dt -dt 0 dt 2dt


Banker B’ Banker A Banker B
Note) The vertical axis measures the costs of screening. The horizontal axis measures the
distance between adjoining bankers.

Figure 3.1: Screening costs of competing bankers

32
v
(B’) (B)

Rise in β

v'

v*

(W)

d’ d* d

Note) The figure above describes the equilibrium of the economy when α + θ < 1 . (W)
represents the decision rule of the worker/innovator given by Eq. (3.14). (B) represents
that of the banker given by Eq. (3.16).

Figure 3.2: Equilibrium when α + θ < 1

33
v
(B’) (B)

v*
v'
(W)

(W’)
d’ d* d

Note) The figure above describes how the economy responds to deterioration of the
education system when α + θ < 1 . (W) represents the decision rule of the
worker/innovator given by Eq. (3.14). (B) represents that of the banker given by Eq.
(3.16).

Figure 3.3: Effects of deterioration in education

34
CHAPTER 4

How Does Financial Development Promote Growth?

4.1 Introduction

What makes an economy grow? Much research has been done to identify the

determinants of economic growth. Among suggested factors, researchers found that

generally investment is one of the most important determinants of economic growth.

This is not surprising. As a child needs a constant supply of nourishment to develop

properly, so does an economy to realize sustained development and growth. Only

that for the economy, nourishment would be in the form of investment in factors of

production such as physical and human capitals and technologies. I start from this

basic proposition that investment in factors of production is one of the fundamental

forces that drive economic growth.

Investment in factors of production generally necessitates the use of funds. The

problem is that the amount of funds is often limited compared to the number of

investment opportunities available and therefore should be allocated to more produc-

tive investment opportunities. Then, who is responsible for allocating these funds

among various investment opportunities? Any undergraduate student who took a

money-and-banking class will tell you with certainty that the answer to the question

35
is the financial sector.2 Indeed, that is what conventional textbooks teach us: one

of the basic roles of the financial sector is to allocate funds efficiently. However, the

existence of the financial sector by itself does not guarantee that the allocation will

be efficient. Financial sectors exist in various forms and differ in their level of so-

phistication across countries. Then, in the presence of asymmetric information, those

financial sectors that are relatively more developed will be more able to efficiently

screen out bad investment opportunities. Then, to the extent that investment is an

important determinant of economic growth, it follows that the degree of development

of the financial sector should matter for economic growth. However, albeit much re-

search, there is much controversy among professional economists regarding the role of

the financial sector in promoting economic growth. And, those studies that do show a

positive relationship between GDP per capita growth and a financial development in-

dicator have been criticized for not accounting for a possible endogenous relationship

in their estimations. Furthermore, it was argued that the existing empirical studies

in general do not show how the financial sector does affect growth.

The goal of this paper is to tackle these two main issues. The strategy I take is to

focus on a potential channel of influence from the financial sector to the real sector.

By doing so, I am able to ameliorate the problem of endogeneity as well as to shed

some light on the largely ignored question of how the financial sector affects economic

growth.
2
In this paper, terms such as financial intermediation, financial sector, and banking sector will
be used interchangeably when there is no confusion.

36
4.2 Related Literature

4.2.1 Theories of the finance-led growth hypothesis

The origin of the finance-led growth hypothesis can be traced back to Bagehot

(1873). Early studies by Goldsmith (1969), McKinnon (1973), and Shaw (1973)

constitute a first systematic investigation into the link between the financial sector

and the real sector. Although they found a positive relationship between these two

sectors, the finance-led growth hypothesis did not receive much attention at the time

due to the lack of a formal theoretical foundation to back the empirical findings.

Under the exogenous growth regime, the only way the financial sector could affect the

growth rate of an economy was via technological innovation, which was not modeled

adequately by then-existing growth theories. With the arrival of endogenous growth

theories, the finance-led growth hypothesis received renewed attention. In a world

governed by endogenous growth theories, the growth rate of an economy can be

enhanced not only by an increase in productivity growth but also by either an increase

in the efficiency of capital accumulation or an increase in the savings rate.

Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and Bencievenga and Smith (1991) observe that

the primary role the banking sector plays is the provision of liquidity and argue

that, by providing liquidity, the banking sector enables more investments in illiq-

uid/productive assets and thereby enhances the efficiency of capital accumulation

and economic growth. Roubini and Sala-i-Martin (1995) study an alternative way

the banking sector can enhance the efficiency of capital accumulation where a re-

duction of agency costs due to financial development allows a larger share of savings

to be channeled into investments. However, whether or not financial development

positively affects savings rate is not a clear-cut issue. For example, Devereux and

37
Smith (1994) show that a reduction in idiosyncratic risk and the rate of return risk

may either reduce or increase savings rates depending on the degree of risk aversion

of economic agents. Furthermore, Japelli and Pagano (1994) show that reducing liq-

uidity constraints reduces savings since the younger generation in their model borrow

much more in the absence of liquidity constraints. Saint-Paul (1992) builds a model

where the financial sector allows more specialization in productive and risky tech-

nology by reducing idiosyncratic risks. More to the spirit of ideas-driven economic

growth, but not quite, Galetovic (1996) studies the interaction between the financial

sector and the research sector. In his model, the financial sector plays the indirect

role of economizing the costs of monitoring research firms for investors. Contrary to

these models where the financial sector promotes the process of learning by doing,

King and Levine (1993) consider the financial intermediaries as actively involved in

the production of ideas itself by screening and monitoring innovative projects.

It is rather odd to note that the theory of the finance-led growth was revived

by the birth of endogenous growth theories, and yet the researchers have paid only

scant attention, with an exception of King and Levine (1993), on the effects of finan-

cial development on innovative activities in examining the validity of the finance-led

growth hypothesis. In the context of both exogenous and endogenous growth theo-

ries, the ultimate engine of economic growth is a rise in the productivity level as an

outcome of either learning by doing or intentional effort to come up with a better

technology. Also, Easterly and Levine (2001) show that the ”residual” rather than

factor accumulation accounts for most of the income and growth differences across

countries. Further, the importance of purposive technological innovation in enhanc-

ing productivity is well illustrated by the amount of effort a large number of countries

38
put into establishing a robust R&D sector. Based on these observations and the fact

that investment in R&D requires funds, at least partly, from the financial sector, I

argue that if the finance-led growth hypothesis is correct, then we should be able to

detect evidence of positive effects of financial development on innovation. Therefore,

my aim in this paper is to examine this particular channel of influence. In doing so,

I hope to shed further light on the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis.

4.2.2 Empirical studies

A flood of empirical studies began to appear in the 1990s to test the validity of

the finance-led growth hypothesis. Unfortunately, theoretical models of finance-led

growth do not provide empirical researchers with structural guidelines on which they

can base their estimation. As a result, one is forced to use reduced-form estimation

and test the general conclusion of these models. Since the implication of all the

theoretical models in this area is basically that a better-developed financial sector

enhances economic growth, regardless of the channel of influence, a typical test strat-

egy involves regressing some indicator of financial development on some aggregate

growth measures such as investment growth, GDP growth or total factor productiv-

ity growth. A first attempt in this direction was made by employing cross-sectional

estimation (King and Levine, 1993, and De Gregorio and Guidotti, 1995). Using a

cross-sectional framework, they find a positive relationship between financial develop-

ment and economic growth. However, a potentially endogenous relationship between

financial development and economic growth made interpretation of these results diffi-

cult. Demetriades and Hussein (1996) and Odedokun (1996) take a Granger causality

39
approach to avoid these problems and present mixed results. They find that the ef-

fects of financial development on growth are country-specific. Based on their findings,

they argue that a robust test of the finance-led growth hypothesis should incorporate

the time dimension of the data under consideration. Benhabib and Spiegel (2000)

employ a panel GMM method to reach a similar conclusion.

By and large, the current empirical literature lacks one crucial element in that

they do not consider the channels of influence suggested by theoretical models and

fail to show how financial development affects economic growth. Furthermore, time-

series approach, while potentially resolving endogeneity issue, does not tell us exactly

what the relationship between these two is. In addition, their results are as hard

to interpret as cross-sectional estimation because Granger causality does not really

provide an answer for the causal relationship between financial development and eco-

nomic growth. Researchers who conduct causality tests in this area argue that, for

some countries, economic growth causes financial development, when what they re-

ally need to say is that economic growth Granger-causes financial development. This

does not really address the question of what causes what, especially when one con-

siders that, statistically, Christmas card sales Granger-cause Christmas. In sum, the

current empirical literature suffers from two problems. First, as long as one regresses

GDP growth on a measure of financial development, the issue of endogeneity is not

satisfactorily resolved. Second, the channel of influence has not been specified so far,

thus, limiting our understanding of how the financial sector affects growth.

In order to examine the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis, I depart

from the conventional literature. Instead of estimating a relationship between ag-

gregate growth measures and financial development indicators as is commonly done

40
in the current literature, I test the validity of the finance-led growth hypothesis by

focusing on the innovation channel of influence, using patent applications as a proxy

for innovative output. Under the framework of ideas-driven growth, the hypothesis

I test is that financial development enhances innovation, which is the main engine

of economic growth. If the finance-led growth hypothesis is right, as the financial

sector develops over time in a certain country, the growth rate of innovation should

be higher, which would, then, lead to faster economic growth due to a rising level

of productivity. Using panel data on twenty eight countries from 1970 to 2000, my

analysis shows that financial development is indeed significant in raising the growth

rate of innovative output.

In section 2, I provide a theoretical motivation for the empirical analysis by ex-

tending a standard Romer-type growth model to include agency costs and draw a

testable implication. In section 3, I discuss the estimation strategy employed and the

issues that need to be addressed. In section 4, I conclude.

4.3 Theoretical background

One of the common assumptions made in finance-led growth theories is that the

financial sector (mainly the banking sector) actively monitors borrowers of funds.

Allen and Gale (2001) show that evidence is to the contrary. They show that in most

cases, the banking sector does not serve as an active monitor. The rationale for this is

that often times the banking sector makes a debt contract with the borrowers in which

profits of a lending bank are not dependent upon the borrower’s degree of success.

Rather, they simply depend on whether the borrower succeeds or not.3 Therefore,
3
Of course, this is not the case for equity contracts. However, in most cases, equity markets are
relatively small in terms of intermediating funds and are ignored in this paper.

41
the welfare of the lending bank will depend more on how well it screens out the bad

borrowers and less on its effectiveness as a monitor. Based on this observation, I

extend a standard Romer-type endogenous growth model and include the financial

sector as a provider of funds for researchers with agency costs to illustrate how the

degree of financial development affects the rate of technological innovation. Note that

agency costs in this model represent the costs of screening for the financial sector.

The goal of the model is, thus, to show that high agency costs discourage innovation

and growth of the economy.

4.3.1 Final goods sector

A perfectly competitive final goods sector produces a single homogenous consump-

tion good by combining labor and intermediate goods. The production function for

the final goods sector is given by


ZA
Y = xαj dj, (4.1)
0

where A is the number of intermediate goods used and x is the amount of inter-

mediate good j used and is between 0 and 1. Given this production function, and

normalizing the price of final goods to one, a firm in the final goods sector maximizes
R RA
its profit; xαj dj − 0 pj xj dj, where pj is the price of an intermediate good j. Profit

maximization gives the price of an intermediate good j as

pj = αxα−1
j . (4.2)

4.3.2 Intermediate goods sector

The intermediate goods sector consists of monopolistic firms that buy designs from

the research sector to be used in production of intermediate goods. These firms are

42
monopolistic since the designs they buy are protected by patents that exclude others

from using the same designs. Therefore, each monopolist produces only one type of

intermediate good. With the design in hand, the monopolist produces intermediate

goods using a one-to-one production function. In other words, the monopolist requires

one unit of capital to produce one unit of intermediate good.

Formally, the monopolist maximizes the profit function given by:

pj (xj )xj − rxj , (4.3)

where r is the interest rate for borrowing capital. The firm’s supply of xj derived from

the profit maximization, together with the demand schedule in Eq.(4.2), determines

the price of xj to be equal to r/α, which implies that xj = x and, consequently, that

Y = Axα .

Using Eq.(4.2) and pj = r/α, we get x = α2 Y /Ar. Then, the profit for each

monopolist can be specified as;

π I = (p − r)x
Y
= α(1 − α) . (4.4)
A

Further, since the total amount of the intermediate goods used in the final goods
RA
sector 0 xi di = Ax, should be equal to the total amount of capital spent in the

intermediate goods sector, (1 − aK )K, x is equal to (1 − aK )K/A. Note that (1 − aK )

is the portion of capital stock used in the intermediate goods sector, and K is the

total stock of capital in the economy. Finally, the production function turns out to

be

Y = A1−α [(1 − aK )K]α . (4.5)

43
4.3.3 The research sector

Recall that my primary goal in this section is to provide a theoretical sketch of

how financial development affects innovation. I aim to show here that the share of

capital spent in research sector is increasing in the degree of financial development as

proxied by lower agency costs.

In this model, each researcher faces a similar problem as the monopolist in the

intermediate goods sector. In other words, each researcher borrows capital from the

financial sector to finance her innovation. What is different from the monopolist’s

case is that the researcher’s cost of borrowing capital is not r but r + c where c

is the exogenous agency costs. The researcher pays an additional cost of c because

the financial sector has to screen the researchers when they borrow funds. With

this environment, the researcher tries to maximize her profit based on her production

function. I make a standard assumption that when the researcher innovates, she takes

the actions of other researchers and the knowledge stock as given so that she faces

the arrival rate of δ defined as:

δ = A1−β [aK K]β−1 , (4.6)

where δ stands for the arrival rate of new technology per unit of capital spent on

innovation at the individual researcher’s level.

When a new technology is developed, assuming that the design lasts forever, the

researcher receives a price, pA which is equal to the monopolist’s profit discounted by

r, (1 − α)x/α. Since x = α2 Y /Ar,

α(1 − α)Y
pA = . (4.7)
rA

44
Given the price pA and the arrival rate δ, the marginal product of capital spent in

the research sector equals simply pA δ. Equating this to the marginal cost of capital,
α2 Y
r + c, and noting that r = (1−aK )K
, I get the share of capital used in the research

sector as:
µ ¶ µ ¶β " µ ¶ #
1−α µ ¶1−α
1−α K A 1
(1 − aK ) = a1−β
K α2 +c . (4.8)
α A K 1 − aK

Although the Eq. (4.8) cannot be solved explicitly for aK , it can be seen that

there exists a unique value of aK by noting that the LHS of the equation is decreasing

in aK and that the RHS of the equation is increasing in aK for the entire range of aK .

4.3.4 The growth of the economy

Given the production function (4.5), I need to specify how the economy evolves

over time. First, technological innovation occurs by the following law of motion:

·
At = At1−β [aK Kt ]β , (4.9)

where β is between 0 and 1.

This specification assumes that technological innovation is a function of capital

devoted in the research sector. However, the production of new technologies faces

diminishing returns in K. Furthermore, it assumes that the stock of knowledge in the

economy also contributes to production of new technologies.

Following Solow (1956), I assume that the capital stock evolves by

·
K t = sYt , (4.10)

where s is a constant investment ratio. Also, assume, for simplicity, that there is no

population growth so that n = 0. Substituting (4.5) into (4.10) and divide both sides

45
by Kt , the growth rate of capital is given by:
· µ ¶1−α
K At
= s(1 − aK )α ≡ gK . (4.11)
K Kt

Similarly, the growth rate of technology is given by:


· µ ¶β
A Kt
= aβK ≡ gA . (4.12)
A At

Along the balanced growth path, the usual steady state condition applies so that

gK = gA = g ≡ the growth rate of the economy. Combining Eq. (4.11) and Eq.

(4.12), the steady state growth rate of the economy, dropping time index, is given by:

β
g = [s(1 − aK )α a1−α
K ]
1−α+β , (4.13)

0
and g ≥ 0 if aK ≤ 1 − α.

Note that the steady state growth rate of the economy is increasing in aK as long

as the share of the capital spent in the research sector is less than or equal to 1 — α.

Further, it can be seen from Eq. (4.8) that the equilibrium amount of capital spent

in the research sector is decreasing in the agency cost, c.

It is shown in this model that the steady state growth rate of the economy is

increasing in aK , which is itself a decreasing function of the agency cost. The testable

implication is that a poorly developed financial sector impedes economic growth by

reducing the amount of capital devoted to technological innovation. Also, note that

that the share of income used for investment in capital accumulation, s, was assumed

to be constant in this model. Hence, this model illustrates that for a given a level

of investment, a smaller share of that investment will be devoted to R&D activities

resulting in a lower rate of technological innovation if the financial sector is relatively

less developed.

46
4.4 Empirical analysis

In the previous section, I presented a simple model in which high agency costs

discourage technological innovation, which is a main engine of economic growth. In

this section, I empirically examine whether financial development does have any sig-

nificant effect on the rate of technological innovation as the model suggests.

4.4.1 Patents as a proxy for technological innovation

The first question that needs to be addressed in order to conduct the investiga-

tion is: how do you measure the underlying technological change in a given country?

Variables such as R&D expenditure, the number of scientists and engineers, or the

number of articles published in scientific journals have been proposed as measures

of technological innovations. The problem with these variables is that they are not

widely available except for a few developed countries. This limits the number of

countries a researcher can include in her sample to a selective few. An alternative

and less direct measure of technological innovation that has been popular among re-

searchers is Total Factor Productivity. By assuming a cobb-douglas type aggregate

production function, one can easily estimate this for a number of countries over a

long period of time. However, this residual measure is only distantly related to tech-

nological innovation (Griliches, 1990). In other words, it simply is something that

economists do not have full understanding of how changes in total factor productivity

are brought about. This ambiguous nature of total factor productivity (TFP) as a

measure of technological innovation, maybe harmless in some contexts, can prove to

be not so harmless in other cases. When the relationship under consideration is the

47
one between development of the private financial sector and total factor productiv-

ity, we first need to have a well-defined idea about how the former affects the latter.

The theoretical literature is not clear on this. What the literature suggests is that

financial development encourages more efficient allocation of investments among in-

novation projects. As innovative activities are enhanced due to development in the

financial sector, productivity, and ultimately the economy’s growth rate, rises. What

is clearly defined in the theoretical literature is how financial development affects in-

novative activities. It does not tell us how financial development affects productivity

as measured by total factor productivity.

In this study, I use patent data as a proxy for technological innovation. A patent is

generally defined as a document issued by an authorized governmental agency, grant-

ing the right to exclude anyone else from the production or the use of a specific new

device, apparatus, or process for a stated number of years. Using patent as a proxy for

technological innovation to examine the effects of financial development on innovative

activities has a number of advantages. Firstly, patent data is the most direct measure

of innovative output. Contrary to other proxies of technological innovation mentioned

above, "a patent does represent a minimal quantum of invention that has passed both

the scrutiny of the patent office as to its novelty and the test of the investment of

effort and resources by the inventor and his organization into the development of

this product or idea, indicating thereby the presence of non-negligible expectation

as its ultimate utility and marketability." (Griliches, 90) Also, "patents are a direct

outcome of the inventive process, and more specifically of those inventions, which are

expected to have a commercial impact... a particularly appropriate indicator for cap-

turing the propriety and competitive dimension of technological change." (Archibugi

48
and Pianta, 96) An inventor will apply for a patent right only if the benefits she

expects to receive from it outweigh the costs of obtaining patent protection. By its

nature, patent data alludes us to qualities of innovations that are produced. Stern et

al (2000) argue that patents, by its very nature, reflect an important portion of the

innovative output by a country and are the most concrete and comparable measure

of innovative output across countries and time. Secondly, as mentioned above, patent

data bears the closest resemblance to innovative output as described in the theoretical

literature in this area. Furthermore, the relationship between financial development

and innovative output is well-defined. It is also intuitively appealing to argue that

patent production requires investments that are intermediated by the financial sec-

tor. Thirdly, and related to the second argument above, using patents allows a more

concentrated focus on the effects the private financial sector has on technological

innovation. Research shows that industries heavily involved in government contract

work tend to patent fewer inventions of a given quality than those which pay for

their own research (Comanor and Scherer, 1969). This indicates that, compared to

other measures of technological innovation, patent data reflects to a lesser degree the

influence of government activities that are not associated with financial development.

Having argued that patent data is the best measure of technological innovation

that serves the conceptual purpose of this study, there still remains a doubt if I

may be barking at the wrong tree. An example is so-called Fox paradox. It states

that in a given country, patent production may come from a small industry that

does not affect the country’s economic growth while a large industry that is actually

responsible for the country’s economic growth remains dormant in terms of patent

49
production.4 Therefore, despite its advantages mentioned above, using patent data

will not serve the empirical purpose of this study if it is not related to economic

activities. Research shows that indeed this is not the case. Comanor and Scherer

(1969) argue that a simple count of the number of patents reflects not statistical

noise but a meaningful message in the results of studies using patents by showing

that the correlation between patents and the value of new product sales is significant.

On an aggregate level, using patent data as a measure of technological change, it

is shown that a higher intensity of technological activities has a generally positive

impact on national growth (Archibugi and Pianta, 1996). Porter and Stern (2000)

reach a similar conclusion in their study that there is a positive link between ideas

production and realized productivity growth. Further, micro-based studies indicate

that patents are actively utilized in production processes. They show that the share

of patents actually used by firms range from 40% to 60% (Napolitano and Sirilli,

1990). EPO survey found that the majority of European firms utilized their patents

most of the time. Also, it found that 84% of patenting firms cited patents in the

case of products and 71% in the case of processes as their usual means of protecting

new products and processes (Archibugi and Pianta, 1996). These studies further

strengthens the validity of using patent data as a proxy for technological innovation.

4.4.2 Data

The patent data I use is based on the Technology Assessment and Forecast Report,

compiled by the United States Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) and reported

to the World Intellectual Property Office on an annual basis. The motivation for using

the U.S. patent data is based on the evidence that the U.S. has the lowest granting rate
4
Heterogeneity across countries such as this can be taken care of by using country dummies.

50
in the world (Griliches, 1990). It indicates that the U.S. has the highest standard for

granting patent rights and gives us a hint about qualities of inventions for which patent

protection is asked. Porter and et al (2000) argue that because USPTO approval

requires that patents constitute novel, non-obvious inventions, patenting captures a

sense of the degree to which a national economy is developing and commercializing

new-to-the-world technologies and that by only including inventions that are granted

patent protection in the U.S., we can be confident both that a relatively common

standard has been applied and that the counted inventors are, in fact, near the global

technological frontier. More importantly, using patent data from one source allows

me to avoid the issue of heterogeneity across databases collected by various agencies.

When one tries to combine the databases of several agencies, she needs to deal with

different classification systems each agency has as well as quality differences in patents

granted by different patent agencies. Many attempts have been made to handle these

problems with only limited success. When a conceivable advantage of this kind of

comprehensive data is basically a larger dataset, the benefit hardly outweighs the costs

of having to deal with aforementioned problems. It is especially so if the number of

countries covered in the U.S. dataset is reasonably large.

USPTO has six categories for patent grants; Utility, Design, Plant, Reissue, DEF,

and Statutory invention registration. Among them, what is relevant for this study is

utility patents. According to the USPTO definition, these are patents that are issued

for the invention of a new and useful process; machine, manufacture, or composition

of matter, or a new and useful improvement thereof. Therefore, utility patents have a

direct bearing on industrial production processes. Once granted, they provide twenty

51
years of protection. This data contains both developed and developing countries, and

the country of origin is based on the residence of the first named inventor.

In the model, the degree of financial development is represented by agency costs.

When the financial sector is relatively less developed, it imposes higher agency costs

to innovators for borrowing funds, leading to a lower rate of technological progress.

Empirically, finding a single measure that captures every aspect of financial devel-

opment is nearly impossible due to complexities involved with functions the financial

serves in the economy. Therefore, I use three different indicators proposed in the

literature to capture various aspects of financial development. They are

• The ratio of private credit by deposit money banks to GDP (henceforth, PC)

• The ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP (henceforth, liquidity)

• The ratio of deposit money bank assets to GDP (henceforth, DMBA)5

PC measures the activity in channeling savings to investors and is equal to the

ratio of claims on the domestic private sector by deposit money banks to GDP. The

assumption is that as the financial sector develops, it will be able to channel more

funds from savers to investors. De Gregorio and Guidotti (1995) also suggest that PC

represents more accurately the role of financial intermediaries in channeling funds to

private market participants. Since the main role of the financial sector I emphasize in

this section is to serve as an effective intermediary of funds, PC is the variable that

I will be primarily interested in.

Liquidity is the most commonly used indicator of financial development and usu-

ally referred to as "financial depth". It measures the overall size of the financial sector
5
Data for these variables are from Beck et al (99)

52
without distinguishing between the financial sectors or between the uses of liabilities

(Beck et al, 99). It is equal to the ratio of currency plus demand and interest bearing

liabilities of banks and other financial intermediaries to GDP. However, the use of

liquidity as a financial development indicator has come under attack recently. De

Gregorio and Guidotti (1995) argue that it is conceivable that a high level of mon-

etization (implied by a high level of liquidity) is a result of the lack of alternative

assets that would serve as stores of value. Eastern Europe and the former Soviet

Union provide evidence for this scenario. To overcome this problem, one can use a

broader measure of monetary aggregates such as M3. However, to the extent that M1

is included in M3, it does not resolve the problem. Moreover, the fact that M3/GDP

is also the inverse of the velocity of circulation of the broad money stock suggests that

a positive association between the level of financial development, proxied by liquidity,

and real GDP is tantamount to a downward trend in the velocity of circulation and

may simply reflect an income elasticity of the demand for money with respect to GDP

which is greater than unity (Demetriades and Hussein, 96). So, I use liquidity for the

sake of completeness and with reservations.

Finally, I also use DMBA as another measure of financial development. DMBA is

a so-called absolute size measure and reflects the importance of the financial services

performed by the banking sector6 .


6
All the measures used here are the ratios of a stock variable to a flow variable, which creates
problems with correct timing and in terms of deflating correctly. Beck et al (99) address these
problems and calculate each measure by
³ ´
1 F Dt F Dt−1
2 CP Ie,t + CP Ie,t−1
GDPt
,
CP Ia,t

where e: end of period, a: average for the period. The end year of year CPI is either the value for
December or, if not available, the value for the last quarter. For additional information, see their
paper.

53
4.4.3 Methodology

There are well-known concerns with respect to using patent data for economic

analysis. First, there is an issue of heterogeneous quality of patents. Naturally,

patents differ greatly in their technical and economic significance over time. Scherer

(1966) suggests that the way to get around this issue is to invoke the law of large

numbers. The idea is that by the law of large numbers, the economic significance of

any sampled patent can be interpreted as a random variable with some probability

distribution. Furthermore, the problem of differing qualities does not apply only

to patent data. Other measures of technological innovation such as a simple count

of scientists and engineers, or R&D expenditures are also prone to this problem.

(Comanor and Scherer, 1969). Given this fact, using patent data as a proxy for

technological innovation may have more merits than other measures for it allows one

to examine a wide range of countries.

Secondly, each country has a different propensity to patent arising from differences

among countries in terms of their industrial composition. Thirdly, and related to the

above, using USPTO patent data may exclude those innovations that are novel to a

country but have been already discovered elsewhere, or those innovations that are not

worthwhile patenting internationally. In order to take care of these two problems, I

follow Eaton and Kortum (1996) and Porter and Stern (2000) and make an assumption

similar to the one above. It states that the value of value of innovations is distributed

according to a fixed distribution across economies and a constant fraction of innovative

output turns out to be valuable enough to justify an international patent. To the

extent that this fractional value varies across countries, it is overcome through the

54
use of fixed country specific effects in the regression. The preceding discussion tells

me that panel estimation is a proper way to conduct the empirical analysis.

Patrick (1966) argues that as the process of real growth occurs, the supply-leading

impetus generally becomes less important and the demand-following financial re-

sponse becomes dominant. Similarly, Fritz (1984), Jung (1986), and Dee (1986) sug-

gest in their studies that developing countries have rather a supply-leading causality

pattern of development than a demand-following pattern. What these studies say is

that the developing countries should provide a fertile testing ground for finance-led

growth hypothesis. If the hypothesis is not valid, a measure of financial development

would not enter significantly in estimation. Furthermore, there is no reason to believe

that choosing developing countries as a sample would present an upward bias in my

estimation. In sum, if finance-led growth hypothesis is valid, the effects of financial

development will be strong and significant for developing countries, and if it is in-

valid, they will be insignificant regardless of the countries chosen. Therefore, I select

28 developing countries from USPTO database to be included in the sample.7

Table (4.1) shows a list of countries that are included in the sample. Figure (4.1)

shows the relationship between averages of real GDP growth rates and patent growth

rates over 1970 - 2000. It shows that the latter is closely related to the former, in line

with the previous discussion on the effects of patents produced on economic growth.

In order to construct a panel data, I compute average growth rates of patent

applications per million persons for six periods: 1970-74, 75-79, 80-84, 85-89, 90-94,

95-2000 as a proxy for the rate of technological innovation. To measure the degree of

financial development, I use the initial levels of financial development indicators for
7
A criterion for selecting developing countries is from IMF.

55
each corresponding period to ameliorate endogeneity.8 There are a couple of hand-

waiving arguments against this as a solution for endogeneity. Firstly, if economic

agents were forward-looking, the use of the initial levels of financial development

indicators would not eliminate endogeneity (Rajan and Zingales, 1998). The idea is

that, if the economy were expected to grow in the future, forward-looking economic

agents would step up lending now hoping to take advantage of a economic boom in

the future. Then, the level of financial intermediation today is going to be affected by

future states of the economy. Hence, endogeneity still exists even if one uses the initial

values of financial development indicators. This argument needs two assumptions

satisfied to be valid. One is that, empirically, the dependent variable used in the

regression is such that economic agents could observe its behavior, for example, its

growth rate, easily enough so that the economy-wide change in lending activity could

occur in response to the changes in its behavior. The other is that this change in

lending activity is sufficiently big so that it affects the total volume of credit in a

non-negligible manner. Aggregate growth measures typically used in this literature

such as GDP per capita growth satisfy these assumptions. Thus, the argument by

Rajan and Zingales (1998) is true if what the analysis focuses on is the relationship

between the financial sector development and aggregate growth measures.

However, the focus in this paper is on the relationship between the rate of tech-

nological change and the degree of financial development, and their argument does

not apply well for two reasons. As for the first assumption mentioned above, the

inherent nature of uncertainty associated with R&D activity makes it difficult for
8
For a discussion of simultaneity, see Tsuru (2000)

56
economic agents to observe the changes in the rate of technological innovation. In ad-

dition, there is no theoretical background to support that future economic conditions

cause changes in the current rate of technological innovation. As a matter of fact,

the consensus is that it is technological innovation that determines future economic

conditions. Further, even if the first assumption is met, the resulting lending activity

is not sufficiently big enough to affect the total volume of credit in a non-negligible

manner since research is only a small part of what bank lending finances. Secondly,

if financial development indicators are correlated across time, then using the initial

values of financial development indicators would not remove endogeneity since they

would simply be proxies for their contemporaneous levels (Demetriades and Hussein,

1996). Figure (4.2) shows movements of financial development indicators for sample

countries across time. Significant variations in these indicators suggest that the use

of initial values of financial development indicators is justified.

In summary, the regression equation that I estimate is the following:

(Patent growth rate)it = αi + β(Financial development indicator)it +

γ(control variables)it + εit (4.14)

where i = 1...28, t = 1...6.

If β comes out positive and significant, it will provide support for the finance-led

growth hypothesis in a sense that the degree of financial development is positively

associated with the rate of technological innovation, the driving engine of economic

growth.

Control variables

57
R&D literature indicates that R&D effort is a significant determinant of techno-

logical innovation. The most commonly used measure of R&D effort for the developed

countries is the number of researchers in the research sector. However, the data is not

available for a long time span for developing countries. Therefore, I instead use the

human capital measure compiled by Barro and Lee (2000). Among various measures

they compiled, I use the percentage of the population 25 years of age or older who have

attained "higher" education (HIATT25) as a proxy for the number of researchers in

the research sector assuming that the number of researchers in the research sector is

positively correlated with the extent of college education in the population. Although

this is a somewhat indirect measure of R&D effort, I believe it to be reasonable to

think that much of the innovation stems from college-educated innovators. For my

analysis, I use the initial levels of HIATT25 for each corresponding period. This vari-

able, according to the literature, is expected to have a positive effect on the patent

growth rate. Therefore, the estimated coefficient should be positive.

Intuitively, people alone cannot generally come up with technological breakthroughs

if they lack infrastructure supporting their R&D activities. This infrastructure is

generally funded by institutions such as government, private businesses and academic

institutions. The volume of funds that supports R&D activities from these institu-

tions is conventionally measured by R&D expenditure data. This data is generally

widely available for developed countries but not for developing countries. Perforce, I

use the real domestic private investment data to proxy for investment in R&D in my

analysis. Then, I compute the average levels of domestic private investment in the five

years immediately preceding each period in the sample (INVEST). The literature is

not clear on what the sign of the estimated coefficient should be. Depending on the

58
nature of returns to scale, the estimated coefficient can be either positive or negative.

So, I will let the data speak for itself.

Knowledge production may also depend on the past knowledge stock. All the

models of endogenous growth incorporate this intertemporal spillover effect in one

way or another. I use the initial level of real GDP per capita for each corresponding

period (Knowledge stock) to capture this potential effect. This variable also cap-

tures the ability of a country to translate its knowledge stock into a realized state of

economic development and so yields an aggregate control for a country’s technological

sophistication (Porter and Stern, 2000). Also, compared to other measures of the past

knowledge stock such as the past patent stock, real GDP per capita provides a more

comprehensive measure of the knowledge stock in the economy as the past patent

stock may be industry-specific and does not convey information on the economy-wide

knowledge stock. According to endogenous growth theories, the sign of the estimated

coefficient should be positive. According to neoclassical growth theories, it should be

negative. So, it would be interesting to see what the data says.

In addition to intertemporal spillover effects, there can also be a cross-country

spillover effect. This will be especially true if a country is an active importer of so-

phisticated technologies as Japan had been in the 50’s and 60’s. Hence, an important

way a country can learn from a technologically more developed country and hasten

its own knowledge production is by importing technology embedded in goods9 . Based

on this observation, I use Openness measured by the average levels of the sum of

exports and imports divided by GDP in the five years immediately preceding each

period in the sample to capture the potential cross-country spillover of knowledge.


9
Foreign direct investment might also be a major channel of technology transfer has it not been
that a majority of FDI is among developed countries.

59
Again, the sign of the estimated coefficient is uncertain due to the fact that what I

am considering here is patent applications filed in the U.S., the foreign country. If a

catch-up effect is dominant, Openness should have a positive effect on the country’s

knowledge production. On the other hand, if a raising-the-bar effect is dominant, it

should have a negative effect.

Wurgler (2000) suggests that the effectiveness of the financial sector also depends

on the magnitude of government intervention. He argues that with a bigger govern-

ment, there is an increased incentive to overinvest in declining industries rather than

improving the supply of finance to growing industries. The effects of government

intervention is proxied by the average levels of the share of total government con-

sumption in GDP for each corresponding period in the sample (Government size).

I expect it to have a negative coefficient.

There is increasing evidence in the literature that legal structure such as intellec-

tual property protection plays a non-negligible role in knowledge production processes

(La Porta et al, 1996). This may be especially true for patent production. I use the

initial values of a legal index compiled by Gwartney et al (2002) to reflect the degree

of IP protection within each country (Legal). This is a composite index of judicial

prudence, impartial courts, protection of intellectual property, military interference

in rule of law and the political process and integrity of the legal system. It provides

a more comprehensive coverage of the legal system than typical indexes used in the

literature, which represents only a particular aspect of the legal framework of a given

country. The literature predicts that it should have positive effects on knowledge

production.

60
Finally, I include the average levels of inflation using the GDP deflator (PI) for

each corresponding sample period to reflect the economic conditions of a country

at the time when a patent application is filed. Generally, an inventor will be less

likely to utilize her invention during times of economic turmoil. Hence, I expect

the estimated coefficient to carry a negative sign to the extent that inflation signals

economic turmoil.10

4.4.4 Estimation

Table (4.2) shows the results of estimation. PC and DMBA come out positive

and significant, suggesting that financial development does have a positive effect on

the rate of technological change. On the contrary, liquidity comes out insignifi-

cant. It may be due to the possibility that liquidity is a poor measure of financial

development as discussed in the previous section.

Human capital (HIATT25) is generally positive and significant as expected.

Note that it has a bigger effect on knowledge production than financial development.

Openness comes out with a negative sign and is insignificant, which suggests that

the raising-the-bar effect is dominant. This is in line with Porter and Stern (2000)’s

finding that a cross-country spillover is weakly negative. Investment is negative and

insignificant. This suggests that, although a higher investment may produce more

technological innovations, it does not necessarily yield a faster rate of technological

change. A possible interpretation, then, would be that there is decreasing returns to

investment in terms of the rate of knowledge production. Knowledge stock is also

negative and insignificant suggesting convergence in terms of knowledge production


10
Data for the variables are obtained from World Development Indicators, CD-ROM, 2000 unless
noted otherwise.

61
among these countries. Government size is generally negative as expected. Infla-

tion (PI) comes out significant and weakly positive, which is in line with the R&D

literature.

Table (4.3) shows the results of estimation when legal structure (Legal) is in-

cluded in the regression. Note that due to data availability, I lose eleven observations

here. Overall, the results are similar to what I have seen in the preceding regression.

Financial development indicators generally come out positive and significant to con-

firm the conclusion we reached above. What is interesting is that Legal comes out

negative and significant. One plausible interpretation would be that a weak legal sys-

tem of a home country induces firms/inventors to seek patent protection from abroad

(the U.S.). In other words, if a home country provides adequate legal protection

for innovations, firms/inventors will be less motivated to apply for patent protection

elsewhere. If this were true, then the frequency with which a foreign firm/individual

applies for a patent protection in the U.S. may be negatively correlated with strength

of the legal system in the home country. Hence, the negative sign I get here may

simply be an artifact of using USPTO data instead of home country patent data.

Table (4.4) shows the results of estimation using only those variables that turned out

to be significant in the previous regressions. The fit is better although the overall

results are similar to the previous regressions.

Overall, my analysis provides support for the finance-led growth hypothesis11 .

More to the point, it provides an answer as to how the financial sector promotes
11
I also ran the regression with distance dummies as the sample contains a large number of Latin
American countries, which could introduce a geographic bias into the analysis. Including distance
dummies did not change the results. Moreover, these dummies were insignificant. These results are
available upon request.

62
economic growth. The answer I get from this analysis is that financial development

enhances economic growth through, at least partially, promoting innovative activities.

4.5 Summary

This paper investigates the relationship between the financial sector and economic

growth by focusing on a specific channel of influence, innovation. The basic idea of

this paper starts from the proposition that investment is an important determinant

of economic growth. Then, the degree of development of the financial sector that

provides fuel to it should also matter for economic growth. This is the essence of the

finance-led growth hypothesis.

In order to examine this issue more carefully, I conduct an empirical investigation

of how the financial sector development could affect economic growth focusing on

the channel of influence the theoretical literature put forward. More specifically, I

ask if the financial development is positively associated with the rate of technological

innovation. If development of the financial sector does have growth-promoting effects

as the finance-led growth literature contends, the answer should be yes.

With this idea in mind, I first provide a simple theoretical model where the rate of

economic growth is partly governed by the share of capital used in R&D sector, which

in turn depends on the degree of financial development proxied by agency costs. The

model indicates that the more developed the financial sector is, the faster the rate of

technological innovation will be. Using patent growth rates as a proxy for the rate of

technological innovation, I find that financial development positively affects the rate

of technological innovation rendering support for the finance-led growth hypothesis.

63
My approach has two advantages over the current studies. Firstly, the channel of

influence from the financial sector to the real sector is explicitly specified, which has

been missing in the current literature. Further, by identifying the channel of influence

from the financial sector to the real sector, this paper is able to produce an interesting

policy implication. That is, when a country liberalizes its financial sector making it

more market-oriented12 , the potential benefit could be in the form of a higher rate of

technological change. However, this benefit may not be fully realized if the country

is not equipped with a viable R&D sector, which is the case for most developing

countries. Secondly, my approach resolves the issue of endogeneity, at least better

than the existing literature, so that interpretation of the results is clearer.

In summary, this paper sheds further light as to how development in the financial

sector affects growth. My analysis indicates that financial development affects eco-

nomic growth by promoting technological change, a fundamental driving engine of

economic growth, rendering further support for the finance-led growth hypothesis.
12
Whether a country should allow free movements of financial capital across borders is a whole
new different question. Capital account liberalization usually entails financial market liberalization.
However, financial market liberalization does not necessarily imply capital account liberalization.

64
Real GDP per
capita growth 2.5
2.0 Singapor Korea

1.5 Thailand

1.0

0.5

0.0
-2.0 Haiti 0.0 2.0 4.0 6.0
-0.5
growth rate of patent per million

Figure 4.1: Long Run GDP Growth vs. Long Run Patent Growth

  65
0.3 0.35
Brazil 0.3 Mexico
0.25 Liquidit
0.25
0.2
dmba 0.2
0.15
0.15
0.1 Private credit
0.1
0.05 0.05
0 0
1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906

0.6 1.2
Philippines Malaysia
0.5 1

0.4 0.8

0.3 0.6
0.2 0.4
0.1 0.2
0 0
1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906

Figure 4.2: Movements of Financial Development Indicators for Selected Countries.

  66
Argentina Indonesia Peru
Brazil India Philippines
Chile Iran Singapore
Colombia Iceland Thailand
Costa Rica Israel Trinidad & Tobago
Dominican Republic Jamaica Uruguay
Ecuador Korea Venezuela
Egypt Mexico South Africa
Guatemala Malaysia
Haiti Pakistan

Table 4.1: Sample Countries Used For Patent Regression

  67
(1) (2) (3)
PC 1.610(3.062)
DMBA 1.070(2.470)
Liquidity 0.706(1.826)
Human Capital 2.112(1.719) 1.726(1.395) 2.023(1.791)
Openness -0.287(-0.700) -0.272(-0.625) -0.316(-0.895)
Inflation 0.023(2.178) 0.018(1.734) 0.024(1.936)
Investment -5.416(-1.398) -4.980(-1.335) -3.830(-1.054)
Knowledge Stock -0.247(-0.842) -0.045(-0.261) -0.009(-0.060)
Government Size -1.246(-1.096) -0.918(-0.817) 0.136(0.140)
N 156 156 156
2
R 0.459 0.443 0.444
DW 2.251 2.223 2.249
F-Statistic 27.578 26.205 26.289
Note) The numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics. The dependent variable is the
average growth rate of patent applications per million. PC is the initial values of the ratio
of private credit by deposit money banks to GDP for each corresponding sample period.
Liquidity is the initial values of the ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP for each
corresponding sample period. DMBA is the initial values of the ratio of deposit money
bank assets to GDP for each corresponding period. Human capital (HIATT 25) is
measured by the initial values of percentage of the population 25 years of age or older
who have attained higher education for each corresponding sample period. Openness is
measured by the average levels of the sum of exports and imports divided by GDP in five
years immediately preceding each period in the sample. Inflation (PI) is the average
levels for each corresponding sample period. Investment (INVEST) is the average levels
of domestic private investment in the five years immediately preceding each period in the
sample. Knowledge stock is the initial levels of real GDP per capita for each
corresponding period. Government size is the average levels of the share of total
government consumption in GDP for each corresponding sample period.

Table 4.2: Fixed Effects Estimation I

  68
(1) (2) (3)
PC 0.909(1.765)
DMBA 0.499(1.241)
Liquidity 0.291(0.755)
Human Capital 2.154(1.932) 2.010(1.816) 2.208(2.016)
Openness -0.244(-0.583) -0.184(-0.411) -0.237(-0.606)
Inflation 0.026(2.318) 0.023(2.220) 0.024(2.374)
Investment -5.917(-1.470) -5.380(-1.367) -4.505(-1.148)
Knowledge Stock 0.045(0.248) 0.116(0.658) 0.128(0.741)
Government Size -0.851(-0.751) -0.534(-0.490) 0.044(0.045)
Legal -0.048(-1.750) -0.051(-1.877) -0.035(-1.408)
N 145 145 145
2
R 0.492 0.491 0.509
DW 2.282 2.265 2.274
F-Statistic 24.901 24.855 26.369
Note) The numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics. The dependent variable is the
average growth rate of patent applications per million. PC is the initial values of the ratio
of private credit by deposit money banks to GDP for each corresponding sample period.
Liquidity is the initial values of the ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP for each
corresponding sample period. DMBA is the initial values of the ratio of deposit money
bank assets to GDP for each corresponding period. Human capital (HIATT 25) is
measured by the initial values of percentage of the population 25 years of age or older
who have attained higher education for each corresponding sample period. Openness is
measured by the average levels of the sum of exports and imports divided by GDP in five
years immediately preceding each period in the sample. Inflation (PI) is the average
levels for each corresponding sample period. Investment (INVEST) is the average levels
of domestic private investment in the five years immediately preceding each period in the
sample. Knowledge stock is the initial levels of real GDP per capita for each
corresponding period. Government size is the average levels of the share of total
government consumption in GDP for each corresponding sample period. Legal is the
initial values of an legal index compiled by Gwartney et al (2002).

Table 4.3: Fixed Effects Estimation II

  69
(1) (2) (3)
PC 0.892(2.400)
DMBA 0.696(2.206)
Liquidity 0.879(2.256)
Human Capital 2.285(2.463) 2.424(2.456) 2.097(2.262)
Inflation 0.015(2.150) 0.012(1.883) 0.019(2.420)
Legal -0.034(-1.164) -0.037(-1.295) -0.021(-0.838)
N 145 145 145
2
R 0.529 0.533 0.523
DW 2.273 2.246 2.270
F-Statistic 65.824 66.734 64.424
Note) The numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics. The dependent variable is the
average growth rate of patent applications per million. PC is the initial values of the ratio
of private credit by deposit money banks to GDP for each corresponding sample period.
Liquidity is the initial values of the ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP for each
corresponding sample period. DMBA is the initial values of the ratio of deposit money
bank assets to GDP for each corresponding period. Human capital (HIATT 25) is
measured by the initial values of percentage of the population 25 years of age or older
who have attained higher education for each corresponding sample period. Inflation (PI)
is the average levels for each corresponding sample period. Legal is the initial values of
an legal index compiled by Gwartney et al (2002).

Table 4.4: Fixed Effects Estimation with Selected Independent Variables

  70
CHAPTER 5

Investment Efficiency and Financial Development

"The proximate causes of economic growth are the efforts to economize,


the accumulation of knowledge, and the accumulation of capital." — Lewis
(1955)

5.1 Introduction

According to the finance-led growth hypothesis, financial development affects in-

vestment in two ways. Firstly, a better developed financial sector may raise the

investment rate by pooling and risk sharing. Specifically, it makes available more

saving opportunities to savers so that there is a larger pool of available funds that

can be used for investment. Although it seems intuitive, the theoretical basis for this

view is ambiguous (Devereux and Smith, 1994; Japelli and Pagano, 1994). Alter-

natively, instead of raising the savings rate, financial development may increase the

investment rate by allowing more efficient transformation of already existing funds

(savings) into investment (Roubini and Sala-i-Martin, 1995). This is the so-called

volume channel. Secondly, the efficiency channel hypothesis states that financial de-

velopment may increase the efficiency of investment by directing the funds to the most

productive uses. As it is the role of the financial sector to distribute funds among

71
various investment opportunities, a better developed financial sector can identify pro-

ductive investment opportunities more efficiently, enabling more efficient allocation

of capital (Greenwood and Jovanovich, 1990; Bencievenga and Smith, 1991).13 So, it

is not necessarily that people invest more with a well-developed financial sector but

that they invest more wisely. This is the focus of this chapter. I examine if there is

any evidence of financial development positively affecting the efficiency of aggregate

investment using developing countries as a sample.

The hypothesis that financial development positively affects the investment rate

has first been examined by King and Levine (1993). In response to the criticism that

this study suffers from simultaneity bias, Levine (1998) uses legal environment as

an instrumental variable to support his previous conclusion.14 Interestingly, a more

recent study by Beck et al (2000), using the dynamic GMM technique to control for

simultaneity and unobserved country-specific effects, concludes that the long-run link

between financial development and physical capital growth is tenuous. Thus far, the

overall impression from the literature is that the nature of the relationship between

financial development and the volume of investment is, at best, controversial.

Compared to the volume channel, the efficiency channel has received relatively

little attention until recently. Wurgler (2000) looks at the effect of stock market

development on the pattern of capital allocation across industries, and finds that

financially less developed countries tend to overinvest in declining industries and


13
For more recent survey, see Tsuru (2000).
14
Benhabib and Spiegel (2000) reach a similar conclusion using panel data although the effects
of financial development is sensitive to the inclusion of country fixed effects which suggest that the
financial development indicators widely used in the literature are proxying for the broader country
characteristics.

72
underinvest in growing ones. Fisman and Love (2003) find that countries have more

highly correlated growth rates across sectors when both countries have well-developed

financial markets.

Although these studies address the interesting question of whether a better-developed

financial market allows firms to take advantage of growth opportunities more easily, it

does not directly relate to the issue of investment efficiency. As the goal of investment

is the accumulation of a factor of production, a more suitable criterion for investment

efficiency is whether a given unit of investment results in a higher output level. Ac-

cordingly, a more pertinent question is whether financial development allows a bigger

bang for the buck in terms of the change in output. In other words, a more efficient fi-

nancial sector enhances productivity of capital measured by the change in the output.

Secondly, the stock markets these studies consider are not a major source of funds

for firms in most countries. By focusing on the stock markets only, an important role

the banking sector plays in these countries is largely ignored.

In this chapter, I address the issue of the efficiency channel using two alternative

measures of aggregate investment efficiency. I find that, for developing countries,

financial development significantly and positively affects productivity of investment.

Further, I depart from the existing studies by focusing on the banking sector to

measure the degree of financial development. The rest of this chapter is organized

as follows. In section 2, I examine whether investment is an important determinant

of output growth when adjusted for its allocative quality. In section 3, based on the

results from section 2, I construct two measures of investment efficiency and analyze

their relationship with financial development. In section 4, I conclude.

73
5.2 Investment, output growth, and financial development

Developing countries around the world make significant investments annually into

what economists regard as important for economic growth in the hope of achieving

a better standard of living. According to the World Bank data, developing countries

spent roughly 0.6% and 4.6% of GNP, on average, for research and development

and education respectively. On the other hand, they devoted approximately 22%

of their GDP for gross domestic fixed investment on average.15 While this number

may exaggerate a bit the degree of emphasis these countries place on physical capital

accumulation, I believe that it clearly shows that developing countries have chosen

mainly the strategy of investment-driven economic growth.

Not coincidentally, this strategy is perfectly in line with what international orga-

nizations such as the World Trade Organization (WTO) and the Asian Development

Bank emphasize as a vital component of sustained economic growth. For example,

Mike Moore, WTO’s director-general in 1999, stressed, in his speech to a group of

trade ministers of least-developed countries, the importance of investment to develop-

ment. Similarly, in its 2000 report of the Country Economic Review — Cambodia, the

Asian Development Bank suggested that “boosting investment rates, currently low

and overly dependent on foreign savings, is critical to achieving the government’s goal

of sustained economic growth.” Figure (5.1) shows the relationship between invest-

ment and output growth for Cambodia in recent years. Although its investment rate

as a share of GDP is lower than most countries, it consistently remains at between

4 and 6 percent of GDP. However, the real GDP per capita growth rate fluctuates
15
For countries whose data are available.

74
significantly between 14 percent and -2 percent. Looking at this picture does not

convey a message consistent with the statement of the Asian Development Bank.

It seems that something other than investment is driving output growth, or lack

thereof, in this country. Unfortunately, the same story applies to most of the devel-

oping countries. The strategy of investment-driven economic growth does not seem

to have worked successfully for them. In sum, investment did not lead to the higher

standard of living for a majority of developing countries (Easterly, 2002). This lack of

evidence that investment is an important element in economic growth strengthened

the position of neoclassical growth theorists who have been arguing, since Solow’s

work, that the focus was misplaced. They argue that, rather than focusing on in-

vestment, less-developed countries should devote more resources to devise a way to

promote knowledge creation, which is deemed to be the only reliable source of long-run

growth. Until endogenous growth theorists arrived on the scene, those who believed

that investment matters for economic growth, particularly development economists,

didn’t have a good answer with which to throw back at them. Now, they were given

new tools, more rigorous and detailed than the Harrod-Domar type models to justify

their claims that investment does have a role in economic growth.

If one hoped to have a more definitive answer to the growth question by leaving the

theoretical battlefield and looking at what the empirical evidence shows, she would be

disappointed. Both camps, innovation-based growth and investment-based growth,

gathered up enough empirical studies to justify and support their positions. De

Long (1992) and Sala-I-Martin (1997) provide support for investment-driven growth.

On the innovation-driven growth side, King and Levine (1994) and Easterly et al

(2001) argue that physical capital accumulation is not the answer to the long-run

75
growth question. Recently, Madsen (2002) tests for causality between investment and

economic growth and finds that growth is largely driven by investment in machinery

and equipment.

Amidst this clamor, a new consensus is emerging that some of the economically

successful countries, of which the economies seem to be significantly driven by tech-

nological innovation nowadays, started out their paths onto prosperity initially by

accumulating physical capital. For instance, Korea was able to grow much faster

than a majority of other developing countries despite the apparent lack of sufficient

technological sophistication (Gylfason, 2004). Hayami and Ogasawara (1999) find

that the main force behind growth for Japan remains to be physical capital accu-

mulation. Similar evidence is presented by Toh et al (2002) for Singapore’s growth

experience. Acemoglu et al (2000) provide a theoretical support for this view and

argue that the reason these countries pursued investment-based growth is because of

relative technological inferiority which made innovation-driven growth more costly.

Then the question that begs our attention is: why the accumulation of physical

capital seems to work in some countries while it is failing in a large number of other

developing countries? As Easterly (2002) suggests, the fact that investment does not

seem to have its intended effect on output growth in developing countries may have

to do with how capital is allocated. In other words, it is not necessarily the volume of

investment but the efficiency with which investment is made that counts. This view

is supported by Blomstrom (1996) who, while finding no evidence that the volume

of fixed investment is the key to economic growth, takes a position that whether

investment is efficient seems to be one of the chief foundations for economic growth.

76
As it turns out, this is one common ground between growth theorists and development

economists. After all, technological advance, THE answer to prosperity, can be viewed

as one form of increased efficiency. So, now the question can be rephrased. We should

ask not how to increase output growth but how to increase efficiency. It is in this

context that the financial sector can play a significant role as a distributor of funds

to investment opportunities.

In this section, I investigate if investment is a significant determinant of output

growth in the presence of the financial sector by introducing an interaction term of

the financial development indicator and investment. A similar approach was adopted

by Burnside and Dollar (2000) to show that aid can be effective in the presence of

good policy framework.

5.2.1 Data

There is evidence showing that, in identifying the determinants of output growth,

the results can be sensitive to what is used to measure the output level (Temple,

1999). Accordingly, the researcher should choose the output measure with the goal

of the analysis at hand in mind. For developing countries, it is reasonable to assume

that a majority of investment would be channeled into industrial sectors that take

up a relatively small fraction of an economy’s GDP. Figure (5.2) shows the share of

industry value added in GDP for developing countries considered in this analysis. It

varies greatly across countries ranging from 13% to about 62% of GDP with a mean of

27%. Consequently, it would underestimate, in the context of the current discussion,

the effects of investment if one measured the output only by GDP. For these reasons,

I use real GDP per capita and real industry value added (henceforth IVA) for ISIC

77
divisions 10 — 45 to measure the output. GDP data are obtained from Penn World

Table 6.1, and IVA data are from World Development Indicator, 2000.16 I divide it by

the population to get IVA per capita. I use the share of gross fixed capital formation

from IMF’s IFS in CD-Rom in GDP to measure the investment rate.17

The optimal measure of financial development would be a variable that reflects the

changes in the cost of financial intermediation that occur as a result of the financial

sector becoming more efficient. The measure that is a close enough proxy for the cost

of providing financial intermediation is arguably the real interest rate (Furstenberg

and Fratianni, 1996). However, in practice, the use of the real interest rate data

is not feasible because of the lack of available data for developing countries. Also,

it carries some undesirable characteristics that are hard to reconcile (Benhabib and

Spiegel, 2000). Therefore, I use the so-called quantity indicators that are widely used

in this literature. Although these size indicators are not perfect measures of financial

development, I argue that they reasonably accurately capture the degree of financial

development for developing countries.18 A caveat is that it is necessary to make

the assumption that the size of the financial sector is negatively correlated with the

costs of providing financial services. For developing countries, I think that this is a

reasonable assumption.

For the current study, I choose two measures of financial development. One is the

ratio of deposit money bank assets to GDP (henceforth DMBA), and the other is the
16
Refer to appendix for more detailed description of all the data used in this chapter.
17
I use the population instead of the number of workers, although the latter would be more
appropriate, due to the lack of available data.
18
Size indicators may not be a good proxy for financial development in developed countries as the
financial sectors in these countries seem to have reached a mature stage in terms of their size as
early as in the 1960s.

78
ratio of private credit by deposit money banks to GDP (henceforth PC). DMBA is

classified as an absolute size measure that reflects the relative importance of deposit

money banks in providing financial services in the economy. PC measures somewhat

different aspect of financial development that relates to the activity of the financial

institutions. These two variables will be used throughout this chapter to measure the

degree of financial development. Although I use two different measures of financial

development, I should note that the preferred measure is DMBA in this chapter.

Gregorio and Guidotti (1995) argue that what type of financial development indicator

is to be used in this type of analysis should be governed by the focus of the research at

hand. Since our focus is on the efficiency aspect of financial intermediation, I believe

that the size of the deposit money bank assets, which reflects the efficiency of banking

management, captures the efficiency aspect of financial intermediation better than the

volume of lending the banking sector is engaged in, which is what PC represents.

5.2.2 Estimation strategy

The list of countries that are considered in this analysis is provided in the ap-

pendix. The choice of countries to be included was based strictly on the availability

of the necessary data. I start out with 53 developing countries from 1970 to 1998.19

Output is measured by real GDP per capita and real industry value added per capita

as explained above. Note that when IVA is used to measure the output, I lose five

countries in my sample. I use five-year averages to compute output growth, which

gives me six observations across time for each country: 1970 — 1974, 1975 — 1979,

1980 — 1984, 1985 — 1989, 1990 — 1994, and 1995 — 1998. Note that the last period is

made up of four years due to data availability.


19
Note that for some countries, the data cover shorter ranges. See the appendix for details.

79
To capture the allocative quality of investment, I interact the investment rate with

the financial development indicators. Hence, the equation I estimate is the following:

git = αi + β 1 Iit + β 2 F Dit + β 3 (I × F D)it + γ(controls)it + εit (5.1)

g is the growth rate of output per capita in real terms. α is a country dummy that

capture the country-specific effects. Investment rate (I) is the log of the initial value

of the share of gross fixed capital formation in GDP for each period. Similarly, to

avoid simultaneity, the log of the initial value of the financial development indicator

(F D) for each period is used to represent the degree of financial development at the

beginning of each period. The equation is estimated by the FGLS.

I start with a base regression that includes only the investment rate and human

capital. To measure the level of human capital, I use the literacy rate. The widely used

measure of human capital is the Barro and Lee data (2000) that lists the percentage

of population, 15 and over, that received a certain degree of education. Although it

is popular among growth researchers, I believe that literacy rate is a better measure

of the level of human capital for developing countries. For example, in a country

like Kenya, between 1980 and 1985, the percentage of secondary school enrollment

in the population, 15 and over, fell from 14.5% to 9.5% while the illiteracy rate fell

from 43.7% to 36.1%. This example illustrates that the level of human capital can be

better reflected by the outcome of the education (which literacy rate captures) than

by the number of people who receive education (which Barro and Lee data captures).

So, although the two variables are generally positively correlated across the sample

countries, I use the literacy rate to measure the degree of human capital. The values

used in the analysis are the initial values for each period. Column (1) of table (5.1)

80
shows the results. The investment rate is negative and insignificant in line with the

literature. On the other hand, human capital proxied by literacy rate turns out to be

significantly positive. However, as can be seen in the column (2) of table (5.1), adding

the initial level of income to the regression to capture the possible convergence effect

renders the human capital variable positive but statistically insignificant. It seems

that for the group of developing countries in the sample, the convergence effect seems

quite large. The third and fourth columns of table (5.1) show the results of including

the financial development indicators in the regression. In addition to these variables,

I include three other variables to control for the policy aspect of the countries. The

share of exports plus imports in GDP, obtained from Penn World Table, 6.1, is used

to measure the degree of openness in the economy. Government size, measured by

the government share in real GDP, is included in the regression to capture the public

sector. The monetary policy aspect of a country is proxied by the rate of inflation,

measured by the percentage change in GDP deflators. All variables are in logs.

5.2.3 Discussion

Overall, the results are generally consistent with the literature with the govern-

ment size and inflation having negative effects on output growth. The coefficient of

the financial development indicator is negative and insignificant. The effect of the

investment rate on real GDP per capita growth seems to get quite big but is still

statistically insignificant. Note that the interaction term, investment rate*financial

development indicator, our variable of interest, is positive and significant for both

measures of the financial development indicators, PC and DMBA, indicating that in-

vestment is a significant determinant of output growth when its allocative quality is

81
taken into account. However, its effect on output growth, compared to other variables

that are significant, seems relatively small.

When I use IVA per capita growth as the output measure, the overall results do not

change. The results are shown in table (5.2). The interaction term is still significantly

positive although its effect is smaller than in the preceding analysis. Interestingly,

both the investment and the human capital are significant determinants of industrial

output per capita growth. It may hint at the possibility that the accumulation of

physical and human capital does what policy-makers believe it does after all, but

that its effect is not evident in the typical growth analysis of developing countries

using GDP per capita growth in which the share of the industrial output is small.

The view that the legal aspect of the economy needs to be included in the analysis

of the role of the financial sector is increasingly gaining acceptance among researchers.

According to this view, the effective functioning of the financial sector is closely linked

to the type of legal framework of the economy so that any investigation on the role

of the financial sector in the economy should take into consideration the integrated

nature of these two variables. On the other hand, one can argue, based on some

evidence that the financial development indicators lose their significance when the

country-fixed effects are included (Benhabib and Spiegel, 2000), that financial devel-

opment is just a proxy for underlying fundamental economic infrastructure, including

the legal framework governing the market activities. In order to account for this

argument, I run another regression with two additional control variables. For this

purpose, I first obtain data on legal system and property rights from Economic Free-

dom of the World: 2002 Annual Report (Gwartney et al, 2002) to capture the legal

82
environment of a country. The degree of the economy’s infrastructural development

is difficult to measure since it involves many different aspects of the economy. In this

study, I use the number of telephone lines per 1000 people to proxy for the infrastruc-

tural development. Although it is an imperfect measure of infrastructure, it has the

advantage of being widely available for a long time span.20 Note that when the legal

environment and infrastructure variables are added to the regression, the sample pe-

riod is shortened from 1970 — 1998 to 1980 — 1998 due to the lack of available data

on legal environment for most of the developing countries prior to 1980.21

Table (5.3) shows the results. Adding these additional variables does not change

the overall picture although the model fit is slightly better. The effects of the inter-

action term on both real GDP per capita growth and IVA per capita growth remain

about the same with most of the coefficient estimates of other control variables com-

ing out with expected signs and generally being consistent with the preceding results.

Overall, the results I obtain from this analysis appear to confirm that investment does

work with a presence of the properly developed financial sector to distribute capital

in an efficient manner.

Although this is admittedly not conclusive evidence for the importance of invest-

ment in enhancing output growth because of the inherent sensitivity of this type of

study to model specification and the sample being used, it seems to provide a rea-

sonable support for the argument that the reason investment has not been effective
20
An alternative proxy for the infrastructure that is popular is infant mortality rate. When I ran
the regression with the infant mortality rate to control for the infrastructure, the results did not
change.
21
Additionally, some countries are dropped from the sample completely due to the lack of data on
the legal environment. A list of those countries dropped is in the appendix.

83
in promoting economic growth for a large majority of the developing countries is the

lack of mechanism to efficiently allocate capital.

5.3 Investment efficiency

The findings from the preceding section indicate that the financial sector positively

affects output growth by enhancing the allocative quality of investment for developing

countries. With this background, my goal in this section is to directly examine the

effects of financial development on the efficiency of investment and test the validity of

the efficiency channel of influence proposed by the finance-led growth literature (see

Greenwood and Jovanovich, 1990; Bencievenga and Smith, 1991).

5.3.1 Measures of investment efficiency

The literature typically defines (aggregate) investment efficiency as a ratio of the

output to the capital stock — or some minor variation of this ratio. The most com-

monly used measure is the so-called incremental capital output ratio, generally known

as ICOR, which looks at the units of capital needed to increase the output level by one

unit. It is essentially the inverse of the marginal product of capital. For instance, Jun

(2003) uses this measure to analyze the investment-growth nexus between 1978 and

2000 for China. Odedokun (1996) adapts a slightly different version of this ratio and

uses a change in output divided by a change in capital stock to examine the effects

of development banking activities on resource allocation in less developed countries.

This ratio can be modified to reflect the belief of the researcher about what the capital

accumulation is thought to achieve. For example, Toh et al (2002) replace the ag-

gregate output measure with estimated total factor productivity to examine whether

the capital is efficiently utilized in Singapore compared to other Asian countries.

84
In order to investigate whether investment is an effective tool for promoting growth

and whether its seeming failure to affect growth can be attributed to other macro-

economic variables, I start out by taking the comments of the Asian Development

Bank (ABD henceforth) on Cambodia seriously. The readers will recall from the

introduction of this chapter the following statement.


“boosting investment rates, currently low and overly dependent on for-
eign savings, is critical to achieving the government’s goal of sustained
economic growth.

What ABD meant seems quite clear. In order to realize a favorable growth rate,

investment rate has to be raised. It implies that there is a systematic relationship

between investment rate and growth rate of an economy. A direct testable implication

of this is that when investment rate rises by a certain percentage point, there will

be a corresponding change in the growth rate of the economy. However, whether the

aggregate investment is efficient in achieving this goal depends, to a large degree, on

the macroeconomic environment. Thus, as this macroeconomic environment changes

over time and across countries, a given unit of investment will produce dissimilar result

in terms of output growth. Given that the efforts of developing countries to achieve a

higher standard of living by focusing on investment have been, thus far, unsuccessful,

and that this failure may be attributed to the inefficient manner in which the funds

were allocated, identifying those elements of the macroeconomic environment that

affect the efficiency of investment has important policy implications.

To this end, I estimate the following:


µ ¶
∆yit Iit
= αi + β it ln + εit (5.2)
∆yit−1 Iit−1
where y is the output and I is the investment rate. αi is a dummy variable that

captures country-specific unobserved effect. β i is an elasticity. It measures the extent

85
of the change in growth rates in response to a change in investment rate in country

i. If investment is made efficiently over time, perhaps due to the presence of a better

developed financial sector, a rise in investment rate of a given unit will result in a

bigger change in the growth rate of the economy. In other words, a rise in investment

rate in Cambodia will result in a higher rate of economic growth than otherwise if

a good allocative mechanism is in place to make sure that additional investment is

put into its best uses. Hence, a higher value of β implies that investment is utilized

efficiently.

A possible objection to this interpretation is that a lower value of β may represent

not inefficient investment but the possibility that agents are looking at a longer-

horizon than the next year. To incorporate this possibility, I estimate βs for 10-year

horizon in this paper. Therefore, one can think of βs as a long-run trend relationship

between investment rate and output growth rate. This is an advantage over the

conventional measure of the investment efficiency that is measured on a yearly basis

and, thus, does not reflect the possible long-run horizon investment decisions.

It is possible that a rise in growth rates can cause the investment rate to grow.

For example, a 2-percent rise in growth rate may induce the economy to raise its

investment rate from 5% to 7% hoping to take advantage of (or accelerate further)

the economy taking off if economic agents are forward-looking and expect the trend

to continue. If this were the case, endogeneity makes interpretation of the results

difficult. Although it is a possibility, however, it is highly unlikely for developing

economies. Empirical evidence shows that the growth experiences of the developing

countries are highly volatile, and there does not seem to be a noticeable upward

86
trend in their growth rates (Temple, 1999). In an environment where growth has

been volatile, it is unlikely that the economic agents behave in a forward-looking

manner and raise investment rate in response to what could be a temporary change

in the growth rate.

Before we proceed, a warning is in order. The βs in this study should not be

interpreted strictly as measuring the causal effect of investment on output growth.

Rather, given the evidence that investment that is adjusted for its allocative quality

is a significant determinant of output growth, the emphasis is on providing an expla-

nation as to why the output growth seems to respond to investment better in some

countries than in others.

In addition to this measure, I also use the ratio of the real GDP to the capital stock.

This is essentially the approximation of the marginal product of capital assuming that

the income shares of the factors of production are constant. The advantage of this

measure over the marginal product of capital as a measure of investment efficiency

is that it does not require any functional assumptions. In this study, this more

conventional measure is used for comparability and completeness.

5.3.2 Investment efficiency estimates

In order to estimate the equation (5.2), I use two measures of output, the real GDP

per capita and IVA per capita, as defined and motivated in the preceding analysis.

Similarly, investment I is measured by the gross fixed capital formation. To avoid

endogeneity, I use the lagged values of I. The data are gathered for 53 developing

87
countries from 1970 to 1998.22 Then, I divide the sample into three sub-periods:

1970 — 1979, 1980 — 1989, and 1990 — 1998 so that I get three estimates of β for each

country. The idea is that I want to incorporate as much time dimension as possible

into my analysis. Then, the equation is estimated by OLS with country dummies.

Table (5.4) and (5.5) report the results.

A larger value of β implies that the growth rate was more sensitive to changes in

investment rate. Looking at the results, we can see that there are some incidences

where an increase in investment rate not only failed to raise growth rate of the output

but actually is associated with a slower rate of growth. However, for the entire

sample, investment efficiency is positive indicating that a rise in the investment rate

is generally positively associated with a rise in output growth rate. And, the impact

of raising investment rate is much greater on the industrial sector output growth rate

than on the national-level output growth rate. In fact, for the entire sample, the mean

of estimated β with the real GDP as the output measure, henceforth β GDP , is 0.05 and

9.5 with IVA per capita as the output measure, henceforth β IV A . A much lower value

of β GDP may indicate why other growth studies have failed to pick up investment rate

as a determinant of economic growth. So, despite the negative experiences of some

countries, raising investment rate does seem to, in general, promote a faster growth

of the economy although its effect is more pronounced in the industrial sector.

Furthermore, these countries seem to be getting better at utilizing investment.

The number of the incidences when investment rate is negatively associated with

output growth rate declines in the 1980s and 1990s. Also, the estimates of βs show
22
This is the same group of countries used in the preceding analysis. This is done intentionally to
keep the sample as consistent as possible throughout the paper. For details about the sample, refer
to the appendix.

88
that investment efficiency improves over time. When we compare the estimated in-

vestment efficiency between 1970s and 1990s, the average of the estimated β GDP rises

from 0.008 in 1970 to 0.055 in 1990s while that of the estimated β IV A rises from 5.37

to 10.17. Thus, again, it seems that the more relevant task for growth economists

should be not asking whether investment matters for economic growth but under-

standing why growth rate of an economy seems to respond well in some countries

and, for these developing countries, better over time.

On the other hand, the estimated investment efficiency displays wide variations

across countries. For the whole sample, the standard deviations are 0.15 and 17.34

for β GDP and β IV A respectively. Over time, the magnitude of these differences across

the countries rises as well. The standard deviations rise from 0.13 to 0.8 and from

13.7 to 19.7 for β GDP and β IV A , respectively, from the 1970s to the 1990s.

Across time, very few countries seem to maintain a high level of investment ef-

ficiency. For the whole sample, the correlation between the estimated βs for two

consecutive decades is generally low. Between the 1970s and 1980s, they are 0.61

when output is measured by real GDP per capita and 0.51 when it is measured by

real IVA per capita. Between 1980s and 1990s, the correlation becomes weaker al-

though it is not clear why this happened. They are 0.32 when output is measured

by real GDP per capita and 0.14 when it is measured by real IVA per capita. This

dynamic and volatile nature of the relationship between investment rate and output

growth rate illustrated by the data further emphasizes the importance of introducing

time dimension to the analysis of developing countries and question the suitability of

cross-sectional studies.

89
By and large, the estimated βs paint a picture that is in line with the findings

of the current growth literature, which allows me to be confident that they carry

useful information about the constraints these countries face in terms of investment

decisions.

5.3.3 Determinants of investment efficiency

Investment may promote output growth via two channels. Firstly, a rise in in-

vestment allows greater production of output by making more capital, a factor of

production, available to be utilized. Clearly, this change in the volume of investment

may not, in itself, be able to support a sustained rate of output growth as diminish-

ing returns eventually kick in. However, investment also creates positive externalities.

The accumulation of capital, embodied with knowledge, allows learning-by-doing of

the workers, which results in the gain in the overall efficiency of production processes.

For example, suppose you have been adding 5 machines to your existing stock of 100

machines every year. This year, you change your plans and start adding 10 machines

instead of five. In the past, there were five more people who knew how to operate

the machine. Now you have ten more people instead of five. Eventually, you will

run out of new people to run newly-added machines (diminishing marginal returns).

However, the pool of people who know how to operate the machine is greater with

ten-percent investment rate than with five-percent. As each person is equipped with

knowledge, and there are more of them, the probability for the occurence of positive

externality is also greater. In other words, when investment rate is raised, the rate of

learning-by-doing for the population also increases. This is a second channel through

which investment can affect growth even in the long-run. Investment enhances the

90
efficiency of overall production processes. Hence, any changes in the economic envi-

ronment that hinder the spillover effects of investment (the second channel above)

or prevent investment to reach its best possible uses (the first channel above) would

lead to a decline in the productivity of investment.

A high rate of inflation distorts the returns to investment and, consequently, the

incentives of investors. Specifically, persistently high rates of inflation may induce

the economic agents to invest in liquid and yet unproductive assets which leads to

inefficient allocation of resources. However, the literature is silent on exactly at what

rate of inflation this would occur. Coupled with this, an unstable monetary policy

that is prone to higher rates of inflation could hinder the effective functioning of the

financial sector as an allocator of funds to various investment opportunities (Savvides,

1995).

In addition, with more government involvement in the private market activities,

resource allocation is more likely to be guided by political motives and less by value-

maximization (Wurgler, 2000). As a result, relatively more suboptimal investment

decisions would occur when the government share of the economic activities is greater.

Another important element of the economic environment that governs the productiv-

ity of investment is the level of human capital available in the economy. I posit that

human capital may serve not necessarily to affect the growth rate of output directly

but to make it possible for capital to be utilized more efficiently. Controlling for the

macroeconomic environment with these variables, I test whether financial develop-

ment indicators enter significantly in determining investment efficiency in the next

section.

91
5.3.4 Estimation

In order to test the hypothesis that financial development affects investment effi-

ciency, I estimate the following equation:

Investment Efficiencyit = αi + γ(F D)it + z(controls)it + εit (5.3)

where α captures country-specific effects. As noted above, investment efficiency is

measured by i) estimated βs from above and ii) average product of capital which is

the ratio of output to capital stock (Y/K). To compute the average product of capital,

I obtain the capital stock data from Penn World Table 5.6. Note that the use of this

measure significantly reduces the sample size. Due to the lack of data availability,

when Y/K is used as a measure of investment efficiency, the time horizon is from 1970

to 1989 instead of 1970 to 1998. Also, I lose 27 countries from my initial sample of

53 countries. The list of countries used in this case is reported in the appendix. To

incorporate as much time dimension as the data allows and following the conventional

way of dividing up the time horizon, I compute the five-year averages of Y/K for 1970

— 1974, 1975 — 1979, 1980 — 1984, and 1985 — 1989.

The control variables are inflation, government size, and human capital as men-

tioned above. Inflation is measured by the growth rate of GDP deflator. Government

size is measured by the share of government expenditure in GDP. Human capital

is measured by literacy rate. The degree of financial development is measured by

two variables, PC and DMBA as discussed above. All variables are the initial val-

ues for each period to avoid simultaneity. Equation (1.2) is estimated with White’s

hetero-skedasticity consistent estimator.

92
5.3.5 Discussion

Table (5.6) reports the results when investment efficiency is measured by β. All

variables come out significant and with expected signs except for inflation. The

results show that a more government involvement reduces investment efficiency con-

firming what Wurgler (2000) found in his study. Human capital is also a significant

determinant of investment efficiency as predicted. More importantly, both of the fi-

nancial development indicators are significant in improving how efficiently investment

is made. In addition, the effects of financial development are the biggest among the

variables included in the analysis. On the contrary, inflation does not seem to be an

important factor of investment efficiency. While it comes out with the expected sign

with β GDP , its sign changes when the dependent variable is β IV A .

Interestingly, the effects of these variables are more pronounced when the output

is measured by IVA. Considering that the significance of these variables in raising

output growth has come under fire despite the intuitive and strong argument for

their roles in enhancing output growth, the current study may shed a new light on

exactly how they would affect economic growth. It seems that one possible way that

these factors, government size, human capital, and financial development, affect the

output growth is by improving the efficiency of investment rather than directly affect

the output growth itself. Furthermore, their effects on output may not be adequately

captured in the conventional studies using aggregate income measures of which the

industrial output takes, in some cases, only a small fraction.

Table (5.7) reports the results of using the average product as a dependent vari-

able. The model fit is much better than the preceding regression. The financial

93
development indicators are still significantly positive as is human capital. However,

the government size is now insignificant although it comes out with a right sign.

Contrarily, inflation, which was not a factor before, enters significantly.

Overall, the results thus far paint a picture that is consistent with what the

literature predicts. Especially, the role of the financial sector seems to be robustly

related to investment efficiency.

5.3.6 The effects of political stability and legal environment

Recently, there has been increasing attention on the sociopolitical factors as deter-

minants of macroeconomic performance. These factors range from cultural aspect of

an economy to religious beliefs of a dominant majority of the population in an econ-

omy and geographical location of a country. Indeed, the possibilities they represent

to the researchers are nearly endless. But, the common thread that connects all these

variables is that they do not necessarily affect macroeconomic performances directly

but do so indirectly by impacting the institutional arrangements that govern eco-

nomic activities (Rodrik, 2004). It is particularly in this context that the researchers

question the role of the financial sector in the economy. One cannot disregard the

possibility that financial development is working not as a source but a mere medium

through which the unobserved social and economic characteristics exert influence on

investment efficiency. Then, ascertaining the validity of the finance-led growth hy-

pothesis requires that these characteristics are accounted for in the analysis. The

most pertinent characteristic in this regard seems to be legal framework of an econ-

omy. It not only governs how well the financial sector functions but also determines

the social arrangement under which economic activities occur. Therefore, I add a

94
legal variable, as in the previous section, to account for this possibility. In addition

to a legal environment, political stability can also affect how effective the investment

can be (De Long, 1992). In a politically unstable economy, there is a higher degree

of uncertainty that economic agents or investors must find a way to reconcile with. I

use the average number of assassinations for each sub-period to proxy for the political

stability of a country.

5.3.7 Discussion

Table (5.8) and (5.9) report the results of adding these two additional variables

to the equation. The effects of legal environment in some instances are significantly

positive, but overall, they don’t seem to matter much, at least for the group of

countries considered here, for investment efficiency. However, it does not necessarily

suggest that the legal environment does not matter for investment efficiency. It may

as well be that the changes in legal environment for these countries have been only

marginal and have not reached the crucial tipping point where they begin to influence

investment efficiency in any meaningful way.

On the other hand, political stability has highly significant negative effects on

investment efficiency when the output is measured by IVA although, interestingly,

for the economy as a whole, it does not seem significant. Most importantly, adding

these two additional variables do not change the result that financial development is

a significant determinant of investment efficiency. The size of the coefficient is some-

what smaller but is, nonetheless, significantly positive as predicted by the finance-led

growth literature.

95
5.4 Conclusion

Theories of the finance-led growth state that the financial sector contributes to the

output growth by distributing capital to the most productive uses. The hypothesis

consists of two testable implications. Firstly, in order for the financial sector to

work its magic, investment needs to be an important determinant of output growth,

the proposition that’s been hotly debated. Secondly, investment efficiency across

countries should be positively correlated with the level of financial development. In

this paper, I test these implications using developing countries. The nature of the

growth process of the developing countries as noted in the literature provides an

ample testing ground for the hypothesis of financial-sector-assisted investment-driven

growth.

Using two measures of investment efficiency, I find evidence that investment ad-

justed for its allocative quality is an important determinant of economic growth and

that investment efficiency is positively affected by financial sector development. The

analysis shows that the positive effect of the financial sector on investment efficiency

is more pronounced in the industrial sectors than in the economy as a whole.

Given the already strong emphasis the developing countries place on investment,

and the relatively low costs it involves (compared to technological innovation), pro-

moting efficiency of investment looks to be a very promising avenue for the less-

developed countries to pursue. The current study shows that in order to achieve

this goal, these countries can take a number of policy measures. Firstly, to make

investment more productive or efficient, careful attention needs to be paid to raising

the general educational level of population. Secondly, a larger share of the economy

96
needs to be liberalized so that investment is made not based on political motives of

the government but on the value-maximization of private economic agents. Thirdly,

in order to promote investment efficiency, efforts need to be made to provide stable

political environment for investors so that the resulting investment decisions are op-

timal. Lastly, developing financial sector should be one of the first priorities for these

countries.

97
16
14
12 GDP per capita growth
10
8
6 Investment rate

4
2
0
-2 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 Year
-4

The GDP per capita is in real terms (1996 dollars), and investment rate is the share of real
investment in GDP. The data for the GDP per capita growth and investment rate are from
Penn World Table 6.1.

Figure 5.1: Output growth and investment in Cambodia

98
A
lg

0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
er
ia
Br
a
Ca zil
m
Co eroo
te n
d'I
vo
ir
Ec e
ua
do
r

Gu Fiji
at
em
al
a
In
di
a
Ja
m
Ko a ic
re a
a,
Re

99
M p.
ala
ys
ia
Ne
pa
Pa l
ki
sta
Pa n
ra
gu
ay
Rw
an
Se da
yc
he
l
Sr les
iL
an
k
Th a
ai
la
nd
U
ru
gu
Figure 5.2: The share of industry value added in GDP in developing countries

ay
Dependent variable: Real GDP per capita growth

(1) (2) (3) (4)


Domestic money
Financial development measured by: Private credit
bank assets
Variable
Investment rate -0.3099(-0.5712) 0.0703(0.1168) 0.3307(1.0213) 0.3855(1.2204)
Human capital 0.6381(2.8295) 0.0153(0.0074) 0.0658(0.1856) 0.0854(0.2396)
Initial Income -2.9996(-2.9743) -3.2506(-2.2796) -3.2307(-2.2567)
Finance -0.1601(-1.1092) -0.1253(-0.2591)
Finance*Investment 0.1348(1.9973) 0.1274(2.3471)
Openness 0.4744(1.2668) 0.3567(1.0113)
Government size -1.4784(-2.7529) -1.3925(-2.5760)
Inflation -0.0513(-2.1944) -0.0508(-2.301)
Nobs. 317 317 303 305
2
R 0.1895 0.2159 0.520258 0.5334
DW 2.18 2.1083 2.5001 2.5109
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

Note) The equation is estimated by FGLS. The numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics.

Table 5.1: Investment Regression I

100
Dependent variable: Real Industry value added per capita growth

(5) (6) (7) (8)


Domestic money
Financial development measured by: Private credit
bank assets
Variable
Investment rate -0.1375(-1.6104) 0.0909(1.7055) 0.1298(2.4752) 0.1417(2.6738)
Human capital 0.1423(3.2804) 0.0901(1.9953) 0.1254(2.8735) 0.1383(3.0470)
Initial Income -0.3823(-8.5597) -0.4046(-7.7167) -0.3984(-7.6494)
Finance 0.0277(0.2389) 0.0317(0.8801)
Finance*Investment 0.0754(1.7650) 0.0563(2.3530)
Openness 0.0697(1.2005) 0.0570(0.9829)
Government size -0.1615(-2.8158) -0.1586(-2.7841)
Inflation -0.0271(-2.0182) -0.0292(-2.2253)
Nobs. 278 278 270 270
2
R 0.1934 0.2436 0.4478 0.4494
DW 2.3510 2.2320 2.2965 2.3020
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

Note) The equation is estimated by FGLS. The numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics.

Table 5.2: Investment Regression II

101
Real Industry value added per
Dependent variable Real GDP per capita growth
capita growth

Financial development Domestic money Domestic money


Private credit Private credit
measured by: bank assets bank assets

Variable
Investment rate 0.2692(0.8820) 0.2974(0.9954) 0.2130(2.8697) 0.2103(2.7962)
Human capital 0.1426(1.7112) 0.1461(1.9618) 0.3167(2.3955) 0.3108(2.3398)
Initial Income -2.9229(-2.2798) -2.6055(-1.8442) -0.4874(-3.6727) -0.4799(-3.6111)
Finance -0.1757(-1.2353) -0.1521(-1.2199) 0.0042(0.1093) 0.0184(0.4246)
Finance*Investment 0.1230(1.7546) 0.1088(1.9662) 0.0516(1.8940) 0.0347(2.0081)
Openness 1.2258(2.1695) 1.1365(1.9915) 0.1806(0.8658) 0.1747(0.7532)
Government size -2.8246(-4.5539) -2.6603(-4.1237) -0.1462(-1.8952) -0.1409(-1.7988)
Inflation -0.1337(-2.3136) -0.1411(-2.3111) -0.0125(-1.2062) -0.0128(-1.2897)
Infrastructure 0.0976(2.1133) 0.07402(1.7424) 0.0072(0.1181) 0.0105(0.1739)
Legal environment 0.4004(1.6279) 0.3390(1.4652) 0.0432(0.7037) 0.0459(0.7553)
Nobs. 163 163 142 142
2
R 0.5776 0.5734 0.4544 0.4583
DW 2.3554 2.3661 2.2032 2.2017
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

Note) The equation is estimated by FGLS. The numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics.

Table 5.3: Investment Regression III

102
GDP
Country
1970s 1980s 1990s
Algeria 0.0959(0.8067) 0.0788(0.0852) 0.0329(0.0186)
Argentina -0.0281(0.0064) -0.0315(0.0243) -0.0301(0.0256)
Bolivia 0.0914(0.0078) -0.0066(0.0021) -0.0516(0.0039)
Botswana 0.2462(0.0432) 0.0883(0.0523) 0.3050(0.0239)
Brazil n.a. 0.0068(0.0152) 0.0012(0.0090)
Burkina Faso -0.0593(0.0436) 0.1508(0.0998) 0.0392(0.0435)
Burundi 0.0489(0.1721) -0.1220(0.2945) -0.0380(0.0700)
Cameroon 0.0539(0.2293) 0.3013(0.0315) 0.1388(0.0368)
Chile -0.0441(0.0524) 0.2068(0.0541) 0.1542(0.0371)
Colombia -0.0252(0.0203) 0.0718(0.0161) 0.0374(0.0045)
Costa Rica -0.0005(0.0241) -0.1696(0.1712) 0.1953(0.0400)
Cote d`Ivoire -0.0439(0.0585) -0.0922(0.1746) 0.0015(0.0441)
Cyprus 0.3592(0.0725) 0.1375(0.0070) 0.1779(0.1986)
Dominican Republic 0.0176(0.0554) -0.0263(0.0152) -0.1117(0.0962)
Ecuador 0.0079(0.0477) 0.0564(0.0588) 0.0490(0.0153)
Egypt -0.1516(0.0592) -0.0786(0.0320) 0.0516(0.0276)
El Salvador -0.0177(0.0142) 0.2126(0.0549) 0.0643(0.0194)
Fiji -0.1863(0.0570) -0.1770(0.1687) -0.0411(0.0222)
Ghana -0.0364(0.1340) 0.0148(0.0513) -0.0104(0.0096)
Guatemala -0.0729(0.0107) 0.0345(0.0125) -0.0656(0.0022)
Haiti -0.0028(0.0723) 0.1915(0.0831) 0.3374(0.0381)
Honduras -0.1998(0.0904) -0.0400(0.0284) -0.0068(0.0822)
India 0.1147(0.1781) 0.0685(0.0290) 0.0718(0.0697)
Indonesia 0.1079(0.0691) 0.1442(0.0220) -0.6386(0.3362)
Iran 0.0026(0.3700) -0.0092(0.2964) 0.0542(0.0260)
Israel 0.0977(0.0884) -0.0105(0.0078) 0.1610(0.0051)
Jamaica 0.0174(0.1006) 0.1386(0.0545) -0.0388(0.0160)
Jordan 0.2868(0.1936) 0.0581(0.0926) 0.0123(0.0763)
Kenya 0.2811(0.5376) 0.2122(0.0590) 0.0494(0.0217)
Korea 0.0910(0.0249) 0.3238(0.1289) 0.3485(0.0497)

Table 5.4: Investment Efficiency Estimates Using GDP

103
Table 5.4: Investment Efficiency Estimates Using GDP (continued)

Lesotho 0.0260(0.1585) -0.0265(0.0287) -0.2076(0.1008)


Madagascar -0.0244(0.0321) 0.0395(0.0181) -0.0177(0.0087)
Malaysia 0.1450(0.0426) 0.1720(0.0098) 0.1039(0.0015)
Mauritius -0.0225(0.0474) 0.0635(0.0901) -0.0868(0.0064)
Morocco 0.0337(0.0073) 0.1658(0.1628) 0.2049(0.6229)
Nepal 0.0578(0.0022) 0.0100(0.1057) 0.0569(0.0414)
Nicaragua n.a. -0.0350(0.0084) 0.0047(0.0023)
Niger -0.1247(0.3071) 0.1095(0.1007) 0.0385(0.0343)
Pakistan -0.0510(0.0202) 0.2127(0.0282) 0.1339(0.0205)
Panama 0.0618(0.0137) 0.1757(0.0392) 0.1056(0.0054)
Papua New Guinea -0.1041(0.0320) -0.1148(0.0258) -0.0664(0.5518)
Paraguay 0.0138(0.0288) 0.0832(0.0471) 0.0966(0.0409)
Peru -0.0864(0.1069) -0.0718(0.0337) -0.0198(0.0106)
Philippines -0.0099(0.0064) 0.1998(0.0225) 0.1625(0.0452)
Rwanda -0.0656(0.0323) -0.1024(0.2519) 0.5560(0.2035)
Senegal 0.3792(0.0949) 0.4705(0.4218) 0.1509(0.0105)
Singapore 0.1851(0.0210) 0.2457(0.0403) 0.4337(0.1907)
Sri Lanka 0.0400(0.0045) -0.0335(0.0224) 0.0372(0.0884)
Thailand 0.1460(0.0519) 0.2082(0.0254) 0.3058(0.0047)
Togo -0.4699(0.1593) -0.1105(0.2084) -0.0172(0.1372)
Trinidad &Tobago -0.1529(0.1345) 0.0679(0.0955) -0.1366(0.3050)
Uruguay 0.0417(0.015) 0.2236(0.0624) 0.0035(0.0376)
Venezuela 0.1054(0.1152) 0.0661(0.0511) 0.0205(0.0536)
Nobs 437 477 424
2
R 0.1944 0.2678 0.5565
DW 2.1556 2.0156 2.1113
Prob(F-stat) 0.0017 0.0000 0.0000
Note) βs are estimated from equation (5.2) using OLS. The numbers in the parenthesis
are standard deviations.

104
IVA
Country
1970s 1980s 1990s
Algeria -2.2125(0.1649) 3.9202(0.9031) -3.4958(3.5071)
Argentina -1.2066(0.9041) -3.626(2.5835) -2.4746(2.203)
Botswana 0.4697(2.2334) -7.4819(7.7584) 2.017(0.1054)
Brazil n.a. 0.7703(2.238) -0.5822(1.2991)
Burkina Faso -9.9135(14.8534) 8.4580(2.9813) 3.6546(13.9438)
Burundi 1.9567(7.7122) 2.6930(0.4997) 1.9071(17.8271)
Cameroon -1.4125(14.7897) 5.6848(1.9119) 1.8284(0.0225)
Chile -3.8672(4.9868) 19.8963(5.1658) 17.876(3.5581)
Colombia -3.5007(3.7782) 5.7932(4.5881) 8.7870(0.9752)
Cote d`Ivoire 14.2528(24.7746) 5.5477(10.2416) 16.5364(26.1071)
Dominican Republic 15.3899(10.8853) 25.1306(9.7111) -7.069(21.7371)
Ecuador -7.6419(8.7375) -11.7707(12.3296) 17.2677(2.1373)
Egypt 9.7605(2.0121) -2.6693(4.7574) 15.8823(2.323)
El Salvador 1.4479(2.9971) 36.7105(7.6437) 8.2869(4.6504)
Fiji -33.2566(4.7908) -15.5363(33.8456) -0.0512(3.2347)
Ghana 6.1689(7.6931) 17.3982(17.4023) 0.2249(0.2847)
Guatemala 14.0998(1.6034) 19.6717(3.9835) 5.378(1.5506)
Haiti 9.1138(6.8254) 27.7791(7.1284) 36.1285(17.6488)
Honduras 12.5832(3.7347) 8.0876(2.9952) 23.5131(13.2606)
India 9.4180(7.7300) -0.9967(6.5817) 6.9128(1.5872)
Indonesia 1.2447(0.6117) 12.933(12.6262) -84.4014(59.5649)
Iran 34.0102(25.0239) 32.1233(47.562) 38.5135(5.6775)
Jamaica 15.0687(6.3684) 19.3543(10.5561) 1.7493(0.7418)
Jordan n.a. 1.2563(7.3034) 3.8924(1.4171)
Kenya 2.8326(68.2315) 8.379(1.1517) 2.6557(1.237)
Korea 36.2086(5.7064) 64.0368(20.2605) 41.0446(1.2586)
Lesotho 3.3637(18.4002) 7.6509(1.2903) 2.9995(1.5160)

Table 5.5: Investment Efficiency Estimates Using IVA

105
Table 5.5: Investment Efficiency Estimates Using IVA (continued)

Madagascar -5.4658(8.2415) 20.2000(26.441) 0.5844(0.6739)


Malaysia 9.6869(10.8412) 13.8038(4.6745) 10.2202(0.3020)
Mauritius 14.8768(5.8593) 26.5417(16.8879) 5.412(0.4324)
Morocco 11.3532(0.8569) 8.0180(2.3918) 17.2071(11.5815)
Nepal -2.4395(0.8408) 0.2222(1.7956) 8.3668(3.9818)
Niger -15.7091(7.2691) 14.4015(21.1447) 8.8712(3.6192)
Pakistan -0.2184(7.4174) 6.6894(13.2983) 13.6878(4.3302)
Panama n.a. 24.1498(1.3229) 22.5887(1.9309)
Papua New Guinea n.a. -0.1054(18.9467) 17.7253(195.0098)
Paraguay 5.4260(2.4496) 42.2938(16.9868) 27.6978(8.9578)
Peru -0.1970(3.1712) -5.5300(3.1704) -4.1787(0.9699)
Philippines 3.3955(1.1552) 42.8161(2.8438) 17.5358(6.0656)
Rwanda -1.9850(0.2441) -37.5001(59.9429) 59.6687(21.6652)
Senegal 31.3559(7.9633) 22.7896(22.644) 7.7239(14.1205)
Singapore 38.3329(6.2111) 34.4393(7.1699) 25.4722(6.9614)
Sri Lanka 21.8508(3.7982) -0.5164(0.6829) 12.021(1.773)
Thailand 8.6302(5.9762) 34.3772(7.3525) 38.1589(0.4704)
Togo 6.9709(11.5213) 22.4846(17.6556) 28.2358(3.0011)
Trinidad &Tobago -3.4754(3.8257) 7.2363(6.4540) 8.3891(2.4667)
Uruguay 8.6821(1.6441) 24.9211(3.8076) -4.1574(3.186)
Venezuela -18.9878(12.4996) 17.8963(4.2571) 7.8113(8.104)
Nobs 367 432 380
2
R 0.1526 0.2838 0.4862
DW 2.1752 1.9342 1.7000
Prob(F-stat) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Note) βs are estimated from equation (5.1) using OLS. The numbers in the parenthesis
are standard deviations.

106
Dependent variable: βGDP
Private credit Domestic money bank
Variable as a measure of financial assets as a measure of
development financial development

Inflation -0.1112(-1.0898) -0.0987(-1.4745)


Government size -0.2205(-2.2836) -0.3720(-2.2187)
Human Capital 0.1547(5.0508) 0.1793(4.9848)
Finance 0.4660(1.9767) 0.3563(1.9333)
Nobs. 155 156
2
R 0.4309 0.4240
DW 2.5519 2.6866
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000
Dependent variable: βIVA
Private credit Domestic money bank
Variable as a measure of financial assets as a measure of
development financial development

Inflation 0.0544(1.0039) 0.0494(1.0010)


Government size -0.5632(-1.7989) -0.5954(-1.8243)
Human Capital 0.3120(3.4340) 0.2242(3.2577)
Finance 1.2073(2.6193) 1.0532(2.2750)
Nobs. 139 140
2
R 0.3742 0.3703
DW 2.0201 2.1304
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000

Note: the numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics. The equation is estimated by white
heteroskedasticity-consistent estimator.

Table 5.6: Investment Efficiency Regression I

107
Dependent variable: Average product of capital
Private credit Domestic money bank
Variable Base regression as a measure of financial assets as a measure of
development financial development

Inflation -0.0359(-2.5863) -0.0449(-3.0064) -0.0455(-3.1122)


Government size -0.1956(-1.0916) -0.1995(-1.1103) -0.1936(-1.0857)
Human Capital 0.4467(5.7401) 0.3729(4.2119) 0.3534(4.0776)
Finance 0.2572(2.004) 0.2772(1.9767)
Nobs. 104 103 103
R
2 0.6355 0.6585 0.6690
DW 2.2637 2.2987 2.3109
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Note: the numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics. Average product of capital is the
ratio of the average real GDP to the average capital stock for five-year horizon. The
equation is estimated by white heteroskedasticity-consistent estimator.

Table 5.7: Investment Efficiency Regression II

108
Dependent variable: β (GDP)
Private credit as a measure of Domestic money bank assets as a
Variable
financial development measure of financial development

Inflation -0.0827(-1.8206) -0.0531(-1.8395) -0.0355(-0.6663) -0.0256(-1.1360)


Government size -0.2628(-2.4071) -0.3083(-2.0627) -0.3525(-2.2158) -0.5227(-2.5030)
Human Capital 0.3336(4.0347) 0.4316(1.9623) 0.3857(3.5601) 0.4184(1.7498)
Finance 0.3571(1.9877) 0.3001(1.0393) 0.2730(1.8211) 0.2129(1.7792)
Assassinations -0.0174(-1.3651) -0.0110(-1.1631) -0.0126(-0.9256) -0.0129(-1.5372)
Legal environment 0.3370(0.8740) 0.3870(1.1297)
Nobs. 155 119 156 120
2
R 0.4312 0.4430 0.4394 0.4476
DW 2.5154 2.4914 2.5428 2.5039
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0008
Dependent variable: β (IVA)
Private credit as a measure of Domestic money bank assets as a
Variable
financial development measure of financial development

Inflation -0.0372(-1.4044) -0.0265(-0.9653) -0.0261(-1.3968) -0.0276(-1.2755)


Government size -1.3864(-1.8963) -0.9877(-1.8532) -1.2503(-1.7640) -0.7591(-1.7773)
Human Capital 0.2549(3.1395) 0.2389(3.4301) 0.2221(3.4440) 0.2006(3.3205)
Finance 1.1202(2.1215) 1.0888(2.4447) 1.3576(2.0013) 1.2589(2.0001)
Assassinations -0.1569(-2.0842) -0.1661(-2.0889) -0.1308(-2.4793) -0.1200(-2.0982)
Legal environment 0.1004(1.1345) 0.2156(0.9504)
Nobs. 139 107 140 108
2
R 0.3809 0.3775 0.3782 0.3848
DW 2.0104 1.9975 2.0776 2.0460
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Note: the numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics. The equation is estimated by white
heteroskedasticity-consistent estimator.

Table 5.8: Investment Efficiency Regression III

109
Dependent variable: Average product of capital
Private credit as a measure of Domestic money bank assets as a
Variable
financial development measure of financial development

Inflation -0.0217(-3.3231) -0.0678(-3.1653) -0.0224(-3.4635) -0.0407(-1.7668)


Government size -0.2416(-4.6977) -0.1495(-2.7244) -0.2347(-4.5103) -0.1941(-2.9712)
Human Capital 0.3357(3.7767) 0.2198(2.8352) 0.3300(3.0456) 0.2537(2.0419)
Finance 0.2145(1.9454) 0.2598(2.0902) 0.2064(1.8106) 0.1163(2.6014)
Assassinations -0.0417(-3.9008) -0.0507(-5.6346) -0.0400(-3.8843) -0.0605(-4.1289)
Legal environment 0.1654(3.1379) 0.2730(4.9516)
Nobs. 103 84 103 84
2
R 0.7152 0.7154 0.7597 0.7701
DW 2.1633 2.5294 2.3569 2.4257
Prob(F-statistic) 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
Note: the numbers in the parenthesis are t-statistics. Average product of capital is the
ratio of the average real GDP to the average capital stock for five-year horizon. The
equation is estimated by white heteroskedasticity-consistent estimator.

Table 5.9: Investment Efficiency Regression IV

110
CHAPTER 6

Conclusion

The primary part of my dissertation investigates the potential effects of financial

sector development on economic growth. In order to reveal the nature of these effects,

I focus on the potential channel of influences from the financial to the real sector.

The nature of interaction between the real and the financial sectors has been hotly

debated among researchers. Those who favor finance-led growth hypothesis argue

that the existence of a vibrant financial sector has a growth-enhancing effects. In

this literature, an economy can grow faster due to an efficient allocation of resources

by the financial sector, mainly banks. A number of channels of influence have been

proposed in the literature, which include increased savings, increased investment rate,

and efficiency thereof, increased human capital accumulation, and positive effects of

the financial sector on innovation processes. Investigations of the validity of these

channels as true agents of long-run growth, so far, have yielded mixed empirical

results.

I investigate the link between the financial sector and economic growth focusing

on the role of the financial sector in funding innovative activities. I pursue this goal by

constructing a model where the economy is driven by innovative activities that require

111
both human capital and external funding from the financial sector. My analysis

shows that when certain conditions are satisfied, there exists a unique equilibrium

where the growth rate of the economy is jointly determined by the levels of human

capital and financial development. An interesting implication of this is that financial

liberalization policies that do not adequately address the fundamentals of the economy

can bring about bank failures and possibly a financial crisis. Furthermore, in addition

to showing that poverty traps can be explained without introducing setup costs, the

model suggests that, depending on the parameter values of the economy, there may

be two forms of poverty traps, one with a small number of bankers and the other with

a large number of bankers.

In addition, I examine empirically whether financial development has any effect

on the rate of technological innovation. I test the validity of the finance-led growth

hypothesis by focusing on the innovation channel of influence, using patent applica-

tions as a proxy for innovative output. Using panel data on twenty eight countries

from 1970 to 2000, my analysis shows that financial development is indeed significant

in raising the growth rate of innovative output.

Lastly, I examine if there is any evidence of financial development positively af-

fecting the efficiency of aggregate investment using developing countries as a sample.

I address the issue of efficiency channel using two alternative measures of aggregate

investment efficiency. I find that, for developing countries, financial development

significantly and positively affects productivity of investment.

112
Appendix A

Data Sources for Chapter 5

Real GDP per capita; Population; Openness as measured by the share of exports
plus imports in GDP in constant 1996 prices; Government size as measured by the
government share in real GDP in constant 1996 prices
Source: Penn World Table Version 6.1, Center for International Comparisons at the
University of Pennsylvania (CICUP), October 2002.

Industry value added: Industry corresponds to ISIC divisions 10-45 and includes manu-
facturing (ISIC divisions 15-37). It comprises value added in mining, manufacturing (also
reported as a separate subgroup), construction, electricity, water, and gas. Value added is
the net output of a sector after adding up all outputs and subtracting intermediate inputs.
It is calculated without making deductions for depreciation of fabricated assets or deple-
tion and degradation of natural resources. The origin of value added is determined by the
International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC), revision 2. Data are in constant
1995 U.S. dollars. Source: World Development Indicator CD-Rom, 2000

Gross fixed capital formation: The total value of a producer’s acquisitions, less dispos-
als, of fixed assets during the accounting period plus certain additions to the value of non-
produced assets realized by the productive activity of institutional units. Fixed assets are
tangible or intangible assets produced as outputs from processes of production that are
themselves used repeatedly or continuously in other processes of production for more
than one year. Data in local currency.
Source: International Financial Statistics CD-Rom, 2000

Deposit Money Bank Assets to GDP: Claims on domestic real nonfinancial sector by
deposit money banks as a share of GDP, calculated using the following deflation method:
(0.5)[Ft / Pet + Ft −1 / Pet −1 ] /[GDPt / Pat ] , where F is deposit money bank claims, P_e is end-
of period CPI, and P_a is average annual CPI. Raw data are from the electronic version of
the IMF's International Financial Statistics (IFS line lines 22, a-d). Data on the deflators
is from the electronic version of the IFS (line 64M..ZF or, if not available, line 64Q..ZF)

113
and annual CPI (line 64..ZF). Data on GDP in local currency (lines 99B..ZF or, if not
available, line 99B.CZF)
Source: http://www.worldbank.org/research/projects/finstructure/database.htm

Private credit by deposit money banks to GDP: Private credit by deposit money banks
to GDP, calculated using the deflation method shown above. Raw data are from the
electronic version of the IMF's International Financial Statistics (IFS lines 22d). Data on
GDP in local currency (lines 99B..ZF or, if not available, line 99B.CZF), end-of period
CPI (line 64M..ZF or , if not available, 64Q..ZF), and annual CPI (line 64..ZF) are from
the electronic version of the IFS.
Source: http://www.worldbank.org/research/projects/finstructure/database.htm

Illiteracy rate: Adult illiteracy rate is the percentage of people aged 15 and above who
cannot, with understanding, read and write a short, simple statement on their everyday
life.
Source: World Development Indicator CD-Rom, 2000

Inflation: Inflation as measured by the annual growth rate of the GDP implicit deflator.
GDP implicit deflator measures the average annual rate of price change in the economy
as a whole for the periods shown.
Source: World Development Indicator CD-Rom, 2000

Legal: Legal system and property rights


Source: Gwartney, James and Robert Lawson with Walter Park, Smita Wagh, Chris
Edwards, and Veronique de Rugy. Economic Freedom of the World: 2002 Annual Report.
Vancouver: The Fraser Institute, 2002. Data retrieved from www.freetheworld.com

Telephone mainlines: Telephone mainlines are telephone lines connecting a customer's


equipment to the public switched telephone network. Data are presented per 1,000 people
for the entire country.
Source: World Development Indicator CD-Rom, 2000

Assassinations: The number of any politically motivated murder or attempted murder of


a high government official or politician
Source: Arthur S. Banks Cross National Time-Series Data Archive downloaded from the
web site: http://www.worldbank.org/research/growth/GDNdata.htm (2005)

114
Appendix B

Countries Used In The Sample

Countries used in the investment regression


(with the real GDP per capita growth as a dependent variable)
Algeria(1) Cyprus* Iran Nicaragua(2) Thailand
Dominican
Argentina Israel Niger Togo
Republic
Trinidad
Bolivia Ecuador Jamaica Pakistan
&Tobago
Botswana*(1) Egypt Jordan(2) Panama Uruguay
Papua New
Brazil(2) El Salvador Kenya Venezuela
Guinea*(1)
Burkina Faso* Fiji* Korea Paraguay
Burundi Ghana Lesotho*(1) Peru
Cameroon Guatemala Madagascar* Philippines
Chile Haiti Malaysia Rwanda*
Colombia Honduras Mauritius* Senegal
Costa Rica India Morocco Singapore*
Cote d`Ivoire* Indonesia(2) Nepal* Sri Lanka
* Countries that are dropped when infrastructure and legal variables are added in the
regression.
(1) Countries for which the sample period is 1975 – 1998
(2) Countries for which the sample period is 1980 – 1998; For Indonesia, the sample
period is 1970 – 1998 when DMBA is used as the financial development indicator.

115
Countries used in the investment regression
(with real Industry Value Added per capita growth as a dependent variable)
Algeria(1) Egypt Kenya Paraguay

Argentina El Salvador Korea Peru

Botswana*(1) Fiji* Lesotho*(1) Philippines

Brazil(2) Ghana Madagascar* Rwanda*

Burkina Faso* Guatemala Malaysia Senegal

Burundi Haiti Mauritius* Singapore*

Cameroon Honduras Morocco Sri Lanka

Chile India Nepal*(1) Thailand

Colombia Indonesia(2) Niger Togo

Cote d`Ivoire* Iran(3) Pakistan Trinidad &Tobago

Dominican Republic Jamaica Panama(2) Uruguay


Papua New
Ecuador Jordan(2) Venezuela
Guinea*(2)
* Countries that are dropped when infrastructure and legal variables are added in the
regression.
(1) Countries for which the sample period is 1975 – 1998;
(2) Countries for which the sample period is 1980 – 1998; For Indonesia, the sample
period is 1970 – 1998 when DMBA is used as the financial development indicator.
(3) For Iran, the sample period is 1975 – 1994

116
Sample countries used when investment efficiency is measured by Y/K
Dominican
Argentina Israel Morocco Thailand
Republic

Bolivia Ecuador Jamaica Nepal* Venezuela

Botswana*(1) Guatemala Keyna Panama

Chile Honduras Korea Paraguay

Colombia India Madagascar* Peru

Cote d’Ivoire* Iran Mauritius* Philippines


* Countries that are dropped when legal environment variable is added to the regression.
(1) Countries for which the sample period is 1975 – 1989.

117
BIBLIOGRAPHY

Aghion, P. and H. Peter (1999). Endogeneous Growth Theory. London, England, The MIT
Press.

Aizenman, J. (2005). "Financial liberalizations in Latin America in the 1990s: A


reassessment." NBER Working Paper Series(11145).

Allen, F. and D. Gale (2001). Comparing Financial Systems. Cambridge, Massachusetts


London, England, The MIT Press.

Archibugi, D. and P. Mario (1996). "Measuring technological change through patents and
innovation surveys." Technovation 16(9): 451-468.

Arestis, P. and P. Demetriades (1997). "Financial Development and Economic Growth:


Assessing the Evidence." The Economic Journal(107): 783-799.

Arestis, P., P.Demetriades, et al. (2002). "The impact of financial liberalization policies on
financial development: Evidence from developing economies." WP.

Arestis, P. and D. Panicos (2002). "Financial Policies and the Aggregate Productivity of
the Capital Stock: Evidence from Developed and Developing Economies." The Levy
Economics Institute of Bard College, Working Paper No.362.

Badawi, A. (2003). "Private Capital Formation and Public Investment in Sudan: Testing
the Substitutability and Complementarity Hypotheses in a Growth Framework." Journal of
International Development 15(6): 783-799.

Barro, R. J. and L. Jong-Wha (2000). "International data on educational attainment:


Updates and Implications." CID Working Paper(42).

Beck, T., D.-K. Asli, et al. (1999). "A new database on financial development and
structure." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series(2146).

Beck, T., D.-K. Asli, et al. (2001). "Law, Politics, and Finance." World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper Series(2585).

118
Beck, T., D.-K. Asli, et al. (2001). "Legal theories of financial development." Oxford
Review of Economic Policy 17(4): 483-501.

Beck, T., D.-K. Asli, et al. (2002). "Law, Endowments, and Finance." NBER Working
Paper Series(9089).

Beck, T. and R. Levine (2002). "Stock Markets, Banks, and Growth: Panel Evidence."
NBER Working Paper Series No. 9082.

Beck, T. and L. Ross (2000). "New Firm Formation and Industry Growth: Does Having a
Market- or Bank-Based System Matter?" World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
Series(2383).

Beck, T., L. Ross, et al. (2000). "Finance and the Sources of Growth." Journal of Financial
Economics 58(1-2): 261-300.

Bencivenga, V. R. and D. S. Bruce (1991). "Financial Intermediation and Endogenous


Growth." Review of Economic Studies 58: 195-209.

Benhabib, J. and M. S. Mark (2000). "The role of financial development in growth and
investment." Journal of Economic Growth 5: 341-360.

Blomstrom, M., E. L. Robert, et al. (1996). "Is Fixed Investment the Key to Economic
Growth?" The Quarterly Journal of Economics 111(1): 269-276.

Bond, S., L. Asli, et al. (2004). "Capital Accumulation and Growth: A New Look at the
Empirical Evidence." WP.

Calderon, C. s. and L. Lin (2003). "The direction of causality between financial


development and economic growth." Journal of Development Economics 72: 321-334.

Chari, A. and H. Peter Blair (2002). "Capital account liberalization: Allocative efficiency
or animal spirits?" NBER Working Paper Series(8908).

Christopoulos, D. K. and G. T. Efthymios (2004). "Financial development and economic


growth: evidence from panel unit root and cointegration tests." Journal of Development
Economics 73: 55-74.

Comanor, W. S. and F.M.Scherer (1969). "Patent statistics as a measure of technical


change." Journal of Political Economy 77: 392-397.

Crosby, M. (2000). "Patents, Innovation and Growth." Economic Record 76(234):


255-262.

119
De Long, J. B. (1992). "Productivity Growth and Machinery Investment: A Long-Run
Look, 1870 - 1980." The Journal of Economic History 52(2): 307-324.

Deidda, L. and F. Bassam (2002). "Non-linearity between finance and growth." Economics
Letters 74: 339-345.

Demetriades, P. O. and A. H. Khaled (1996). "Does financial development cause economic


growth? Time-series evidence from 16 countries." Journal of Development Economics 51:
387-411.

Diamond, D. W. (1984). "Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring." Review of


Economic Studies 51: 393-414.

Driffill, J. (2003). "Growth and Finance." The Manchester School 71(4, Special Issue):
363-380.

Easterly, W. (2002). The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and
Misadventures in the Tropics. Cambridge, Massachusetts; London, England, The MIT
Press.

Easterly, W. and L. Ross (2001). "What Have We Learned from a Decade of Empirical
Research on Growth? It's Not Factor Accumulation: Stylized Facts and Growth Models."
World Bank Economic Review 15: 177-219.

Easterly, W., L. Ross, et al. (2004). "Aid, Policies, and Growth: Comment." The American
Economic Review 94(3): 774-780.

Ergungor, O. E. (2004). "Market- vs. bank-based financial systems: Do rights and


regulations really matter?" Journal of Banking and Finance 28: 2869-2887.

Evans, A. D., C. J. Green, et al. (2002). "Human Capital and Financial Development in
Economic Growth: New Evidence Using the Translog Production Function." International
Journal of Finance and Economics 7: 123-140.

Fatas, A. (2000). "Do business cycles cast long shadows? Short-run persistence and
economic growth." Journal of Economic Growth 5: 147-162.

Fisman, R. and L. Inessa (2003). "Financial development and the composition of industrial
growth." NBER Working Paper Series(9583).

Fisman, R. and L. Inessa (2004). "Financial development and growth in the short and long
run." NBER Working Paper Series(10236).

Fry, M. J. (1995). Money, Interest, And Banking In Economic Development. Baltimore


and London, The Johns Hopkins University Press.

120
Fuente, A. d. l. and M. Jos'e Mari'a (1996). "Innovation, bank monitoring, and endogenous
financial development." Journal of Monetary Economics 38(269): 301.

Galetovic, A. (1996). "Specialization, intermediation, and growth." Journal of Monetary


Economics 38: 549-559.

Gapinski, J. H. (1996). "Heterogeneous Capital, Economic Growth, and Economic


Development." Journal of Macroeconomics 18(4): 561-586.

Goldsmith, R. W. (1969). Financial Structure and Development. New Haven, CT, Yale
University Press.

Greenwood, J. and J. Boyan (1990). "Financial Development, Growth, and the Distribution
of Income." The Journal of Political Economy 98(5, Part 1): 1076-1107.

Greenwood, J. and B. D. Smith (1997). "Financial markets in development, and the


development of financial markets." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 21:
145-181.

Gregorio, J. D. and E. G. Pable (1995). "Financial development and economic growth."


World Development 23(3): 433-448.

Griliches, Z. (1990). "Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey." Journal of


Economic Literature 28(4): 1661-1707.

Gwartney, J. D., R. A. Lawson, et al. (1999). "Economic Freedom and the Environment for
Economic Growth." Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 155(4): 643-663.

Gylfason, T. (2004). "To grow or not to grow: Why institutions must make a difference."
CESifo Dice Report, Journal for Institutional Comparisons 2(2): 3-15.

Hamilton, J. D. and J. Monteagudo (1998). "The Augmented Solow Model and the
Productivity Slowdown." Journal of Monetary Economics 42(3): 495-509.

Hansen, H. (2000). "Aid Effectiveness Disputed." Journal of International Development


12: 375-398.

Harrison, P., O. Sussman, et al. (1999). "Finance and Growth: Theory and New Evidence."
WP.

Hayami, Y. and O. Junichi (1999). "Changes in the Sources of Modern Economic Growth:
Japan Compared with the United States." Journal of the Japanese and International
Economies 13(1): 1-21.

121
Hendriks, L. (2000). "Equipment investment and growth in developing countries." Journal
of Development Economics 61: 335-364.

Hirschey, M. and J. R. ernon (2004). "Are scientific indicators of patent quality useful to
investors?" Journal of Empirical Finance 11: 91-107.

Jacoby, H. G. and E. Skoufias (1997). "Risk, Financial Markets, and Human Capital in a
Developing Country." The Review of Economic Studies 64(3): 311-335.

Johnson, D. K. N. and D. Popp (2003). "Forced Out of the Closet: The Impact of the
American Inventors Protection Act on the Timing of Patent Disclosure." Rand Journal of
Economics 34(1): 96-112.

Judson, R. (1998). "Economic Growth and Investment in Education: How Allocation


Matters." Journal of Economic Growth 3: 337-359.

Jun, Z. (2003). "Investment, Investment Efficiency, and Economic Growth in China."


Journal of Asian Economics 14(5): 713-734.

Khan, M. S. and S. S. Abdelhak (2000). "Financial development and economic growth: An


overview." IMF Working Papers(00/209).

King, R. G. and R. Levine (1993). "Finance, Entrepreneurship, and Growth: Theory and
Evidence." Journal of Monetary Economics 32(3): 513-542.

King, R. G. and R. Levine (1994). "Capital Fundamentalism, Economic Development, and


Economic Growth." Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 40(0):
259-292.

King, R. G. and L. Ross (1993). "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right." The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3): 717-737.

Lee, J.-W. (2005). "Human capital and productivity for Korea's sustained economic
growth." Journal of Asian Economics 16: 663-687.

Levine, R. (1997). "Financial development and economic growth: Views and agenda."
Journal of Economic Literature 35: 688-726.

Levine, R. (1998). "The Legal Environment, Banks, and Long-run Economic Growth."
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 30(3): 596-613.

Levine, R. (1999). "Law, Finance, and Economic Growth." Journal of Financial


Intermediation 8(1-2): 8-35.

122
Lopez, R. (1995). "Synergy and Investment Efficiency Effects of Trade and Labor Market
Distortions." European Economic Review 39(7): 1321-1344.

Luintel, K. B. and K. Mosahid (1999). "A quantitative reassessment of the finance-growth


nexus: evidence from a multivariate VAR." Journal of Development Economics 60:
381-405.

Madsen, J. B. (2002). "The Causality between investment and economic growth."


Economics Letters 74: 157-163.

Mankiw, N. G., D. Romer, et al. (1992). "A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic
Growth." The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(2): 407-437.

McKinnon, R. I. (1973). Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington, DC.,


Brookings Institute.

Ndikumana, L. o. (2005). "Financial development, financial structure, and domestic


investment: International evidence." Journal of International Money and Finance 24:
651-673.

Odedokun, M. O. (1996). "International evidence on the effects of directed credit


programmes on efficiency of resource allocation in developing countries: The case of
development bank lendings." Journal of Development Economics 48: 449-460.

Outreville, J. F. (1999). "Financial development, human capital and political instability."


UNCTAD Discussion Papers(142).

Popp, D., T. Juhl, et al. (2004). "Time In Purgatory: Examining the Grant Lag for U.S.
Patent Applications." Topics in Economic Analysis & Policy 4(1).

Porter, M. E. and S. Scott (2000). "Measuring the "ideas" production function: Evidence
from international patent output." NBER Working Paper Series(7891).

Rioja, F. and V. Neven (2004). "Finance and the sources of growth at various stages of
economic development." Economic Inquiry 42(1): 127-140.

Romer, P. M. (1990). "Endogenous Technological Change." The Journal of Political


Economy 98(5): S71-S102.

Ross, L. (2001). "International financial liberalization and economic growth." Review of


International Economics 9(4): 688-702.

Rousseau, P. L. and V. Dadanee (2005). "Finance, investment, and growth: Time series
evidence from 10 Asian economies." Journal of Macroeconomics 27: 87-106.

123
Rousseau, P. L. and R. Sylla (1999). "Emerging Financial Markets and Early U.S.
Growth." NBER Working Paper Series No. 7448.

Saint-Paul, G. (1992). "Technological choice, financial markets, and economic


development." European Economic Review 36: 763-781.

Saint-Paul, G. (1993). "Productivity growth and the structure of the business cycle."
European Economic Review 37: 861-883.

Sala-I-Martin, X. (1997). "I Just Ran Two Million Regressions." The American Economic
Review 87: 178-183.

Savvides, A. (1995). "Economic Growth in Africa." World Development 23(3): 449-458.

Shan, J. Z., G. M. Alan, et al. (2001). "Financial development and economic growth: An
egg-and-chicken problem?" Review of International Economics 9(3): 443-454.

Shaw, E. S. (1973). Financial Deepening in Economic Development. New York, Oxford


University Press.

Stern, S., E. P. Michael, et al. (2000). "The determinants of national innovative capacity."
NBER Working Paper Series(7876).

Tadesse, S. (2005). "Financial development and technology." William Davidson Institute


Working Paper(749).

Toh, M. H. and N. Wai Choong (2002). "Efficiency of Investments in Asian Economies:


Has Singapore Over-Invested." Journal of Asian Economics 13(1): 52-71.

Tsuru, K. (2000). "Finance and Growth: Some theoretical considerations, and a review of
the empirical literature." OECD Economics Department Working Paper(228).

Wachtel, P. (2001). "Growth and Finance: What do we know and how do we know it?"
International Finance 4(3): 335-362.

Wαlde, K. and W. Ulrich (2004). "R&D expenditure in G7 countries and the implications
for endogenous fluctuations and growth." Economics Letters 82: 91-97.

Wurgler, J. (2000). "Financial markets and the allocation of capital." Journal of Financial
Economics 58: 187-214.

Xu, Z. (2000). "Financial development, investment, and economic growth." Economic


Inquiry 38(2): 331-344.

124
Yamano, N. and T. Ohkawara (2000). "The Regional Allocation of Public Investment:
Efficiency or Equity"." Journal of Regional Science 40(2): 205-229.

125

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen