Sie sind auf Seite 1von 25

Original Article

Governance practices and firm performance:


Does shareholders’ proximity to management
matter?
Received (in revised form): 5th March 2014

Richard Bozec
is a Full Professor of Accounting at the Telfer School of Management, University of Ottawa where he currently teaches advanced financial
accounting courses. He is joining the growing number of researchers in the field of corporate governance who are shifting to more holistic
analytical approaches, taking into account the variety of controls that interact to affect a firm’s performance.

Mohamed Dia
is a Full Professor of Quantitative Methods at the School of Commerce and Administration of the Faculty of Management of the Laurentian
University. He received his PhD in Management Science from the Business School of Tunis, and has been a postdoctorant at the Telfer School
of Management of the University of Ottawa and at the University of Quebec at Montreal. His research focuses on the Multicriteria Decision Aid,
Data Envelopment Analysis, Fuzzy Sets theory and in the applications of these techniques in Corporate Finance, Risk Management and
Portfolio Selection.

ABSTRACT This article investigates the link between corporate governance practices and firm
performance, a topic that received a lot of attention by regulators, interest groups and academics.
Research in this field has recently shifted from the analysis of one or more specific governance
provisions to the analysis of multiple aspects of corporate governance. In fact, most studies now
use corporate governance indexes that capture a wide range of corporate governance provisions
(index-based studies). The objective and main contribution of this article is to revisit the govern-
ance–performance relationship while taking into account shareholders’ proximity to the locus of
management. Shareholders’ proximity is defined based on ownership concentration and whether
or not the dominant/controlling shareholder holds top executive positions in the firm. The lowest
level of proximity is evidenced in firms with dispersed ownership, the highest level in controlled
entities where the controlling shareholder holds the CEO and/or Chair positions. Governance is
measured on a global scale using the Report on Business (ROB) index. The study is conducted
over a 4-year period (2002–2005) using panel regressions in a two-stage least squares framework on
a sample of Canadian publicly traded companies (470 firm-year observations). The results of the
study show a positive relationship between the ROB global index (and sub-indexes) and Tobin’s Q
whether ownership is dispersed or is concentrated in the hands of a dominant or controlling
shareholder. Shareholders’ proximity to management has no impact on the governance–perfor-
mance relationship. Overall, the results support a one-size-fits-all approach to governance, a pol-
icy adhesion that underlined the widespread adoption of Codes of Good Governance and legal/
regulatory changes in the years following Enron’s collapse in the United States. Initiatives were in
large part supported by a general consensus toward a stock market-centered model of governance.
However, with the recent debt crisis in the United States, public perception has changed.

Correspondence: Telfer School of Management,


University of Ottawa, 55 Laurier E, Ottawa, Ontario,
Canada K1N 6N5
E-mail: bozec@telfer.uottawa.ca

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
www.palgrave-journals.com/jdg/
Bozec and Dia

The credibility of such a model for governing our institutions is called into question. Our study
tempers these concerns by showing that governance controls should not account for ownership
differences in the context of publicly traded companies. Instead, good governance practices based
on an independent board of directors that promotes transparency and protects shareholders’ rights
should be prioritized whether or not ownership is dispersed or concentrated. From a corporate
governance standpoint, this study sheds new light on controlled companies. Our results show that
improving transparency and control adds value to all publicly traded companies including those
with concentrated ownership. Moreover, if holding the CEO and/or Chair positions has the
potential to increase the power of a dominant/controlling shareholder, it does not seem to trans-
late into higher agency costs to the firm, nor does the presence of insiders seems to affect
the effectiveness of the controls in place. Publicly traded companies may therefore welcome
dominant/controlling shareholders in key management positions without compromising on firm
performance and value. In any case, putting in place good governance practices seems essential to
ensure that managers/shareholders are kept in check and work in the best interests of their
company.
International Journal of Disclosure and Governance (2015) 12, 185–209. doi:10.1057/jdg.2014.3;
published online 10 April 2014

Keywords: governance indexes; performance; ownership concentration; shareholders’


proximity; insiders; one-size-fits-all approach

INTRODUCTION In academia, a growing number of research-


Corporate governance refers to the process and ers questioned this global policy of adhesion to
structure for overseeing the direction and man- the Anglo-Saxon style of ownership and con-
agement of a corporation so that it carries out its trol that gave rise to a one-size-fits-all approach
mandate and objectives effectively. Adoption of to governance. Among those researchers,
Codes of Good Governance and legal/regulatory Bebchuk and Hamdani (2009) assert that aca-
changes has spread worldwide, especially in the demics and shareholder advisers should develop
years following Enron’s collapse in the United separate methodologies to account for firms’
States. So far, initiatives were in large part specificities. They highlight the fact that firms
supported by a general consensus toward a stock with a dominant/controlling shareholder require
market-centered model of governance (Gilson, different governance arrangements than firms
2001). The Anglo-American model appeared to with dispersed ownership. In firms with concen-
be the end point of corporate governance evolu- trated ownership, the fundamental concern is the
tion at least until the recent Wall Street crisis, a risk that the dominant/controlling shareholder
crisis that was larger in scale than any prior crises may behave opportunistically at the expense of
since the Great Depression of the 1930s (Clarke, minority shareholders (risk of expropriation or
2010). The collapse of many major financial Principal–Principal problems), whereas in widely
institutions seriously calls into question the supre- held firms the fundamental concern is the risk
macy of the Anglo-American model of corporate that management may behave opportunistically
governance and the modern economic ortho- at the expense of shareholders (interests misalign-
doxy. The crisis of confidence and credibility that ment or Principal–Agent problems). Bebchuk
marked the investment scene has increased public and Hamdani argued that ownership structure
criticism of the stock market-centered approach differences should call for different control
in general, and of corporate governance controls devices. For instance, in firms with dispersed
in particular. ownership, the board must be independent from

186 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

management, whereas in firms with a domi- moderating effect of ownership on the govern-
nant/controlling shareholder, independence of ance–performance relationship is conflicting.
the board should be from the dominant/con- Prior studies suffer from the following limita-
trolling shareholder. tions. First, attention has been devoted to only
In response, in October 2011, the Canadian one aspect of shareholders’ proximity to the
Coalition for Good Governance (CCGG) issued locus of management, that is, ownership con-
a set of governance recommendations for non- centration. However, Lins (2003) shows that
dual-class companies with concentrated owner- agency costs are expected to be higher when
ship (CCGG, 2011). CCGG recognizes that a the management group has sufficient control to
dominant/controlling shareholder may have a exploit minority shareholders. Entrenchment is
legitimate interest in being actively involved in also exacerbated when key strategic positions are
the board of directors of the firm. However, held by the dominant/controlling shareholder
CCGG believes that the dominant/controlling (Hoi and Robin, 2010). Second, prior studies did
shareholder’s representation on the board (related not account for the increase risk of expropriation
directors) should be limited to the proportion of associated with the use of dual-class/multiple
his/her equity holding (but no more than two- voting shares, pyramids and cross-holdings by
thirds). Moreover, a related director is deemed dominant/controlling shareholders. These prac-
not to be independent of management (even if tices are quite common among publicly traded
he/she is in fact independent of management) if companies outside the United States and the
(i) the CEO is related to the dominant/control- United Kingdom as they allow continued foun-
ling shareholder or (ii) the director is related to a ders control over a company while injecting new
controlling shareholder (legal control). Similar equity. However, dual-class/multiple voting
guidelines were issued in 2008 by the Institute shares, pyramidal and cross-ownerships structures
for Governance of Private and Public Organiza- create a separation between voting rights and
tions (IGPPO, 2008). cash-flow rights that increases expropriation costs
Opponents to the one-size-fits-all approach and adversely affects firm performance (for
to governance find support in recent empirical example, Claessens et al, 2002; Mitton, 2002;
evidence (see La Porta et al, 1999, among Baek et al, 2004; Bozec and Laurin, 2008).
others) showing that corporate ownership Finally, prior studies only controlled for one
around the world does not resemble that of the aspect of endogeneity, that is, reverse causality
United States or the United Kingdom. Instead, or spurious correlation, and generally offered a
ownership is generally concentrated in the weak cross-validation of the mitigating effect of
hands of dominant/controlling shareholders. ownership concentration on the governance–
Moreover, proponents of the path dependency performance relationship.
theory (Bebchuk and Roe, 1999) argue that The objective of this article is to revisit the
these fundamental differences in ownership governance–performance relationship in the
structures will persist over time even in the face context of publicly traded companies while
of an emerging shareholder culture. improving of the methodology. First, we take
Despite increased attention devoted by aca- into account shareholders’ proximity to the locus
demics and some interest groups to the con- of management. Shareholders’ proximity is
trasting reality of corporate ownership outside defined based on ownership concentration and
the United States and the United Kingdom, whether or not the dominant/controlling share-
only few empirical studies have verified the holder holds a top executive position in the firm
claim that governance controls should account (CEO/Chair positions). The lowest level of
for ownership differences. Index-based studies proximity is evidenced in firms with dispersed
include Connelly et al (2012), Henry (2010) ownership, the highest level, in controlled enti-
and Klein et al (2005). Overall evidence on the ties where the controlling shareholder holds the

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 187
Bozec and Dia

CEO and/or Chair positions. Second, by taking impact on the governance–performance


the excess voting rights into account, that is, the relationship nor has the presence of insiders.
difference between voting rights and cash-flow Overall, the results support a one-size-fits-all
rights of the ultimate owner, we propose a approach to governance for publicly traded
refined classification of the sample firms along corporations.
the ownership concentration spectrum. Third, The remainder of this study is structured in
we use a combination of methods to address the the following way. The next section presents
risk of endogeneity (panel regressions in a two- the literature on the board governance–perfor-
stage least squares (2SLS) framework) and to mance relationship and introduces shareholders’
assess the moderating effect of shareholders’ proximity to the locus of management as a
proximity on the governance–performance potential moderating factor of this relationship.
relationship (moderated regressions analysis and Research methodology is described in the sec-
sub-group analysis). tion after that, including sample selection, cor-
Consistent with recent governance–perfor- porate governance index and shareholders’
mance relationship studies, we defined govern- proximity metrics. The penultimate section
ance on a broader scale, making use of the presents the empirical tests and reports the
ROB index. This index measures the quality of results. The final section summarizes and con-
the corporate governance practices of Canadian cludes the study.
companies. Published on a yearly basis by the
Globe and Mail, the index distinguishes between
four blocks of corporate governance, namely, PRIOR LITERATURE AND
board composition (BC), compensation, share- HYPOTHESES
holder rights and disclosure. The firms selected
are included in the ROB index. They are all Governance–performance
listed on the Toronto Stock Exchange (TSX) relationship
and comprise Canada’s benchmark S&P com- Agency theory is gaining increasing acceptance
posite index. as a useful theoretical approach in the field of
The study is conducted in Canada. Like the corporate governance (Durisin and Puzone,
United States, but contrary to most other non- 2009). Agency theory is the main theory used
US countries, Canada has a relatively good to predict the relationship between governance
reputation in terms of its legal and extra-legal practices and firm performance. Rooted in
institutions aimed at protecting investors. Public economics and finance, agency theory informs
equity markets are therefore well developed. At the control approach aimed at curbing self-
the same time, ownership may be highly con- serving behaviors of managers (agent) that may
centrated. Overall, Canada features companies negatively impact shareholders’ (principals’)
with a wide range of ownership structures from wealth (Eisenhardt, 1989).
widely held firms to family controlled busi- Early research on the governance–perfor-
nesses. This provides an ideal setting to assess mance relationship usually focused on one or
the potential moderating effect of shareholders’ more governance attributes. The board of
proximity on the relationship between govern- directors has generally been perceived as the
ance practices and firm performance. backbone of corporate governance. The board
The results of the study show a positive contributes to alleviating agency costs to the
relationship between the ROB indexes and firm by monitoring and rewarding top execu-
Tobin’s Q. This relationship remains positive tives to ensure wealth maximization for the
whether ownership is dispersed or concentrated shareholders. Conceptualizing the board of
in the hands of a dominant or controlling directors from the Principal–Agent framework
shareholder. Ownership configuration has no has been used to explain the way boards should

188 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

be structured and how they should be function- effective compensation, disclosure and share-
ing (Zahra and Pearce, 1989; Weisbach and holder rights practices have a positive impact on
Hermalin, 2003). One of the most debated firm value.
characteristics of the board is its independence From an agency theory standpoint, better
from management. controls and improved transparency should lead
Research in governance has recently shifted to better performance. Index-based studies rely
from the analysis of one or more specific govern- almost exclusively on provisions that are gen-
ance provisions to the analysis of multiple aspects erally consistent with a US style approach to
of corporate governance. In fact, most studies governance (Bozec and Bozec, 2012). There-
now use corporate governance indexes that fore, overall empirical results give credence to a
capture a wide range of corporate governance one-size-fits-all approach to governance. We
provisions. The main objective of these studies is propose the following general hypothesis:
to investigate whether, overall, corporate gov-
Hypothesis 1: There is a positive relationship
ernance predicts firm performance and value.
between governance practices and firm
Index-based studies are growing in number (see
performance.
Bozec and Bozec, 2012, for a review of the
literature). Overall, studies based on US firms
show conflicting results (see, among others,
Bhagat and Bolton, 2008; Chidambaran et al, Governance–performance
2008; Bebchuk et al, 2009; Spellman and relationship and ownership
Watson, 2009). In contrast, studies conducted in concentration
emerging countries and transitional economies Under the agency framework, two offsetting
(see, among others, Price et al, 2007; Bauer et al, effects emanate from ownership concentration:
2008; Garay and Gonzalez, 2008; Black et al, the potential substitution between ownership and
2009), as well as those from Europe (Beiner et al, internal controls (positive effect) and the risk of
2006; Blom and Schauten, 2008; Clacher et al, expropriation (negative effect). On the one hand,
2008; Renders et al, 2010), generally found a concentrated ownership means more power in
positive relation between corporate governance the hands of a dominant/controlling shareholder
practices and firm performance and value. that could translate into better monitoring. The
Evidence from Canadian markets includes dominant/controlling shareholders play a crucial
Foerster and Huen (2004), Klein et al (2005), role in disciplining the managers. This, in turn,
Gupta et al (2006) and Bozec et al (2010). Firms may result in agency cost reductions. In fact,
selected for these studies are listed on the TSX equity ownership has the potential to substitute
and are ranked by the Globe and Mail ROB, for other control devices inside the firm, a notion
based on a set of corporate governance provi- that has a relatively long history in financial
sions. Foerster and Huen (2004) find some economics. The earliest instance of its formulation
evidence that when portfolios of firms are that we can find is Alchian and Demsetz (1972)
created based on their governance index scores, who explain that, in addition to competition from
the top quintile of firms has significantly higher outside and inside managers, control by share-
returns than the other quintiles. The study of holders over managers is facilitated by a temporary
Bozec et al (2010) shows a positive relation consolidation of shares votes into voting blocks
between governance and firm technical effi- owned by one or two contenders (p. 788).
ciency. In contrast, results from Klein et al On the other hand, concentrated ownership
(2005) as well as from Gupta et al (2006) show increases the risk of minority shareholder
no significant relation between the ROB index expropriation. The risk of expropriation
and firm value (Tobin’s Q). However, Klein emerges when the shareholder has not only the
et al (2005) find that sub-indexes measuring ability but also the incentive to expropriate.

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 189
Bozec and Dia

As the ownership gets beyond a certain point, could be in a position to enjoy all of the private
the large owners gain nearly full control and benefits of control while internalizing only a
prefer to use firms to generate private benefits small fraction of the costs. Voting and cash-flow
of control that are not shared by minority share- rights divergence increases the risk of minority
holders (Shleifer and Vishny, 1997). Diversion shareholder expropriation because it gives the
of corporate resources may take different forms. dominant shareholder both the ability and the
One frequent mechanism through which large incentive to derive private control benefits.
shareholders can extract resources from the firm Empirical studies usually show that excess voting
is by arranging disadvantageous transactions rights adversely affect firm performance when
between their firm and other firms that they the dominant shareholder’s share of the equity
control. These deals are referred to as related (cash-flow rights) is small (for example, Claessens
party transactions. et al, 2002; Mitton, 2002; Baek et al, 2004; Bozec
In an attempt to determine the turning and Laurin, 2008).
points, Morck et al (1988) note that the risk of The use of a dual-class shares structure is
expropriation is assumed to be higher when the quite common among public companies con-
percentage of ownership of the dominant trolled by families. It allows continued founder
shareholder falls between 5 and 25 per cent. In control over a company to keep it growing
fact, with more than 5 per cent ownership, the while injecting new equity capital instead of
dominant shareholder may have the ability to debt. For instance, in Canada, Magna Interna-
expropriate. But with less than 25 per cent of tional holds both Class A and Class B shares.
the cash-flow rights, the dominant shareholder However, Class B shares carry 500 votes for
has also the incentive to expropriate because he every one Class A share vote giving Magna’s
or she does not fully internalize the costs of founder and Chairman full control over the
expropriation. The methodology developed by company with only 3.4 per cent of the com-
Morck et al (1988) has been widely used in pany’s equity. The use of dual-class shares has
research. The model has been applied to a been very controversial especially when this
variety of samples and time periods. A 10 per device translates into legal control giving the
cent threshold has often been used to identify controlling shareholder more incentive and
the presence of a dominant shareholder. The more power to extract private benefits from
results generally support a non-monotonic lin- the company. Therefore, we expect expropria-
ear relationship between firm performance and tion costs to be higher in companies where the
ownership concentration – with a change from controlling shareholder holds more than 50 per
alignment to entrenchment and then back to cent of the voting rights but less than 50 per
alignment as ownership concentrates (for exam- cent of the cash-flow rights.
ple, Hermalin and Weisbach, 1991; Chen et al, Figure 1 summarizes the expected levels of
1993; Faccio and Lasfer, 1999; Holderness et al, agency costs involved with ownership con-
1999; Short and Keasey, 1999). centration. For the purpose of this article, we
Excess voting rights – that is the separation define a ‘dominant shareholder’ as one who
between the dominant shareholder’s voting and owns less that 50 per cent of the votes but
cash-flow rights – exacerbates the risk of expro- sufficient equity (10 per cent) to influence
priation thus creating larger agency costs. corporate decision making. We take into
Bebchuk et al (2000) explain how shares with account the level of ownership concentration
multiple voting rights (dual-class shares), pyrami- as a potential indicator of shareholders’ proxi-
dal ownership structures and cross-ownership mity to the locus of management. On the one
can be used to obtain control of voting rights hand, more ownership by the dominant/con-
that are well in excess of cash-flow rights. As a trolling shareholder decreases the costs asso-
result of this separation, dominant shareholders ciated with misalignment of interests between

190 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

OWNERSHIP CONCENTRATION SPECTRUM


Voting Rights

0% 10% 50% 100%

Controlled Controlled
Dispersed Dominant (with cash-flow rights (with cash-flow rights
< 50%) ≥50%)

AGENCY COSTS FROM MISALIGNMENT


Principal-Agent problem

High Moderate Low Low

Low Moderate High Low

AGENCY COSTS FROM EXPROPRIATION


Principal-Principal problem

Figure 1: Ownership concentration and agency costs.

managers and shareholders (Principal–Agent on the governance–performance relation-


problem). On the other hand, with the excep- ship.
tion of controlled companies where voting and 2. Expropriation effect hypothesis: Ownership
cash-flow rights are aligned (or cash-flow rights concentration is expected to increase the
above 50 per cent), ownership concentration is risk of expropriation (Principal–Principal
expected to increase the risk of expropriation problem) and therefore the need for inter-
(Principal–Principal problem). The level of nal controls to curb the extraction of
ownership concentration may moderate the the firm’s resources by the dominant/con-
governance–performance relationship in the trolling shareholder. Under the expro-
following three ways: priation effect hypothesis, we should
expect a positive impact of ownership con-
1. Misalignment effect hypothesis: Dominant/ centration on the governance–perfor-
controlling shareholders have greater mance relationship.
incentives and more power to monitor 3. Reversal effect hypothesis: As portrayed in
management. Shareholders–managers mis- Figure 1, any potential gain from share-
alignment can be resolved through effective holders–managers interest alignment could
monitoring by the dominant/controlling be canceled out by a loss from an increased
shareholder. Therefore, the presence of risk of expropriation. If this offsetting effect
blockholders has the potential to decrease is taking place effectively along the owner-
the agency costs from misalignment (Prin- ship concentration spectrum, ownership
cipal–Agent problem). Under the misalign- structure should not have any significant
ment effect hypothesis, we should expect a impact on the overall agency costs of
negative impact of ownership concentration the firm (costs from misalignment and

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 191
Bozec and Dia

expropriation costs combined). Under the are expected to be relatively low since share-
reversal effect hypothesis, we should not holders–managers misalignment is resolved
expect any impact of ownership concen- through effective monitoring by the controlling
tration on the governance–performance shareholder. Moreover, when the cash-flow
relationship. rights held by the controlling shareholder are
aligned with his/her voting rights, the incentive
Few empirical studies analyzed the moderating
to expropriate minority shareholders is expected
effect of ownership concentration on the gov-
to be significantly reduced.
ernance–performance relationship. The list of
The risk of endogeneity includes spurious
some of these studies is provided in Table 1
correlation and reverse causality. Panel regression
along with details on the methodology used,
is one common method to control for spurious
including sample selection, metrics, methods
correlation, whereas the use of instrument vari-
and results. Index-based studies include
ables in a 2SLQ/3SLS framework (and/or in a
Connelly et al (2012), Henry (2010) and
system of simultaneous equations) helps to
Klein et al (2005). Non-index-based studies
address reverse causality. Only by using both
(Anderson and Reeb, 2004; Dong-Song and
methods at once could one control for the overall
Zootae, 2007; Setia-Atmaya, 2009) focus on
risk of endogeneity. Moreover, two techniques
one aspect of governance, namely, board inde-
can be employed to test the moderating effect of
pendence. Overall, empirical evidence on the
ownership concentration on the relationship
mitigating effect of ownership is conflicting.
between governance and performance: a moder-
Results show that the impact of ownership
ated regression analysis incorporating two-way
concentration on the governance–performance
interactive terms (Ownership × Governance) and
relationship is either positive (Setia-Atmaya,
a sub-group analysis. A moderated regression
2009), negative (Dong-Song and Zootae,
analysis aims at assessing the form of the hypothe-
2007), non-existent (Henry, 2010) or mixed
sized relationship while a sub-group analysis helps
(Klein et al, 2005). Additional evidence supports
to assess the strength of the contingent relationship.
a positive relationship between governance and
Cross-validation of the results is possible when
performance only for a sub-group of firms, that
incorporating both techniques. However, none
is, firms with no pyramidal structure (Connelly
of the index-based studies reported in Table 1
et al, 2012) and family firms (Anderson and
have combined these different methods (panel
Reeb, 2004).
regressions with instrumented variables, moder-
With the exception of Connelly et al (2012),
ated regressions and sub-group analysis) therefore
none of the studies reported in Table 1 incorpo-
decreasing the overall validity of the results.
rated excess voting rights in the analysis.
Given the mixed empirical evidence and the
Connelly et al (2012) used a dummy variable
possible theoretical predictions regarding the
indicating the presence of a control-enhancing
moderating effect of ownership structure on
pyramidal ownership structure to create sub-
the governance–performance relationship, the
groups. However, they do not measure the
following hypothesis is tested using a two-tailed
separation between voting rights and cash-flow
approach.
rights of the ultimate owner. Not accounting for
excess voting rights might result in a poor Hypothesis 2: The ownership structure,
classification of the sample firms along the own- whether dispersed or concentrated in the
ership spectrum. From the agency theory stand- hands of a dominant or controlling share-
point, Figure 1 shows that controlled companies holder holding less than 50% of the cash-
that do not make use of any dual-class shares flow rights, has no impact on the relation-
and/or pyramids/crossholdings do not present ship between governance practices and
any particular issues. In this context, agency costs firm performance.

192 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Table 1: Moderating effect of ownership concentration on the governance–performance relationship review of empirical studies
Study Country Sample Metrics Methods Results
© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591

Governance (G) Performance Ownership Panel 2SLS 3SLS Moderated Sub-


(P) regression groups
analysis analysis

Index-based studies
Connelly et al Thailand 216 family firms Self-constructed Tobin’s Q High/Low (40% — √ — √ Positive G–P relationship
(2012) (2005) index (117 cut off point) only when cash-flow
provisions) rights and voting rights
are aligned
Henry (2010) Australia 120 firms listed Self-constructed Agency costs % equity held by √ — √ — Positive G–P relationship
on the ASX index (8 insiders and No moderating effect of
(1992–2002) provisions) outsiders ownership
(institutions, concentration
others)
Klein et al (2005) Canada 263 firms listed ROB index Tobin’s Q Type: Family, — √ — √ No relationship between
International Journal of Disclosure and Governance

on the TSX from the government, total ROB index and P


(2002) Globe and Mail widely-held, Mixed results based on
mixed ownership type and
sub-indexes
Non-index-based studies
Setia-Atmaya Australia 316 firms listed Board Tobin’s Q 1/0 (20% cut off √ √ √ √ Positive G–P relationship.
(2009) on the ASX independence point) Positive moderating
(2000–2005) effect of ownership
concentration
Dong-Song & Korea 347 firms listed Board Profit % equity held by — — √ — Positive G–P relationship
Zootae (2007) on the KSE independence insiders and Negative moderating

Governance practices and firm performance


(1999) outsiders effect of outside
(controlling ownership
and large concentration
shareholders)
Anderson & The United 403 firms from Board Tobin’s Q Family/Non- √ √ √ √ Positive G–P relationship
Reeb (2004) States the S&P 500 independence family only for family firms.
(1992–1999) No relationship for
non-family firms
Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
193
Bozec and Dia

Governance–performance achieve either absolute control or de facto con-


relationship and insider positions trol (control with less than 50 per cent of the
The roles of chairperson and CEO are funda- votes). The dominant/controlling shareholder
mental. The chairperson ensures that the might have more incentive to expropriate
board’s activities are carried out with due (especially if the separation between his/her
diligence and information is provided to the voting rights and cash-flow rights is significant)
directors on a timely basis. The board’s chair- but also more ability to corrupt the board in
person has the greatest influence over the order to extract private benefits from the firm
board’s functioning. The CEO is responsible (especially if the shareholder owns more than
to the board for overall strategy and day-to-day 50 per cent of the votes).
affairs of the company. As the nature and In such circumstances, Dahya et al (2008)
emphasis of these two roles are clearly different, argue that appointment of a strong board can
corporate governance codes usually recom- still be a deterrent to diversion despite the fact
mend that the Chairman and CEO positions that the dominant/controlling shareholder
be assumed by different individuals (non-dua- could easily remove directors and appoint new
lity structure). ones. First, the incentive for an outside director
At this stage, the concept of shareholders’ to carry out his/her tasks may come from the
proximity to management can easily be refined market for directors. Assuming that such a
by considering whether or not the dominant/ market is in place, any failure to monitor may
controlling shareholder is also a top executive of result in losses in human capital for the director.
the firm. Proximity to management is assumed Second, boards can be held liable for approving
to be increased whenever the dominant/con- unfair or prejudicial transactions between the
trolling shareholder is also the CEO and/or dominant/controlling shareholder and the firm.
Chairman of the board. In this context, Hoi and In addition, Dahya et al (2008) show that
Robin (2010) present supporting evidence that dominant/controlling shareholders may be
entrenchment is exacerbated when the domi- willing to reduce their diversion of corporate
nant shareholder serves as a top executive. In resources by appointing independent directors
the same vein, Lins (2003) shows that since it is in exchange for an increase in firm value.
the management group that administers a firm, In sum, in line with Dahya et al (2008), if we
the reduction in value from potentially higher assume that the presence of insiders increases
agency costs is more when the management the agency costs without compromising the
group has sufficient control to exploit minority effectiveness of governance controls, we pro-
shareholders. Holding strategic positions pose the following hypothesis:
enhances the dominant shareholder’s ability to
Hypothesis 3: There is a positive and stronger
expropriate, potentially increasing expropria-
relationship between governance practices
tion costs. Therefore, we expect the govern-
and firm performance when the dominant
ance–performance relationship to be positive
or the controlling shareholder holding less
and stronger when the dominant shareholder or
that 50% of the cash-flow rights is also the
the controlling shareholder holding less than
Chairman and/or the CEO.
50 per cent of the cash-flow rights is also a top
executive of the firm.
One could argue that proximity to manage-
ment means more power in the hands of a METHODOLOGY
dominant/controlling shareholder that could be
used to control the board therefore compromis- Sample selection
ing its effectiveness. This situation is more likely This study covers a period of 4 years from
to happen when dual-class shares are used to 2002 to 2005. Canada experienced important

194 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

reforms during this period including the enact- index distinguishes between four blocks of
ment of Bill 198 in 2002, the equivalent of the corporate governance. The first block, BC,
Sarbanes Oxley Act in the United States. (maximum of 37 marks out of 100), assesses
Therefore, we expect more variation in corpo- the independence of the members serving on
rate governance practices during this time the board, the audit committee, the compensa-
frame, a precondition for the use of panel tion committee and the remuneration commit-
regressions. We also choose our sample period tee. The second block deals with compensation
because of data availability considerations. The (maximum of 25 marks) and captures, among
ROB index and the weight assigned to each other things, whether the directors and the
provision are relatively consistent across the CEO are required to own stocks. The third
4-year period under investigation. Substantial block, shareholder rights (maximum of 28
changes have been made in the construction of marks), evaluates different scenarios that could
the index in the following years. impair shareholder rights including the presence
We initially selected firms covered in the of non-voting or subordinate shares and
2005 Globe and Mail survey (hereafter, Report employee stock options. Finally, the fourth
on Business or ROB). This survey is based on block, ‘disclosure’ (maximum of 10 marks),
209 firms listed on the S&P/TSX composite measures the availability and quality of informa-
index. From that list, we eliminated financial tion on corporate governance. Appendix A
institutions (n = 28). We also excluded firms presents the major criteria considered within
with incomplete time series data on the ROB the ROB rating categories for 2005.
index for the 2002–2005 period (n = 51). The As our study uses panel data, the index and
remaining sample consists of 130 firms or 520 the weight assigned to each provision must be
firm-year observations. Next, we excluded consistent across the 4-year period under inves-
companies with a controlling shareholder hold- tigation. This condition is largely met for the
ing more than 50 per cent of the cash-flow ROB index from 2002 to 2005. When minor
rights (n = 32 firm-year observations). These differences do exist, we re-estimated the
companies represent only a small portion of the weights of the indexes and sub-indexes in line
controlled companies in our sample (25 per cent). with the weighting scales of the ROB index of
Moreover, agency costs for these companies are 2005. For instance, the maximum allocated to
expected to be relatively low (see Figure 1). We the BC sub-index was 40 marks from 2002 to
also excluded outliers defined as Q ratio over 2004 but only 37 marks in 2005. In that case,
4.00 (n = 18 firm-year observations). Our final the adjustment consists of multiplying the sub-
sample (470 firm-year observations) comprises index ‘Board Composition’ from 2002 to 2004
companies with dispersed ownership (n = 187 by 37/40. A similar process was carried out to
firm-year observations), dominant shareholders standardize the other sub-indexes.
(n = 179 firm-year observations) and companies The use of commercial ratings has been
controlled with less than 50 per cent of cash- recently criticized for not equally weighting
flow rights (n = 104 firm-year observations). governance indicators and, as a result, for being
We collected financial data from StockGuide too subjective (Daines et al, 2010). To test the
and ownership data from firms’ proxy circulars reliability and credibility of the ROB index, we
(available on SEDAR Website). collected the 2004 corporate governance ratings
for each firm in our sample from Institutional
Shareholder Services (ISS), a well-established US
Corporate governance metrics governance index (CGQ ratings). The ISS index
We define governance practices using the index was available for the firms comprising our final
developed by ROB that captures a wide variety sample. Pearson correlation tests reveal that the
of governance indicators. More precisely, the 2004 ROB and ISS global indexes are highly

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 195
Bozec and Dia

correlated (57 per cent). Similar results are found (with the controlling shareholder hold-
for the 2004 ROB and ISS board of directors ing (1) or not holding (0) an executive
sub-indexes (58 per cent) adding credibility to position).
the ROB index employed in our study.

Shareholders’ proximity Firm value


Shareholders’ proximity to management is In line with prior research (see Table 1), we
defined based on ownership concentration and focus on a widely used market-based perfor-
whether or not the dominant/controlling mance measure: Tobin’s Q. More precisely, we
shareholder holds the Chairman and/or the use an approximation of Tobin’s Q (Q), which
CEO positions. Ownership concentration is is defined as the market value of equity plus the
measured based on voting rights. Following book value of debt divided by the book value of
previous studies (La Porta et al, 1999; Claessens total assets. A high Q value indicates that the
et al, 2002), we focus on the ultimate, rather capital market expects the firm to have good
than the immediate, dominant/controlling growth perspectives and valuable intangibles
shareholder. Pyramidal structures in many cor- (Cronqvist and Nilsson 2003). In this sense, Q
porations in Canada suggest that identifying an particularly captures the expected capitalized
immediate dominant/controlling shareholder is value of agency costs resulting from different
not sufficient for defining corporate ownership ownership structures (Morck et al, 1988). Note
structure (Bozec and Laurin, 2008). Therefore, that the denominator of the Q ratio should be
when the principal shareholder of a firm is the replacement cost of assets. Since the data
another corporate entity, we find the principal required to calculate the replacement cost of
shareholder of that entity, and so on, until we assets is not available, we follow previous
find the ultimate dominant/controlling share- research using the book value of assets.
holder. The principal shareholder is defined as
the shareholder that holds at least 10 per cent of
Control variables
the voting rights. If more than one shareholder
On the basis of prior studies, we introduce a set
has greater than 10 per cent of the voting rights,
of firm-specific control variables, including firm
the dominant/controlling shareholder is the
size (SIZE), age (AGE), debt (DEBT), growth
shareholder with the greatest voting rights. We
(CAPEX), industry (SECTOR) and years
manually collected the ultimate dominant/con-
(YEAR). SIZE is defined as the log of total
trolling shareholder’s voting rights. The follow-
assets, whereas AGE is a dummy variable that
ing categories are created:
takes the value of 1 if the firm has been operating
1- Firms with dispersed ownership (DISPERSED): for at least 10 years and 0 otherwise. The impact
Firms with no shareholder holding more of firm size and age on performance is, however,
than 10 per cent of the voting rights. unclear. If large and old firms usually have more
2- Firms with a dominant shareholder (DOMI- liquid trading and more diversified activities than
NANT): Firms with a shareholder holding small and young firms (Claessens et al, 2002),
at least 10 per cent but less than 50 per cent they also usually have fewer growth opportu-
of the voting rights (with the dominant nities (Morck et al, 2002).
shareholder holding (1) or not holding (0) DEBT is defined as the book value of long-
an executive position). term debt over total assets. Debt can play a
3- Controlled entities (CONTROLLED): positive role in motivating managers to be
Firms with a shareholder holding at least efficient in order to meet debt repayments
50 per cent of the voting rights, but less (Stiglitz, 1985), or because it reduces agency
than 50 per cent of the cash-flow rights costs associated with the existence of free cash

196 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

flows by reducing the cash flow available for 2SLS panel regressions
managers to spend at their discretion (Jensen, Panel regressions help to control for spurious
1986). However, debt can also exert a negative correlation. To control for reverse causality, we
influence on firm performance because debt run instrumental variables in a 2SLS panel
repayments may sometimes force managers to regressions framework. The challenge with this
forego profitable investment projects (McConnell approach is to find good instruments, that is,
and Servaes, 1995). variables that are correlated with the endogen-
Our proxy for growth opportunities ous variable (ROB), but uncorrelated (or not
(CAPEX) is measured as capital and R&D directly correlated) with the dependent vari-
expenditures over total assets. Following pre- ables (Q). Given the lack of a specific theore-
vious studies using Tobin’s Q (see, for instance, tical framework, we follow previous Canadian
Morck et al, 1988), we expect growth to posi- studies using the ROB index (Klein et al, 2005;
tively affect firm performance. We also control Bozec and Bozec, 2007) and consider, as a
for industry and year effects. Two series of potential instrument, a dummy variable indicat-
dummy variables are created: SECTOR for each ing whether or not the firm is cross-listed on a
industry (using Stockguide classification), and US stock exchange (US-Listed). About 40 per
YEAR for each year between 2002 and 2005. cent of our sampled firms are listed on a US
In cases where the voting rights and cash- exchange. Consistent with Klein et al (2005),
flow rights of the dominant/controlling share- we find US-Listed to be highly correlated with
holder were not aligned, we collected his/her the ROB index and sub-indexes but uncorre-
cash-flow rights. We then measured the gap lated with Q, a preliminary indication of the
between voting rights and cash-flow rights instrument’s validity. In the first stage, ROB
(WEDGE). As additional metrics of excess index is regressed on the instruments, including
voting rights, we use a dummy variable, which US-Listed, to obtain the fitted values. The
takes the value of either 1 if the ultimate second-stage regression uses the instrumented
shareholder’s voting rights exceed his cash- ROB variables (or fitted value from the first
flow rights or 0 otherwise (SEPARATION), stage).
and a ratio variable that consists of cash-flow
rights over voting rights (CFR/VR). The
following example will illustrate the process. RESULTS
Suppose that a family owns 40 per cent of the
shares of a publicly traded firm A, which in Descriptive and univariate analysis
turn owns 30 per cent of the equity of firm B. Table 2 reports summary statistics of share-
In this case, the family would be identified as holders’ proximity for firms with concentrated
the dominant shareholder of firm B. The ownership. Results show large gaps between
family is said to control indirectly 30 per cent voting rights and cash-flow rights for con-
of the voting rights in firm B (that is, the trolled companies with an average separation
weakest link in the chain of voting rights) and ratio of 0.53 compared with 0.04 for compa-
about 12 per cent of the cash-flow rights (that nies with a dominant shareholder. High
is, the product of 40 and 30 per cent). In this deviation from the one share-one vote princi-
example, the magnitude of the separation ple was expected for the sub-sample of con-
between voting and cash-flow rights trolled companies as it comprises firms with a
(EXCESS) would be 0.18, that is, the percen- shareholder holding more than 50 per cent of
tage of voting rights less the percentage of the voting rights but less than 50 per cent of
cash-flow rights (0.30–0.12 = 0.18). the cash-flow rights. Deviation from the one
Appendix B presents the definition of the share-one vote principle only affects 22 per
variables used in our study. cent of the firms with a dominant shareholder.

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 197
Bozec and Dia

Table 2: Summary statistics of shareholders’ proximity


Dominant and controlled Dominant Controlled
Mean (standard deviation) Mean (standard deviation) Mean (standard deviation)

Ownership concentration (%)


• Voting rights (VR) 0.3871 0.1999 0.7092
(0.2721) (0.1079) (0.1303)
• Cash-flow rights (CFR) 0.1620 0.1554 0.1734
(0.1152) (0.0938) (0.1447)
Separation between voting rights and cash-flow rights
• Wedge (VR–CFR) 0.2251 0.0446 0.5358
(0.2702) (0.0996) (0.1694)
• Multiple voting shares 31.54 13.71 61.54
(% of firms)
• Non-voting shares 20.07 6.86 42.31
(% of firms)
• Pyramids (% of firms) 14.13 6.70 26.92
• Deviation from one share-one 50.88 22.35 100.00
vote (% of firms)
Insider positions held by the ultimate owner (%)
• Chair 68.46 49.71 100.00
• CEO 52.69 31.43 88.46
• CEO and/or Chair 68.46 49.71 100.00

n 283 179 104

Consistent with the agency theory framework the three sub-samples. Overall, results show
portrayed in Figure 1, we expect the risk of that the average score of the ROB total index
expropriation to be higher in controlled is higher for firms with dispersed ownership
companies. (74.05) compared with firms with a dominant
Results from Table 2 show that controlling shareholder (69.60) and a controlling share-
shareholders managed to achieve control holder (59.49). Similar results are obtained for
via the use of (i) multiple voting rights in the BC and shareholders’ rights sub-indexes.
61 per cent of the cases, (ii) non-voting shares Both sub-indexes appear to most strongly
in 42 per cent of the cases and (iii) pyramidal influence the ROB total index. Low scores on
structures in 26 per cent of the cases. All the BC sub-index for controlled companies is
the controlling shareholders were holding key consistent with prior studies showing that own-
positions in their respective firms, whereas ership concentration has a significant negative
only 50 per cent of the dominant shareholders impact on board independence (see, for
did. Once control is achieved, the controlling instance, Anderson and Reeb, 2004; Setia-
shareholder seems to get more engaged in the Atmaya, 2009). Low scores on shareholders’
strategic and daily activities of his/her firm. rights for controlled companies may be
These results are similar to those of prior explained in part by the widespread use of
Canadian studies including King and Santor non-voting or subordinate voting shares that
(2008) and Bozec et al (2010). affect 42 per cent of the controlled firms
Table 3 reports summary statistics of the compared with only 7 per cent for the firms
ROB indexes and firm performance (Q) for with a dominant shareholder (see Table 2). Ten

198 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

Table 3: Summary statistics of ownership concentration, corporate governance practices and firm
performance (Q)
Levels of ownership concentration Tests for differences
Dispersed Dominant Controlled P values
Dispersed versus Dominant versus
dominant controlled

ROB total index


Mean 74.0549 69.6036 59.4977 0.0023 0.0000
Median 75.8952 70.1714 61.2641 — —
Standard deviation 14.3200 13.3657 11.1542 — —
BC sub-index
Mean 30.4278 28.3073 24.6827 0.0084 0.0002
Median 32.0000 30.0000 25.0000 — —
Standard deviation 7.1556 8.1337 6.7411 — —
Compensation sub-index
Mean 12.1946 11.8704 11.8572 0.4466 0.9757
Median 12.0000 12.0000 12.0000 — —
Standard deviation 4.4618 3.6154 3.3066 — —
Shareholder rights sub-index
Mean 22.0809 20.4137 14.0624 0.0014 0.0000
Median 23.3333 21.6364 12.8333 — —
Standard deviation 4.5289 5.3344 5.3150 — —
Disclosure sub-index
Mean 9.3515 9.0123 8.8955 0.3220 0.7830
Median 10.4000 9.5333 9.7667 — —
Standard deviation 3.2224 3.3216 3.6240 — —
Firm performance (Q)
Mean 1.4571 1.4395 1.0672 0.8122 0.0000
Median 1.1944 1.2796 0.9092 — —
Standard deviation 0.7268 0.6874 0.5562 — —

n (total = ) 187 179 104 — —

marks were allocated to this provision alone (see may translate into better monitoring that
Appendix A). reduces the need of internal controls (substi-
Overall, results show that firms with tution argument).
dispersed ownership complied with best Average Tobin’s Q, is significantly higher for
practice provisions more rigorously than firms with dispersed ownership (1.45) and firms
firms with concentrated ownership. There with a dominant shareholder (1.43) compared
are two possible explanations for these results. with controlled companies (1.06). Concentra-
One could argue that controlling share- tion of ownership among non-controlled com-
holders may prefer to put in place weak panies does not seem to impact firm perfor-
controls or an opaque structure in order to mance. On the other hand, capital market
facilitate acts at their discretion (expropria- participants seem to expect controlled compa-
tion argument). Alternatively, more power nies to have lower growth perspectives than
in the hands of a controlling shareholder non-controlled firms.

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 199
Bozec and Dia

Table 4: ROB indexes and firm value (Q) full sample (Hypothesis 1)
Expected sign Total index Board Compensation Shareholder rights Disclosure

Intercept ? 3.989 3.931 4.192 4.021 4.211


(4.890)*** (4.616)*** (5.149)*** (4.878)*** (5.642)***
ROB index + 0.009 0.009 0.028 −0.002 0.026
(2.918)*** (1.536)* (4.058)*** (−0.277) (5.610)***
WEDGE − 0.022 −0.140 −0.167 −0.249 −0.211
(0.121) (−1.037) (−1.528) (−3.457)*** (−1.527)
SIZE ? −0.234 −0.207 −0.228 −0.197 −0.227
(−5.649)*** (−4.601)*** (−5.288)*** (−4.219)*** (−5.472)***
DEBT ? −0.587 −0.588 −0.598 −0.555 −0.505
(−3.057)*** (−2.919)*** (−2.735)*** (−2.585)** (−2.179)**
CAPEX + 2.531 2.581 2.554 2.553 2.466
(4.083)*** (4.360)*** (4.302)*** (4.478)*** (4.006)***
AGE ? −0.005 0.009 −0.008 0.046 0.027
(−0.031) (0.055) (−0.049) (0.287) (0.176)
SECTOR ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year effect ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm effect ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adjusted R2 0.220 0.200 0.219 0.191 0.223


F (10.452)*** (9.368)*** (10.378)*** (8.912)*** (10.587)***
n 470 470 470 470 470

*, **, ***: statistically significant for the threshold values of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively.

Multivariate analysis investment projects (McConnell and Servaes,


1995). As expected, the variable CAPEX, a
Governance–performance relationship proxy for growth opportunities, is positive and
(Hypothesis 1) significant in all the regressions.
Table 4 reports the multivariate results on the
relationship between ROB indexes and Q.
Panel regressions (2SLS approach) are per- Governance–performance relationship
formed on the full sample. Overall, with the and ownership concentration
exception of the shareholders rights sub- (Hypothesis 2)
index, results show a positive and significant This section addresses one aspect of share-
impact of the ROB total index and sub- holders’ proximity to the locus of management,
indexes on firm performance. These results that is, ownership concentration. Panel regres-
are consistent with Hypothesis 1 and prior sions from Table 5 aim at analyzing the impact,
non-US index-based studies. if any, of ownership concentration on the
Results from Table 4 also show a negative relationship between the ROB total index and
and significant impact of firm size and debts on Tobin’s Q. First, moderated regressions are
firm performance. These results suggest that performed on the full sample (see the first two
larger firms may have fewer growth opportu- columns of Table 4) while incorporating
nities than smaller firms (Morck et al, 2002). In dichotomous ownership variables (concentrated
addition, when the level of debts is increasing, versus dispersed; controlled versus dominant/
managers may be forced to forego profitable dispersed) and two-way interaction variables

200 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

Table 5: ROB total index, firm value (Q) and ownership concentration (Hypothesis 2)
Expected sign Full sample Sub-samples
Dominant/ Controlled Dispersed Dominant Controlled
Controlled (1/0) (1/0)

Intercept ? 4.003 4.035 3.296 4.795 5.310


(4.520)*** (4.594)*** (5.036)*** (4.946)*** (3.623)***
ROB index + 0.012 0.011 0.012 0.011 0.006
(1.972)** (2.233)** (1.965)* (2.513)** (4.470)***
Ownership (1/0) None 0.174 0.567 — — —
(0.488) (2.555)** — — —
OWNERSHIP/ROB None −0.004 −0.005 — — —
(−0.885) (−0.914) — — —
WEDGE − 0.117 −0.326 — 0.279 −0.418
(0.715) (−1.009) — (0.570) (−1.120)
SIZE ? −0.245 −0.244 −0.175 −0.288 −0.336
(−5.539)*** (−5.944)*** (−3.789)*** (−4.914)*** (−3.728)***
DEBT ? −0.548 −0.591 −0.993 −0.275 −0.538
(−2.942)*** (−3.297)*** (−1.524) (−3.590)*** (−3.873)***
CAPEX + 2.504 2.504 1.422 2.665 0.426
(4.084)*** (3.981)*** (2.194)** (2.802)*** (0.764)
AGE ? −0.009 −0.018 0.086 −0.354 0.711
(−0.059) (−0.114) (0.381) (−1.098) (4.070)***
SECTOR ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year effect ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm effect ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Adjusted R2 0.219 0.219 0.112 0.262 0.265
F (9.220)*** (9.229)*** (2.802)*** (6.755)*** (3.851)***
n 470 470 187 179 104

*, **, ***: statistically significant for the threshold values of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively.

(OWNERSHIP/ROB). Then, the govern- In Table 6, we rerun the tests from Table 5
ance–performance relationship is analyzed for while replacing the ROB total index by the BC
each of the three sub-groups (dispersed, domi- sub-index. BC sub-index includes key govern-
nant and controlled). ance provisions related to the composition and
On the full sample, the coefficient of the functioning of the board of directors. Consis-
ROB total index is positive and significant. tent with Table 5, results from Table 6 show no
However, as expected (Hypothesis 2), the significant relationship between the interactive
coefficient of the interactive term OWNER- term OWNERSHIP/BC and Q. However, the
SHIP/ROB is not suggesting that the positive coefficient of the BC sub-index is positive and
relationship between the overall ROB index significant only for the sub-sample of firms with
and Q is not derived from closely or widely concentrated ownership (dominant and con-
held firms. Hypothesis 2 is further supported trolled) suggesting a stronger relationship
when panel regressions are run for each of the between BC and Q for closely-held firms.
three sub-samples. In each case, the coefficient These results are consistent with those of Setia-
of the ROB total index remains positive and Atmaya (2009) who studied board indepen-
significant for each of the three sub-groups. dence (see Table 1).

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 201
Bozec and Dia

Table 6: BC sub-index, firm value (Q) and ownership concentration (Hypothesis 2)


Expected Full Sample Sub-Samples
sign
Dominant/ Controlled Controlled Dispersed Dominant Controlled
(1/0) (1/0)

Intercept ? 4.076 3.984 2.882 4.886 5.057


(4.387)*** (4.447)*** (3.435)*** (5.184)*** (3.177)***
Board index + 0.008 0.010 0.007 0.011 0.009
(0.744) (1.203) (0.734) (1.874)* (5.966)***
Ownership (1/0) None −0.150 0.235 — — —
(−0.588) (1.254) — — —
OWNERSHIP/ None 0.001 −0.001 — — —
BOARD
(0.135) (−0.166) — — —
WEDGE − −0.014 −0.450 — −0.043 −0.403
(−0.106) (−1.376) — (−0.090) (−0.974)
SIZE ? −0.211 −0.211 −0.108 −0.266 −0.313
(−4.510)*** (−4.573)*** (−2.650)*** (−4.252)*** (−3.254)***
DEBT ? −0.565 −0.599 −1.151 −0.220 −0.503
(−2.893)*** (−3.118)*** (−1.679)* (−2.348)** (−4.896)***
CAPEX + 2.579 2.568 1.502 2.744 0.300
(4.288)*** (4.283)*** (2.262)** (2.940)*** (0.434)
AGE ? −0.008 0.005 0.088 −0.295 0.687
(−0.047) (0.027) (0.381) (−0.871) (4.760)***
SECTOR ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year effect ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm effect ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adjusted R2 0.198 0.197 0.088 0.240 0.259


F (8.242)*** (8.172)*** (2.381)*** (6.109)*** (3.772)***
n 470 470 187 179 104

*, **, ***: statistically significant for the threshold values of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively.

Results from panel regressions using the Com- total index and the BC sub-index. Results are
pensation, Shareholders’ Rights and Disclosure reported in Table 7. The variable INSIDER
ROB sub-indexes are not reported here but are takes the value of 1 if the dominant/controlling
overall similar to those presented in Tables 5 and 6. shareholder is holding the CEO and/or Chair
position. No test is performed on the sub-sample
of controlled companies because all the control-
Governance performance relationship ling shareholders are insiders (see Table 2).
and insider positions (Hypothesis 3) In all the regressions, neither the INSIDER
This section addresses the second dimension of variable nor the interactive term INSIDER/
shareholders’ proximity that takes into account ROB are significant. Contrary to Hypothesis 3,
the level of involvement of the dominant/ the results show that holding strategic positions
controlling shareholder in the daily activities by a dominant/controlling shareholder does not
of the firm. Regressions are performed on the have any impact on the governance–performance
full sample and sub-samples with the ROB relationship. Moreover, the presence of insiders

202 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

Table 7: ROB Index, firm value (Q) and insider positions (Hypothesis 3)
Expected ROB Total Index BC Sub-Index
sign
Full sample Dominant and Dominant Full sample Dominant and Dominant
controlled controlled

Intercept ? 3.446 3.884 4.584 3.588 4.076 4.701


(2.863)*** (3.512)*** (3.830)*** (3.304)*** (4.252)*** (4.652)***
ROB index + 0.017 0.016 0.018 0.020 0.020 0.022
(2.070)** (1.737)* (1.901)* (1.286) (1.319) (1.498)
Insider (1/0) − 0.752 0.706 0.726 0.459 0.365 0.425
(1.514) (1.162) (1.136) (1.235) (0.793) (1.000)
INSIDER/ − −0.009 −0.011 −0.011 −0.013 −0.015 −0.018
ROB
(−1.180) (−1.074) (−1.164) (−1.098) (−1.029) (−1.267)
WEDGE − −0.029 0.022 0.387 −0.170 −0.055 0.157
(−0.201) (0.189) (0.564) (−1.957)* (−0.380) (0.230)
SIZE ? −0.240 −0.272 −0.302 −0.210 −0.251 −0.273
(−5.827)*** (−6.135)*** (−5.708)*** (−4.420)*** (−4.964)*** (−4.482)***
DEBT ? −0.592 −0.310 −0.333 −0.592 −0.298 −0.288
(−2.585)** (−2.728)*** (−1.809)* (−2.571)** (−2.401)** (−1.451)
CAPEX + 2.504 2.646 2.629 2.601 2.793 2.822
(3.970)*** (3.215)*** (2.686)*** (4.536)*** (3.751)*** (3.125)***
AGE ? −0.019 −0.030 −0.362 −0.007 −0.017 −0.310
(−0.128) (−0.172) (−1.159) (−0.040) (−0.091) (−0.973)
SECTOR ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Year effect ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Firm effect ? Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adjusted R2 0.221 0.274 0.262 0.199 0.257 0.240


F (9.333)*** (7.638)*** (5.873)*** (8.266)*** (7.084)*** (5.317)***
n 470 283 179 470 283 179

*, **, ***: statistically significant for the threshold values of 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively.

has no direct impact on Q which suggests that the First, following previous studies (see, for
overall agency costs of the firm are not influenced instance, Villalonga and Amit, 2006; Bozec
by insiders. Ownership concentration alone may and Laurin, 2008), we re-conducted our panel
give the dominant/controlling shareholder suffi- regressions using industry-adjusted Q instead of
cient power to expropriate. Q. For each firm, industry-adjusted Q is
Similar results are obtained when governance is defined as the difference between Q and indus-
measured based on the Compensation, Share- try average Q. Second, prior evidence (see Black
holders’ Rights and Disclosure ROB sub-indexes. et al, 2009) shows that governance has influence
on future performance. Since our tests consider
only the contemporaneous relationship bet-
Robustness checks ween ROB indexes and firm value, we rerun
The following additional tests were performed our multivariate analysis adding lagged ROB
in order to verify the robustness of our results. indexes. Third, we re-conducted our tests using

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 203
Bozec and Dia

OLS estimations instead of panel regressions. concentration spectrum. If ownership by a


OLS were performed using pooled and cross- dominant/controlling shareholder is likely to
sectional data (for each year from 2002 to decrease agency costs associated with misalign-
2005). Fourth, we replaced WEDGE by differ- ment of interests between managers and share-
ent metrics which all capture the separation of holders (Principal–Agent problem), it increases
cash-flow rights and voting rights (ratio CFR/ the risk of expropriation (Principal–Principal
VR and SEPARATION: see Appendix B). problem), canceling out any expected gains
None of these additional tests changed the from interests alignment. Our results show that
overall results reported in Tables 4–7. good corporate governance practices in the
context of high agency costs (interests misalign-
ment and expropriation costs combined) have
CONCLUSION the potential to deter diversion of firm
resources. Improving transparency and control
Summary adds value to all publicly traded companies
The objective of this article is to revisit the including those with concentrated ownership.
governance–performance relationship while However, if holding the CEO and/or Chair
taking into account shareholders’ proximity to positions has the potential to increase the power
the locus of management. Shareholders’ proxi- of a dominant/controlling shareholder, it does
mity is defined based on ownership concentra- not seem to translate into higher agency costs to
tion and whether or not the dominant/ the firm nor does the presence of insiders seems
controlling shareholder holds top executive to affect the effectiveness of the controls in
positions in the firm (CEO/Chair positions). place. Publicly traded companies may therefore
Governance is measured on a global scale while welcome dominant/controlling shareholders in
taking into account the ROB index. The study key management positions without compro-
is conducted over a 4-year period (2002–2005) mising on firm performance and value. In any
using unbalanced panel regressions on a sample case, putting in place good governance practices
of Canadian publicly traded companies (470 seems essential to ensure that managers/share-
firm-year observations). holders are kept in check and work in the best
The results of the study show a positive interests of their company. In this regard, as the
relationship between the ROB global index nature and emphasis of the CEO and Chairman
and sub-indexes and Tobin’s Q (Hypothesis 1). roles are clearly different, it remains critical that
This relationship remains positive whether these two positions be assumed by different
ownership is dispersed or concentrated in the individuals (non-duality structure).
hands of a dominant or controlling shareholder. Our study contributes to the methodology
Therefore, ownership concentration has no on many fronts. First, contrary to prior index-
impact on the governance–performance rela- based studies including Klein et al (2005), we
tionship (Hypothesis 2). Contrary to our expec- propose shareholders’ proximity to manage-
tations (Hypothesis 3), the results also show that ment as a better predictor of the level of a firm’s
holding key strategic positions by the domi- agency costs than ownership type or category.
nant/controlling shareholders does not affect Second, we address the case of dual-class firms
the relationship between governance and Q. while carefully collecting the voting rights and
the cash-flow rights of the ultimate owner. By
doing so, we propose a refined classification of
Contributions to the literature our sample firms along the ownership conti-
From an agency theory standpoint, the results nuum (dispersed, dominant, controlled). Third,
of our study suggest that the agency costs of the the risk of endogeneity that plagues research in
firm are relatively stable along the ownership corporate governance has been tackled while

204 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

analyzing the governance–performance rela- reputation, formulating or ratifying organiza-


tionship using fixed effects methodologies (to tional strategy and networking for the firm.
control for spurious correlation) and a 2SLS Boards should also be called on to advise and
setting with instrumental variables (to control enhance strategy formulation. Insiders should
for reverse causality). be valued for their operational expertise and the
CEO/Chair should provide a unity of com-
mand. Future research should test whether or
Contributions to practice not special control arrangements are required
Overall, the results support a one-size-fits-all for non-dual-class controlled companies. The
approach to governance despite growing con- governance–performance relationship should
cerns from academics and interest groups about be analyzed in that unique context.
the appropriateness of pursuing such strategy
when ownership is concentrated in the hands of
a dominant/controlling shareholder. The one- REFERENCES
size-fits-all approach to governance has also Alchian, A.A. and Demsetz, H. (1972) Production,
information costs, and economic organization
been criticized in the aftermath of the 2008
American Economic Review 62(5): 777–795.
US debt crisis that called into question the
Anderson, R.C. and Reeb, D.M. (2004) Board
supremacy of the US market-centered model composition balancing family influence in
of governance. Our study rejects these claims S&P 500 firms. Administrative Science Quarterly
by showing that governance controls should 49(2): 209–237.
not account for ownership differences in the Baek, J.-S., Kang, J.-K. and Suh Park, K. (2004)
context of publicly traded companies. Instead, Corporate governance and firm value: Evi-
good governance practices based on an inde- dence from the Korean financial crisis. Journal
pendent board of directors that promotes trans- of Financial Economics 71(2): 265–313.
parency and protects shareholders’ rights should Bauer, R., Frijns, B., Otten, R. and Tourani-Rad, A.
be prioritized whether or not ownership is (2008) The impact of corporate governance on
dispersed or concentrated. corporate performance: Evidence from Japan.
Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 16(3): 236–251.
Bebchuk, L.A., Cohen, A. and Ferrell, A. (2009)
What matters in corporate governance? Review
Limitations and direction for future of Financial Studies 22(2): 783–827.
research Bebchuk, L.A. and Hamdani, A. (2009) The elusive
Only controlled companies with a controlling quest for global governance standards. Uni-
shareholder holding less than 50 per cent of the versity of Pennsylvania Law Review 157(5):
cash-flow rights are selected in this study. Dual- 1263–1317.
class companies represent a large portion of Bebchuk, L.A., Kraakman, R.H. and Triantis, G.G.
Canadian controlled companies listed on the (2000) Stock pyramids, cross-ownership, and
TSX. On the other hand, non-dual-class con- dual class equity: The mechanisms and agency
trolled companies are more prevalent among costs of separating control from cash-flow
private companies. Misalignment and expro- rights. In: R.K. Morck, (ed.) Social Science
Research 460(6951): 295–318.
priation costs are expected to be relatively low
Bebchuk, L.A. and Roe, M.J. (1999) A theory of
in these entities where shareholders’ identifica-
path dependence in corporate ownership and
tion with and commitment to the firm should governance. Stanford Law Review 52(1): 127–170.
be strengthened. In these circumstances, the Beiner, S., Drobetz, W., Schmid, M.M. and
role of the board should be less about account- Zimmermann, H. (2006) An integrated frame-
ability and monitoring and more about growing work of corporate governance and firm valua-
the enterprise. As such, the board should tion. European Financial Management 12(2):
be engaged in building an organizational 249–283.

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 205
Bozec and Dia

Bhagat, S. and Bolton, B. (2008) Corporate govern- Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J. and Lang, L.
ance and firm performance. Journal of Corporate (2002) Disentangling the incentive and
Finance 14(3): 257–273. entrenchment effects of large shareholdings.
Black, S.B., Kim, W., Jang, H. and Park, K.-S. Journal of Finance 57(6): 2741–2771.
(2009) How Corporate Governance Affects Clarke, T. (2010) Recurring crises in Anglo-
Firm Value: Evidence on Channels from American corporate governance. Contributions
Korea, Working Paper available on the Social to Political Economy 29(1): 9–32.
Science Research Network, Electronic Library, Connelly, J.T., Limpaphayom, P. and Nagarajan, N.J.
http://www.ssrn.com. (2012) Form versus substance: The effect of
Blom, J. and Schauten, M.B.J. (2008) Corporate ownership structure and corporate governance
governance and the cost of debt. In: J.O. on firm value in Thailand. Journal of Banking
Soares, J. Pina and M. Catalao-Lopes (eds.). and Finance 36(6): 1722–1743.
New Developments in Financial Modeling Cronqvist, H. and Nilsson, M. (2003) Agency costs
Cambridge Scholars Publishing, UK, pp. of controlling minority shareholders. Journal of
116–145. Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38(4): 695–719.
Bozec, Y. and Bozec, R. (2007) Ownership con- Daines, R.M., Gow, I.D. and Larcker, D.F. (2010)
centration and corporate governance practices: Rating the ratings: How good are commercial
Substitution or expropriation effects? Canadian governance ratings? Journal of Financial Economics
Journal of Administrative Sciences 24(3): 182–195. 98(3): 439–461.
Bozec, R. and Bozec, Y. (2012) The use of govern- Dahya, J., Dimitrov, O. and McConnell, J.J. (2008)
ance indexes in the governance-performance Dominant shareholders, corporate boards, and
relationship literature: International evidence. corporate value: A cross-country analysis. Jour-
Canadian Journal of Administrative Sciences/ nal of Financial Economics 87(1): 73–100.
Revue canadienne des sciences administratives Dong-Song, C. and Zootae, J. (2007) Outside
29(1): 79–98, March. directors, ownership structure and firm profit-
Bozec, R., Dia, M. and Bozec, Y. (2010) Govern- ability in Korea. Corporate Governance 15(2):
ance-performance relationship: A re-examina- 239–250.
tion using technical efficiency measures. British Durisin, B. and Puzone, F. (2009) Maturation of
Journal of Management 21(3): 684–700. corporate governance research, 1993–2007:
Bozec, Y. and Laurin, C. (2008) Large shareholder An assessment. Corporate Governance: An Inter-
entrenchment and performance: Empirical national Review 17(3): 266–291.
evidence from Canada. Journal of Business Eisenhardt, K.M. (1989) Agency theory: An assess-
Finance Accounting 35(1–2): 25–49. ment and review. Academy of Management
Canadian Coalition for Good Governance (2011) Review 14(1): 57–74.
Governance differences of controlled corpora- Faccio, M. and Lasfer, M.A. (1999) Managerial
tions, Guidelines, Toronto, Canada. Ownership, Board Structure and Firm Value:
Chen, H., Hexter, J.L. and Hu, M.Y. (1993) The Uk Evidence, National Bureau of Eco-
Management ownership and corporate value. nomics Research, Cambridge, USA, 42 pp.
Managerial and Decision Economics 14(4): 335–346. Foerster, S.R. and Huen, B.C. (2004) Does corpo-
Chidambaran, N.K., Palia, D. and Zheng, Y. (2008) rate governance matter to Canadian investors?
Corporate Governance and Firm Perfor- Canadian Investment Review 17(3): 19–23.
mance: Evidence from Large Governance Garay, U. and Gonzalez, M. (2008) Corporate
Changes, Working Paper available on the governance and firm value: The case of Vene-
Social Science Research Network, Electronic zuela. Corporate Governance: An International
Library, http://www.ssrn.com. Review 16(3): 194–209.
Clacher, I., Doriye, E. and Hillier, D. (2008) Does Gilson, R.J. (2001) Globalizing corporate govern-
Corporate Governance Matter? New Evi- ance: Convergence of form or function. The
dence from the United Kingdom, Working American Journal of Comparative Law 49(2):
Paper available on the Social Science Research 329–357.
Network, Electronic Library, http://www.ssrn Gupta, P.P., Kennedy, D.B. and Weaver,
.com. S.W. (2006) Corporate Governance Scores,

206 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

Tobin’s Q and Equity Prices: Evidence from Morck, R., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1988)
Canadian Capital Markets, ssrn, Working Management ownership and market valuation:
paper, 34 pp. An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial
Henry, D. (2010) Agency costs, ownership structure Economics 20(Jan–March): 293–315.
and corporate governance compliance: A pri- Morck, R., Stangeland, D.A. and Yeung, B. (2002)
vate contracting perspective. Pacific-Basin Inherited wealth, corporation control and eco-
Finance Journal 18(1): 24–46. nomic growth: The Canadian disease? In: R. K.
Hermalin, B.E. and Weisbach, M.S. (1991) The Morck (ed.) Concentrated Corporate Ownership.
effects of board composition and direct incen- Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
tives on firm performance. Financial Manage- Price, R., Roman, F. and Rountree, B. (2007)
ment 20(4): 101–112. Governance Reform and Transparency: The
Hoi, C.-K. and Robin, A. (2010) Agency conflicts, Case of Mexico, Working Paper available on
controlling owner proximity, and firm value: the Social Science Research Network, Electronic
An analysis of dual-class firms in the United Library, http://www.ssrn.com.
States. Corporate Governance: An International Renders, A., Gaeremynck, A. and Sercu, P. (2010)
Review 18(2): 124–135. Corporate governance and performance: Con-
Holderness, C.G., Kroszner, R.S. and Sheehan, D.P. trolling for sample selection bias and endo-
(1999) Were the good old days that good? geneity. Corporate Governance: An International
Changes in managerial stock ownership since Review 18(2): 87–106.
the Great Depression. The Journal of Finance Setia-Atmaya, L. (2009) Governance mechanisms
54(2): 435–469. and firm value: The impact of ownership
Institute for Governance of Private and Public concentration and dividends. Corporate Govern-
Organizations (IGPPO) (2008) The Indepen- ance: An International Review 17(6): 694–709.
dence of Board Members: A Quest for Legiti- Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1997) A survey of
macy, Policy Paper No. 3, Prepared by Yvan corporate governance. Journal of Finance LII(2):
Allaire (Chair of the Board of Directors), 737–781.
Montreal, Canada. Short, H. and Keasey, K. (1999) Managerial owner-
Jensen, M.C. (1986) Agency costs of free cash flow, ship and the performance of firms: Evidence
corporate finance and takeovers. American from the UK. Journal of Corporate Finance 5(1):
Economic Review 76(2): 323–329. 79–101.
King, M.R. and Santor, E. (2008) Family values: Spellman, G.K. and Watson, R. (2009) Corporate
Ownership structure, performance and capital Governance Ratings and Corporate Perfor-
structure of Canadian firms. Journal of Banking mance: An Analysis of Governance Metrics
and Finance 32(11): 2423–2432. International (GMI) Ratings of US Firms,
Klein, P., Shapiro, D. and Young, J. (2005) Corpo- 2003 to 2008, Working Paper available on
rate governance, family ownership and firm the Social Science Research Network, Electronic
value: The Canadian evidence. Corporate Gov- Library, http://www.ssrn.com.
ernance 13(6): 769–784. Stiglitz, J.E. (1985) Credit markets and the control
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and Shleifer, A. of capital. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking
(1999) Corporate ownership around the 12(2): 133–152.
world. Journal of Finance 54(2): 471–518. Villalonga, B. and Amit, R. (2006) How do family
Lins, K.V. (2003) Equity ownership and firm value ownership, control, and management affect
in emerging markets. Journal of Financial and firm value? Journal of Financial Economics 80(2):
Quantitative Analysis 38(1): 159–184. 385–417.
McConnell, J. and Servaes, H. (1995) Equity own- Weisbach, M.S. and Hermalin, B.E. (2003) Boards
ership and the two faces of debt. Journal of of directors as an endogenously determined
Financial Economics 39(1): 131–157. institution: A survey of the economic literature.
Mitton, T. (2002) A cross-firm analysis of the impact Social Science Research Network 9(April): 7–26.
of corporate governance on the East Asian Zahra, S.A. and Pearce, J.A. (1989) Board of
financial crisis. Journal of Financial Economics directors and corporate financial performance.
64(2): 215–241. Journal of Management 15(2): 291–334.

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 207
Bozec and Dia

APPENDIX A 2. Compensation (25 marks)


 Stocks owned by directors and CEO
Major criteria considered within (13 marks)
the ROB corporate governance  Loans to senior executives (2 marks)
rating categories for 2005  Disclosure of compensation policies
The overall ROB index comprises four cate- regarding CEO bonuses (4 marks)
gories or sub-indexes that in turn include  Disclosure of compensation policies
different factors. The data were obtained from regarding CEO and top executives
the proxy information circular for shareholders. (6 marks)
The maximum weight assigned to each factor is 3. Shareholder rights (28 marks)
shown in brackets.  Election of the board (6 marks)
 Degree of dilution when stock options are
1. BC (37 marks) owned by employees (6 marks)
 Independence of the board of directors,  Other option plans (6 marks)
the audit committee, the compensation  Presence of non-voting or subordinate
committee and the nominating commit- voting shares (10 marks)
tee (19 marks) 4. Disclosure (10 marks)
 Duality structure (position held by the  Related directors (1 mark)
Chairman and the CEO) (5 marks)  Directors’ biography (1 mark)
 Relationship between directors (3 marks)  Disclosure of fees paid to an outside
 Engagement of the CEO versus other compensation consultant (1 mark)
outside commitments (2 marks)  Attendance record of directors at commit-
 Women on the board (2 marks) tees and meetings (2 marks)
 Performance evaluation of the board  Disclosure of the compensation paid to
(3 marks) directors last year (3 marks)
 Meetings of the board without manage-  Disclosure of directors’ ages and retire-
ment (3 marks) ment policies (2 marks)

208 © 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209
Governance practices and firm performance

APPENDIX B

Table B1: Variables description


Governance index
TOTAL ROB total index
BOARD ROB sub-index related to the board structure and composition
COMPENSATION ROB sub-index related to the directors’ and CEO’s stock ownership
SHAREHOLDER ROB sub-index related to employees’ stock options and the presence of non-voting
RIGHTS shares
DISCLOSURE ROB sub-index related to the quality and availability of information on corporate
governance
LAG TOTAL 1 year lag period of the ROB total index
Performance
TOBIN’S Q (Q) [Market value of equity + book value of total debt/Total assets] of the firm
Proximity:
DISPERSED Firms with no shareholder holding more than 10% of the voting rights
DOMINANT Firms with a shareholder holding at least 10% but less than 50% of the voting rights
CONTROLLED Firms with a shareholder holding at least 50% of the voting rights but less than 50%
of the cash-flow rights
CEO/CHAIR 1 if the dominant/controlling shareholder holds the CEO and/or the Chair
positions, otherwise 0
Control variables
AGE 1 if the firm is listed on StockGuide for at least 10 years, otherwise 0
DEBT Long-term debt over assets
SIZE Logarithm of assets at the end of the financial year
CAPEX Total capital expenditures (including R&D expenditures) / total assets
SECTOR Dummies for sector
YEAR Dummies for 2002, 2003, 2004 and 2005 (2005 is the reference year)
WEDGE Voting rights (VR) minus cash-flow rights (CFR)
SEPARATION 1 if the voting rights (VR) exceed the cash-flow rights (CFR), otherwise 0
CFR/VR Ratio of cash-flow rights (CFR) over voting rights (VR)

© 2015 Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 1741-3591 International Journal of Disclosure and Governance Vol. 12, 3, 185–209 209

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen