Sie sind auf Seite 1von 18

49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 303

© 2003 Journal of Peace Research,


vol. 40, no. 3, 2003, pp. 303–320
Sage Publications (London, Thousand Oaks,
CA and New Delhi)
[0022-3433(200305)40:3; 303–320; 032988]

Civil War Settlements and the Implementation of


Military Power-Sharing Arrangements*
MAT THEW HODDIE
Department of Political Science, Texas A&M University

CAROLINE HARTZELL
Department of Political Science, Gettysburg College

This article considers the role that the implementation of peace agreements has on the prospects for
fostering a durable peace following the negotiated resolution of civil wars. Focusing on the 16 peace
agreements between 1980 and 1996 that have included provisions for the sharing or dividing of military
power among former combatants, the authors find that the complete implementation of this aspect of
settlements significantly improves the prospects for maintaining peace. They suggest that this proves to
be the case because of the important and credible signals of conciliatory intent among former enemies
that are made through the process of implementation. They find that implementation serves as a con-
crete signal of a genuine commitment to peace as signatories to an agreement prove willing to endure
the costs associated with both compromising their original war aims and withstanding potential chal-
lenges from within their own groups. Based on these results, the authors offer policy recommendations
focusing on the role that third-party actors and aid donors might play in facilitating the successful
implementation of negotiated peace agreements.

Introduction peaceful means (see Mason, Weingarten &


Fett, 1999; Enterline & Balch-Lindsay,
The recent growth in the academic literature
2001), scholars have turned their attention
concerning the resolution of civil wars
to the question of how different aspects of
reflects the international community’s
the settlement process shape the prospects
heightened attention to the challenge of
for a durable peace following the conclusion
establishing negotiated bargains capable of
of civil violence.1
bringing bloody intrastate conflicts to an
In this article, we consider one aspect of
end. Having explored such issues as the con-
the settlement process – the implementation
ditions under which civil war combatants are
of peace agreements. We offer an explanation
most likely to agree to end a conflict through
as to why the implementation of settlements
is crucial for ensuring a durable peace and an
* Thanks to Donald Rothchild for helpful comments. An empirical demonstration of the plausibility
appendix detailing the military power-sharing or power- of our argument based on an examination of
dividing provisions agreed to in each of the cases coded in
the article and assessing the extent to which each provision 16 civil war settlements reached between the
is implemented can be found from a link at: http://www-
polisci.tamu.edu/Hoddie/Index.htm. Authors’ e-mail 1 Recent works concerning civil war settlements include
addresses: Matthew Hoddie: mshoddie@polisci.tamu.edu; Stedman (2001); Stedman, Rothchild & Cousens (2002);
Caroline Hartzell: chartzel@gettysburg.edu. Walter (2002); and Fortna (2002).

303
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 304

304 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

years 1980 and 1996. We find that full environment of pervasive uncertainty and
implementation of settlements is associated distrust among former opponents makes the
with the maintenance of stability within full implementation of settlements a chal-
postwar states because of the effects that this lenging but crucial prerequisite to peace.
process has on the perceptions of former According to this perspective, full implemen-
combatants. By implementing the provisions tation of peace accords proves important
of a peace agreement, signatories engage in because it provides reassurances to wartime
costly signaling regarding their commitment opponents that their partners in the settle-
to the peace, signals that serve to reassure ment process value stability over conflict and
opponents about the prospects for long-term remain committed to the process of estab-
coexistence. lishing a self-enforcing peace.2 This perspec-
The article is divided into four sections. tive highlights the central role that the issue
The first section provides an overview of the of credible commitment plays in the post-
existing literature concerning the implemen- civil war environment. As former opponents
tation of peace agreements and notes some commit to living side by side following the
common limitations associated with these end of war, they require proof that their con-
studies. In the second section, we develop the tributions to settlement stability will not
claim that the full implementation of agree- redound to their detriment in future inter-
ments often proves to be a crucial prerequi- actions with their competitors.3
site to stability because it serves as a means In short, advocates of the full implemen-
for former combatants to signal their com- tation of peace agreements argue that this
mitment to the maintenance of peace. In the process is important because it serves to
third section, we substantiate this perspective convince adversaries that the commitments
regarding the implementation process and its they made to peace in the bargaining stage of
relationship to durable peace through an the settlement process are credible. While we
examination of 16 negotiated settlements. share this outlook, we view the existing
We find that successful efforts to implement literature as deficient in two important
agreement provisions for the sharing or respects – one theoretical and another
dividing of military power are strongly empirical. Our theoretical concern with
associated with peace in the long term. We existing studies is the failure to explain
conclude in the final section with a dis- exactly how the process of settlement
cussion of policy prescriptions that we derive implementation serves to increase confi-
from our findings regarding the importance dence among groups that the intentions of
of costly signaling in civil war settlements. their former adversaries are benign. It
remains uncertain exactly why it proves to be
the case that the process of carrying out the
Existing Studies Concerning the
terms of a settlement produces the credibility
Implementation of Civil War
and trust necessary for a self-sustaining
Settlements
peace.
Most of the academic literature relating to Our second concern regarding the
civil war peace agreement implementation
2 For studies that offer this perspective regarding the
has focused on the anarchic environment in importance of peace agreement implementation, see de
which this process takes place and the chal- Soto & del Castillo (1995); Hampson (1996); Stedman &
lenges this presents for ensuring the main- Rothchild (1996); and Stedman (2001). See also United
States Institute of Peace (1996).
tenance of stability. These works tend toward 3 See Leeds (1999) and Walter (1997, 2002) for more on

the view that an immediate post-civil war the issue of credible commitment.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 305

Ma t t h e w Ho d d i e & Carol i n e Har tz e l l C I V I L WA R S E T T L E M E N T S 305

established literature on peace agreement parties to the dispute have little guarantee
implementation rests on the evidence that that war will not return beyond a faith that
has most often been employed to demon- their former enemies hold a preference for
strate the relationship between this process peace over war. In the absence of evidence
and the durability of peace. For the most that further supports this hope, however,
part, previous studies of peace agreement former combatants are likely to remain wary
implementation have taken the form of and reluctant to support a peace process with
country-specific case studies rather than the potential to leave members of the collec-
cross-national investigations.4 This approach tivity at risk. How might parties genuinely
has provided a wealth of insights regarding interested in ending war move beyond the
the processes of implementation in indi- distrust created by the conflict and establish
vidual states but has inhibited the develop- a self-enforcing peace? The principal way
ment of a generalizable theory about how parties to a negotiated settlement can effec-
this process relates to the durability of peace. tively overcome this distrust, we argue, is by
This study seeks to remedy these two defi- making their commitment to peace apparent
ciencies. We develop a theory of the means and credible to all by sending signals that
by which participation in the implemen- have unavoidable costs attached to them. In
tation process cultivates the credibility of the words of Fearon (1997: 69), this type of
commitments. Negotiating and implement- commitment is only likely to be perceived as
ing peace agreements, we argue, generates credible ‘when the act of sending it incurs or
costs for the parties who participate in the creates some cost that the sender would be
settlement process. By enduring these costs, disinclined to incur or create if he or she were
groups send credible signals to their com- in fact not willing to carry out’ the obligation.
petitors that serve to emphasize the integrity The peace process provides the oppor-
of the commitment they have made to the tunity for settlement participants to send
peace. We then employ a cross-national costly signals demonstrating their genuine
study of 16 states that have had varying levels interest in peace. In particular, two stages of
of success in their efforts to implement their this process provide valuable information
settlements in order to validate our theory regarding the intentions of former enemies:
concerning a relationship between the costly (1) the construction of a peace settlement
signals associated with implementation and (2) the implementation of the settle-
efforts and the successful maintenance of ment. As we demonstrate below, each of
domestic peace in the long term. these stages in the civil war settlement
process exacts high costs from the parties that
engage in them.5 These costs are associated
Signaling to Overcome Security
Concerns: Enduring the Costs of 5 Although we focus on two stages of the civil war settlement

Bargaining and Implementing Peace process, it is more accurate to describe this process as con-
sisting of three stages: (1) the decision regarding whether or
Settlements not to enter into negotiations, (2) settlement construction,
and (3) agreement implementation. Parties have an oppor-
The post-civil war environment is defined by tunity to engage in costly signaling at the initial stage of the
uncertainty. New postwar governing insti- settlement process in the sense that the decision to enter into
discussions with an enemy grants the opposition a degree of
tutions are often embryonic and have yet to recognition. This involves a cost to all war participants by
demonstrate a capacity for resolving conflicts acknowledging competing claims regarding the legitimate
peacefully. Given this unsettled environment, right to govern the state. Agreeing to negotiate may prove
particularly costly if talks collapse without reaching a
4 Notable exceptions include Stedman, Rothchild & mutually acceptable settlement, as it is difficult to withdraw
Cousens (2002) and Walter (2002). recognition once it has been established.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 306

306 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

with a loss of power vis-à-vis a former enemy their capacity unilaterally to shape the
as well as a potential loss of credibility or postwar society.
stature within one’s own group. It is the very In addition to the costs of conceding power
fact that individuals are willing to absorb to rivals for state control, there is also the like-
these unavoidable costs – to engage in costly lihood that with the signing of a power-sharing
signaling – that suggests a genuine commit- settlement a group representative will lose
ment to peace and reassures all parties to the credibility among some members of the collec-
settlement that they will not be the future tivity he or she represents.6 More militant inter-
targets of their domestic competitors. ests resistant to compromise may condemn the
settlement and those involved in its design for
The Costs of Signing a Settlement marginalizing or weakening the group in
One concrete signal of conciliatory intent exchange for the more ambiguous rewards of
among former enemies is generated through peace. In some instances, those most dissatis-
the construction and signing of a peace fied with the power-sharing arrangement may
agreement that outlines the bargains neces- even seek to challenge the continued leadership
sary to end the war. An almost constant of settlement signatories.
feature of these settlements is the mutual Singer’s (1991: 266) discussion of negoti-
commitment to develop power-sharing and ations to resolve the conflict between Sin-
power-dividing institutions that specify the halese and Tamils in Sri Lanka illustrates the
distribution of state influence among breakdown of group unity that often follows
wartime adversaries. In our earlier study of commitment to a power-sharing arrange-
38 civil war agreements signed between 1945 ment. The competition between rival Sin-
and 1998, we found that only one of those halese parties created a dynamic in which
agreements (Angola’s short-lived 1989 compromises with the minority Tamils con-
Gbadolite Accord) failed to include any pro- sistently exacted high political costs for the
visions for sharing or distributing power accommodating faction:
(Hartzell & Hoddie, 2003). the UNP [United National Party] screamed
The unambiguous intent behind the ‘sellout’ when Bandaranaike concluded an
creation of power-sharing and power- agreement with the Tamils giving them a bit
dividing institutions is to limit the capacity of autonomy in Tamil regions; and they did so
again in the early 1970s, when Mrs. Ban-
of any one party to the conflict to dominate
daranaike (who took over the lead of the SLFP
the postwar state and use its advantaged [Sri Lanka Freedom Party] after her husband’s
position to harm the interests or survival of assassination in 1959) tried it. On the other
its rivals. While often considered an hand, Mrs. Bandaranaike and the SLFP have
important precondition to peace, making screamed ‘sellout’ at every effort the UNP
concessions to share or divide power is government has made to reach accommo-
dation with the Tamil since they came to
likely to be particularly painful to signato- power in 1977.
ries. In most cases, the agreement to estab-
lish power-sharing or power-dividing In summary, the costs to a leader in
institutions signals the end of the pursuit of signing on to a settlement are twofold. First,
what is typically (although not universally) there is the cost of conceding the loss of war
the main objective of the war: monopoly aims and the necessity of compromise with
control of the state. By committing them- rivals. Second, there is the likelihood that the
selves to participate in these institutions, very act of agreement will create schisms
signatories are creating a set of rules that 6 Fearon (1994, 1997) has referred to this phenomenon as

will by virtue of their very existence limit audience costs.


49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 307

Ma t t h e w Ho d d i e & Carol i n e Har tz e l l C I V I L WA R S E T T L E M E N T S 307

within parties to the agreement between target of militant interests within one’s own
those who prove more and less amenable to coalition of actors. What sets this stage of the
the compromises that have been reached. peace process apart from the initial negotia-
While the recognition of these costs to tions is that the real costs of the settlement
group representatives makes negotiated become readily apparent to all parties. Any
settlements relatively rare, they are also the ambiguity regarding the price to be paid for
reason that these commitments are often stability becomes quickly clarified, and those
highly credible and significant when reached. costs may prove unacceptable. Stedman &
All sides to the agreement recognize that sig- Rothchild (1996: 20) make this point in the
natories are both limiting their own power following terms:
and potentially creating schisms within their the pay-offs of implementing peace agree-
own faction. These costly signals are likely to ments are not common knowledge: no one
be sent only by those who have a genuine knows for certain the rewards and costs associ-
interest in peace.7 ated with making peace or returning to war.
Many settlements use elections to establish in
part the pay-offs of peace. However, since the
The Costs of Implementing a Settlement winner and loser in an election are not known
The implementation of the provisions of in advance, the players are uncertain about the
recently negotiated peace accords provides pay-offs regarding peace. A party may agree to
former combatants with another oppor- a settlement only in the hope of winning an
tunity to assess whether the intent of former election; if the party loses the election, then it
may prefer a return to war.
rivals is conciliatory or duplicitous. This is
the stage in the process when parties to nego- There is ample anecdotal evidence to
tiations must demonstrate that they are suggest that both the signatories to an agree-
credible partners in sustaining peace by ment as well as their followers may be reluc-
assisting in the creation and maintenance of tant to continue to abide by a settlement’s
power-sharing or power-dividing insti- provisions once the costs associated with a
tutions. Failure to participate in the durable peace have become clarified. The
implementation of peace accords exposes actions of late Union for the Total Indepen-
recalcitrant actors as preferring a return to dence of Angola (UNITA) party leader Jonas
war rather than the outcomes determined at Savimbi following the signing of the Bicesse
the bargaining table. Accords is the commonly cited example of a
Participation in the implementation of leader who in his actions during the
peace accords serves as a powerful indication implementation stage of the peace process
of conciliatory intent in large measure demonstrated a lack of credibility vis-à-vis
because of the costs that parties to a settle- his former adversaries. When it became clear
ment are willing to endure. The costs are the to Savimbi that he was not the popular
same as those associated with signing a settle- choice for president in initial postwar elec-
ment – setting limits on access to state power tions, he chose a return to war rather than
and accepting the possibility of becoming a submit to the loss of personal power that
would have resulted from continued adher-
7 This description of the post-civil war peace process has ence to the agreement’s provisions.
obvious parallels to Putnam’s (1988) claim that inter- Atlas & Licklider (1999: 37) describe the
national diplomacy takes the form of a two-level game in
which negotiators contend with the interests of both a potential for the development of schisms
domestic audience and the other states participating in the among former civil war allies during the
bargaining. Within the context of the postwar state, the
two levels of the game are (1) between former civil war
implementation process in the following
adversaries and (2) within each party to the conflict. terms:
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 308

308 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

post-settlement tensions often arise, not from their access to state power (Hartzell, 1999;
reopening fissures between former foes but Hartzell & Hoddie, 2003).
deepening divisions among former allies. . . . Here we turn our attention to the set of
Certain groups or factions feel that they have
not received their just desserts from the settle- signals of cooperative intent among former
ment or that the terms of the settlement adversaries that takes place with the
threaten their interests or security. This implementation of a peace agreement. As
tension mounts until either the former allies indicated above, we consider this stage of the
resort to violence against one another or the peace process to be important because it is
settlement supporters are forced to change
policy and violate the settlement. with implementation of an agreement that
the ultimate costs of compromise are made
The process Atlas & Licklider identify indi- clear to both signatories and followers.
cates that the costs of accommodation Rather than consider how efforts to imple-
become clear during the implementation of ment all four forms of power-sharing pro-
a peace agreement. Leaders are at greatest risk visions affect the prospects for postwar
of facing challenges from militant members stability, we narrow our focus to considering
of their own group as individuals become the impact of negotiating and implementing
aware and potentially dissatisfied with the only military power-sharing and power-
price of the initial bargain. dividing arrangements.
In this sense, the implementation of a Our rationale for focusing solely on
civil war peace accord provides valuable military arrangements is based on their
information to former combatants. If full central significance to the prospects for peace
implementation takes place, it indicates a in postwar states. Prior to the signing of a
sincere desire for peace as demonstrated by a settlement, a collectivity’s army provides the
willingness to endure both a loss of personal greatest degree of security for a group as well
power and challenges from militant as the most obvious source of leverage vis-
members of the group. à-vis adversaries. In most cases, the
implementation of a military power-sharing
or power-dividing arrangement requires that
An Empirical Test collectivities forgo the capacity to protect
their own interests and instead entrust their
In earlier studies, we demonstrated that security to the newly established institutions
peace agreements are more likely to meet of the postwar state.8 Thus, intense feelings
with success if the settlements include greater of insecurity and resistance are likely to
numbers of provisions for sharing and emerge around this issue, especially if the
dividing power along four possible dimen- implementation of those provisions limits a
sions: the political, military, territorial, and group’s capacity to provide for its own
economic bases of state power. We suggested defense. Centering our analysis on this chal-
that this result obtains because former com- lenging aspect of many peace agreements
batants perceive the inclusion of multiple should provide the clearest indication of how
forms of power-sharing or division within a efforts to implement settlements influence
single agreement as offering mutually the prospects of the maintenance of stability.
reinforcing guarantees of security. In signing
the agreement, parties to the conflict have 8 Among the 16 settlements we consider, only 3 (Azerbai-

signaled their conciliatory intent toward jan, Chechnya, and Georgia–South Ossetia) do not require
any integration of the militaries. Yet even in these 3
their former adversaries through a commit- instances, there is the requirement that the armies cooper-
ment to a set of institutional rules limiting ate in one form or another following the settlement.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 309

Ma t t h e w Ho d d i e & Carol i n e Har tz e l l C I V I L WA R S E T T L E M E N T S 309

Case Selection actors might play a role in the negotiations,


In order to substantiate that a relationship but the antagonists had to meet to discuss
exists between the implementation of conditions relevant to ending the dispute.
military power-sharing arrangements and Finally, 16 of the 24 negotiated civil war
durable peace, we identified all civil war resolutions reached between 1980 and 1996
settlements reached between the years 1980 included provisions for some form of the
and 1996 that specified the establishment of sharing or dividing of military power among
military power-sharing or power-dividing former combatants. We designated an agree-
institutions.9 We selected 1996 as the last ment as including such provisions if it called
year in which settlements could be included for any of the following: (1) creation of the
in the data analysis so that there would be in state’s security forces through the integration
all cases at least five years since the signing of of former antagonists’ armed forces on the
the settlement for efforts at implementation basis of a formula representative of the size
to take place. of the armed groups; (2) creation of the
We identified as civil wars those domestic state’s security forces on the basis of equal
conflicts settled within our specified time- numbers of troops drawn from the antago-
frame that met the four criteria of the Cor- nists’ armed forces; (3) appointment of
relates of War project: (1) the conflict members of armed faction(s) that do not
resulted in at least 1,000 battle deaths per dominate the state, or of weaker armed
year; (2) the national government was one of factions, to key leadership positions in the
the parties to the dispute; (3) there was state’s security forces; and (4) allowing antag-
resistance on the part of both the national onists to retain their own armed forces or to
government and its adversaries during the create their own security forces.
course of the conflict; and (4) the dispute What we seek to demonstrate in this
occurred within a single political unit (Small article is that among these 16 cases, those
& Singer, 1982). Between 1980 and 1996, negotiated settlements that were followed by
37 settled domestic disputes were consistent full implementation of military power-
with these four requirements. sharing or power-dividing provisions were
Among the identified 37 civil wars that more likely to enjoy a durable peace than
ended between 1980 and 1996, a subset of those that failed to implement such pro-
24 of these conflicts concluded via the visions.
process of negotiated settlement.10 We con-
sidered a negotiated settlement to have been Coding
reached if representatives of the opposing
sides to a conflict participated in the direct Dependent Variable: The Maintenance of
talks that led to the agreement. Third-party Peace Our dependent variable is settle-
ment success, defined as the absence of a
9 We chose not to investigate agreements signed prior to recurrence of sustained, violent civil conflict.
1980 because of difficulties with obtaining reliable data on We code settlements that have endured to
the implementation of older peace settlement provisions.
Academic interest and research concerning questions of the present without a return to war as long-
peace agreement implementation has developed only in term successes.11
recent years. For this reason, the more time that has elapsed
since the signing of the agreement, the greater is the like-
lihood that information on implementation processes will
be incomplete or unreliable in nature.
10 Among these civil wars, those that were not resolved 11 Among the civil war settlements included in this study,

through bargaining by 1996 ended with a victory by one none has failed after remaining stable for the first five
party to the conflict. years.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 310

310 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

Independent Variable: Implementation of We defined settlements as fully imple-


Military Power-Sharing or Power-Dividing mented if by the end of the five-year period
Provisions The independent variable is the former combatants had fulfilled all of the
degree to which the military power-sharing military power-sharing and/or power-
and power-dividing arrangements called for dividing requirements outlined in the
in the 16 peace settlements were imple- original agreement. Although efforts at
mented within five years following the demobilization or the creation of joint
signing of the agreement. Our logic for armies may have suffered delays during the
focusing on the initial five-year period five-year period, as long as parties were in
following the settlement is twofold. First, it compliance with the measures by the end of
often takes an extended period of time to that time they were coded as having fully
implement some of the types of measures implemented their agreements regarding the
opposing sides agree to as part of a settle- exercise of military power. The Mozambican
ment. Analyzing implementation efforts for case is instructive in this respect. Mozam-
a period shorter than five years would involve bique’s settlement called for government
the risk of missing genuine efforts on the part troops and Renamo’s rebel forces to integrate
of former adversaries to follow through on in order to form a new national army.
settlement commitments. Second, the value Renamo initially delayed sending students
of implementation as a costly signal of con- for officer training for the new joint army
ciliatory intent is likely to attenuate over and the demobilization of Renamo and
time as peace proves durable. For this reason, government troops was not completed until
implementation efforts following the first nearly two years after the peace agreement
five years should appear less significant than was signed. Ultimately, however, demobiliza-
those that occurred immediately following tion by both groups proved so successful that
the end of the war. in 1995 President Joaquim Chissano
Where possible, we coded implemen- announced that conscription would be
tation of the military agreements on an necessary in order to get the new, integrated
annual basis. By and large, we relied on two Mozambique Democratic Armed Forces up
sources for coding the implementation of to full strength (Military Balance, various
these agreements – the International Insti- years).
tute for Strategic Studies’ yearly publications We designated implementation as partial
Strategic Survey and The Military Balance. in those instances in which all parties to the
These materials were also supplemented with settlement made some effort to follow
case-study materials where possible.12 through on their commitments but failed to
12 Our use of a five-year period of analysis does pose a implement them fully within five years. Two
potential problem for assessing the influence that settle- accords intended to end the civil war in
ment implementation has on peace in those cases in which
agreements specify a period of time (typically less than five
Angola provide examples of partial
years) within which settlement implementation should implementation of military power-sharing
take place. When is implementation of a settlement best provisions. The Bicesse Accords, signed in
assessed? In theory, this issue could best be dealt with by
rating implementation efforts based on whether or not 1991, called for the creation of an army,
they took place within the time period specified by the totaling 40,000 men, which was to be evenly
settlement. The limitation associated with this approach is
that not all settlements indicate the period of time within
divided between government and UNITA
which peace agreement implementation should be troops. Although UNITA did send some of
complete. In the interests of consistency, we have opted to its troops to assembly points to be disarmed
analyze implementation efforts among all cases for the first
five years even when settlements have specified a shorter and demobilized, tens of thousands of guer-
period of time for this stage of the peace process. rillas and their arms were concealed in
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 311

Ma t t h e w Ho d d i e & Carol i n e Har tz e l l C I V I L WA R S E T T L E M E N T S 311

remote areas. By the time elections were held agreed to may end up signaling something
in September 1992, only 45% of govern- different all together – a marked lack of com-
ment troops had been demobilized and 24% mitment to the settlement in whose con-
of the forces assembled by UNITA had given struction they have participated.
up their weapons. Angola’s Lusaka Protocol, Table I summarizes our assessment of the
signed in 1994, also called for the creation of level of success at implementing the military
a unified national army, this time with a power-sharing or power-dividing bargains
strength of approximately 90,000 troops. specified in the 16 settlements; the narratives
Although the integration process was for each case provided in the appendix briefly
deemed to have concluded in 1998 and outline the basis for the individual coding
UNITA claimed at that time to have com- decisions.13 There is a relatively good distri-
pleted the demobilization process, UNITA bution of implementation successes and
was reported to have 25–30,000 fully failures among the 16 negotiated civil war
equipped troops that had not been demobil- agreements that required military power-
ized (Strategic Survey and Military Balance, sharing among former combatants. We find
various years). that four states failed to implement these
Finally, we defined settlement implemen- provisions, another four only partially ful-
tation as failed in those cases in which either filled their commitments, and eight states
some or all of the parties refused to live up fully implemented their plans for the sharing
to their commitments or no forward or dividing of military power.
momentum took place regarding the
measures to be implemented. The Cam- Method
bodian settlement constitutes a case of failed Prior studies of civil war settlement
implementation of military measures. The implementation typically have taken the
Paris Agreement, signed in 1991, called for form of detailed descriptions of the postwar
the regroupment, cantonment, and disarma- politics of a particular state.14 This article
ment of at least 70% of the forces of each of seeks to build on earlier case studies through
the four warring factions – the Communist a systematic, cross-national examination of
Cambodian government, the forces under the effect that implementation of military
Son Sann, Sihanouk’s forces, and the Khmer power-sharing and power-dividing arrange-
Rouge – with the remaining 30% to be ments have on settlement stability. By
incorporated into a new national army. considering the effects of settlement
Although the Phnom Penh government and implementation in multiple states, we seek
the two non-communist factions cooperated to identify common patterns in the peace
to some extent in this operation, the Khmer process that might not prove readily
Rouge refused to regroup and disarm its apparent when concentrating on the specifics
forces (Strategic Survey, various years). associated with a single state’s efforts to tran-
Based on these criteria, we assess groups sition from civil war to stable polity.
that fully implement the military measures A dilemma that we confronted in
to which they have agreed as having engaged 13 The narratives provided in the appendix (available from

in the most costly form of signaling regard- a link at http://www-polisci.tamu.edu/Hoddie/Index.htm)


briefly describe the provisions of the settlement specifying
ing their commitment to the negotiated the sharing or dividing of military power as well as post-
settlement. Groups that partially implement settlement efforts at implementation.
14 See, for example, the case studies in the edited volumes
the military agreements signal a lower degree
by Walter & Snyder (1999), Cousens, Kumar & Wer-
of commitment to the settlement, while mester (2001), and Stedman, Rothchild & Cousens
groups that fail to implement the terms (2002).
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 312

312 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

Table I. Assessment of Implementation Efforts Among the 16 Peace Settlements Reached Between 1980
and 1996 that Included Provisions for the Sharing or Dividing of Military Power

Conflict settled Assessment of implementation* Settlement outcome

Angola, 1989–91 Partial Return to war


Angola, 1992–94 Partial Return to war
Azerbaijan, 1989–94 Failed Maintenance of peace
Bosnia, 1992–95 Complete Maintenance of peace
Cambodia, 1970–91 Failed Maintenance of peace
Chad, 1989–96 Partial Maintenance of peace
Chechnya, 1994–96 Complete Return to war
El Salvador, 1979–92 Complete Maintenance of peace
Georgia–SO, 1989–92 Complete Maintenance of peace
Lebanon, 1975–89 Partial Maintenance of peace
Mozambique, 1982–92 Complete Maintenance of peace
Nicaragua, 1981–89 Complete Maintenance of peace
Philippines, 1972–96 Complete Maintenance of peace
Rwanda, 1990–93 Failed Return to war
Sierra Leone, 1992–96 Failed Return to war
South Africa, 1983–91 Complete Maintenance of peace
* Within five years.

developing this study is the relatively small influence of other potentially important vari-
number of instances in which a negotiated ables.16 This limitation is apparent in this
settlement to civil war included a military study as we are unable to control for the
power-sharing or power-dividing arrange- effects of other factors likely to influence the
ment. That there are only 16 cases in the prospects for a durable peace following civil
time-frame we examine means that we war such as the intensity of the conflict prior
cannot employ a statistical methodology to to settlement, the potential participation of
demonstrate the relationship between third-party actors in maintaining stability, or
implementation and the maintenance of even the effects of efforts at implementing
peace. We instead rely on a form of analysis other aspects of the peace agreement not
described by both Lijphart (1971, 1975) and associated with military power-sharing. It is
Smelser (1973) as appropriate for the study because of this absence of statistical controls
of small datasets: the comparative method. that this study’s findings should be inter-
In contrast to individual case studies’ preted as only suggestive of a relationship
attention to detail, the comparative method between variables.
shares with statistical methodologies a
concern with identifying causal patterns Findings
between variables (Lijphart, 1971, 1975; We present our findings employing the com-
Smelser, 1973; Jackman, 1985).15 A chief parative method in Table II. The table
weakness of the comparative method relative suggests a strong relationship between
to more sophisticated approaches is the 16 In the words of Lijphart (1971: 684), ‘The comparative
inability to control statistically for the method should be resorted to when the number of cases
available for analysis is so small that cross-tabulating them
15 For a discussion of the value of the case-study approach further in order to establish credible controls is not
as a means for testing the validity of theories, see Eckstein feasible.’ Also see Lieberson (1991) for a discussion of other
(1975) and King, Keohane & Verba (1994). problems associated with the comparative method.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 313

Ma t t h e w Ho d d i e & Carol i n e Har tz e l l C I V I L WA R S E T T L E M E N T S 313

Table II. Level of Implementation of Military Power-Sharing or Power-Dividing Provisions and the
Maintenance of the Peace

Level of implementation Return to war Peace Total

None 2 2 4
(50%) (50%) (100%)
Partial 2 2 4
(50%) (50%) (100%)
Complete 1 7 8
(12.5%) (87.5%) (100%)
Total 5 11 16

successful efforts at implementation of an isms maintaining stable intergroup relations.


agreement’s military power-sharing or This stands in significant contrast to those
power-dividing provisions and the mainten- instances in which former combatants prove
ance of peace. In those eight instances in unwilling to fulfill their commitments to
which former combatants either reneged on share the coercive instruments of the state,
their commitments or only partially fulfilled with only half of those states continuing to
expectations, there was an eventual return to enjoy peace.
war in exactly half of the cases. In contrast, We interpret this finding as demonstrat-
the peace proved durable in seven of the ing the importance of the costly and credible
eight cases (87.5%) in which post-civil war signals that may be made by parties to the
states with agreements requiring military conflict during the different stages of the
measures fully implemented this aspect of peace process. The act of simply agreeing to
the settlement. In only one of these eight a peace settlement is an important first signal
cases (12.5%) did the country experience a of conciliatory intent demonstrating that all
return to civil war.17 signatories have a genuine interest in peace.
This distribution among cases suggests This is indicated by the willingness of agree-
that once an agreement has been reached ment participants to limit the scope of their
requiring the sharing or dividing of military own power and endure the challenges of
power between former combatants, the critics within the group that inevitably
prospects for continuing stability are emerge with efforts at compromise.
enhanced by faithful implementation of the Implementation of the agreement serves
arrangement. Peace proves much more as the second significant costly signal of
durable if groups make good on the promises conciliatory intent. Former combatants
made at the negotiating table, with almost all monitor the behavior of their adversaries for
states that have implemented military evidence that, once the costs necessary to
power-sharing or power-dividing mechan- endure for a successful compromise have
been clarified for both leaders and followers,
17 The single instance of the return to conflict following signatories are still committed to stability
implementation of military power-sharing occurred in and peaceful coexistence. Evidence of a
Chechnya. Chechnya stands out as a case in which the
military arrangements required by the settlement were
failure to act in a manner consistent with the
particularly limited, including joint Russian–Chechen agreement’s provisions increases the likeli-
patrols and checkpoints manned by the opposing sides. hood that individuals will lose faith in the
The fact that these operations did not require substantial
efforts by the warring parties may have limited their value good intentions of their competitors and
as signals of a commitment to peace. will opt for a return to conflict. This option
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 314

314 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

often proves preferable to having coopera- progress and facilitate communication


tive actions abused for advantage by an among parties may play a critical role in
unreliable partner to the settlement.18 helping to stabilize the peace. If, for example,
Our findings do raise a question for which members of the international community are
our test of the theory regarding costly sig- able to convince one group of former
naling, credible commitments, and durable combatants that the other truly is making a
peace does not provide a ready answer: Why good-faith effort to implement settlement
did half of the cases that did not see full provisions, an enduring peace may yet be
implementation of the military provisions fostered.
agreed to as part of the settlement succeed in
maintaining the peace? One possible answer
Peace Processes as Signals of
to this question pertains to those cases that
Conciliatory Intent: Policy
were partially implemented. In at least some
Recommendations for
of these cases, actors may have believed that
Implementation Success
the failure to implement provisions fully was
the result of resource constraints, lack of Informed by the view that the carrying out
technical expertise, or other related factors of a civil war settlement’s provisions is
that do not reflect a lack of will to implement important to the sustainability of peace, in
the provisions on the part of the participants. this section of the article we consider factors
If some parties to a settlement have reason to that may improve the prospects for success-
believe that others are engaging in costly sig- ful agreement implementation. In particular,
naling through their implementation efforts we focus on two conditions that may
but are, for reasons outside of their control, enhance the likelihood of effective agree-
falling short on implementation, the former ment implementation: (1) the presence of
may be reassured enough to give peace a third-party actors within the post-conflict
chance. It is precisely in these types of cases state and (2) a high level of economic
that adequate access to resources and the development in the state undergoing the
presence of third parties able to monitor transition from war to peace.
18 We considered the possibility that the relationship we
These factors have been previously
identify between the implementation of civil war settle- identified as improving the prospects for
ments and the maintenance of peace is spurious. One both agreement implementation and peace
factor that may condition both implementation and peace
is the casualty rate of the conflict the settlement is designed maintenance in the works of other scholars
to resolve. The relatively benign environments associated interested in the politics of post-civil war
with wars of low intensity might make former combatants states. This section’s discussion is intended to
predisposed toward genuine implementation efforts and a
willingness to allow the nascent peace to endure unchal- acknowledge the potential importance of
lenged. The existing literature on the durability of civil war these factors to both the implementation of
settlements has demonstrated that a relationship between
higher casualty rates and settlement failure exists (Hartzell, peace agreements and the peace process more
Hoddie & Rothchild, 2001). Do higher casualty rates also generally despite the fact that our use of the
dim the prospects for settlement implementation? Our comparative method precluded their inclu-
analysis of the 16 cases included in this study suggests that
this is not the case. Among the eight settlements of con- sion as statistical controls in our empirical
flicts with casualty rates below the median value for this investigation. Because we view the peace
indicator, only three (37.5%) fully implemented their
settlements; for the remaining eight settlements of conflicts
process as taking the form of signals between
with casualty rates above the median value, five (62.5%) former combatants, our understanding of
fully implemented their agreements. This suggests that how these two factors may condition settle-
while more benign environments may be conducive toward
maintaining the peace, they do not appear to have a similar ment success necessarily diverges in import-
effect on the likelihood of implementation. ant ways from those of earlier studies.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 315

Ma t t h e w Ho d d i e & Carol i n e Har tz e l l C I V I L WA R S E T T L E M E N T S 315

Anarchy, Third-Party Actors, and former adversaries that limit their willingness
Agreement Implementation to carry out intrastate conflict settlements,
In many states experiencing civil war, central many scholars advocate a prominent, facili-
authority weakens to the point that the tating role for third parties during the
domestic environment approximates the implementation process (Walter, 1997,
anarchy that defines the international 1999, 2002; Stedman, 1997). The presence
system. Based largely on this insight, the of a third-party actor, whether representing
growing body of research that exists on civil an international organization or state, is
wars and their resolution has borrowed a believed to have the effect of restoring order
number of concepts from the international to the anarchic domestic environment and
relations literature, including the security guaranteeing that the agreements made at
dilemma, credible commitments, and the the bargaining table will be carried out
role of imperfect information (see, for without harming the interests of any of the
example, Hartzell, 1999; Posen, 1993; and parties involved. In short, the presence of a
Walter, 1997, 2002). These conditions, it is third-party actor creates the security that is a
assumed, pose many of the same challenges prerequisite to implementation success.
for domestic groups implementing civil war Consistent with this article’s emphasis on
settlements as they do for states seeking to post-civil war military arrangements, Walter
carry out international agreements. (1999: 46, emphasis added) discusses the
Civil war combatants that negotiate a role of external actors in minimizing the
resolution to civil war must also contend potential for cheating during the disarma-
with two distinct dilemmas that emerge with ment and demobilization of soldiers:
the signing of an agreement within a state. Third parties can verify compliance with the
These are additional hurdles to settlement terms of demobilization and warn of a surprise
implementation that are unlikely to affect attack, they can guarantee that soldiers will be
the prospects for carrying out international protected as they demobilize, and they can
become involved if one or both sides resume
agreements. As Walter (1999) observes,
the war. Third parties can thus ensure that the
former enemies are required to (1) live payoffs from cheating no longer exceed the payoffs
within the same territory as their former from faithfully executing the settlement’s terms.
enemies and (2) divest themselves of all Once cheating becomes difficult and costly,
means of self-defense.19 The heightened promises to cooperate should gain credibility
security concerns generated by these two and cooperation should become more likely.
challenges in the domestic settlement In a similar vein, Stedman (1997) outlines
environment have led most scholars to a set of three strategies (inducement, social-
conclude that the prospects for successful ization, and coercion) that third parties
settlement implementation are limited if might deploy in order to manage and control
former combatants are left to their own spoilers seeking to derail progress toward
devices. peace once a settlement has been reached. In
Recognizing that the civil war environ- this sense, both Walter and Stedman are sug-
ment generates particular concerns among gesting that during the implementation stage
19 As noted earlier in this article, negotiated civil war settle-
of the agreement third-party actors are most
ments have not always required former combatants to effectively deployed as enforcers of the agree-
divest themselves of all means of self-defense. In rare cases, ment. Their role is not only to identify
settlements have allowed combatants to keep their security potential spoilers to an agreement but also to
forces or to create new security forces under their own
control. We code these as instances of military power- impose high costs on settlement violators so
dividing measures. that they have no choice but to return to
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 316

316 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

behaviors consistent with the original com- Because actions with the potential to serve
promise.20 as signals of conciliatory behavior are likely
We share Walter and Stedman’s view that to be discounted if they are perceived as a
third-party actors have a potentially import- reaction to the demands of a third-party
ant role to play in facilitating agreement enforcer, the establishing of trust among
implementation. Yet our perspective diverges former combatants becomes less probable
from that offered in their studies in two and peace may prove less durable once the
respects. First, we think it is significant to external actor leaves the scene. In this sense,
note that there are instances in which a nego- we believe that the most appropriate role for
tiated accord has been implemented and third-party actors is simply that of an inter-
peace has endured even in the absence of mediary between former combatants that
third-party enforcement. Examples of such communicates its findings as it monitors and
successes considered in this study include the verifies progress toward implementation.21
resolved conflicts in both South Africa and Indications that a third party has the inten-
the Philippines. This suggests that the tion of enforcing an agreement mean that
absence of third-party enforcement is not the value of the signal that comes with
consistently the crucial prerequisite to the implementation is lost.22
establishing and maintenance of peace.
Second, given our understanding of peace Levels of Development and Agreement
processes as taking the form of a set of signals Implementation
between former adversaries, we consider it In a study of the resolution of post-World
problematic to have third-party actors War II civil wars, Doyle & Sambanis (2000)
defend the agreement against spoilers. Our find a positive association between higher
concern with this policy prescription is that levels of economic development and the
it has the potential to mask the intentions maintenance of peace. The reasons Doyle &
behind the actions of parties to the agree- Sambanis (2000: 785) believe that this
ment. In other words, the presence of a third- association exists are most plainly stated as a
party force acting as agreement enforcer will hypothesis: ‘More developed economies with
often mean that parties to the settlement will lower levels of poverty should be both better
not have the opportunity to assess whether able to rebuild after war and less susceptible
behavior consistent with the signed agree- to wars stemming from economic grievance.’
ment is based on a genuine desire for peace This article’s perspective on peace pro-
or simply expedient behavior intended to cesses taking the form of mutual signals of
placate the interested third parties. conciliatory intent offers a different expla-
nation for why more economically developed
20 Walter (2002: 24–26) specifically discounts the role that states emerging from bargained settlements
costly signals made between former adversaries may play in
resolving civil conflicts, suggesting instead that third-party to civil war may enjoy greater success in
enforcers provide the most assured path to peace. Her skep- maintaining peace. The financial resources of
ticism about the value of signals made between former
adversaries is largely based on a belief that groups have a 21 This view regarding the role of third-party actors as

limited capacity to monitor and verify settlement compli- monitoring rather than forcing compliance is articulated in
ance by their competitors. Yet it seems unwarranted to Stedman & Rothchild (1996).
suggest that costly signals between former adversaries and 22 We are suggesting that third parties limit their actions to

the efforts of third-party enforcers are mutually exclusive observers of agreement implementation, but this would
mechanisms for encouraging stability in states emerging not prohibit them from taking a more active role and inter-
from civil war. Third-party actors may serve a valuable vening if parties engaged in large-scale acts of violence.
function as their efforts to monitor and verify implemen- Once mass violence has emerged, the issue of whether
tation efforts amplify the costly signals made at this stage costly signals of conciliatory intent have been made by
of the process. parties to the agreement is obviously no longer relevant.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 317

Ma t t h e w Ho d d i e & Carol i n e Har tz e l l C I V I L WA R S E T T L E M E N T S 317

Figure 1. Postwar Life Expectancy and Implementation of Military Power-Sharing or Power-Dividing


Provisions to Civil War Settlements

72.55 GSO89-92

LEB75-89

PHI72-96
CHE94-96
ELS79-92
AZB90-94 BOS92-95
Postwar Life Expectancy

SAF83-91

NIC81-89

CAM70-91

ANG92-94
ANG89-91
CHD89-96
MOZ82-92

SAL92-96

RWA90-93
34.7
0 Degree of implementation 1
Key to data points: Cases of failed implementation – Rwanda (RWA90-93), Sierra Leone (SAL92-96), Cambodia (CAM70-91), and
Azerbaijan (AZB90-94). Cases of partial implementation – Chad (CHD89-96), Angola (ANG89-91), Angola (ANG92-94), and
Lebanon (LEB75-89). Cases of full implementation – Mozambique (MOZ82-92), Nicaragua (NIC81-89), South Africa (SAF83-91),
Bosnia (BOS92-95), El Salvador (ELS79-92), Chechnya (CHE94-96), Philippines (PHI72-96), Georgia, South Ossetia (GSO89-92).

wealthier states give the participants in peace processes within countries with greater levels
processes of those countries a greater capacity of wealth often have an advantaged ability to
to implement the programs first outlined in offer the conciliatory signals associated with
peace settlements. De Soto & del Castillo faithful agreement implementation that tend
(1994) note that the costs of implementing to foster a durable peace.
a peace settlement can often prove over- Figure 1 offers support for the claim that
whelming to a developing state. De Soto & higher levels of economic development are
del Castillo (1994: 72) calculate the costs for associated with a greater capacity to imple-
implementing the Salvadoran accords for a ment the military power-sharing or dividing
single year in the following terms: aspects of settlements. Using life expectancy
following the end of the war as a proxy
For 1993 alone, El Salvador needed about
$250 million to reintegrate ex-combatants measure of development, the figure indicates
into society (through purchase of land, agri- that among the 16 cases with settlement pro-
cultural credit, housing, credit for small enter- visions for the sharing or dividing of military
prises, pensions for the disabled, etc.) and to power there is an approximate relationship
promote democratic institutions (National between economic development and
Civil Police, National Public Security
Academy, human-rights activities, and activi-
implementation success.23 Most strikingly,
ties related to the coming elections).
23 Data for postwar life expectancy collected from the

This suggests that countries need substantial Doyle & Sambanis (2000) dataset used in their article
‘International Peacebuilding: A Theoretical and Quantita-
financial resources to implement peace tive Analysis’. Data available at http://www.worldbank.
settlements. As a result, participants in peace org/research/conflict/papers/peacebuilding/.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 318

318 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

the figure demonstrates that two of the four implementation has on settlement durability.
cases of complete implementation failure are Although case studies of agreement
among the poorest states included in our implementation have helped to identify
dataset: Rwanda and Sierra Leone. particular characteristics of the implemen-
Because signals of conciliation associated tation process as well as challenges associated
with agreement implementation are often with fulfilling settlement obligations, this
costly, states undergoing the transition from literature has yet to develop generalizable
civil conflict to peace should have ready theories regarding the peace process. The
access to international assistance that would findings of this study suggest that future
facilitate their meeting the expectations cross-national research should prove a
outlined in the settlement. Without such valuable enterprise in efforts to further
assistance, the failure to carry out settlement develop theories concerning the peaceful and
provisions as a result of resource scarcity durable resolution of civil wars.
carries the risk of being misperceived as an
act of bad faith by former adversaries and has
the potential to reignite hostilities. References
Atlas, Pierre M. & Roy Licklider, 1999. ‘Conflict
Conclusions Among Former Allies After Civil War Settle-
ments: Sudan, Zimbabwe, Chad, and
This article offers two contributions to the Lebanon’, Journal of Peace Research 36(1):
growing literature on the processes associated 35–54.
with the resolution of civil wars. First, this Cousens, Elizabeth M.; Chetan Kumar & Karin
study develops a theory to explain why settle- Wermester, eds, 2001. Peacebuilding as
ment implementation is important for Politics: Cultivating Peace in Fragile Societies.
building an enduring peace in states Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
de Soto, Alvaro & Graciana del Castillo, 1994.
emerging from violent civil conflict via nego-
‘Obstacles to Peacebuilding’, Foreign Policy 94
tiated settlement. By implementing the pro-
(Spring): 69–74.
visions of an agreement, leaders of the de Soto, Alvaro & Graciana del Castillo, 1995.
compromising groups are unambiguously ‘Implementation of Comprehensive Peace
signaling their genuine commitment to Agreements: Staying the Course in El
peace. These signals are understood to be Salvador’, Global Governance 1(2): 189–203.
credible because they are associated with Doyle, Michael W. & Nicholas Sambanis, 2000.
heavy costs to the implementing parties in ‘International Peacebuilding: A Theoretical
terms of both an immediate loss of political and Quantitative Analysis’, American Political
power vis-à-vis their competitors in the war Science Review 94(4): 779–801.
and the likely loss of support among the Eckstein, Harry, 1975. ‘Case Study and Theory
more militant members of their own groups. in Political Science’, in Fred I. Greenstein &
Nelson W. Polsby, eds, Handbook of Political
We believe that it is the willingness to endure
Science, Volume 1, Political Science Scope and
these costs in an effort to demonstrate a Theory. Reading, MA: Addison Wesley
preference for stability that allows former (79–138).
antagonists to surmount security concerns Enterline, Andrew J. & Dylan Balch-Lindsay,
and move toward a self-sustaining peace. 2001. ‘By Sword or by Signature? A Compet-
A second contribution of this study ing Risks Approach to the Civil War Process,
concerns its methodology. This article is 1820–1992’, available at http://www.psci.
among a very few to undertake a systematic, unt.edu/enterline/Working%20Papers/BySw
cross-national examination of the effect that ordOrBySignature.pdf.
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 319

Ma t t h e w Ho d d i e & Carol i n e Har tz e l l C I V I L WA R S E T T L E M E N T S 319

Fearon, James D., 1994. ‘Signaling Versus the ing in Comparative Studies Based on a Small
Balance of Power and Interests: An Empirical Number of Cases’, Social Forces 70(2):
Test of a Crisis Bargaining Model’, Journal of 307–320.
Conflict Resolution 38(2): 236–269. Lijphart, Arend, 1971. ‘Comparative Politics and
Fearon, James D., 1997. ‘Signaling Foreign Policy the Comparative Method’, American Political
Interests: Tying Hands Versus Sinking Science Review 65(3): 682–698.
Costs’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 41(1): Lijphart, Arend, 1975. ‘The Comparable-Cases
68–90. Strategy in Comparative Research’, Compara-
Fortna, Page, 2002. ‘Does Peacekeeping Keep tive Political Studies 8(2): 158–177.
Peace? And If So, How?’, paper presented at Mason, T. David; Joseph P. Weingarten, Jr. &
the American Political Science Association Patrick J. Fett, 1999. ‘Win, Lose, or Draw:
Annual Meeting, Boston, MA, 29 August–1 Predicting the Outcome of Civil Wars’,
September. Political Research Quarterly 52(2): 239–268.
Hampson, Fen Osler, 1996. Nurturing Peace: Why Posen, Barry, 1993. ‘The Security Dilemma and
Peace Settlements Succeed or Fail. Washington, Ethnic Conflict’, Survival 35(1): 27–47.
DC: United States Institute of Peace Press. Putnam, Robert, 1988. ‘Diplomacy and
Hartzell, Caroline A., 1999. ‘Explaining the Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level
Stability of Negotiated Settlements to Games’, International Organization 42(3):
Intrastate Wars’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 427–460.
43(1): 3-22. Singer, Marshall R., 1991. ‘Prospects for Conflict
Hartzell, Caroline & Matthew Hoddie, 2003. Management in the Sri Lankan Ethnic Crisis’,
‘Institutionalizing Peace: Power Sharing and in Joseph V. Montville, ed., Conflict and Peace-
Post-Civil War Conflict Management’, making in Multiethnic Societies. New York:
American Journal of Political Science 47(2): Lexington (259–286).
318–332. Small, Melvin & J. David Singer, 1982. Resort to
Hartzell, Caroline; Matthew Hoddie & Donald Arms: International and Civil Wars,
Rothchild, 2001. ‘Stabilizing the Peace After 1816–1980. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Civil War: An Investigation of Some Key Vari- Smelser, Neil, 1973. ‘The Methodology of Com-
ables’, International Organization 55(1): parative Analysis’, in Donald Warwich &
183–208. Samuel Osherson, eds, Comparative Research
International Institute for Strategic Studies. The Methods. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall
Military Balance, annual editions. London: (42–86).
IISS. Stedman, Stephen John, 1997. ‘Spoiler Problems
International Institute for Strategic Studies. in Peace Processes’, International Security
Strategic Survey, annual editions. London: 22(2): 5–53.
IISS. Stedman, Stephen John, 2001. ‘International
Jackman, Robert W., 1985. ‘Cross-National Implementation of Peace Agreements in Civil
Statistical Research and the Study of Com- Wars: Findings from a Study of Sixteen Cases’,
parative Politics’, American Journal of Political in Chester A. Crocker, Fen Osler Hampson &
Science 29(1): 161–182. Pamela Aall, eds, Turbulent Peace: The Chal-
King, Gary; Robert O. Keohane & Sidney Verba, lenges of Managing International Conflict.
1994. Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Infer- Washington, DC: United States Institute of
ence in Qualitative Research. Princeton, NJ: Peace Press (737–752).
Princeton University Press. Stedman, Stephen John & Donald Rothchild,
Leeds, Brett Ashley, 1999. ‘Domestic Political 1996. ‘Peace Operations: From Short-Term to
Institutions, Credible Commitments, and Long-Term Commitment’, International
International Cooperation’, American Journal Peacekeeping 3(2): 17–35.
of Political Science 43(4): 979–1002. Stedman, Stephen John; Donald Rothchild &
Lieberson, Stanley, 1991. ‘Small N’s and Big Elizabeth M. Cousens, eds, 2002. Ending
Conclusions: An Examination of the Reason- Civil Wars: The Implementation of Peace
49Q 04hoddie (ds) 27/3/03 2:46 pm Page 320

320 j ou r n a l o f P E A C E R E S E A RC H volume 40 / number 3 / may 2003

Agreements. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner & MATTHEW HODDIE, b. 1969, PhD in
International Peace Academy. Political Science (University of California,
United States Institute of Peace, 1996. ‘Why Davis, 2000); Assistant Professor, Texas A&M
Peace Agreements Succeed or Fail’, PeaceWatch University (2001– ). Recent articles in Inter-
3(1): 1. national Organization, Political Studies, and
Walter, Barbara, 1997. ‘The Critical Barrier to American Journal of Political Science.
Civil War Settlement’, International Organiz-
ation 51(3): 335–364.
Walter, Barbara, 1999. ‘Designing Transitions CAROLINE HARTZELL, b. 1962, PhD in
from Civil War’, in Barbara Walter & Jack Political Science (University of California,
Snyder, eds, Civil Wars, Insecurity, and Inter- Davis, 1994); Associate Professor, Gettysburg
vention. New York: Columbia University Press College (1993– ). Recent articles in Journal of
(38–69). Conflict Resolution, International Organiz-
Walter, Barbara. 2002. Committing to Peace: The ation, and American Journal of Political Science.
Successful Settlement of Civil Wars. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Walter, Barbara & Jack Snyder, eds, 1999. Civil
Wars, Insecurity, and Intervention. New York:
Columbia University Press.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen