Sie sind auf Seite 1von 45

DETERMINANTS OF GROWTH IN

THE ARAB COUNTRIES

DRAFT
Not for Quotation

By
Makdisi S., Fattah Z. and I. Limam

February, 2000
Determinants of Growth in The Arab Countries

1. Introduction

Over the last fifteen years or so, growth performance of the Arab region as a
whole has been disappointing and mixed relative to that of the rest of developing
countries. In comparison with other regions in the world, growth rates in Arab
countries have been remarkably volatile and at times lower than that of the poor-
performing regions such as Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA).

This growth pattern is believed to be inextricably linked to several


characteristics of most of the countries in the region notably, their heavy
dependence on oil; weak economic base; high population growth and
unemployment rates; low rates of returns on investment in physical and human
capital; low level of integration in the world economy; under-development of
market institutions and, with very few exceptions, the omnipresence of the state.

The relative better growth performance of Arab countries in the 1960’s,


1970’s and the first half of the 1980’s is largely attributed to positive external
environment in the form of high energy export prices.1 This situation has been
reversed in the second half of the 1980’s and early 1990’s resulting in sharp
declines in domestic investment, savings and growth. Although oil is justifiably
perceived by many as the most important source of growth in the Arab countries,
other factors have also played an important role in shaping the growth picture of
the region.2

There is hardly any disagreement about the necessity for Arab countries to
rely on less volatile sources of growth that would insulate the region from adverse
external developments. The external environment is not likely to be as favorable as
it had been since the early 1970’s and until the mid 1980’s. Analyzing what have
been the main determinants of the recent growth performance is a first step toward
identifying what needs to be done to make growth more sustainable.

1
Unless otherwise mentioned, Arab countries include: Algeria, Bahrain, Comoros, Djibouti, Egypt , Iraq, Jordan,
Kuwait, Lebanon, Libya, Mauritania, Morocco, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia, Somalia, Sudan, Syria, Tunisia,
United Arab Emirates and Yemen. On the other hand, Arab oil-exporting countries are: Algeria, Bahrain, Iraq,
Kuwait, Libya, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia and United Arab Emirates.
2
Arab countries currently sit on 62% of proven world oil reserves and account for almost 30% of actual world
production. In addition, oil represents more than two thirds of total Arab exports.

2
The recent empirical growth literature has suggested a wide range of growth
correlates. The list includes among others, initial conditions, macroeconomic
performance, trade openness, government size, income distribution, financial
market development, natural resource abundance, institutions, politics and physical
geography. These ultimate sources of growth have been shown to be as important
as the proximate factors of growth namely, physical capital, labor and the
efficiency with which these factors are combined.

This paper will attempt to use the broader framework provided by the recent
empirical growth literature to measure the relative contribution of the main sources
of growth in the Arab countries. It will also address the issue of whether Arab
growth pattern is unique or could be fully explained by means of a global
framework. First, the recent growth pattern of the Arab region is analyzed within
an international perspective, using other groups of developing countries as a basis
for comparison. Then, we will proceed to analyze the relative growth performance
within the Arab region.

By identifying the principal aggregate agents of growth and disentangling


the regional from the global characteristics, we hope to map out the micro-growth
issues that need to be addressed by further studies at individual-country level.

Section 2 gives an overview of the growth performance of the countries of


the region during the period 1960-1998. Using an empirical model based on large
cross-country data sets, section 3 provides an account for the proximate and
ultimate sources of growth in the Arab region. Section 4 analyzes the growth
performance of the Arab countries from a regional perspective. Section 5
concludes.

2. Growth Record of the Arab Region

Over the period 1960-1998, Arab growth has followed the growth pattern of
the World economy. After a period of relatively high growth rates during the
1960’s and 1970’s, growth has slowed down during the 1980’s and 1990’s.
However, the impact of the worldwide recession in the early 1980’s has been more
pronounced for Arab countries whose growth performance has not only been
below world average but also at times weaker than that of the low-performing
SSA.

3
Table 1 shows clearly that per capita real GDP in the Arab region has even
declined during the 1980’s and grew annually by a mere 1 percent during the most
part of the 1990’s. In addition, Arab non-oil exporting countries have generally
fared better than oil-exporting countries in terms of per capita GDP growth.

Another salient feature of recent growth performance of Arab countries is its


extreme volatility. Figure 1 shows that during the period 1960-1998, the average
per capita GDP growth rate of Arab countries has been characterized by a high
variability in comparison with world average. Starting from the second half of
1980’s, variability of growth rates has declined somewhat but remained higher
than that of the average world growth rate. Over the entire period 1960-1998, the
variance of the average growth rate of per capita GDP for the Arab region is twice
as high as that of the average world growth rate.

This pattern is closely linked to the fluctuation in the terms of trade in


general and world energy prices in particular. Figure 2 shows that the average
growth rate of Arab oil-exporting countries is much more volatile than their non-
oil counterparts. In comparing terms of trade fluctuations across a number of
regions for the period 1980-1995, Gamo et al. (1997, p. 14) have found that Arab
oil-exporting countries have the highest terms of trade variability, and that terms of
trade variability of Arab non-oil exporting countries, has been higher than that of
developing countries as a group.

All Arab countries have been affected by oil price fluctuations. Naturally,
oil-exporting countries are extremely vulnerable to price variation given the
relative importance of the oil sector in production and exports. On the other hand,
Arab non-oil countries are indirectly affected by oil price fluctuation through
workers’ remittances and other financial flows stemming from oil exporting
countries.

The patterns of investment and savings in the Arab countries, have also
followed the growth pattern described above. Table 2 shows that during the oil-
boom period 1974-1985 the average investment ratio in Arab countries was very
close to the average investment ratio of the high performing East Asian countries.
The average national saving ratio for oil countries in the same period has reached
the level of 50 percent of GDP, while that of non-oil Arab countries was at 15
percent.

4
During the subsequent period 1986-1997 corresponding to the decline in
world oil prices, both investment and saving ratios have decreased sharply in Arab
countries. Arab oil-exporting countries have borne the brunt of the adjustment cost
with, an 8 percentage points decline in investment and a sharp 21 percentage points
decline in saving ratios. The average investment ratio in non-oil Arab countries
has declined by 6 percentage points, while the average national saving ratio
remained the same between the two periods. Unlike their oil-exporting
counterparts, non-oil Arab countries have maintained investment levels above
national savings. This has resulted into chronic current account deficits and
increased indebtness.

To sum up, recent Arab growth has experienced an overall upward trend
followed by an overall downward trend.3 After a high growth/high investment
period running from the 1960’s until the mid-1980’s associated with two major oil-
price booms, Arab countries have witnessed a low growth/low investment period
that runs through 1998. At prema facie, the presented evidence shows that this
growth pattern is associated with fluctuations in world oil prices and hence with
the nature of the factor endowments of the Arab countries.

In addition, Arab growth has been characterized by a remarkable volatility.


This again stems from the excessive reliance of Arab countries on volatile oil
receipts accounting for more than two thirds of their total export receipts. Even
non-oil Arab countries are subject to fluctuation in their own terms of trade, being
primary factor exporters themselves. Oil price fluctuation also indirectly affects
them through its impact on the flows of workers ‘remittances, investment and
financial assistance flows from oil-exporting Arab countries. All this factors
combined make the Arab region one of the most vulnerable group to external
shocks.

3. Arab Economic Growth in a Global Context

In this section we will use a cross-country regression framework to put Arab


region’s economic growth in international perspective. We will try to identify a
small set of regressors that would account for most of the variation of cross-

5
country per capita GDP growth. The absence of guidance from growth theory as to
which variable to include, makes the choice among the great number of possible
correlates of growth a difficult one. However, our selection will be guided by
variables that proved more “robust” than others in recent literature.4

In addition, we will favor variables that are believed to have shaped Arab
region’s recent growth performance. We will not focus here on the problems of
causation, endogeneity or the possible correlation between growth correlates.

Variables to be Used in the Analysis

The first type of variables included are those pertaining to initial conditions.
Recent empirical growth literature provides ample evidence of the existence of
conditional income convergence across countries. Under the assumption of
diminishing marginal returns to capital, the lower the initial level of income the
greater the opportunity of catching up through higher rates of capital accumulation
and diffusion of technology.

This convergence is evidenced by the negative relationship between growth


rate of per capita GDP and the initial level of GDP per capita after controlling for
other relevant variables such as measures of government policies, institutions,
politics and variables related to the character of national population. We will take
the 1960 level of real GDP per capita, Y60, as a measure of initial income.

Countries with higher stock of human capital and knowledge have also been
found to be able to forge ahead through higher growth rates. The simple inclusion
of a measure of human capital in a Barro-type regression equation, however,
overlooks the dual role played by the latter. Human capital not only affects growth
as an additional factor of production, together with physical capital and labor, but
also the efficiency with which these factors are combined.

Ben Habib and Spiegel (1994), have found evidence that human capital
affected Total Factor Productivity Growth (TFPG) through its impact on the
capacity of a country to innovate and the capability of using and adapting foreign
3
This finding has also been reported in Page(1998) and Bisat et al.(1997).
4
We believe on our side that there is a lot a spuriousness associated with the Barro-type cross-country regression
framework. However, until we come up with a better framework to analyze cross-country growth performance ,

6
technology. Arguably, human capital also encourages the accumulation of other
factors of production.

In our analysis, a measure of human capital will be used to explain both


growth as well as TFPG. As a proxy for the level of human capital, we will take
the logarithm of the years of secondary education in the population, KLLSEC, for
the period 1970-1989. This variable is taken from Sachs and Warner (1997).

Higher investment ratios, INVY, are generally found to be associated with


higher growth rates. We include this variable as a regressor without reference to
issues of causality and endogeneity. We also include the percentage change in the
terms of trade, GTOT, as a proxy for exogenous shocks. It is conventionally
assumed that positive terms of trade shocks are associated with higher growth and
vice versa.

Another important source of growth highlighted by the new empirical


growth literature is institutions. Institutions can be defined as the regular and
patterned forms of social behavior and interaction among human beings
established by formal and informal rules.

Institutions matter for growth because they affect incentives of actors. For
they affect the behavior of people in a society and very often lock their behavior
within a regularized pattern, institutions produce path dependence that could
explain prolonged periods of poor economic performance and hence the inability
of poor countries to catch up.

In order to take into account the role of institutional environment in growth,


we will use the institutional indicators developed by international investment risk
services and introduced in the literature by the work of Knack and Keefer (1995).
Our measure of institutions, ICRG, is a composite of four indicators (a)
Government repudiation of contracts, (b) Risk of Expropriation, (c) Rule of Law
and (d) Bureaucratic quality.5 This measure is computed for the decade of the
1980’s and is borrowed from Easterly and Levine (1996).

we will continue to use it as a suggestive tool to measure the relative contribution of the many sources of growth
across countries and regions.
5
See Knack and Keefer (1995) for a full description of these variables.

7
Macroeconomic performance plays an important role for growth
sustainability. Fisher (1993) has shown that growth is negatively associated with
inflation, large budget deficits and distorted foreign exchange markets. Among the
three measures, we favor inflation. For one, internationally comparable data on
budget deficits are scattered and not available for a large number of Arab
countries. On the other, the widely used black market premium (BMP) rate as a
measure distortion in foreign exchange market is neither a good proxy for the level
of distortions in the economy nor an appropriate measure of the adequacy of
macroeconomic policies.

Low BMP rates in Egypt or the Arabian Gulf countries reflect more the
abundance of foreign exchange more than the absence of distortions in the
economy or the presence of stable macroeconomic environment. In addition, the
high BMP in Iraq reflects the impact of the Iran-Iraq war and the aftermath of the
Iraqi invasion of Kuwait. In order to approximate the level of distortions in the
economy we will use a the share of Government consumption in GDP, GCY.

Openness has been used extensively in the literature as a major determinant


of growth performance. Openness affects growth positively in as much it magnifies
the benefits of international knowledge spillover and technological diffusion as
well as enforces cost discipline through import competition and the drive to export.

Openness measured by the ratio of trade to GDP is simply not appropriate


for the case of Arab countries. Most Arab countries have high trade ratios
reflecting partly the nature of their factor endowment.

Following the work of Sachs and Warner (1995), we adopt the definition of
openness, SOPEN, reported in Sachs and Warner (1997). Openness purports to the
fraction of years during the period 1970-1990 in which the country is rated as open
according to the following criteria: (a) Non-tariff barriers covering less than 40
percent or more of traded goods, (b) average tariff rates below 40 percent, (c) a
BMP of less than 20 percent, (d) no extreme controls in the form of taxes, quotas
or state monopolies on exports and (e) the country is not considered a socialist
country. A value of SOPEN=1 means the country has remained open to trade
during the entire period, while a value SOPEN=0 means the country remained
completely closed.

8
Among the recently introduced variables into the empirical literature is
natural resource abundance.6 Sachs and Warner (1997), for instance, have found
compelling evidence that countries with high initial ratio of natural resource
exports tend to growth slowly in subsequent periods. Earlier findings of
development literature about the disappointing performance of resource-abundant
countries have motivated their study on the link between natural resources and
economic growth.

Natural resource abundance negatively affects growth through several


channels. Natural-resource abundant countries tend to exhibit the Dutch-disease
syndrome in terms of overvalued exchange rates, and hence the difficulty to
develop a profitable export-oriented or import-competing manufacturing sector.7
Resource-rich countries are also associated with wasteful consumption and public
investment behavior, and provide incentives for rent-seeking and other
unproductive activities. In addition, it is widely observed that natural resource
availability forestalls reform. Finally, the secular decline of world prices of natural
resources and their high volatility translate into high uncertainty which, in turn,
impacts negatively growth.

The idea of incorporating natural resource abundance as a correlate of


economic growth is of great appeal given the high endowment of Arab countries in
natural resources notably, oil. Most of the arguments presented to explain the
negative link between natural resource abundance and growth performance apply
in the context of Arab countries, although undeniably, oil export revenues have
contributed to the improvement of their welfare and helped finance investment in
infrastructure and in human capital. In fact, four of the Arab oil-producing
countries namely, Kuwait, Bahrain, Qatar and the United Arab Emirates, are
ranked by the 1999 Human Development Report, among the top 45 countries in the
world in terms of the United Nations’ Human Development Index.

The share of exports of primary products in GNP, SXP, will be used to


measure natural resource abundance. This variable is measured for the year 1970
and is borrowed from Sachs and Warner (1997).

6
Natural resources are defined as primary agriculture, fuels and minerals.
7
Radelet et al. (1997), p. 8.

9
A final growth agent that is not very frequently used in the recent empirical
growth literature, is the role of population variables. High population growth ,
GPOP, affects negatively economic growth mainly through its impact on the
quality of human capital and capacity to fulfill basic needs such as access to basic
health care, education and clean environment.

Inclusion of this variable is justified on the ground that Arab countries have
one of the highest population growth rates in the world with an average of over 2.5
percent a year.

Regression Results

In order to give an order of magnitude to the contribution of the above


agents of growth, we regress the average growth rate of real per capita GDP on
several subsets of the variables described above. All variables, except when it is
otherwise mentioned, are averaged over the period 1960-1998 or any sub-period
within it, in case of unavailable data. The sample data is made of the 212 countries
included in the World Bank database prepared for the Global Research Project
(GRP) dealing with the sources of growth in the world. Not all the countries in the
sample were used in the analysis since some of them did not have complete data on
all the variables pertaining to our analysis.

Table 3 reports the regression results of our model(s). With respect to the
recent empirical literature, our results confirm the relative importance of the
investment ratio (INVY), quality of institutions (ICRG), macroeconomic
performance (INFLATION), initial level of income (Y60), human capital
(KLLSEC) and the degree of openness (SOPEN) in affecting long-term growth
performance. The respective coefficients of these variables were found to have the
expected signs and statistically significant at reasonable levels of significance.

In contrast, some of the variables such as terms of trade growth (GTOT) and
population growth (GPOP) were found to be insignificant. The ambiguous impact
of population on growth can be theoretically rationalized. Population can, in
principle, affect positively growth through its impact on market size. In addition to
this scale effect, population growth, if associated with an expansion of better
quality labor force, could be conducive to growth. The potential positive impact of

10
these two factors work in opposite direction against the “Malthusian” impact
resulting from the excessive call on the available quantity and quality of resources.

The ambiguous impact of terms of trade on long-term growth has been


reported in several instances in the literature.8 There are several plausible
explanations for that. The terms of trade variable has been obtained, given the
requirements of our cross-country analysis, by computing its average growth over
the entire period 1960-1998. Therefore, the impact of terms of trade as an
exogenous shock could be diluted owing to the operated smoothing. In order to
take this shortcoming into account, we have used the standard deviation of the
terms of trade of each country over the entire period as an alternative. The new
variable turned out to be insignificant as well.

The impact of terms of trade on economic growth could be proportional to


the dependence of any country on a limited number of exported commodities. In
other words, a diversified economy is less likely to be affected by terms of trade
decline given that the impact will be limited to a relatively small number of
sectors. In contrast, a deterioration in the terms of trade will be felt throughout the
economy in case of high export concentration or excessive dependence on a
limited number of export commodities such as oil.

Finally, the ambiguous effect of terms of trade on growth could be due to the
asymmetry of this effect. A persistent improvement in terms of trade might lead to
an improvement in income and expenditure, while a deterioration does not
necessarily lead to a proportional reduction in these variables. The recent World
Bank report on Global Economic Prospects (2000), reports several cases in point
from the Arab region.9 For instance, following the 1998 slump in oil prices,
Bahrain, Oman and Saudi Arabia used foreign reserves and accumulated foreign
assets to alleviate the pressure on fiscal deficits and trade balances. In contrast,
other oil exporters such as Algeria and Yemen with more binding financial
constraints had to adjust through expenditure cuts and exchange rate devaluation.

8
For instance, Gamo et al. (1997, p. 27) reported a similar result for the case of several Arab countries.
9
World Bank (2000, pp. 142-143).

11
Explaining Arab Growth Differential Relative to Other Regions

In order to put growth in the Arab region into an international context, we


use previous regression results to analyze the variables that account for most of the
difference in its growth performance with respect to a group of reference regions.

To perform the analysis, we adopt specification (1) in table 3. This


specification is parsimonious and includes the most relevant variables found in the
literature to affect long-term economic growth.

Table 4 gives the relative contribution of the relevant variables to the growth
differential of Arab countries relative to three regional groups.10 These groups are
EASIA including 6 high performing East Asian countries; SSA including 15
countries from Sub-Saharan Africa and LATIN including 17 countries from Latin
America.

The included variables explain most of the expected difference in growth


performance of Arab countries with respect to the rest of the groups. Table 4 shows
that the quality of institutions and factor endowments, negatively affect the relative
performance of Arab countries with respect to all the reference groups. In
particular, the quality of institutions accounts for most of the growth differential of
Arab countries with respect to the high performing East Asian countries.

Investment ratio is the next important variable accounting for most of the
growth differential of Arab countries with respect to the rest of the groups.
Investment accounts for as much as 17 percent of the growth differential between
Arab countries and the high performing East Asian countries. This result is, at
prima facie, at odd with the fact that Arab countries have maintained an investment
ratio close to that of East Asia and higher than that of other regions in the world.
This might be attributable to the endemic problem of capital inefficiency in the
Arab countries.

Many have presented plausible explanations for the low efficiency of capital
in the Arab region. Page (1998) suggested that this low efficiency of capital is due
to the dominant role of the state and the nature of capital inflows in the region

10
For lack of relevant data only 8 Arab countries were included in the analysis: Algeria, Egypt, Mauritania,
Morocco, Saudi Arabia, Sudan, Syria and Tunisia.

12
destined mainly to finance public investments and low-productivity projects in the
non-tradable sector such as housing. He also pointed out that protectionism and
lack of integration in world economy precluded these countries from boosting their
efficiency and competitiveness.

Others, such as El-Badawi (1999), argue that Arab countries as a group,


provide an inadequate institutional support for investment and private sector
development.

Openness does not seem to explain the difference of Arab growth


performance with respect to Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America. However,
openness explains around 12 percent of the growth differential with respect to East
Asian countries. The average index of openness over the period 1960-1998, for the
East Asian group is 5 times that of the Arab countries’ group included in the
analysis.

Part of the explanation in this regard lies in the stunning success of the
export-led strategy pursued by East Asian countries. Openness was simply a
byproduct of that strategy. In contrast, the relative lack of openness of the Arab
countries is due to the inward-looking strategy based on import-substitution,
followed by many countries of the region during the 1960’s and 1970’s. The
average unweighted tariff rate in Arab countries is high relative to many regions of
the world. Arab Gulf states maintain lower average tariff rates than the rest of the
Arab countries. However, average unweighted tariff rates in non-oil exporting
countries are hight and exceeding 20 percent in the case of Egypt, Jordan, Morocco
and Tunisia. With the recent efforts at reforming external trade and the adherence
of the majority of Arab countries to the World Trade Organization (WTO), this
situation might change in the near future.

Table 4 also shows that human capital, as approximated by education


attainment, accounts for the Arab region’s growth under-performance with respect
to East Asia and Latin America. The relative weak contribution of education to
economic growth in Arab countries is at odd with what is commonly believed.
Arab countries have spent more on education than many developing countries.

Table 5 shows clearly that Arab countries as a whole fair much better than
the average developing country in terms of spending on education. In addition, as

13
shown in table 5, there is a net improvement in several education measures such as
enrollment rates and literacy. However, Arab countries are still lagging behind
developing countries. In 1995, more than 43 percent of adults above 15 years of
age are illiterate compared to only 30 percent in the group of developing countries.
These statistics are more alarming given the gender gap in terms of literacy.
Illiteracy rates among females, 55.8 percent, are much higher than those of males,
estimated at 31.6 percent.11 Illiteracy among women is linked to poor health and
low education attainment among children, and hence the low quality of human
capital.

Using a six-Arab-country panel data, El-Erian et al. (1998, p. 11) have found
that the rapid expansion in education did not result in higher productivity or more
rapid economic growth.12 Aside from measurement problems that might have
affected their results, they argue that the weak link they have found between
education and growth is attributable to the low quality in the delivery of
educational services and labor markets distorted educational choices in Arab
countries.

They argue that education systems in Arab countries focus more on


repetition of definitions, knowledge of facts and concepts and less so on
developing critical thinking and problem-solving capacity. On the other hand, the
higher wages prevailing in the public sector are set without consideration for
alternative employment opportunities in other sectors.13 This has led to an
education system that is focused on preparing students for public employment.

A close line of argument is presented by Ridha (1998) who argues that, the
quality of education in Arab countries is low because education systems are over-
politicized to the extent that they deviate from the objectives they are supposed to
achieve. He asserts that, the educational systems in Arab countries are manipulated
to reach political ends. His argument is best summarized by the following
excerpts:

11
UNESCO Statistical Yearbook (1997).
12
The countries included are: Algeria, Egypt, Jordan, Kuwait, Syria and Tunisia.
13
Arab countries are believed to have the best paid civil service in the world with about 10 % of GDP devoted to
public wages and salaries.

14
“Indoctrination replaced free and critical thinking, and authoritarian values
permeated every educational tool and practice: the curriculum, the textbooks,
and the methodology of teaching.”

Ridha (1998, pp. 3-4).

Another argument advanced by Pritchett (1996) can possibly explain the


weak link between education and growth in the Arab countries. He argues that in a
perverse institutional environment, education and accumulated capital could be
used in wasteful and counterproductive activities.

High levels of distortions and state interventions have notoriously


characterized Arab countries. In addition, the fact that most of these countries are
resource-abundant provides incentives for rent seeking. This has led to the
proliferation of rent-seeking activities and the swelling of bureaucracy that
although might have contributed to the employment of educated labor, have done
less so, if any, to economic growth.

Starting from a relatively high per capita income relative to the rest of the
groups in the early 1960’s, did not provide a high potential for rapid growth in
Arab countries. Finally, inflation did not also contribute in any significant way to
the growth differential with respect to other regions except the inflation-prone
Latin America.

Growth Accounting in International Perspective

To further put growth performance in international perspective, we use the


growth accounting framework to see whether factor accumulation or factor
productivity have accounted for most of the growth differential of the Arab relative
to other regions.
Growth can be the result of the growth of inputs such as capital and labor, or
their productivity. The debate over the share of inputs as compared to that of their
total productivity is still very lively. The empirical evidence is mixed. Many such
as Mankiw et al. (1992), argue that the share of physical and human capital
together with population growth account for as much as 80 percent of international
variation in per capita income. Young (1995) on the other hand, argues that what is
often labeled as the “Asian miracle,” is the outcome of a temporary rapid factor

15
accumulation. Those holding a different view claim that TFP is the key to
economic growth and that factor accumulation plays only a less important role.14

In order to carry out the accounting exercise, we have used a two-factor,


homogeneous of degree one, Cobb-Douglas production function in per capita form.
Capital shares required to measure the relative contribution of factor accumulation
and productivity were estimated using the following regression equation:

∆Log (Yit / Lit ) = λi + α i ∆Log ( K it / Lit ) + ε it

The slope coefficient in the above equation represents the capital share in
output, Y represents real output, K the capital stock and L labor. Y is measured by
real GDP and is obtained from World Bank database. The capital stock data are
taken from Nehru and Dhareshwar (1994), and L is approximated by total labor
force and taken from the World Bank world development indicators. Real GDP
and capital stock series are based on 1987 constant prices.

The sample we used comprises 92 countries and data cover the period 1960-
1997. The list of countries included in our sample was determined on the basis of
the availability of capital stock data in Nehru and Dhareshwar (1994).15 It should
be mentioned that since their capital series stop at the year 1990, we have used
fixed investment figures from World Bank database to complete the capital series
from 1991 until 1997.

In order to account for the possible impact of the noise generated by the high
variability of yearly data, we have estimated two versions of the above equation.16
A short-term version using original data for the output per worker and capital per
worker, and a long-term version using three-year moving averages of the same
variables.

Table 6 provides the regional averages of capital shares using the two
specifications indicated above. Looking at table 6, several remarks are in order.

14
See for instance, Klenow and Clare (1997).
15
The Arab countries included in the sample are: Algeria, Egypt, Iraq, Jordan, Kuwait, Libya, Morocco, Sudan and
Tunisia.
16
An attempt at using cointegration analysis for the two versions have led to the rejection of the existence of
cointegration relationships for most of the countries in the sampe. We do not include the results of this tests for
space considerations.

16
First, our estimates of the world average capital share was found to be above the
commonly assumed value of 0.3 or 0.4. This finding is in line with recent results
provided in Senhadji (1999). Bisat et al. (1997) have previously found that the
average capital share in Arab countries is well above 0.5 and about 0.7 for Arab
oil-producing countries.

Secondly, high-performing East Asian countries hold the lowest capital


share in the group. And thirdly, Latin American and industrialized countries have
the highest capital shares.

These findings have an implication for the computation of TFPG. Given the
difference in regional capital shares, applying the same share for all the countries
to compute TFPG could be very misleading.

Table 7 provides estimates of the relative contribution of capital, labor and


TFPG to economic growth of the countries included in the sample. Overall, the
results show the predominance of capital contribution over that of labor and TFPG,
in growth performance during the period 1960-1997. This remark holds true for the
high performing East Asian countries such as Korea, Malaysia and Thailand. The
only exception was Singapore where TFPG contribution exceeded that of capital

For the 9 Arab countries included in the sample, only Egypt, Morocco and
Tunisia managed to have positive TFPG. Out of the 6 remaining Arab countries in
the sample that had negative TFPG, 4 were oil-exporting countries.

TFPG has contributed positively to the economic growth of the East Asian
group in the sample. The only exception was the Philippines.

In order to assess the relative contribution of the variables accounting for


inter-regional TFPG performance, we have regressed TFPG on relevant variables
based on recently established results in the literature.17 We conducted these
regressions using values for capital shares ranging from 0.3 to 0.7. Each
hypothetical value for capital share was applied uniformly over the different
countries in the sample. This was done to see whether different values of the
capital share affect the impact of the regressors on TFPG.

17
Only 6 Arab countries were included in the analysis given the lack of data. They are: Algeria, Egypt, Jordan,
Morocco, Sudan and Tunisia.

17
The included regressors were the quality of institutions, ICRG; inflation rate,
INFL; the initial income, Y60; the initial enrollment rate in primary school,
PRIM60, and the adopted measure of natural resource abundance, SXP. Other
conventional variables such as openness, growth in terms of trade and political
stability have been tried but were dropped for lack of statistical significance.

Table 8 reveals that for lower values for capital share, the parameter
estimates tend to be significant and of the expected signs. Institutions and the stock
of human capital, as approximated by the initial enrollment rate, affect positively
TFPG. The negative sign attached to the initial income, points to the existence of
catching up effect at the TFPG level. Inflation was also found to affect negatively
TFPG. Finally, the natural resource curse was found to apply at the productivity
level too. Natural resource abundance affects negatively TFPG.

At higher values of the capital share, the explanatory power of the model
drops. This is due to the fact that at higher values of the capital share, capital
accounts for a higher portion of overall economic growth as well as TFPG. Hence,
the other variables become less relevant. However, it should be mentioned that the
only two variables that remained significant for different values of the capital
share, are initial income and human capital. This finding is widely in line with the
recent literature on TFPG.18

In order to put Arab countries’ TFPG performance into global perspective,


we have computed the contribution to TFPG of the relevant variables for different
values of the capital share. Table 9 reports the results after applying uniformly to
all countries each of the hypothetical values for the capital share between 0.3 and
0.7. Table 10, reports the results of the same exercise after applying different
regional values for the capital share.

Based on our estimation, we have applied the value of 0.5 to the Arab and
Sub-Saharan regions as well as the whole sample. The values applied for other
regions are respectively, 0.4 for East Asia and 0.7 for Latin America.

Overall, the results exhibited in tables 9 and 10, point to the overriding
importance of the quality of institutions and the stock of human capital in
explaining the lower growth and productivity performance of the Arab countries in
18
See for instance the findings of Senhadji (1999).

18
comparison with the high performing East Asian countries and with the rest of the
world in general.

4. Explaining Intra-Regional Arab Growth Performance

In the previous section, Arab countries’ growth performance has been


compared with other reference regions. In this section, we will dwell on the
relative performance of individual countries with respect to the Arab region’s
average performance.

There is a considerable variation in the growth performance of Arab


countries. It was shown earlier that growth in oil-exporting countries is subject to a
higher variability than that of non-oil exporting countries. In addition, the average
growth performance of the oil exporting countries over the period 1960-1998, has
been below that of non-oil exporting countries. Table 11, shows that the countries
which were able to achieve an average real GDP growth rate over 2 percent a year,
during the period 1960-1998 were, except for Oman, non-oil exporting countries.
The best growth performers were Egypt, Jordan, Morocco, Oman, Syria and
Tunisia. Oman’s average growth rate was the highest followed by Egypt and
Tunisia.

In order to assess the relative performance of each Arab country with respect
to the average performance of the Arab group, we have first computed for each
country a yearly z-score defined as the distance of its growth rate of GDP per
capita with respect to the average per capita growth rate of the whole sample of
Arab countries, divided by the standard deviation of this growth rate over the same
year. The better achievers have then been defined as those countries whose
average z-scores over the entire sample period, were positive.

After excluding countries for which ample data were not available, the over-
achievers were: Oman (0.40), Egypt (0.30), Tunisia (0.27), Jordan (0.24), Syria
(0.11) and Morocco (0.08). All Arab oil-exporting countries, except Oman had
negative average z-scores.

Interestingly enough, according to our own estimates and those of Bisat et


al. (1997), these countries except for Jordan, were the only Arab countries whose
TFP have contributed positively to output growth during the last 3 decades or so.

19
Oman and Egypt have also taken the lead in this respect. In addition, the over-
achievers had in general the lowest growth variability among the sample group
except, Oman. The higher variability of the latter is attributable to the fact that it is
an oil-exporter and therefore subject to the effect of oil price fluctuation.

Available data do not permit to establish systematic links between growth


performance in all Arab countries on the one hand and their country-specific
characteristics (structural, policy, initial conditions, institutional, political, other
internal and external factors) on the other. Preliminary analysis indicates, however,
that the better achievers tend to have, except for Syria, above average indicators for
integration in the world economy (be it through the crude measure of openness,
share of FDI in GDP, or share of manufactured exports in total commodity
exports). They also tend to be more diversified and have enunciated, except for
Syria, economic reform earlier than other countries.

Table 12. exhibits the sectoral distribution of production of the better growth
achievers Egypt, Jordan, Morocco, Syria and Tunisia, with respect to the sample
average. The numbers show clearly that these countries have more diversified
economies than the average. The contrast is more stark if we compare this group
with the group of oil-exporting countries.

Using the normalized Hirshman export concentration index, we found that


Arab growth over-performers have the lowest values of this index compared to
other Arab countries. For 1995, these indexes were: 0.172 for Morocco; 0.211 for
Tunisia; 0.244 for Egypt; 0.270 for Jordan and 0.533 for Syria.19 These rates
compare favorably with 0.940 for Kuwait; 0.765 for Iraq and 0.765 for Oman.

Oman is the only Arab oil-country ranked as an over-achiever. The Omani


economy is not diversified and is not considered an exception with regard to other
relevant variables such as institutions, openness and human capital. Oman’s
growth over-performance with respect to the other oil countries could be
attributable to the catching up effect alone.

Having started in the 1960 by a very modest income per capita that was
lower than that of Somalia, one of the least developed Arab countries, Oman had

19
These rates are taken from UNCTAD (1999). They were computed based on the 3-digit SITC classification, revision 2. A
value of the index closer to zero means more export diversification and vice versa.

20
the potential of catching up. The presence of oil has allowed it to catch up rather
quickly.

In order to account for the relative growth performance within the Arab
region, we have used a cross-country regression framework applied to a panel data
of 14 Arab countries and spanning the period 1970-1995. For the sake of
increasing sample variation, we have used for each country 5 five-year period
averages for 1970-1975, 1975-1980, 1980-1985, 1985-1990, 1990-1995.

An attempt at using the same cross-country regression framework we have


used previously for the Arab region, was not successful. All the relevant variables
turned out to be insignificant. This could be explained by the fact that cross-
country variation in the data is much higher than time variation.

We have used instead an alternative model in which the growth rate of per
capita GDP is determined by the domestic saving ratio, SAVY; the debt-service
ratio, DEBTS; the share of manufactures in total merchandise exports, MANUF;
and the level of initial income per capita, YINI.

The model was estimated using the fixed-effect panel regression method.20
The estimation results reported in table 13, show that the parameters of all the
variables considered were significant and of the expected sign.

Since data were not available for all the countries and for all the years, only
a limited number of countries in the sample was used for comparative purposes.
Table 14 shows that high saving ratios have contributed significantly to the relative
better growth performance of the oil-exporting countries such as Algeria and Saudi
Arabia. On the other hand, export diversification explains the relative better
performance of countries such as Egypt, morocco and Tunisia. Debt overhang also
explains the lower growth performance of countries like Algeria and Morocco.

These results notwithstanding, the country-specific growth determinants or


the unexplained growth, remain relatively high. The high variation in individual
intercepts in our regression point to that effect. These individual factors should be
tackled at a more disaggregated country-specific level.

20
Hausman’s specification statistic for the test of fixed versus random effect model was (1.09 at 4 degrees of
freedom) in favor of the former.

21
5. Concluding Remarks

(1) The overall growth performance of the Arab countries has been both mixed
and characterized by a higher degree of volatility compared to other regions
of the world. We believe that the factors responsible for this volatility
include, among others, fluctuations in world oil prices, droughts, workers'
remittances, foreign aid and debt, not to mention political factors such as
civil and regional wars.

(2) Using cross-country regressions, we found that the quality of institutions


and factor endowment tended to affect negatively the relative growth
performance of the Arab countries in comparison with three comparator
regions. More specifically, the investment ratio, openness and human
capital explain the low growth performance of the Arab countries relative to
the high performing East Asian group. Human capital, on the other hand, is
the factor that explains the lower performance of the Arab countries with
respect to Latin America.

(3) It is the quality of physical and human capital rather than their quantity that
explains the relatively lower Arab growth performance. This may partly be
attributed to the dominant role of the State in these countries, with its
ensuing distortions in the economy.

(4) Our examination of the relative contribution of factor accumulation and total
factor productivity to economic growth for a sample of 92 countries
indicates that factor accumulation accounts for most of the growth
performance for the period 1960-1997. While TFPG contributed positively
to the growth performance of the East Asian countries, it was not an
important source of growth in the Arab region. Among the Arab countries
included in the sample, only Egypt, Morocco and Tunisia had positive
TFPG. The quality of institutions and human capital accounted for the lower
performance of the Arab countries in terms of TFPG and in comparison with
the other regions of the world.

(5) The degree of exposure to external shocks and the extent of economic
diversification were relevant factors in explaining variations in growth
performance within the Arab World.

22
In view of the aggregate nature of our study and in light of the above
findings, several relevant policy issues deserve further analysis in conjunction with
country specific studies:

! To achieve sustainable growth in the future, Arab countries must take policy
measures that should substantially enlarge and diversify their economic
base. This should go in tandem with measures needed to enhance their
capacity to withstand adverse domestic and external shocks and lessen their
exposure to the volatility that the region as a whole has experienced.
Political factors apart, far reaching economic and institutional reforms have
to be put in place.

! The dominance of the State has given rise to distorted labor market signals
that have encouraged employment in the public and other low productivity
sectors. As the roles of the State and the public sector are changing,
including that of employers of last resort, Arab educational system should be
reformed so as to be able to dispense the type of education and knowledge
that is more in line with the requirements of modern market-based and open
economies rather than one that prepares graduates for employment in the
public sector. Furthermore, closing the wide educational gender gap and
reducing illiteracy among women in Arab countries, should also be a high
priority on the agenda of policy makers.

! Policies of greater openness and integration in the world economy should be


vigorously pursued simultaneously with appropriate domestic economic and
institutional reforms at home. These policies, as attested by the experiences
of the Arab and other regions, would contribute positively to growth
performance. Experience has also shown that countries endowed with
abundant natural resources may tend to delay reform and fail to develop a
competitive manufacturing sector and a more diversified economy. The
outcome would ineluctably be poorer long-term growth prospects, unless
appropriate reforms are implemented.

The country specific studies will no doubt shed important additional light on
the determinants of growth in each of the countries concerned. These studies
should enable us to explain, for example, the within regional variation in the role
of human and physical capital, the influence of the State and institutions and the

23
relative impact of external and internal shocks as they relate to economic growth. It
is equally useful to analyze the way ultimate and proximate determinants of growth
interact in each country. It would be an addition to our understanding of the growth
process in Arab countries, to show, for instance, how economic policy, institutions,
politics and other country characteristics affect the way factors of productions are
used and combined.

Finally, it would be desirable to operate a sectoral decomposition of growth


in Arab countries. Such a decomposition is useful for identifying the sectors that
have been successful in achieving better growth performance, expanding
investment and employment and raising productivity and earnings. This
decomposition should also help explain why certain sectors have been more
successful than others.

24
References

Barro R. (1991), “Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries,” Quarterly


Journal of Economics, 104: 407-433.

Benhabib, J. and M. Spiegel (1994), “The Role of Human Capital in Economic


Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data,” Journal of
Monetary Economics 34: 143-173.

Bisat A. El-Erian M.A. and T. Helbling (1997), “Growth Investment, and Saving
in the Arab Economies,” IMF working paper WP/97/85.

Easterly W. and R. Levine (1996), “Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and


Ethnic Divisions,” The World Bank.

El Badawi Ibrahim (1999), “Can Reforming Countries Perform an Asian


Miracle?: Role of Institutions and Governance on Private Investment,” in Limam I.
(ed) “Institutional Reform and Development in the MENA Region,” published by
Arab Planning Institute and Economic Research Forum for the Arab Countries,
Iran and Turkey.

El-Erian, Helbling T. and J. Page (1998), “Education, Human Capital


Development and Growth in the Arab Economies,” paper presented in the Joint
Arab Monetary Fund, Arab Fund for Economic and Social Development Seminar
on “Human Resource Development and Economic Growth”, Abu Dhabi, United
Arab Emirates, 17-18 May, 1998.

Fischer S. (1993), “The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in Growth,” Journal of


Monetary Economics 32 (3): 485-512.

Gamo P.A. Fedelino A. and S.P. Horvitz (1997), “Globalization and Growth
Prospects in Arab Countries,” IMF working paper WP/79/127.

Klenow P. J. and A. R. Clare (1997), “The Neoclassical Revival in Growth


Economics: Has it Gone Too Far?” In NBER: Macroeconomics Annual 1997, MIT
Press.

25
Knack S. and P. Keefer (1995), “Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-
Country Test Using Alternative Institutional Measures” Economies and Politics
7(3): 207-227.

Mankiw, N. G., Romer D., and D. N. Weil (1992), “A Contribution to the


Empirics of Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (2): 407-437.

Nehra V. and Dhareshwar A. (1994), “New Estimates of Total Factor


Productivity Growth for Developing and Industrial Countries,” Policy Research
Working Paper # 1313, the World Bank.

Page J. (1998), From Boom to Bust- and Back? The Crisis of Growth in the
Middle East and North Africa, in Nemat Shafik (ed), “Prospects for Middle
Eastern and North African Economies: From Boom to Bust and Back?” Published
by the Economic Research Forum for Arab Countries, Iran and Turkey.

Pritchett L. (1996), “Where Has All the education Gone?” World Bank Policy
Research working paper # 1581.

Radelet S., J. Sachs and Lee J.W. (1997), Economic Growth in Asia, Harvard
Institute for International Development.

Ridha M. J. (1998), “Charting the Future Education and Change in the Arab
Countries: A platform for the 21st Century,” paper presented in the Joint Arab
Monetary Fund, Arab Fund for Economic and Social Development Seminar on
“Human Resource Development and Economic Growth,” Abu Dhabi, United Arab
Emirates, 17-18 May, 1998.

Sachs, J.D. and A. M. Warner (1997), “Natural Resource Abundance and


Economic Growth,” Center for International Development and Harvard Institute
for International Development.

Sachs J. D. and A. M. Warner (1996), “Sources of Slow Growth in African


Economies,” Development Discussion paper no. 545 Harvard Institute for
International Development.

26
Sachs, J.D. and A. M. Warner (1995), “Economic Reform and the Process of
Global Integration,” Brookings papers on Economic Activity, 10-1-118.

Senhadji A. (1999), “Sources of Economic Growth: An Extensive Growth


Accounting Exercise,” IMF Working Paper WP/99/77.

UNCTAD (1999), Handbook of International Trade and Development Statistics


1996-1997.

UNESCO (1996), Statistical Yearbook.

UNESCO (1997), Statistical Yearbook.

United Nations, Macroeconomic Data System.

United Nations (1999), Human Development Report 1999.

World Bank (2000), Global Economic Prospects and the Developing Countries
2000, World Bank Publication.

World Bank: Global Research Project Database.

Young A. (1995), “The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the statistical Realities


of the East Asian Growth Experience,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (3):
641-680.

27
APPENDIX

28
1961-1970 1971-1980 1981-1990 1990-1998

Arab Countries 4.23 2.62 -0.76 1.07

Arab Oil-Exporting 5.97 0.93 -1.71 0.10

Arab Non-Oil Exporting 3.08 3.93 0.00 1.48

East Asia and Pacific 4.27 3.63 2.58 2.02

Latin America and Caribbean 2.68 2.55 0.29 1.80

Sub-Saharan Africa 1.84 1.60 0.20 0.35

World 3.14 2.57 1.01 0.62

Source: World Bank, GRP database.

29
Figure 1 : REAL GDP PER CAPITA GROWTH
: AN INTERNATIONAL PERSPECTIV
12

10

6
GROWTH RATE

4
Arab
2 World

0
60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98
-2

-4

-6

YEAR

30
Figure 2: Oil and Growth Performance

18

16

14

12
GDP GROWTH RATE

10

8 Arab Oil
6 Arab Non-Oil

0
70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97
-2

-4
YEAR

31
Investment Ratio Saving Ratio

1974-1985 1986-1997 1974-1985 1986-1997

Arab Region 28.33 22.51 26.13 16.41

Arab Oil 29.04 21.91 42.78 20.33

Arab Non Oil 27.81 22.73 14.99 15.15

East Asia and Pacific 30.45 34.79 30.09 33.98

Latin America and Caribbean 22.34 20.65 19.47 19.13

Sub-Saharan Africa 23.58 17.79 20.41 22.7

World 24.39 22.7 23.15 21.23

Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators 1999.

32
Variable (1) (2) (3) (4)
INVY 0.09 0.08 0.1 0.09
(1.77)** (1.82)** (1.72)** (1.83)**
ICRG 0.29 0.28 0.3 0.33
(2.23)* (2.15)* (2.27)* (2.48)*
INFL -0.002 -0.002 -0.002 -0.002
(-2.730)* (-3.10)* (-2.49)* (-2.83)*
Y60 -0.0004 -0.0004 -0.0004 -0.0004
(-5.91)* (-5.58)* (-5.73)* (-5.46)*
KLLSEC 0.32 0.31 0.37 0.38
(1.18)*** (1.15)*** (1.33)*** (0.17)***
SXP -2.52 -3.06 -3.47 -3.47
(-2.08)* (-2.00)* (-2.33)* (-2.31)
SOPEN 0.47 0.47 0.22 0.66
(1.08) (1.08) (0.51) (1.35)***
GCY 0.04
(1.01)
GTOT -0.04
(-0.44)
GPOP 0.35
(1.48)***
EASIA 0.67 0.88 0.81 0.47
(1.20) (1.66) (1.33) (0.79)
SSA -1.17 -1.15 -1.02 -1.28
(-1.62) (-1.63) (-1.29) (-1.98)
LATIN -0.23 -0.08 -0.15 -0.30
(-0.68) (-0.18) (-0.36) (-0.93)
Number of Observations 71 71 68 71
Adjusted R-squared 0.68 0.68 0.68 0.69
(1) Constant terms not reported. (2) See text for definition and sources of data for variables used.
(3) Estimation based on white Heteroskedastic consistent standared errors. (4) t- ratios in parentheses.
* Significant at the 5% level ** Significant at the 10% level *** Significant at the 20% level

33
Variable Arab-SSA Arab-EASIA Arab-Latin
INVY 0.46 -0.41 0.35

ICRG -0.30 -0.51 -0.12

INFLATION 0.12 0.01 0.25

Y60 -0.31 -0.14 0.30

KLLSEC 0.16 -0.24 -0.18

SXP -0.05 -0.23 -0.20

SOPEN 0.04 -0.29 0.01

SSA 1.17 0.00 0.00

EASIA 0.00 -0.67 0.00

LATIN 0.00 0.00 0.23

Predicted Growth 1.29 -2.48 0.62

Actual Growth 1.38 -2.40 0.70

34
Arab States Developing Countries Sub-Saharan Africa

S T S T S T
1980 36.6 9.2 35.5 5.2 17.5 1.6
1985 45.6 10.7 37.6 6.5 21.2 2.2
1990 50.6 11.8 41.8 7.1 21.6 3
1993 51.7 12.3 45.6 8.1 23 3.5
1995 53 12.2 46.7 8.3 23.5 3.6

Percentage of Illiterate Population 15 years and over

Arab States Developing Countries Sub-Saharan Africa

1980 59.2 42 59.8


1985 53.6 37.1 54.4
1990 48.3 32.8 48.7
1995 43.4 29.6 43.2

Expenditures on Education % GNP and per capita

Arab States Developing Countries Sub-Saharan Africa

% GNP Per capita % GNP Per capita % GNP Per capita


1980 4.1 109 3.8 31 5.1 41
1985 5.8 122 4 28 4.8 26
1990 5.3 112 4 41 5.3 30
1995 5.5 112 4.2 45 5.9 28

Source: UNESCO Statistical year book (1996).

35
Region Number of Countries Average Capital Share Average Capital Share

(Short-term version) (Long-term version)

Whole Sample (world) 92 0.67 0.59

Arab Countries 9 0.61 0.52

East Asia 6 0.48 0.38

Sub-Saharan Africa 21 0.59 0.48

Latin America 22 0.79 0.78

36
Country Growth Capital Labor TFPG
Algeria 0.031 0.034 0.006 -0.009
Angola 0.012 0.028 0.002 -0.017
Argentina 0.026 0.014 0.008 0.003
Australia 0.036 0.046 -0.002 -0.008
Austria 0.032 0.034 0.001 -0.003
Bangladesh 0.035 0.039 -0.006 0.003
Belgium 0.029 0.042 -0.001 -0.011
Bolivia 0.031 0.013 0.011 0.006
Brazil 0.048 0.055 0.001 -0.007
Cameroon 0.031 0.048 0.004 -0.021
Canada 0.037 0.029 0.008 0.001
Chile 0.041 0.033 0.002 0.006
China 0.068 0.063 0.002 0.003
Colombia 0.045 0.041 0.002 0.001
Costa Rica 0.044 0.057 0.002 -0.015
Cote d'Ivoire 0.049 0.034 0.014 0.002
Cyprus 0.056 -0.036 0.020 0.072
Denmark 0.028 0.020 0.005 0.003
Dominican Republic 0.048 0.053 0.007 -0.012
Ecuador 0.048 0.029 0.011 0.008
Egypt 0.057 0.035 0.011 0.011
El Salvador 0.034 0.037 0.007 -0.011
Ethiopia 0.031 0.043 0.007 -0.018
Finland 0.032 0.022 0.003 0.007
France 0.032 0.033 0.002 -0.003
Germany 0.030 0.025 0.002 0.004
Ghana 0.023 0.010 0.018 -0.006
Greece 0.040 0.047 0.001 -0.008
Guatemala 0.039 0.031 0.007 0.001
Guyana 0.015 0.028 -0.011 -0.002
Haiti 0.008 0.029 0.004 -0.025
Honduras 0.040 0.034 0.010 -0.004
Iceland 0.040 0.041 0.001 -0.002
India 0.044 0.057 -0.002 -0.011
Indonesia 0.058 0.033 0.015 0.010
Iran 0.046 0.049 0.010 -0.013
Iraq 0.023 0.020 0.020 -0.018
Ireland 0.046 0.006 0.007 0.032
Israel 0.058 0.051 0.003 0.004
Italy 0.033 0.037 0.001 -0.004
Jamaica 0.016 0.023 0.004 -0.012
Japan 0.053 0.063 0.003 -0.013
Jordan 0.052 0.116 -0.013 -0.051
Kenya 0.048 0.029 -0.002 0.021
Korea 0.081 0.065 0.012 0.004
Kuwait 0.022 -0.015 0.056 -0.018
Libya 0.058 0.165 -0.011 -0.096
Luxembourg 0.036 0.033 0.000 0.004
Madagascar 0.013 0.028 -0.004 -0.011
Malawi 0.042 0.017 0.018 0.007
Malaysia 0.069 0.046 0.016 0.007
Mali 0.033 0.013 0.013 0.006
Malta 0.059 -0.026 0.015 0.070
Mauritius 0.047 0.040 -0.009 0.016
Mexico 0.046 0.063 -0.001 -0.016
Morocco 0.049 0.025 0.013 0.011
Mozambique 0.020 0.046 -0.008 -0.019

37
Myanmar 0.034 0.036 0.002 -0.004
Netherlands 0.031 0.027 0.005 -0.001
New Zealand 0.025 0.035 -0.001 -0.008
Nicaragua 0.023 0.052 -0.006 -0.022
Nigeria 0.030 0.008 0.023 -0.001
Norway 0.038 0.018 0.006 0.013
Pakistan 0.055 0.019 0.021 0.015
Panama 0.048 0.038 0.012 -0.002
Paraguay 0.047 0.042 0.012 -0.006
Peru 0.032 0.052 -0.012 -0.008
Philippines 0.039 0.041 0.008 -0.010
Portugal 0.042 0.058 -0.001 -0.015
Rwanda 0.020 -0.043 0.049 0.014
Senegal 0.026 0.006 0.019 0.001
Sierra Leone 0.010 0.038 -0.006 -0.022
Singapore 0.080 0.026 0.025 0.029
South Africa 0.030 0.027 0.009 -0.006
Spain 0.039 0.050 0.001 -0.011
Sri Lanka 0.045 0.011 0.017 0.016
Sudan 0.030 0.028 0.014 -0.012
Sweden 0.024 0.025 0.003 -0.003
Switzerland 0.022 0.039 0.001 -0.018
Tanzania 0.038 0.016 0.017 0.005
Thailand 0.072 0.055 0.012 0.005
Trinidad and Tobago 0.021 0.019 0.011 -0.009
Tunisia 0.051 0.028 0.012 0.010
Turkey 0.050 0.040 0.007 0.003
Uganda 0.016 0.013 0.015 -0.012
United Kingdom 0.023 0.014 0.003 0.006
United States 0.031 0.047 -0.009 -0.007
Uruguay 0.019 0.007 0.004 0.008
Venezuela 0.028 0.012 0.023 -0.006
Zaire 0.005 -0.001 0.027 -0.021
Zambia 0.019 0.003 0.018 -0.002
Zimbabwe 0.039 0.020 0.011 0.008

38
Variable α = 0.3 α = 0. 4 α = 0.5 α = 0.6 α = 0.7
ICRG 0.24 0.18 0.13 0.07 0.02
(3.00)* (2.31)* (1.56)*** (0.83) (0.20)
INFL -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.0005 -0.0004
(-2.08)* (-1.75)** (-1.44)*** (-1.17) (-0.94)
Y60 0.0004 -0.0003 -0.0002 0.0002 -0.0001
(-6.62)* (-5.37)* (-4.05)* (-2.8)* (-1.70)
PRIM60 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.01
(2.75)* (2.59)* (2.41) (2.21)* (2.01)*
SXP -1.71 -1.12 -0.55 0.03 0.61
(-2.01)* (-1.31)*** (-0.61) (0.04) (0.62)
EASIA -0.19 -0.49 -0.79 -1.09 -1.39
(-0.51) (-1.42)*** (-2.38)* (-3.30)* (-4.07)*
SSA -0.89 -0.68 -0.47 -0.26 -0.05
(-2.60)* (-1.87)** (-1.20) (-0.61) (-0.11)
LATIN -0.67 -0.61 -0.56 -0.50 -0.45
(-2.27) (-1.99)* (-1.71) (-1.43)*** (-1.19)
Adjusted R-squared 0.58 0.45 0.29 0.16 0.09
Number of Observations 75 75 75 75 75

(1) Constant terms not included and t - ratios in parentheses. (2)Estimation based on White heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors.
(3) *: significant at 5% level or less; **: significant at 10% level; *** significant at 20% level.
Variable Alpha Arab-SSA Arab-Hasia Arab-Latin Arab-World
ICRG 0.3 -0.176 -0.408 -0.077 -0.427
ICRG 0.4 -0.136 -0.314 -0.059 -0.329
ICRG 0.5 -0.095 -0.22 -0.042 -0.231
ICRG 0.6 -0.055 -0.126 -0.024 -0.132
ICRG 0.7 -0.014 -0.033 -0.006 -0.034
INFL 0.3 0.056 0.002 0.084 0.033
INFL 0.4 0.05 0.002 0.076 0.03
INFL 0.5 0.045 0.002 0.068 0.026
INFL 0.6 0.04 0.002 0.06 0.023
INFL 0.7 0.035 0.001 0.053 0.02
Y60 0.3 -0.062 0.015 0.491 0.643
Y60 0.4 -0.052 0.012 0.408 0.535
Y60 0.5 -0.041 0.01 0.326 0.428
Y60 0.6 -0.031 0.007 0.244 0.32
Y60 0.7 -0.021 0.005 0.162 0.213
PRIM60 0.3 0.067 -0.657 -0.528 -0.486
PRIM60 0.4 0.064 -0.627 -0.504 -0.463
PRIM60 0.5 0.061 -0.596 -0.48 -0.441
PRIM60 0.6 0.058 -0.566 -0.455 -0.419
PRIM60 0.7 0.055 -0.536 -0.431 -0.396
SXP 0.3 0.147 0.009 0.01 -0.005
SXP 0.4 0.097 0.006 0.006 -0.003
SXP 0.5 0.047 0.003 0.003 -0.001
SXP 0.6 -0.003 0 0 0
SXP 0.7 -0.053 -0.003 -0.004 0.002
TFPG Actual 0.3 -0.441 -2.158 -0.578 -1.068
TFPG Predicted 0.3 0.032 -1.039 -0.021 -0.242
TFPG Actual 0.4 -0.742 -1.881 -0.838 -1.217
TFPG Predicted 0.4 0.024 -0.921 -0.072 -0.23
TFPG Actual 0.5 -1.044 -1.604 -1.098 -1.366
TFPG Predicted 0.5 0.017 -0.802 -0.123 -0.219
TFPG Actual 0.6 -1.346 -1.328 -1.358 -1.515
TFPG Predicted 0.6 0.01 -0.684 -0.174 -0.207
TFPG Actual 0.7 -1.648 -1.051 -1.618 -1.664
TFPG Predicted 0.7 0.002 -0.566 -0.226 -0.196

40
Variable Arab-SSA Arab-Easia Arab-Latin Arab-World

ICRG -0.095 -0.537 0.439 -0.231

INFL 0.045 0.003 0.051 0.026

Y60 -0.041 0.084 0.020 0.428

PRIM60 0.061 -0.671 -0.343 -0.441

SXP 0.047 0.075 -0.143 -0.001

(1) Assumptions:
Arab alpha=0.5
SSA alpha=0.5
Hasia alpha=0.4
Latin alpha=0.7
World Alpha=0.5

41
Country Period Average Growth Standard Deviation of Growth
Algeria 1961-1998 1.14 8.79
Egypt 1961-1998 3.15 3.08
Jordan 1976-1998 2.07 7.97
Kuwait 1969-1998 -2.90 11.35
Mauritania 1961-1998 1.52 6.30
Morocco 1974-1998 2.25 4.61
Oman 1964-1998 7.38 17.52
Saudi Arabia 1961-1998 1.72 6.47
Sudan 1961-1998 0.87 6.21
Syria 1961-1998 2.88 8.52
Tunisia 1962-1998 3.11 3.82
United Arab Emirates 1974-1998 -2.97 8.64

42
Country Agriculture Mining and Quarrying Manufacturing Other Sectors

Egypt 24 10 19.0 44.0

Jordan 7.5 2.8 10.7 70.1

Morocco 18.7 3.9 17.4 50.6

Syria 24.0 5.5 13.52 53.2

Tunisia 18.8 7.2 13.24 52.1

Arab Average 16.3 22.2 9.9 44.0

Oil Countries 7.9 38.0 7.5 38.0

Non-Oil Countries 24.0 6.6 12.4 45.0

Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators and United Nations MEDS.

43
Variable Coefficient t-Ratio

SAVY 0.16 4.99*

DEBTS -0.13 -4.31*

MANUF 0.045 1.56

YINI -0.0008 -3.43*

N=53

R-Adjusted=0.60

* Significant at the 1 percent level.

44
Predicted Growth SAVY DEBTS MANUF YINI Individual Effect
-1.33 2.28 -2.61 -0.73 0.51 -0.78
1.40 -1.45 0.01 0.35 1.23 1.26
0.03 -0.79 -1.14 0.69 1.08 0.18
-1.60 3.39 2.38 -0.67 -4.93 -1.77
-0.89 -2.34 0.54 -0.78 1.83 -0.14
1.39 -1.50 0.69 -0.08 -0.38 2.66
1.00 0.41 0.13 1.21 0.66 -1.41

45

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen