Sie sind auf Seite 1von 24

Urban Studies, Vol. 33, N o.

8, 1407± 1430, 1996

Social Polarisation, Econom ic Restructuring and


W elfare State Regimes

Chris H amnett

[Paper received in ® nal form , March 1996]

Sum m ary. T he central argu m ent of this paper is that it is miscon ceived to view social polaris-
ation of occu pation al stru cture and incom es in glob al cities as eith er inevitab le or as a direct
prod uct of econom ic restruc turing. It is argu ed that this neglects the key role of differen t welfare
state stru ctures which can and do in¯ uence both occup ation al and incom e stru ctures indepen-
dently of the processes of econ omic restru cturing. T he form and exten t of polarisat ion in different
cities are likely to re¯ ect the nature and form of w elfare state regim es in differen t cou ntries as
w ell as the form of econ om ic restru cturing and other factors such as the scale of im m igration .
Evidence from London suggests that grow ing incom e polarisat ion is accom panied by a profes-
sion alisatio n of the occu pation al stru cture.

Introduction
In recent years, the concepts of social polar- relatively and possibly absolute ly, at the ex-
isation and duality have becom e the conve n- pense of the middle. This is the dominant
tional wisdom regarding the changing social interpretation and re¯ ects the concerns of a
structure of major cities in W estern capitalist num ber of com mentators (Harrison and
countries. Although the precise de® nitions of Bluestone, 1988; Kuttner, 1983; Lawrence,
polarisation vary (M arcuse, 1989; Pahl, 1984; Levy, 1987). M arcuse (1989, p. 699)
1988; Pinch, 1993), it is widely accepted that put it well:
major cities are increasingly being divided
into a grow ing highly skilled and highly paid The best im age¼ is perhaps that of the egg
upper stratum and a grow ing low-skilled, and the hour glass: the populat ion of the
low -incom e stratum with a high proportion city is norm ally distribu ted like an egg,
of ethnic minority groups . The middle social widest in the middle and tapering off at
stratum is declining, both absolutely and both ends; when it becomes polarized the
relatively. Thus, pola risation is a term refer- middle is squeezed and the ends expand
ring to a change in certain social distribu tions till it looks like an hour glass. The middle
such that there is a shift away from a statisti- of the egg may be de® ned as intermediate
cally norm al or egg-shaped distribu tion to- social strata¼ Or if the polarization is be-
wards a distribu tion where the bottom and tw een rich and poor, the middle of the egg
top ends of the distribu tion are grow ing, refers to the middle incom e group¼ The
Chris Ham nett is in the Department of Geography, King’ s College London, Strand, London WC2R 2LS, UK. Fax: 0171-873-2612.
E-mail: C.H AMNETT@ KCL.ac.uk. The author wishes to thank the many individuals at seminars in the Departments of Geography
at Birkbeck College, the London School of Economics, and Shef® eld, Edinburgh and Loughborough Universities as well as colleagues
at the 1995 ESF Conference on the Future of European Cities, the London Seminar, and the 1995 Urban Change and Con¯ ict
Conference who made many perceptive and critical comments on earlier versions of this paper. He doubts that this version w ill entirely
satisfy them.

0042-0980/96/081407-24 $6.00 Ó 1996 The Editors of Urban Studies


1408 CH RIS H AM N ETT

metaphor is not structural dividin g lines, utility, it can serve only as a hypothe sis,
but of a continuum , whose distribu tion is the prelude to empirical analysis, rather
becom ing increasingly bi-m odal. than as a conclusion which takes the exist-
ence of con® rmatory evide nce for granted.
M ollenkopf and Castells (1991, p. 406)
also note that the dual city notion: ª usefully Secondly, and follow ing from this, I wish to
emphasises one trendÐ both the uppe r and dispute the way in which the concept of
the low er strata of a given society grow at social polarisation and the associated concept
disprop ortionate ratesº . of the dual city is com monly used as a
The purpose of this paper is to outline and general, all-purpose signi® er of grow ing in-
challenge the dom inant theory of urban so- equality and social divisio ns. W hile I accept
cial pola risation. It is not disputed that in that social polarisation has an im portant rep-
recent years a num ber of major cities have resentational, ideologica l and rhetorical role
experienced grow ing incom e inequa lity in regarding grow ing social divisio ns in cities
that the gap between the average incom es of (Beauregard, 1993; M ollenko pf and Castells,
the rich and poor has widened, nor is it 1991), there is a parallel danger that, by
disputed that, in many cases, the incomes of uncritically accepting the existence of social
the low est deciles have actually fallen in real pola risation as some sort of general, catch-all
terms whilst those of the highest deciles have process, we may fail to see the existence of
risen substantially. It is accepted that the different form s of polarisation in different
num ber of individu als and households at cities. Social polarisation is not a single ,
both the bottom and top ends of the incom e hom ogeneous, process which operates in the
distribu tion have grow n considerably over same way in different places.
the last decade in many capitalist countries Thirdly, and perhaps most im porta ntly,
(Atkinson, 1993; Jenkins and Cow ell, 1994; there is the danger that, by uncritically ac-
Stark, 1992; Gardiner, 1993; Hills, 1995), cepting the conve ntional wisdom , we may
and that this trend has been parallelled by the fail to realise that the forces driving polaris-
grow th of unem ploym ent and greater insecu- ation in different cities differ or are mediated
rity in the labour market (Burgers, 1996). in various ways.
W hat I do wish to dispute are three things. It is thus necessary conceptually to unpac k
The ® rst is that the existence of social polar- the term polarisation and to examine the
isation is often simply taken for granted. It extent to which different form s of polaris-
has becom e the conve ntiona l wisdom regard- ation are found in different contexts and to
ing social division s in W estern capitalist cit- theorise the reasons for such variations.
ies. But we should not fall into the trap of Otherwise we risk becom ing slaves to unex-
uncritically accepting the existence of polar- amined, im precise or ill-de® ned concepts. As
isation as a dem onstrable fact of contem por- M ollenkopf and Castells (1991, p. 405) point
ary urban life, as som e com mentators tend to out:
assum e. As Fainstein et al. (1993, p. 13) The dual city is a useful ideologica l notion
pointed out: because it aims to denoun ce inequality,
The im ages of a dual or polarised city are exploita tion, and oppre ssion in cities. But
seductive, they prom ise to encapsulate the its underlying assumptions are rarely made
outc ome of a wide variety of com plex explic it, because those who employ it tend
processes in a single, neat and easily com- to favour social critique over social theory.
prehensible phrase. Yet the hard evidence The politic al and emotiona l charge of a
for such a sweeping and general con- dualist approach and the failure to spell
clusion regarding the outcom e of econ- out its assumptions means that it cannot
omic restructuring and urban change is, at comprehend the com plexity of urban so-
best, patchy and ambiguous . If the concept cial reality.
of `dual’ or `pola rising’ city is of any real M ollenkopf and Castells highligh t the exist-
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1409

ence of two different form s of polarisation: structures of welfare provision and taxation
the social and the spatial. These may or may which are instrum ental in in¯ uencing both
not be related, as it is hypothe tically possible the necessity to enter the paid labour market,
to have social polarisation (at the city level) and the incom es derived from paid employ-
without spatial pola risation/segregation and ment and from welfare bene® ts. It will fur-
vice versa, though in capitalist cities social ther be argued that the extent of pola risation
divisio ns generally go hand-in-hand with in many US cities is a result of the speci® c
spatial segregation via the operation of the institutiona l conte xt in that country , particu-
housing market and the price mechanism. larly the high and grow ing level of im mi-
The issue of spatial segregation will not be gration and its im plication for labour supply ,
discussed in this paper. the relative paucity of welfare provisions and
Finally, and follow ing on from the con- incom e support for the poor, and the absence
cerns outlined above , it is the intention of of effective minim um wage legislation and
this paper to challenge the dom inant theory the grow th of a large, low -paid casualised
of polarisation advanced by Sassen and oth- service sector. The rapid grow th of incom e
ers which sees occupational and incom e pola risation in the UK in the 1980s and early
polarisation as the outcom e of a general shift 1990s may also re¯ ect som e similar trends,
from manufacturing to services which is par- although the absence of a grow ing low-skill
ticularly marked in global cities as a result of section of employed labour force in Britain
their concentration of key advanced business and in other western Europea n countries may
and ® nancial services, gentri® cation and the re¯ ect differences in job opportu nities and
grow th of sweated manufacturing. This the- welfare provision which inhibit the growth of
sis of pola risation is essentially uni-c ausal, this section of the paid labour force. In recent
focusing on the dominant role of economic years we have seen the emergence of tw o
restructuring. It will be argued that, whilst different literatures: one on polarisation and
there is strong evidence for grow ing incom e econom ic restructuring, and another on wel-
inequality in capitalist econom ies, there is no fare state regim es. These literatures have
evide nce of occupational polarisation on the rarely been brought toge ther but, as this pa-
basis of of® cial statistics, and that the devel- per will attempt to show , the relationship
opm ent of incom e pola risation may be the between the two is crucial.
result of changes in taxation and differences The paper is divide d into three major sec-
in the structure and form of welfare provision tions. The ® rst outlines the main elements of
and other factors in som e W estern countries. the dom inant social polarisation thesis, par-
The thesis to be put forward is that the ticularly as advanced by Sassen. The second
extent and the form s of social pola risation in section gives empirical evide nce for the UK
different countries are unlikely to be hom o- and London regarding changes in incom e
geneous or uni-dir ectional, that they are a inequality and occupationa l structure during
result of a combination of econom ic restruc- the 1980s. It show s that whilst there is strong
turing which is changing the structure of the evidence for incom e inequality there is no
labour market, the structure of occupations evidence for occupational polarisation which
and incom es in the paid labour market and would be expected if Sassen’ s thesis is cor-
the division betw een the econom ically active rect. The third section puts forward an
and the inactive and unemployed. In ad- alternative thesis based on the idea of welfare
dition, it will be argued that there may be state regim es. It argues that the grow th of
other forces generating incom e polarisation incom e pola risation in the 1980s in Britain
such as shifts in house hold com position and and other W estern capitalist countries ow es a
the age structure of the population. Finally, it great deal to changes in government policie s
will be argued that the extent of polarisation regarding the welfare state, and argues that
in the occupationa l and incom e structures of while industrial restructuring in global cities
W estern societies is likely to be mediated by and elsewhere is im porta nt, it is miscon-
1410 CH RIS H AM N ETT

ceived to view this as the sole cause of where (Hamnett, 1994a,b ; 1995), it is unne-
incom e pola risation. cessary to go into detail. Suf® ce to say that
Sassen (1984) argues on the basis of her
work on Los Angeles and New York that
Social Polarisation: Sassen’ s Thesis
econom ic restructuring has had several major
In a well-known series of books and papers, im plications in global cities and suggests that
Saskia Sassen (1984, 1985, 1986, 1990, new form s of econom ic grow th no longer
1991) systematically outline d a thesis for produc e the type s of job supply that ª were
global cities whereby social polarisation in constitutive of the massive expansion of the
these cities is seen as the result of a form of middle class in the post-W orld W ar II pe-
econom ic restructuring which is particularly riodº . Instead, there has been ª a vast expan-
concentrated in such cities. This restructuring sion in the supply of low-wage jobs and a
has several key elements. First, there is the shrinking supply of middle -incom e jobsº
shift from manufacturing to services, particu- (Sassen, 1984, p. 139).
larly advanced business services. This shift is In 1991 she generalised the thesis from
seen to result in a polarised occupational and New York and Los Angles to all global
incom e structure which is characterised by cities, arguing that new structures of econ-
grow th both at the top and at the bottom end omic activity in globa l cities, particularly
by virtue of the more polarised nature of the the rapid grow th of ® nancial and busine ss
service sector, and the contraction of the services and the sharp decline in manufac-
manufacturing sector which contained more turing industry have ª brought about changes
skilled-manual, middle-incom e jobs. in the organization of work re¯ ected in a
Secondly, Sassen points to the grow th of shift in the job supply and polarization in
low -grade service jobs which are seen to be the incom e distribution and occupation al
dependent on the grow th at the top end of the distribution of workersº (Sassen, 1991, p. 9;
occupationa l and income structure. These emphasis added).
jobs are concentrated in the personal service Sassen sum marised her thesis as follow s:
sector and provide services for the wealthy.
New conditions of growth have con-
She pointe d out (Sassen, 1984, p. 145) that:
tributed to elements of a new class align-
The dem and for low-wage workers to ser- ment in global cities. The occupational
vice the high-inc ome lifestyles of the rap- structure of major grow th industries char-
idly expanding top-level workforc e is a acterised by the locational concentration of
key factor in the expansion of an inform al major grow th sectors in global cities in
sector in cities like New York and Los combination with the polarised occu-
Angeles. pationa l structure of these sectors has cre-
ated and contributed to grow th of a high
Thirdly, Sassen points to the grow th of infor-
incom e stratum and a low-incom e stratum
malisation within what remains of the
of workers. It has done so directly through
`dow ngraded’ manufacturing sector. These
the organization of work and occupational
low -skill, low -pay jobs are strongly concen-
structure of major grow th sectors. And it
trated in the im migrant labour force which is
has done so indirectly through the jobs
seen to be attracted to globa l cities by virtue
needed to service the new high-in com e
of the grow ing labour market opportu nities.
workers, both at work and at home, as well
This grow ing occupationa l and incom e polar-
as the needs of the expanded low-wage
isation is said to be linked to a grow ing
work force. (Sassen, 1991, p. 13; emphasis
geogra phic al polarisation as the top and bot-
added)
tom of the occupationa l and incom e structure
becom e increasingly differentiated in space. It is clear that Sassen sees social pola risation
As the main elements of Sassen’ s thesis as the outc om e of econom ic restructuring.
have been outlined in this journal and else- Indeed, chapter 9 of The Global C ity is titled
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1411

`Econom ic Restructuring as Class and Spa- grow ing unemployed and econom ically inac-
tial Polarisation’ . It is also clear that Sassen tive group excluded from the labour force
sees the outcom e of econom ic restructuring rather than the grow th of a large, low -skilled
as an absolu te increase at both the top and and low -paid labour force. W hile this may be
bottom of the occupational and incom e struc- true in the US, with its large and grow ing
tures. She also sugge sts that the process of im migrant labour force, willing to work for
econom ic restructuring and polarisation are low wages (possibly forced to because of the
com mon to all global cities. She argues that lim ited nature of welfare provision) it is not
New York, London and Tokyo ª have under- necessarily true of all W estern capitalist
gone massive and parallel changes in their countries (Burgers, 1996).
econom ic base, spatial organization and so- W hat is missing from Sassen’ s treatment
cial structure’ (Sassen, 1991, p. 4; emphasis of pola risation is that the causes of polaris-
in origina l) and she suggests that: ation may be multi, rather than mono-causal,
ª transformations in cities ranging from Paris that polarisation may be grow ing in terms
to Frankfurt to Hong Kong and SaÄ o Paulo of incom e but not occupation, and that the
have responded to the same dynam icº . These extent and form of social and spatial polari-
are bold claims, but not everybody accepts sation may be linked to the structure of
them . Levine (1992, p. 175) for instance, welfare state in different countries. It is
asks argued here that Sassen’ s model of polari-
sation is US-based, prim arily mono-causal,
To what extent is econom ic restructuring a
and fails to appreciate that the econom ic
`single global process’ ? To what extent
pressures tow ards polarisation are mediated
does the social polarisation of cities ¯ ow
by different welfare state regim es. W hat
inexorably from the intrinsic nature of
may be happening in certain cities in the
post-Fo rdist produc tion or the inherent
US is not necessarily happening in similar
division of the service sector into high-
cities in other countie s because of differ-
wage and low-wage employm ent?
ences in the econom ic, social and institu-
It is here argued that this thesis, while very tional context. The next section looks at
stim ulating, is simultaneously partial and the empirical evidence for incom e and occu-
overge neralised by virtue of its dual focus on pational polarisation in London to see to
econom ic restructuring and the econom ically what extent it suppor ts or contradicts
active labour force, and its failure to exam ine Sassen’ s thesis.
differences in welfare state regim es. It also
generalises from the experience of New York
Income Polarisation : The Empirical Evi-
and Los Angeles to global cities as a whole.
dence in Britain
Social polarisation is seen as a direct un-
mediated consequence of econom ic restruc- First, some of the evide nce on incom e and
turing. It is also here argued that, while there earnings inequality both in London and in
is undoub ted evidence of grow ing incom e Britain as a whole will be sum marised. It is
polarisation in som e capitalist econom ies, well established that the level of incom e
and particularly in the major cities, the evi- inequality increased substantially in Britain
dence on the occupational structure of the during the 1980s. This is not the same thing
econom ically active labour force points to- as incom e pola risation in that incom e in-
wards professionalisation (or an increase in equality between rich and poor can grow
the proportion of professionals and man- without any increase in the num ber or pro-
agers), rather than pola risation. This is not to portion s of the rich and poor groups (Kloost-
say that major changes in employm ent struc- erman, 1996). Also, it should be stressed that
ture and opportu nities are not taking place, Sassen’ s thesis focuses on polarisation of
but that in many western Europea n countries, individu al earnings from employment. This
they are more likely to create a large and differs from incom e, which is usually de® ned
1412 CH RIS H AM N ETT

as incom e from earnings, transfer and wel- incom es of the top decile group rose by 71
fare paym ents, etc. This can be measured per cent while that of the other decile groups
either in terms of individ ual incom e units or rose by betw een 38 per cent (second decile)
households. Household income is som etim es to 16 per cent (low est decile). In 1979 aver-
`equiva lised’ to take into account the differ- age earnings of the top 10 per cent were 3.9
ent number of people in a household. If tim es greater than the average earnings of the
Sassen is correct, both incom e inequality and bottom 10 per cent. B y 1991, the inter-decile
num bers of earners at the top and bottom ratio had risen to 5.75. There is thus little
ends of the distribution should have in- doubt that the distribution of earnings from
creased in London . This trend should be employm ent became markedly more unequal
more marked than in Britain as a whole. during the 1980s.
Otherw ise, it can be argued that it is nationa l These are national ® gures, however. They
factors which are responsib le, rather than tell us nothing about the extent to which
London’ s role as a global city. incom e inequality has increased differen-
Stark (1992), using Family Expenditure tially over space, particularly in London
Survey data, show ed that the distribu tion of com pared to the rest of the country. First,
gross norm al weekly household pre-tax in- there is evidence that incom es rose much
com e in the UK became more unequal during faster in London and the South East than
the 1980s. The top decile’ s share of total they did in the rest of the country . Stark
incom e increased from 24.4 per cent in 1980 (1992) shows that from 1979 to 1991 real
to 28.9 per cent in 1990 and the share of the average gross norm al household incom e rose
second decile rose from 16.1 per cent to 16.7 by 37 per cent in London and by 31 per cent
per cent. Conve rsely, the share of the bottom in the rest of the South East, compared to a
70 per cent decreased, particularly those of national average of 23 per cent (Stark, 1992,
the lowest 30 per cent. The share of the Table 30). In the Midlands and the northern
low est decile fell from 2.2 per cent to 1.6 per regions by contrast, the real increase ranged
cent. The Gini coef® cient of inequality rose from 9 per cent to 19 per cent. But these
consistently from 35.8 in 1980 to 42.0 in ® gures do not show an increase in incom e
1990. There were similar changes in the dis- pola risation or inequality.
tribution of annua l disposable house hold in- Looking speci® cally at income inequality,
com e (Stark, 1992). The top decile’ s share of the shares of the top decile of household
total incom e rose from 22.7 per cent in 1979 incomes in London rose from 24.8 per cent
to 26.9 per cent in 1989, while the shares of of the total in 1979/80 to 28.3 per cent in
the next two deciles rose slightly and those 1985/86 and to 33.5 per cent in 1989/90. The
of the bottom 70 per cent fell. There is no share of the next decile rose only marginally
doubt that household incom e distribu tion in (from 16.1 per cent to 16.5 per cent), whilst
the UK became markedly more unequal dur- those of all othe r deciles fell. A similar,
ing the 1970s, due in part to the ® scal, mon- though less marked, pattern was found in all
etary and labour market polic ies adopted by the othe r regions (Stark, 1992, Table 31).
government but also because of changes in Perhaps the most telling evide nce, how ever,
household com position . is that when Stark looke d at the changing
These ® gures are for overall house hold percentage of households in each region in
incom e including transfers. Stark next looked the national top 10 per cent and bottom 10
at individu al earnings from employment us- per cent of gross house hold norm al weekly
ing the New Earnings Survey. He found that incom e in 1979/80 and 1989/90, he found
shares of the top decile rose substantially that the percentage of house holds in London
betw een 1979 and 1991 (from 18 per cent to in the top 10 per cent of national incom es
23 per cent) the share of the second decile rose from 14.3 per cent in 1979 to 20.1 per
rose marginally ; while that of the bottom cent in 1989, while the proportion in the
seven deciles fell. The real, in¯ ation-adjusted bottom 10 per cent also rose from 8.4 per
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1413

Table 1. Percentag e of househo lds in each region in the national top 10 per cent
and bottom 10 per cent of gross househo ld norm al weekly incom e

T op 10 per cent Bottom 10 per cent

1979/80 1989/90 1979/80 1989/90

G reater London 14.3 20.1 8.4 10.3


R est of South East 14.8 19.4 7.0 6.6
East M idlands 9.3 10.0 8.2 8.2
W est M idlands 10.3 9.8 8.2 10.8
East A nglia 7.7 11.6 9.6 7.3
South W est 7.5 10.6 9.5 7.0
Y orkshire /Hum berside 6.1 6.2 12.2 12.2
N orth 7.1 6.4 14.6 13.3
N orth W est 8.3 8.8 11.1 10.7
W ales 7.3 7.2 11.0 11.6
Scotland 8.9 8.0 11.9 13.3
N orthern Ireland 6.1 9.2 18.2 18.0

Source: Stark (1992, Table 32; from Family Expenditu re Survey).

cent to 10.3 per cent (Table 1). In the South 1979 to 1994. It is clear that male earnings
East, by contrast, although the proport ion of
inequality increased more rapidly in Greater
households in the national top 10 per cent
London than elsewhere during the 1980s, but
of incom es rose from 14.8 per cent to 19.4
earnings of full-tim e wom en workers did not.
per cent, the proportion in the bottom 10
This is a re¯ ection of higher increases in
per cent of national incom es fell from 7 per
wom en’ s earnings at the bottom end in Lon-
cent to 6.6 per cent. This clearly indicates
don than elsewhere.
that households in London became more
polarised in incom e terms relative to the
The Changin g Socio-econom ic Structure
national average during the 1980s. The de-
of Lond on, 1981± 91
gree of incom e inequality between rich and
poor rose sharply and the proportions of rich Sassen (1991, p. 24) argues that ª New York,
and poor also increased. Incom e inequa lity London and Tokyo show parallel employ-
also increased sharply in Britain as a whole. ment and earnings trendsº and she argues
These are household incom e ® gures, how- that, while London has witnessed an increase
ever, and Sassen’ s thesis relates speci® cally in professionals and managers, ª the num ber
to earnings from employm ent. But, once of clerical and blue-collar service jobs has
again, Stark shows evidence of grow ing also increased signi® cantly in the City and in
earnings inequa lity in London. In 1979, the London at largeº (p. 269). Although she
inter-decile ratio for adult males in London provide s data on the changes in the industrial
was 2.60, the highe st ® gure of all regions structure of London, she provide s no data to
except Northern Ireland where special factors back up her argum ent that London has seen
are at work. By 1991, the inter-decile ratio an ª occupationa l transform ationº (p. 233).
had increased to 3.58 in London, com pared This section examines census data on the
to 3.16 in Great Britain as a whole (Table 2). socio-econom ic structure of London to see
This is a bigger increase than in any other what evidence there is for a polarisation of
region. The pattern of inter-decile change for occupations.
full-tim e females was less clear, rising from The data used in the paper are derived
2.30 to 2.74 in London, but more sharply in from publish ed data for the 1961, 1971, 1981
all othe r regions. Recent research (Hamnett and 1991 censuses on socio-econom ic
and Cross, 1996) con® rms these trends from classi® cation of economically active (em-
1414 CH RIS H AM N ETT

Table 2. D istributio n of earning s by region, as percenta ge of mean earnings (full-tim e earnings


only)

1979 1991
Inter-de cile ratio
Lower U pper Lower U pper
decile decile decile decile 1979 1991

Males
Greater London 58.2 151.4 46.8 167.7 2.60 3.58
Rest of South East 61.4 145.3 50.6 160.0 2.37 3.16
Great B ritain 61.0 145.3 50.4 159.2 2.38 3.16
Fem ales
Greater London 63.1 144.9 54.9 150.5 2.30 2.74
Rest of South East 65.1 147.1 57.1 156.3 2.26 2.74
Great B ritain 64.4 147.0 54.3 158.9 2.28 2.92

Source: Stark (1992, Table 34).

ployed and unem ployed ) usual residents. has been added to the socio-econom ic ® gures
There are some 17 socio-economic groups in the 1991 census, nam ely those on gove rn-
and these are show n in Table 3. From these ment training schem es. In this analysis, they
groups is derived a standard classi® cation are counted along with groups 16 `Armed
into 6 large groups . The ® rst group (1, 2 and forces’ and 17 ª occupation inadequately de-
13) consists of employers and managers; the scribedº . The three categories form a residual
second (3 and 4) of professional workers category of limited num erical importance
(both employe rs and employe es); the third and they can be disregarded for the sake of
group (5 and 6) consists of othe r non-m anual the analysis.
workers (artists, allied workers, intermediate, Looking ® rst at the occupational structure
and junior non-m anual workers including of all persons in London, it is clear that there
clerical workers). The fourth group com- was a sharp increase in the number of man-
prises the skilled manual and supervisory agers and in the num ber of professionals
workers and self-employed (non-pr o- between 1981 and 1991. The num ber of
fessional) workers ( 8, 9, 12 and 14). The managers increased by 27 per cent and the
® fth group is comprised of semi-skilled and num ber of professionals by 25 per cent. By
personal service workers (7, 10 and 15). contrast, the num bers of persons in every
Finally, there are the unskilled (11). In ad- othe r socio-econom ic group fell: by almost 3
dition, 16 is Armed Forces and 17 is per cent in the case of junior and interm edi-
ª occupation inadequately describedº . All ate non-m anual workers; by 18 per cent for
data are 10 per cent. It should be stressed that skilled manual workers, manual ow n-account
a major change in the classi® cation of occu- workers and supervisors; 26 per cent for
pations occurred in 1980 which affected the semi-skille d and personal service workers;
socio-econom ic group classi® cation of the and by 22 per cent for unskilled workers
1981 census. This had the effect of reducing (Table 4).
the proport ion of professionals, increasing As a result, the proportion of managers
the proportion of interm ediate non-m anual and employers rose by 4.7 percentage points
workers, reducing the propor tion of junior from 12.6 to 17.3 per cent. The proportion of
non-m anual workers and raising the pro- professionals also rose from 4.5 to 6.1 per
portion of semi-skilled and personal service cent and, despite the absolute decline, the
workers. proportion of all othe r non-m anual workers
It should also be noted that a new category rose from 37 per cent to 39 per cent. The
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1415

Table 3. The standard 17 OPC S/socio-ec onom ic groups

1 Em ployers and managers in large establish ments


2 Em ployers and managers in sm all establish m ents
3 Professio nal workers, self-em ployed
4 Professio nal workers, em ployees
5.1 A ncillary workers and artists
5.2 Forem en and supervis ors, non-m anual
6 Junior non-m anual workers
7 Personal service w orkers
8 Forem en and supervis ors, manual
9 Skilled m anual workers
10 Semi-skilled m anual w orkers
11 U nskilled m anual w orkers
12 O wn-accou nt workers, other than professio nal
13 Farm ers (em ployers and managers )
14 Farm ers (ow n-accou nt)
15 A gricultur al w orkers
16 M em bers of Arm ed Forces
17 Inadequ ately describe d occupati ons

percentage share of all three manual groups manual workers by 1.7 points. All three man-
fell, by 2.2 percentage points in the case of ual groups declined in proportionate terms.
skilled manual workers; 3.1 per cent for Again, there is no evidence of pola risation
semi-skilled and personal service workers; and a strong movement tow ards what can be
and by 0.8 points for unskilled manual work- termed professionalisation.
ers. It is clear that, on the basis of the of® cial The changes in the occupational structure
statistics, the process of change is one that of econom ically active females are broadly
can be termed `professionalisation’ Ð that is, similar, although the structure of wom en’ s
an increase in the proportion of professionals occupations is very different from that of
and managers. There is no evidence of polar- men. The num ber of managers and profes-
isation, or of `proletarianisation’ in the occu- sionals grew extremely rapidly, by 76 per
pational structure. cent and 93 per cent respectively, though
These are overall changes, however. W hat adm ittedly from a very low initial base. This
of the changes in the occupational structure indicates the wom en are beginning to move
of econom ically active men and women? into managerial and professional jobs in con-
Looking at the occupationa l structure of siderable num bers. The proportion of women
males, we ® nd (Table 5) a very similar pat- in all other occupational groups fell, by a
tern of changes. There was an absolute in- remarkable 28 per cent in the case of semi-
crease in the num bers of employers and skilled and personal service workers (Table
professionals (11 per cent and 13 per cent 6). In proportionate terms, the percentage of
respectively), and a decline in the num bers in female managers and professionals rose by 6
all othe r categories: a 5 per cent fall in the and 1.6 points respectively. The proportions
num ber of intermediate and junior manual almost doubled : from 7.6 per cent to 13.5 per
workers; a 19 per cent fall in the num ber of cent for managers and from 1.7 per cent to
skilled manual workers; 24 per cent in the 3.3 per cent for professionals. By far the
semi-skilled and personal service workers; largest female occupationa l group is inter-
and a 32 per cent fall in unkskilled workers. mediate and junior non-m anual workers,
The proportion of managers grew by 4.2 which includes clerical workers, and this
percentage points, professionals by 1.8 group remained stable at 58 per cent. The
points, and intermediate and junior non- bigge st decline was in the proport ion of un-
1416

T ab le 4. S ocio-econom ic change in L ondon, 1981± 91: all residents, econom ically active, em ployed and
unem ploy ed

Percentage
Percentage point
Grouped A bsolute Percentage change
S EG s 1981 1991 change change 1981 1991 1981± 91

1,2,13 42 521 54 070 11 549 27.16 12.6 17.3 4.7


3,4 15 055 18 892 3 837 25.49 4.5 6.1 1.6
5,6 124 936 121 432 2 3 504 2 2.80 37.1 39.0 1.9
8,9,12,14 66 048 54 214 2 11 834 2 17.92 19.6 17.4 2 2.2
7,10,15 53 368 39 630 2 13 738 2 25.74 15.8 12.7 2 3.1
CH RIS H AM N ETT

11 18 502 14 510 2 3 992 2 21.58 5.5 4.7 2 0.8


S ub-total 320 430 302 748 2 17 682 2 5.52 95.1 97.1 2.1
16,17,gov . 16 654 8 933 2 7 721 2 46.36 4.9 2.9 2 2.1
T otal 337 084 311 681 2 25 403 2 7.54 100 100 0

Source: 1981 and 1991 C ensuses of Population, Econom ic A ctiv ity T ables (10 per cent data).
T ab le 5. S ocio-econom ic change in L ondon, 1981± 91: m ales econom ically activ e, em ployed and unem ployed

Percentage
Percentage point
Grouped Percentage change
S EG s 1981 1991 Change change 1981 1991 1981± 91

1,2,13 31 961 35 472 3 511 10.99 16.1 20.4 4.2


3,4 12 697 14 316 1 637 12.91 6.4 8.2 1.8
5,6 43 528 41 361 2 2 167 2 4.98 22.0 23.7 1.7
8,9,12,14 59 809 48 142 2 11 667 2 19.51 30.2 27.6 2 2.6
7,10,15 28 377 21 635 2 6 742 2 23.76 14.3 12.4 2 1.9
11 11 402 7 739 2 3 663 2 32.13 5.7 4.4 2 1.3
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N

S ub-total 187 756 168 665 2 19 091 2 10.17 94.8 96.8 1.9
16,17,gov . 10 225 5 630 2 4 595 2 44.94 5.1 3.2 1.9
T otal 197 981 174 295 2 23 686 2 11.96 100 100 0

Source: 1981 and 1991 C ensuses of Population, Econom ic A ctiv ity T ables (10 per cent data).
1417
1418 CH RIS H AM N ETT

skilled wom en workers, from 18 per cent to group declined by 33 per cent, 1961±91; the
13 per cent: a ® ve-poin t fall. Once again, the skilled manual group by 49 per cent; the
evide nce points strongly tow ards profession- semi-skille d and personal service group by
alisation. There is no evidence of polarisation 45 per cent; and the unskilled by 65 per cent.
in the female occupationa l structure between By contrast, the number of managers grew
1981 and 1991 on the basis of census socio- by 10 per cent and the num ber of pro-
econom ic data. fessional workers by 9 per cent. Table 7 also
The three sets of changes analysed above show s that the proportion of managers and
are consistent. They all show a trend towards professionals has risen consistently in every
professionalisation rather than polarisation. intercensal decade. Conve rsely, the manual
There is no census evidence at all for occu- groups have fallen more or less consistently
pational polarisation in Greater London in every intercensal decade. Looke d at over-
1981±91. There is also no evide nce for ab- all, the proportion of managers and profes-
solute grow th of clerical or less-skilled ser- sionals increased by 11.8 percentage point
vice jobs, as Sassen claims. All the over the period 1961±91 (from 16.7 per cent
less-skilled groups show ed declines, both for in 1961 to 28.5 per cent in 1991). This is a
males and females. very large increase. Conversely, the share
There are two possible counte rs to this. taken by manual groups and personal service
The ® rst is that pola risation may not have workers has fallen by 13.2 points (from 57.6
manifested itself in the 1981±91 decade, but per cent to 44.4 per cent). The proportion in
may have done so earlier. The second is that the interm ediate and junior non-m anual cate-
it may exist at a more local scale. Given the gories rose by 0.7 percentage points. W here
nature of Sassen’ s polarisation thesis, both econom ically active males are concerned, it
arguments are quite dubious . First, Sassen is clear that the last 30 years are marked by
argues that global cities have risen to prom i- a grow ing degree of professionalisation.
nence in the 1980s with the increased im port- There is no evidence of polarisation.
ance of ® nancial and busine ss services, and Table 8 show s the comparable ® gures for
the polarisation thesis is seen as conting ent wom en, 1971±91. Although the occupational
on these changes in econom ic structure. If distribu tion is very different, the overall pat-
the changes had not occurred in the 1980s, tern of changes is similar with a marked
they are unlikely to have occurred in the increase in the proportion of wom en in the
1960s or 1970s. Secondly, while polarisation professional and managerial categories and a
may not be occurring in certain areas or may percentage decrease in all othe r categories.
be intensi® ed in others, the thesis is a city- The number of skilled manual workers fell
wide one. If it is not occurring at a city-w ide by 37 per cent, the semi-skilled by 42 per
scale, then its im portance is much dim in- cent and unskille d by 29 per cent, com pared
ished. Finding pola risation in a few neigh- to a rise of 140 per cent for professionals and
bourho ods or census tracts would not managers. In proportionate terms, the pro-
establish it as a major social phenom enon. fessional and managerial group almost tre-
The analysis below looks at male occu- bled, rising from 6.3 per cent to 16.9 per cent
pational change 1961±91 for Greater London of the total num ber of economically active
as a whole and female occupation al change females.
1971±91. It may be objected that the census data are
The absolute ® gures and absolute change biased in som e way, perhaps because of the
® gures are not give n as they would add well-know n undercount of young males in
unnecessarily to the num ber of tables. In- the inner cities in 1991, particularly in inner
stead, Table 7 show s the percentage ® gures London where it may have amounte d to 10
for men for each of the four census, overall per cent of the total. It is likely to be most
percentage point change and overall percent- marked among the less skilled trying to avoid
age change. The junior and interm ediate poll tax. I have thus draw n on another
T ab le 6. S ocio-econom ic change in L ondon, 1981± 91: fem ales econom ically activ e, em ploy ed and
unem ploy ed

Percentage
Percentage point
Grouped A bsolute Percentage change
S EG s 1981 1991 change change 1981 1991 1981± 91

1,2,13 10 560 18 598 8 038 76.12 7.6 13.5 5.9


3,4 2 376 4 576 2 200 92.59 1.7 3.3 1.6
5,6 81 408 80 071 2 1 337 2 1.64 58.5 58.3 2 0.2
8,9,12,14 6 239 6 072 2 167 2 2.68 4.5 4.4 2 0.1
7,10,15 24 991 17 995 2 6 996 2 27.99 18.0 13.1 2 4.9
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N

11 7 100 6 771 2 329 2 4.63 5.1 4.9 2 0.2


S ub-total 132 674 134 083 1 409 2 1.06 95.4 97.6 2.2
16,17,gov . 6 429 3 303 2 3 126 2 48.62 4.6 2.4 2 2.2
T otal 139 103 137 386 2 1 717 2 1.23 100 100 0

Source: 1981 and 1991 C ensuses of Population, Econom ic A ctiv ity T ables (10 per cent data).
1419
1420 CH RIS H AM N ETT

Table 7. Proportion ate socio-ec onom ic change in London 1961±91: econom ically active m ales

Percentag e Percentag e Percentag e


point change change
Grouped SEG s 1961 1971 1981 1991 1961±91 1961±91

1,2,13 11.9 13.9 16.1 20.3 8.4 10.3


3,4 4.8 6.0 6.4 8.2 3.4 9.4
5,6 23.0 23.5 22.0 23.7 0.7 2 33.2
8,9,12,1 4 34.8 32.8 30.2 27.6 2 7.2 2 48.7
7,10,15 14.5 13.4 14.3 12.4 2 2.1 2 44.8
11 8.3 7.2 5.8 4.4 2 3.9 2 65.3
Sub-total 97.4 96.9 94.8 97.8 0.4 2 35.8
16,17, gov. 2.6 3.1 5.2 3.2 0.6 2 20.5
Total 100 100 100 100 0 2 35.4

Source: 1961, 1971, 1981, 1991 Censuses of Populatio n (10 per cent tables).

source. Nick Buck (1994) has carried out the national econom y, as the global cities
an analysis of occupational change in thesis would sugge st. (Buck, 1994, p. 8)
London using a Labour Force Survey micro-
W e have then, what in terms of Sassen’ s
data set for 1979 and 1992 and employing
thesis is rather a paradox: grow ing incom e
Esping-A nderson’ s (1993) occupational and
inequality, but no polarisation of the occu-
industrial classi® cation of Fordist and `post-
pational structure. Similar evidence from the
industrial’ occupations. This classi® cation
Netherlands (Hamnett, 1994a ) suggests that
groups managers, clerical and sales, skilled
Britain is not unique in this respect, and
manual and unskille d manual workers as
preliminary evidence for Paris (Preteceille,
`Fordist’ occupations and professional, semi-
1995) agree. Indeed, there is strong evidence
professional, skilled service and unskilled
that, despite the grow th of part-tim e service
service as `post-industria l’ occupations. Buck
jobs, the occupationa l structure of the US is
notes the existence of sampling errors,
becom ing increasingly managerial and pro-
changes in occupational and industrial
fessionalised (W right and M artin, 1987).
classi® cations and the problem s they can
This interpretation is supported by Esping-
pose and, like the census data, his ® gures are
Anderson (1993) who argues that occu-
for residents of London and do not include
pational upgra ding is inherent in the
com muters. This said, he found that in both
post-industrial trajectory of the US. Klooster-
the `Fordist’ and `post-industria l’ hierarchy,
man (1996) adds that
there was a marked grow th at the top end and
a decline at the bottom . As he noted, ª In The trend towards occupational upgrading
sum mary, neither hierarchy show s polariza- does not tell the whole story of the Amer-
tion, in the sense of grow th of top and bot- ican employm ent structure. During the
tom at the expense of the middle º (Buck, 1970s and 1980s, a decoupling seems to
1994, pp. 7±8). He concludes that: have taken place betw een the occupational
level and the wage level in the United
States. According to Esping-A nderson, a
The relative grow th of the service sectors
depola risation of the occupational struc-
has led to an expansion of the upper sec-
ture has been accom panied in the US by a
tions of the hierarchies, including man-
polarisation of wage structure. (Klooster-
agers. W hile unskilled service workers
man, 1996)
have retained their share, in contrast to
unskille d manual workers, they have not To the extent that this is true, and profession-
expanded, either absolutely, or relative to alisation is not merely a statistical artefact of
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1421

Table 8. Proportio nate socio-ec onom ic change in London, 1971±91: econom i-


cally active fem ales

Percentag e
Percentag e point Percentag e
change change
1971 1981 1991 1961±91 1961±91
1,2,3,4 6.3 9.3 16.9 10.6 1 140.4
5,6 56.4 58.5 58.3 1.9 2 7.4
8,9,12.1 4 6.3 4.5 4.4 2 1.8 2 36.9
7,10,15 20.4 18.0 13.1 2 7.3 2 42.5
11 6.2 5.1 4.9 2 1.3 2 28.7
16,17, gov. 4.4 4.6 2.4 2 2.0 2 51.6
Total 100 100 100 0 2 10.4
Source: 1971, 1981, 1991 Censuses of Populatio n (10 per cent tables).

the devaluation of job titles which is ac- driving force of pola risation? At this stage, it
com panied by a dow nwards shift in work is im porta nt to return to the argum ents re-
skillÐ a question W right conside rs but dis- garding state monetary, ® scal and welfare
missesÐ then the paradox of grow ing incom e policies and their im portanc e for incom es
polarisation without occupationa l polaris- and occupational structures. Buck (1994, p.
ation may apply to the US as well as to 6) has suggested that
Britain and other similar countries (see
Globa l cities argum ents focus on polaris-
Clarke and M cNicolas, 1996, for evide nce on
ation within occupational hierarchies, and
Los Angeles). There is, how ever, a strong
would argue that these are what is speci® c
view that of® cial data take no account of
to large cities. On the other hand one
changes in the meaning of job titles or the
might expect changing patterns of employ-
conte nt of job categories and it is argued that
ment and inactivity, as well as the relative
the reality is one of deprofessionalisation
incom es of these groups to the employe d
rather than professionalisation (Bruegel and
popula tion, to depend largely on state pol-
Lyons, 1985). W hile this may be true to
icy and national economic performance.
som e extent, I think it is highly questiona ble
to argue that deprofessionalisation casts In an attempt to shed som e empirical light on
doubt on professionalisation, but not on the the im porta nce of changing patterns of em-
evide nce for polarisation (which involve s ploym ent and on welfare policy, Buck at-
grow th at both the top and bottom ends). tempted to analyse the rapid grow th of
Either the number of managers and profes- household incom e inequality in London us-
sionals is increasing, or it is not. It cannot be ing FES micro-data sets. He found, looking
argued both ways as som e attempt to do. at all house holds, that whereas the inter-
decile ratio betw een the incom es of the low-
est and the highest decile in London and the
Incom e Inequality W ithout Occupational
UK was very similar during 1978±80 at 3.85
Polarisation: An Attempt to Explain the
and 3.75 respectively, the ratios rose to 8.17
Paradox
and 5.94 during 1989±91. In London, the
It has been shown that incom e inequa lity inter-decile ratio had more than double d in a
grew in London during the 1980s, but that decade. The inter-decile ratio rose sharply in
the occupationa l structure shows no sign of the UK as a whole , but it rose far more
polarisation. How and why has this com e sharply in London (Table 9).
about and what light does it shed on Sassen’ s Buck (1994) also presented ® gures for
thesis of econom ic restructuring as the major households with an employed `head’ . These
1422 CH RIS H AM N ETT

Table 9. Incom e distribut ion measures: Greater London and the UK 1978±81
and 1989±91

Lowest H ighest Inter-dec ile


decile M edian decile ratio

A ll househo lds
1978± 80
G reater London £50.5 £107.8 £194.3 3.85
UK £45.1 £93.5 £169.0 3.75
G L/UK 1.12 1.15 1.15 1.03
1989± 91
G reater London £88.2 £322.4 £720.6 8.17
UK £91.3 £256.4 £542.0 5.94
G L/UK 0.97 1.26 1.33 1.38

H ousehol ds with employed `head’


1978± 80
G reater London £65.3 £120.0 £204.8 3.14
UK £61.2 £103.7 £179.5 2.94
G L/UK 1.07 1.16 1.14 1.07
1989± 91
G reater London £188.2 £399.0 £791.0 4.21
UK £157.7 £310.0 £604.2 3.83
G L/UK 1.19 1.29 1.31 1.10
Source: Family Expendit ure Survey (m icro-dat a).

® gures show that the inter-decile ratio for equality but changing patterns of in-
Greater London for 1978±80 was 3.14 com- equality between the employed popula tion
pared to 2.94 for the UK as a whole. By and in Esping-A nderson’ s terms the
1988±91, the inter-decile ratios had risen to ª outside r surplus popula tionº . (Buck,
4.21 and 3.83 respectively: a marked in- 1994, p. 5)
crease, but not as great as that for all house-
holds. Buck examined a num ber of factors which
The differences in the tw o sets of ® gures might explain the differences in inter-decile
suggest that while the increase in incom e change ratios betw een London and Britain as
inequality was greater in London than in the a whole. He argued that a major part of the
UK as a whole, the increase in incom e in- rise in earnings inequality since the 1970s
equality was much greater for all house holds was com mon across the country , althoug h
than for households with an employe d head. London did show a greater change. But he
This suggests that the causes of greater in- show ed that while unem ploym ent and inac-
com e inequality in both London and in the tivity rates had risen sharply across Britain
UK as a whole lie as much outside employ- from 1979 to 1992, they had risen much
ment as they do within it. Buck com ments more rapidly in London.
that
W hereas in 1979 London enjoye d
There is no evidence of any distinc tive markedly lower rates than the country as a
change in incom e inequality among the whole , by 1992 it had markedly higher
employe d population in London, and we rates. Thus for men the London rate was
might be better looking at nationa l expla- 20 per cent below the national rate in
nations of change. The conclusion one 1979, but by 1992 it was 20 per cent
could draw is that what appears speci® c to above. For wom en the change is even
London is not changing occupational in- more extreme. (Buck, 1994, p. 10)
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1423

He also found, using a household-le vel state policy. She says in the introdu ction to
de® nition of unem ploym ent and inactivity, The Global City that one of its key questions
that in 1979 around 7.5 per cent of the concerns the relationship between state and
working- age households in both London and city where strong links exist between a city
the UK had no employed workers. By 1992 and the world econom y (Sassen, 1991, p.
this had increased to 15.6 per cent in the UK 14). Her answer is clear. She is of the view
and 19.2 per cent in London. He argued that that: ª the nation state is becom ing a less
It is in the grow th of the `outsider surplus central actor in the worldº (p. 167), and that
population’ that London has experienced a the welfare state is less im porta nt under the
change that is distinctive compared to the ª new econom ic regim eº (p. 338). She argues
nation as a whole, and to a much greater that there has been a general trend towards
degree than changes within the employed the ª dism antling of a system that provide d a
labour market. (Buck, 1994, p. 11) measure of job security, health bene® ts, and
othe r com pone nts of a social wage to a criti-
To con® rm this interpretation he undertook cal mass of workersº (p. 333) and she sug-
decom positio n analysis of incom e inequa lity gests that this raises several questions about
change. This showed ® rst that the contribu- the intersection of econom ics and politics
tion of differences in employm ent status be- and the state and about the ª naturalº tenden-
tw een households with an employed `head’ cies of capitalist econom ies. She asks if in-
and those with an inactive or unem ployed creasing econom ic and social pola risation ª is
head as the major factor in explaining change
the `natural’ outc om e of the operation of the
in incom e inequality, but that its im portanc e
econom ic system when politica l claims carry
was almost tw ice as marked in London as in
little weightº (p. 334).
the UK as a whole. This, says Buck, re¯ ects
Sassen is quite correct that there has been
both the higher grow th of unem ploym ent a tendency towards the dismantling of the
in London, but also the higher and more social welfare system in a num ber of capital-
rapidly rising incom es of those in work, ist countries, but I would question that there
which sets them at a greater distance in has been: ª a generalized dism antlingº or a
London than elsewhere from those on state grow th of incom e polarisation in all coun-
welfare bene® ts. (Buck, 1994, p. 12) tries (see Hills, 1995, and Gardiner, 1993, for
The occupation al differences contributed to a discussion). The signi® cance of the welfare
the grow th of incom e inequality, but they state has varied conside rably from country to
had a relatively minor effect com pared to the country , as do the extent and the pace of the
changing patterns of unem ploym ent. Buck retreat from the welfare state. In order to
(1993) has also underta ken com parative appreciate the causes of variations in social
work on the scale and causes of incom e pola risation, it is necessary to focus on dif-
polarisation in New York and London and ferences in welfare state regim es, including
has found that changes in occupational struc- the availability and level of social bene® ts,
ture were a more im porta nt cause of incom e the extent of collective consum ption such as
polarisation in New York than in London education, health and child care, state labour
where the grow th of unem ploym ent and market intervention and the like.
econom ic inactivity proved more im portant. Econom ic restructuring is extrem ely im -
At this point, it is appropriate to try to gener- portant as a major force shaping the nature of
alise the argum ent. W estern capitalist countries, but econom ic
restructuring does not occur in a social and
political vacuum. On the contrary, it every-
Econom ic Restructuring, W elfare Regim es
where and always takes place within the
and Social Polarisation
context of nation states with different regula-
Sassen does touc h on the issue of welfare tory regim es, legal structures and welfare
1424 CH RIS H AM N ETT

policie s and with different nationa l and local has been no national conve rgence in social
cultures. The outcom es of globa l economic variations in socio-econom ic trends.
restructuring are essentially variable depend-
She quotes Howell (1992) as saying
ing on the ways in which restructuring pro-
cesses are mediated within different states. It is alm ost a truism of comparative politi-
Different structures of welfare and labour cal econom y that econom ic im peratives
market practices will cushion the im pacts in create basic constraints on states but do
different ways. They can also have an inde- not determine the way in which states
pendent effect. As Kloosterman (1996) must deal with those constraints. (Howell,
points out 1992; quote d in Silver, 1993, p. 339)
Silver goes on to argue that states indirectly
Descending from global logic to nationa l
shape the social structures through trade and
and local variation¼ does not necessarily
industrial policie s such as labour law and
im ply that the outcom es of economic re-
industrial relations policies that in¯ uence na-
structuring will be identic al in every ad-
tional labour markets. She instances grow th
vanced city. Differences in the economic
of a ¯ exible workforce in the US and the UK
base, the national institut ional framework
com pared to France where the Labour Code
and urban policy have contributed to a
retarded its developm ent. She also argues
variety of urban experiences in the 1980s.
that states directly in¯ uence social structures
(Klooste rman, 1996, p. 1)
through welfare progra mmes and tax struc-
tures which redistribute wealth (see also
It has long been recognised in the social
Hamnett, 1996, forthcoming).
policy sphere that variations in state welfare
Silver conclude s by pointin g out that, in
structures and policie s are of major im port-
recent years, the globalisation of markets and
ance in shaping the patterns of social out-
rising unem ploym ent have led many to be-
com es. The US has virtually no public
lieve in the econom ic im pote nce of nation
housing , whereas the UK, Sweden, the
states. Silve r argues on the contrary, that
Netherlands, France and Germany all have a
nation states
large social housin g sector (though now un-
der threat in som e countries). Thus, out- Remain a vital mode of econom ic organi-
com es in terms of social and residential zation within the emerging international
segregation are likely to be very different divisio n of labour¼ By modifyin g com -
(Harloe and Martens, 1985; Harloe, 1993). mon global forces in produc t and labour
Hilary Silver (1993) sugge sts that inter- markets and through redistributa tive wel-
national econom ic restructuring has led to fare polic ies, nation-states continue to vary
similar changes in employm ent and incom e in their social structures. W hile undergo-
structure in Britain, France and the US. ing similar social trends, nationa l conve r-
There is a shift from manufacturing to ser- gence is muted. (Silve r, 1993, p. 348)
vices; the absolute share of credentialled
Sim ilar argum ents have been put forward by
workers increased; more jobs became more
Lash and Urry (1993) regarding polarisation.
insecure; organised labour declined in mem-
They argue that the process of `re¯ exive
bership; female labour force participation
accumulation’ in capitalist society that give s
rates rose; regional employm ent opportu ni-
rise to a large service class and a smaller
ties dive rged; and unem ploym ent, incom e
working class also give s rise to a new low er
inequality and poverty all increased. But she
class. But they also argue that these kinds of
argues that
structural change do not always lead to the
developm ent of an unde rclass or a large-
W hile all these trends move in the same
scale lower class. Instead, they argue that
direction, they also proceeded at different
rates in different countries, so that there the extent of underclass and new low er
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1425

class formation depends on a de® cit of for ª almost the entire net employm ent in-
institutiona l regula tion in econom y and crease over the past decadesº (p. 19). They
society. (Lash and Urry, 1993, p. 146) also note that welfare state institutions dic-
tate the choice of non-e ntry via the provision
and suggest that in societies such as Sw eden
of a social wage and tax and service treat-
and Germany, different institutional set-ups
ment of households and their im pact on child
lead to
care and working wom en. Finally, they sug-
a different outcom e, that is to a preser- gest that the welfare state also furnishes the
vation of quite a large working class and a basic means for labour market exit through
much more lim ited developm ent of a new the introdu ction of early retirement which
lower class. (Lash and Urry, 1993, p. 146) provide s many redundant workers with the
option of a social wage rather than having to
By far the most important work for my argu- move into bottom -end jobs. In sum
ment, how ever, is that of Esping-A nderson
and his colleagues (1993). His earlier (1990) The structure of the welfare state is a key
work on welfare state regim es is well know n. feature in the contem porary process of
He argued, on the basis of labour and social social strati® cation: it creates and abol-
security policies, that it was possible to ishes `empty slots’ , it helps decide who
group countries into three major types ® lls them and how they are to be re-
depending on the character of their welfare warded, it de® nes what is unde rtaken
regim es. Esping-Anderson’ s more recent within them, and, ® nally, it shapes the
work (1993) on com parative changes in class pattern of mobility between them. (Esping-
structure and mobility in different welfare Anderson, 1993, p. 20)
regim es takes this argum ent further to argue The principal im plication of this analysis is
that ª conte mporary social strati® cation is that there are marked differences between the
heavily shaped by institutions, the welfare occupational and incom e structures of differ-
state in particularº (p. 1). ent W estern capitalist countries. They argue
The argum ent advanced by Esping-A nder- that while the Scandinavian countries:
son and colleagues is that the welfare state ª exemplify an extrem e case of a gendered,
revolutionise d the structure of the labour welfare state service-led trajectoryº , Canada
market and labour market behaviour. They and the US are characterised by their ª large
argue that the social wage violate s the as- low-end consumer service labour marketº
sum ption that classes and life chances can be (Esping-A nderson, 1993, p. 4). They sugge st
identi® ed through com mon labour market that
condition s, in that welfare states introdu ce
the possibility of a ª welfare state client In North America, unskilled service jobs
classº (p. 19). They also argue that tend to be very poorly paid, predom inantly
® lled by youth and im migrants, and func-
The sometimes massive expansion of wel- tion very much as ® rst-entry, or stop-ga p
fare state employment implies not only new jobs. In both (Canada and the US) a dis-
occupational groups, but also the emerg- tinct low-end mobility circuit emerges
ence of a huge production and reward sys- which is unpa ralleled elsewhere: unskille d
tem isolated from the operation of market sales, clerical and service jobs appear to
forces. (Esping-Anderson, 1993, p. 19) constitute a com mon job reservoir for peo-
ple with low education. (Esping-A nderson,
They argue that this expansion manifests it-
1993, p. 5)
self not just by education and training pro-
grammes, but also by labour market They add that the welfare state, the industrial
measures and direct welfare state employ- relations system and education are key insti-
ment grow th. They note that in Scandina via, tutiona l ® lters for employm ent structuration,
welfare state employm ent grow th accounts noting that
1426 CH RIS H AM N ETT

If the welfare state is service intensive, it generous and com prehensive but where so-
will bias service employm ent trends; if it cial rights are strictly tied to employm ent
provide s a high social wage guarantee, the record and there is a strong com mitm ent to
scope for a low-wage-based service econ- preserve the traditional caring functions of
omy is sharply reduced. (Esping-Anderson, the family. Thus, there is a bias against col-
1993, p. 33) lective social services, except health, and an
im plicit discouragem ent of female labour
They point out that where trade unions are market participation. Clearly, this is an ideal-
centralised, strong and bargain nationally, as type schema which ® ts countries unevenly,
in Germany and Scandinavia, the employ- but Esping-A nderson argues that one of the
ment outcom e will be very different from characteristics of strong welfare states is that
that in North America where unions tend to they tend to produce a relatively large
be weak, fragmented and localised. In these ª outsider surplus popula tionº , consisting of
circum stances, a low -paid, low -skilled stra- people unable to enter into employm ent, of
tum of workers is more likely to develop. early retirees, long-te rm unem ploye d and
Esping-Anderson and his colleagues un- othe rs subsisting on the social wage. This
dertook a com parison of trends in class struc- conclusion is supported by Burgers’ (1996)
turation in six countries in the 1960s and the analysis of the im plications of the unemploy-
1980s. They assess the professionalisation, ment and disability bene® t system for the
prole tarianisation and the polarisation theses form of social pola risation in the Netherlands
using an occupation al classi® cation which which has an increasingly professionalised
groups occupations into `Fordist’ and `post- employe d workforc e and a large group of the
industrial’ categories. The countries they unemployed and econom ically inactive. In
examine are Canada, Germany, Norway, countries such as the US, on the othe r hand,
Sw eden, the UK and the US. They note that, where the welfare state is weaker, there is a
at one extreme, the US and Canada (and to a large, low-wage, service proletariat. Thus,
lesser degree, the UK) have relatively re- post-industrial societies can experience tw o
sidual welfare states, characterised by only a alternative kinds of polarisation. In the strong
low social wage guarantee and by a passive welfare states, the polarisation is betw een
approa ch to full employm ent policy. At the
other extreme, they note that Norway and A small, but highly upgra ded insider struc-
Sw eden have welfare state and industrial re- ture and a large outsider surplus popu-
lations institut ions that are lation. In the othe r case, a large service
class proletariat will constitute the pivotal
Explicitly designed to in¯ uence the em- source of polarization. (Esping-A nderson,
ploym ent structure. The social wage 1993, p. 28)
guarantee is extraordinarily high, thus re-
ducing the individu al’ s compulsion to ac- It is not possible to sum marise all their
cept unattractive jobs; both welfare states ® ndings, but they examined the degree of
feature a strong com mitm ent to collective pola risation by exam ining the changing ratio
services, thus directing employm ent to- of top±bottom jobs within the Fordist and the
wards welfare state service jobs. In both post-industrial occupational hierarchy. In the
cases we ® nd com prehensive and central- Fordist hierarchy, they took the ratio of un-
ized trade union systems which, for skilled manual workers over managers; and
decades, have pursue d solida ristic wage in the `post-industrial’ , they took unskille d
bargaining policie s aimed at minim izing service workers over professionals. They ex-
earnings differentials. (Esping-A nderson, amined the declining middle thesis by taking
1993, p. 35) the percentage share of the middle within
each of the two hierarchies. Lookin g at the
They argue that Germany represents a third top±bottom ratio in the hierarchies, they
regim e with a welfare state which is both found ª a clearly declining degree of pola riza-
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1427

tionº , particularly in the Fordist hierarchy skilled and low -paid consum er service jobs.
owing to the decline of unskille d workers. M y argum ent is that Sassen has neglected the
They also found that the percentage share of crucial role of different welfare state systems
the middle groups increased in all countries in the production on social polarisation, and
bar Sweden which saw a sharp increase in has erroneously generalised from the US ex-
the middle of the Fordist groups. perience to global cities in other societies
They were only able to study the occu- where the form of the welfare state has pro-
pational earnings structure for Germany, duced a range of very different outcom es.
Sw eden and the US, but they state that
The pervasive low-wage effect on job Immigration, Low -wage Job s and Polaris-
trends within the American consum er ser- ation in the US
vice sector stands out clearly. The Ameri-
I also wish to argue that the American situ-
can earnings distribu tion is alm ost the
ation is very different because of the large
exact opposite of the German. Instead of
and continu ing volum e of new im migrants
an extraordinarily privile ged top, the
who help to swell the ranks of new entrants
United States is characterized by its ex-
into low-paid consum er service jobs. Esping-
tremely under-privile ged bottom . The un-
Anderson notes that minoritie s occupy a dis-
skilled service workers are¼ a very badly
proportionate share of these jobs, and Soja
paid workforce. (Esping-A nderson, 1993,
and Scott (1986) point out that
p. 50)
They argue, more contentiously, that com- Over the past twenty years¼ nearly 2 mil-
paring the 1960 and 1988 earnings distri- lion im migrants from the Third W orld
bution in the US (Latin America and Asia especially) have
moved into the Los Angeles region, cre-
There does not appear to be much suppor t ating what is perhaps the largest ¯ oating
for the declining middle thesis since ex- pool of cheap unskilled labor in any ad-
actly the opposite has happened: in every vanced capitalist city. This localized labor
case, the middle-layer occupations have pool (conta ining a high proportion of un-
im proved relatively while the top levels docum ented workers) reproduc es many of
have lost. (Esping-A nderson, 1993, p. 51) the conditions of Third W orld labor mar-
They conclude by arguing that kets and plays a vital role in the sweatshop
econom y of the city¼ (it) swells the bur-
The Fordist hierarchy has everywhere ex- geoning service sector¼ provide s cheap
perienced a marked decline of the tra- dom estic services for the¼ wealthy’ . (Soja
ditiona l manual working class; to a degree and Scott, 1986, p. 253)
this has been offset by a modest rise in
clerical and sales occupations. Fordism is, The role of ethnic minoritie s in pola risation
so to speak, becom ing post-industrial- receives considerable attention from Sassen
ized¼ Despite the divergent shape of the (1991, pp. 299±317). She states that
post-industrial hierarchy, there is very lit- It is im possible to disregard the facts of
tle evidence to suggest strong polarization. race and nationality in an exam ination of
Everywhere, the trend favours higher social and econom ic processes in New
grade occupations such that the shape of York. To a lesser extent this is also the
the post-industria l occupational hierarchy case with London. (Sassen, 1991, p. 299)
is biased towards the top and the middle
rather than the bottom . (Esping-A nderson, Sassen adds that
1993, p. 53)
The large in¯ ux of im migrants into the
It is clear from this analysis that the US is United States from low -wage countries
distinctive in the im porta nce of its low- over the last ® fteen years cannot be unde r-
1428 CH RIS H AM N ETT

stood separately from this re-structuring. part, they have no other option. The welfare
(Sassen, 1991, p. 316) bene® ts available in the Netherlands, Scandi-
navia, Germany and, to a lesser extent, in
Sassen is quite correct in this. The problem
Britain, are simply not available at the same
concerns the nature of the causal process. As
level in the US. To this extent, occupational
I have argued elsewhere (Hamnett, 1994a ),
pola risation in the US may be the produc t of
Sassen argues that it is the expansion of
both the nature of the welfare state and a
low -wage jobs that has led to the grow th of
high level of im migration from low-wage
im migration.
countries. I am not alone in making this
The expansion in the supply of low -wage suggestion. Addressing the suggestion of
jobs generated by the major grow th sectors why: `increasing inequality apparently pro-
is one of the key factors in the continu- duces a shrinking middle in the US and a
ation of the ever-higher levels of the cur- fattening middle in the UK’ , Pahl (1988,
rent im migration . (Sassen, 1991, p. 316) p. 260) stated that
In other words, econom ic restructuring has The answer presum ably lies in the differ-
led to change s in labour demand and migrant ent household structures and patterns of
¯ ow s. She is opposed to the reverse expla- incom e in the tw o societies and in particu-
nation, namely that the existence of large- lar, the role of illegal im migrants and es-
scale im migration from low-wage countries tablishe d ethnic minorities that make
has enabled the grow th of low-wage service distinctive im pacts on labour markets and
jobs. She argues that advanced capitalism who also have distinctive family house-
ª may promote conditions for inform alisation. hold structures. The different systems of
The presence of large im migrant com muni- welfare will also be crucially im portant.
ties¼ can be seen as mediating in the process
The core of my argum ent is that while
of inform alization rather than directly gener-
Sassen may be right that, in New York and
ating itº (p. 282) and ª it is the econom y
Los Angeles, there is occupational and in-
rather than im migrants which is producing
com e polarisation within the paid labour
low -wage jobsº .
force, the evidence from other W estern cities
I have considerable sym pathy with this
does not support this. In most large non-
argument, partly for political reasons, in that
American cities, grow ing incom e inequality
it is easy to slip into a right-w ing, anti-im mi-
is com bine d with professionalisation of the
grant stance, blam ing im migrants for under-
paid labour force. This is not to suggest, of
cutting wages. I ® nd it dif® cult, however, to
course, that large and grow ing num bers of
overloo k the fact that the US, particularly
people are not experiencing low incom es.
the major cities, has a level of immigration
Rather, it is to argue that, in countries with
unpara llelled in most other W estern coun-
stronger welfare states, a larger proportion of
tries, and that it is also almost the only
the popula tion may be able to live outside the
W estern country to have seen the rapid
paid labour force on state bene® ts. I accept,
grow th of large num bers of low -wage service
of course, that in a grow ing num ber of W est-
jobs. Sassen refers to ª the vast supply of
ern countries the welfare state is under grave
low -wage jobs required by high incom e gen-
threat. W e may be facing the sort of future
tri® cation in its residential and com mercial
currently found in New York and Los Ange-
settingsº (Sassen, 1991, p. 9).
les. But, this is not simply a result of the
M any of these jobs are, of course, com- unm ediated operation of market forces and
mon to all W estern cities, particularly globa l privatisation. It is also an outcom e of the
cities, but New York and Los Angeles are historical legacy and also of politica l struggle
perhaps unique in the ease with which it is to preserve welfare states against neo-liberal
possible to hire cheap im migrant labour to econom ic pressures. As Dieleman and Ham-
underta ke low -paid consumer service jobs. In nett (1994) have observed, ª there is no single
SO CIAL PO LA RISA TIO N 1429

global city, only global cities, located within in London: professi onalisati on not polarisat ion,
the context of their ow n particular nation Built E nvironm ent, 20(3), pp. 192±203.
H A M NETT , C. (1995) W hy Sassen is wrong: a
state.º W e have to bring the state, the struc-
respons e to Burgers, Urban Studies , 33, pp.
ture of civil society and politic al strategy 107±110.
back into discussions of polarisation H A M NETT , C . (1996) A stroke of the Chancello r’ s
alongsid e econom ic restructuring. pen: the social and regional im pact of the Con-
servativ es abolition of higher rates of incom e
taxation , Environm ent and Planning A (forth-
References com ing).
H A M NETT , C. and C R OS S , D. (1996) Incom e equal-
A TKINS ON , A. B. (1993) W hat is happeni ng to the ity trends in London, 1979±994. (unpubli shed
distribut ion of incom e in the U K? LSE W elfare m anuscrip t).
State Program me, W SP 87. H A M NETT , C. and R AND OLPH , W . (1988) Ethnic
B E AUR EGA RD , B. (1993) Represent ing urban de- m inorities in the London labour m arket: a
cline: postw ar cities as narrativ e objects, U rban longitud inal analysis 1971±1981, New Comm u-
Affairs Quarterly , 29, 2, pp. 187±202. nity, 14, pp. 333±346.
B R O WN , P. and C R OM PTON , R. (Eds) (1994) H A RLO E , M . (1995) The People’ s H om e: Social
Econom ic Restructu ring and Social Exclusion . Rented Housing in Europe and America . O x-
London: UC L Press. ford: B asil Blackw ell.
B R U EGEL , I. and L Y ONS , M . (1995) The insecure H A RLO E , M . and M AR TENS , M . (1985) The restruc-
professio nalisatio n of London . Paper given to turing of housing provisio n in Britain and the
the ESRC London Sem inar . N etherlan ds, Environm ent and Planning A, 17,
B U C K , N . (1993) Comparative incom e distribu tion pp. 1063±1087.
in tw o welfare regim es: the impacts of house- H A RRISO N , B . and B L UESTO NE , B. (1988) The
hold and labour m arket change in Britain and G reat U -turn, C orporate Restructu ring and the
Germ any. W orking Papers of the E uropean Sci- Polarizin g of A merica . N ew Y ork: Basic
enti® c Foundatio n N etw ork on H ousehold B ooks.
Panel Studies, N o. 84. University of Essex, H ILLS , J. (1995) Inquiry into Incom e and W ealth.
Colcheste r. V olum e 2: A Sum mary of the E vidence. York:
B U C K , N . (1994) Social divisions and labour m ar- Joseph Row ntree Foundatio n.
ket change in London: nationa l, urban and H O W ELL , C. (1992) The dilem mas of post-
global factors . Paper for the ESRC London Fordism : socialist s ¯ exibility , and labour
Sem inar, 28 O ctober. m arket deregul ation in France, Politics and
B U R GER S , J. (1996) N o polarisa tion in D utch cit- Society , 20(1), pp. 71±100.
ies? Inequali ty in a corpora tist country , U rban J EN KINS , S. P. and C OW EL L , F. A. (1994) Dw arfs
Studies , 33, 1, pp. 99±105. and giants in the 1980s: Trends in the UK
C L AR KE , W . A . V . and M C N IC HOLA S , M . (1996) incom e distribut ion, Fiscal Studies , 15, pp. 99±
Re-exam ining econom ic and social polarisa tion 118.
in a m ulti-ethn ic m etropolit an area: the case of J OR D AN , B. and R EDLEY , M . (1994) Polarisati on,
Los A ngeles, Area, 28, pp. 56±63. undercla ss and the w elfare state, W ork, Em-
D IELEM AN , F. and H AM N ETT , C . (1994) Globalisa - ploym ent and Society , 8, pp. 153±176.
tion, regulatio n and the urban system , U rban K EN NETT , P. (1994) M odes of regulatio n and the
Studies , 31, pp. 357±364. urban poor, U rban Studies , 31, pp. 1017±1032.
E SPING - A ND ER SON , G. (1990) The Three W orlds of K LO OST ERM AN , R. C. (1996) Double D utch: polar-
Welfare Capitalism . Cam bridge: Polity Press. ization trends in Am sterdam and Rotterdam
E SPING - A ND ER SON , G . (Ed.) (1993) C hanging after 1980, Regional Studies , 30. (forthco ming).
Classes: Strati® cation and M obility in Post- K U TTNER , B . (1983) The declinin g m iddle, Atla-
industria l Societies . London: Sage. ntic M onthly , July, pp. 60±72.
F AIN STEIN , S., G OR DO N , I. and H A RLO E , M . (1992) L AS H , S. and U RRY , J. (1993) Econom ies of Signs
Divided C ities: New York and London in the and Spaces . London: Sage.
Contem porary W orld . Oxford: B asil B lackw ell. L AW R ENC E , R . Z. (1984) Sectoral shifts and the
G AR DINER , K . (1993) A survey of incom e in- size of the m iddle class, The Brooking s Review ,
equality over the last tw enty years: How does Fall, pp. 3±11.
the U K com pare? London School of E conom - L EVINE , M . (1992) The changin g face of urban
ics W elfare State Program me, W SP 100. capitalis m , U rban Affairs Quarterly , 28(1), pp.
H AM N ETT , C. (1994a) Social polarisa tion in global 171±80.
cities: theory and evidenc e, U rban Studies , 31, L EVY , P. (1987) The middle class: is it really
pp. 401±424. vanishin g? The Brooking s Review , Summ er,
H AM N ETT , C. (1994b) Socio-eco nom ic exchang e pp. 77±122.
1430 CH RIS H AM N ETT

MAR CUSE , P. (1989) Dual city: a muddy metaphor S AS SEN , S. (1985) C apital mobility and labour
for a quartered city, International Journal of m igration: their express ion in core cities, in:
Urban and Regional Research, 13, pp. 697±708. M . T IM BERLA KE (Ed.). U rbanizat ion in the
M A RCUS E , P. Y. (1993) W hat’ s so new about W orld Econom y. N ew York: Academ ic
divided cities?, Internat ional Journal of U rban Press.
and Regional Research , 17, pp. 355±365. S AS SEN , S. (1986) New York city: econom ic re-
M O LLENKO PF , J. H . and C AS TELLS , M . (1991) structur ing and imm igration , D evelopm ent and
Dual City: Restructu ring New York. N ew York: C hange , 17, pp. 85±119.
Russell Sage Founda tion. S AS SENS , . (1990) Finance and business services
M U RPHY , P. and W A TSO N , S. (1994) Social polar- in N ew Y ork City: internati onal linkages and
isation and Australian cities, Internat ional dom estic effects, Internat ional Social Science
Journal of U rban and Regional Research , 18, Journal , 125, pp. 287±306.
pp. 573±590. S AS SEN , S. (1991) The G lobal C ity: New York,
M Y LES , J. (1988) The expandi ng middle: Cana- London, Tokyo. Princeton , NJ: Princeton U ni-
dian evidence on the de-skilli ng debate, Ca- versity Press.
nadian Review of Sociolog y and Anthropo logy, S ILVER , H . (1993) N ational concept ions of the
25, pp. 247±267. new urban poverty: social structur al change in
P AH L , R. (1988) Som e rem arks on inform al w ork, B ritain, France and the U nited States, Interna ti-
social polarisa tion and the social structur e, onal Journal of U rban and Regional Research ,
Internat ional Journal of Urban and Regional 3, pp. 336±354.
Research , 12, pp. 247±267. S OJA , E. W . and S C OTT , A. J. (1986) L os Angeles,
P INC H , S. (1993) Social polariza tion: a com pari- capital of the late twentieth century, Society
son of evidence from Britain and the United and Space, 4, pp. 249±254.
States, Environm ent and Planning A, 25, pp. S TAR K , T. (1992) Incom e and wealth in the 1980s ,
779±795. 3rd edn. W orking Group Papers, Fabian So-
P R ETEC EILLE , E. (1995) D ivision sociale de ciety, London.
l’ espace et globalis ation: le cas de la m etropole V O GLER , C. (1985) The Nation State: The
parisienn e, SocieÂteÂs Contem poraine s (forth- N eglected D imension of Class . A ldershot :
com ing). G ow er.
S AS SEN , S. (1984) The new labour dem and in W R IGHT , E. and M AR TIN , B. (1987) The trans-
global cities, in: M .P. S M ITH (Ed.) Cities in form ation of the A merican class structure ,
Transform ation, vol. 26 Urban Affairs Annual. 1960±1980, Am erican Journal of Sociolog y,
Beverley Hills: Sage. 93, pp. 1±29.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen