Sie sind auf Seite 1von 9

SPECIAL ARTICLE

E-Governance and Corruption in the States


Can Technology Serve the Aam Aadmi?

Jennifer Bussell

T
A comparative evaluation of one-stop, computerised he potential to use information and communication
citizen service centres in various Indian states has been technologies to improve public service delivery has
been a key topic of policy interest in both the Indian
carried out in this paper to assess their efficacy. It is
states and the centre over the last decade. The central govern-
found that the outcomes of policies related to ment’s National e-Governance Plan (NeGP), established in
e-governance in India are not correlated to conventional 2006, set out an impressive agenda for developing e-Govern-
variables such as economic development. Instead the ment services, networking infrastructure, state data centres,
and village-level centres for delivering core services to citizens
extent to which political parties in power expect such
(Government of India 2006a). This programme built on earlier
policies to affect their current and future electoral efforts by a wide range of states to offer computerised services
statuses affects implementation. such as ration cards, income certificates, building licences,
land records, and income tax payments. From eSeva in Andhra
Pradesh, Nemmadi in Karnataka, and Friends in Kerala to
e-Mitra in Rajasthan, Civic Centres in Gujarat, and Sugam in
Himachal Pradesh, state governments have been leaders in
computerised service centres.
Yet, as the central and state governments continue to imple-
ment the NeGP across the country, we have only a minimal un-
derstanding of how states approached the problem of compu-
terised service delivery in the years leading up to the national
plan, what types of services were made available to citizens,
what obstacles were faced by politicians and bureaucrats in
the implementation of these initiatives, and the extent to
which these programmes are likely to benefit citizens. Ana-
lysts have evaluated individual computerisation initiatives
(see, inter alia, Ahuja and Singh 2006; Bhatnagar and Singh
2009; Caseley 2004; Kuriyan and Ray 2009), but no compre-
hensive comparison of state activities has evaluated compu-
terisation policy outcomes. Did all states implement computer-
ised service centres in a similar manner? Did all states deliver
similar types of services to their citizens through these cen-
tres? If not, what explains the variation in state government
choices over e-Government programmes?
This article addresses these questions on the basis of a com-
prehensive study of state e-Government initiatives during the
period 1999-2009.1 In particular, I evaluate state efforts to in-
troduce one-stop service centres, similar to the common service
centres promoted in the NeGP. This analysis offers two impor-
tant findings. First, while nearly all major Indian states imple-
mented some type of computerised service centre programme
during this period, the programmes themselves differed sig-
nificantly in terms of the number and type of services made
available to citizens (Figure 1, p 78). This substantial diversity
Jennifer Bussell (jennifer.bussell@mail.utexas.edu) is with the Lyndon B in strategies taken by state governments highlights the dra-
Johnson School of Public Affairs, University of Texas at Austin.
matic ways in which the potential benefits of reformed service
Economic & Political Weekly EPW June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 77
SPECIAL ARTICLE

delivery are limited to those citizens in only a few states and technology to automate processes and establish service centres.
only certain populations within the states. However, the cost of opening a single centre is relatively low
Second, this variation in policy design and implementation (Toyama et al 2004) and the cost of basic software and technol-
cannot be explained based on variations in economic or social ogy infrastructure has decreased over the last 15 years. A service
conditions, levels of pre-existing technology infrastructure, or centre programme was within the economic reach of all states
the electoral conditions in a given state. Instead, in order to during this period and, as shown below, economic conditions are
explain policy outcomes, it is necessary to understand the not correlated with any major characteristics of state policies.
expected effect of these policies on the economic resources of Alternatively, general political conditions might influence
incumbent politicians and in particular politicians’ expectations the likelihood that politicians would want to invest in a pro-
about the threat of more transparent service delivery to estab- gramme to improve service delivery. Those politicians who
lished sources of corrupt income. While there was considerable face the greatest electoral threat from their opponents might
initial enthusiasm to use new technologies, the actual benefits be more enthusiastic about introducing a new type of public
offered to citizens are constrained in many cases by persistent good, in the form of improved service delivery, to increase their
efforts to retain access to a rich source of corruption: the bribes chances of retaining power. However, because politicians in
citizens pay to get the services they are promised by the state.2 nearly every Indian state face the threat of anti-incumbency
bias (Uppal 2009), the pressure to perform is in important
Understanding Variations ways consistent across all states. As a result, it seems instead
Erstwhile Chief Minister Chandrababu Naidu in Andhra that all politicians would have an interest in improving serv-
Pradesh gained significant media attention for his efforts to ices, and it is less probable that small electoral differences had
computerise government services – everything from electric- a strong effect on the character of reform. Other characteristics
ity bills and property tax payments to caste and income certifi- of electoral competition such as the characteristics of political
cates – and to offer them in one location. The potential constituencies and vote blocs may instead play an important role
Figure 1: Maximum Number of Available Services Per Centre in the implementation of policies, which are considered below.
in the States (2006)3 Contrary to these arguments, it is posited that the primary
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45
cause of diverse computerised service centre policies is varia-
Uttarakhand
tion in the extent to which incumbent politicians expect these
Delhi
centres to affect their economic resources. As in other con-
Orissa texts, politicians weigh the expected costs and benefits of im-
Haryana proving public services. Yet, the costs to Indian politicians of
Tamil Nadu digitising public service delivery arise because new techno-
logies can streamline government processes, and so can also
West Bengal
limit the ability of officials to generate and appropriate bribes
Kerala
from inefficiencies in service delivery. Where bribes are avail-
Rajasthan able in public service delivery – for example, when citizens
Uttar Pradesh find it necessary to pay “speed money” to access services – pol-
Maharashtra iticians are less likely to be supportive of policies to increase
Punjab
transparency in administration.
In the Indian political system, politicians have multiple possi-
Gujarat
ble sources of corrupt income, including bribes paid by citizens
Karnataka
for services, kickbacks on contracts with the private sector, and
Himachal Pradesh funds skimmed from official state development programmes
Chhattisgarh (Bardhan 2005; Davis 2004; Frankel 2005; Jenkins 2006; Old-
Andhra Pradesh
enburg 1987; Wade 1985). While recent media attention has fo-
cused on major cases of grand corruption, such as in the Com-
improvements to the quality of service delivery seemed vast, monwealth Games (NDTV 2010a), the Maharashtra housing
and chief ministers from across the country sent officials to scandal (Financial Express 2010), illegal export of mineral re-
learn about the “eSeva” model.4 Because citizens have often sources in Karnataka (Pandey 2010), and 2G spectrum licensing
faced difficult circumstances when attempting to access public (NDTV 2010b), it is corruption in the day-to-day activities of the
services, it is not surprising that many state leaders saw this as state in interaction with the public that amounts to a Rs 21,000
an opportunity to increase their standing in the eyes of citi- crore (Transparency International India and CMS 2005) market
zens by improving service delivery.5 in petty corruption that directly affects Indian citizens.
But if politicians hope to use higher quality, technology- Whether the source of corrupt income is corporate kickbacks
enabled services to improve their chances of re-election, then or bribes from individuals, politicians do not extract rents
why did state governments differ so dramatically in their in- through the machinery of the state solely for personal pecuni-
troduction of service centres? One answer might be that ary gain, but often to enhance their hold on political power
poorer states did not have the economic resources to purchase (Frankel 2005; Iype 2004; Wade 1985). Access to bribes can
78 June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
SPECIAL ARTICLE

serve as an important electoral resource for incumbents. in areas with high petty corruption are less likely than their
Because there is no explicit funding mechanism for Indian state peers in lower corruption regions to support the initial intro-
assembly elections, candidates often fund their campaigns duction of reforms.
without guaranteed support from the party (Wade 1985). While all Indian states display some petty corruption, levels
While the Election Commission of India (ECI) limits candidate differ quite dramatically across the states. Figure 2 shows a
expenditure in state elections (ECI 2007), spending by political measure of petty corruption calculated based on a survey con-
parties and supporters of candidates is not limited, thereby cre- ducted by Transparency International India and the Centre for
ating a loophole that indirectly allows for higher spending by Media Studies in which a random sample of Indian citizens
the candidate, who can attribute expenditures above the limit was asked about their experiences paying bribes in 11 govern-
to the party or friends (Iype 2004). As one former candidate for ment departments (Transparency International India and CMS
a Lok Sabha seat in Kanpur noted, “I spent within the limit of 2005). This measure is based on an index of corruption in all
Rs 1.5 lakh. But my friends and party put in Rs 20-25 lakh” departments. The survey found substantial variation in the
(Jayant Malhoutra, as quoted in Rekhi and Shekhar 1996). level of petty corruption across the Indian states: bureaucrats
The potential for somewhat unlimited financial support has typically demanded bribes from fewer than 20% of citizens in
pushed up campaign spending. For example, in Karnataka’s states such as Kerala and Gujarat, versus more than 50%
2008 assembly elections, one successful candidate stated that, of citizens in Uttar Pradesh or Rajasthan (ibid). As a result, if
“the quantum of money being used in elections has been the level of petty corruption is linked to computerisation
increasing despite the restrictions. The ECI can’t contain it” policy choices, we should be able to evaluate this relationship
(Kumar, as quoted in Sharma 2008). Analysts estimate that across the states.
approximately Rs 4,000 crore was spent across Karnataka’s Figure 2: Petty Corruption in the States
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
224 constituencies (Sharma 2008). This increasing economic Kerala
demand of campaigns places pressure on politicians to find Himachal Pradesh
lucrative sources of funding. Gujarat
While politicians may not take bribes directly from citizens Andhra Pradesh
in order to accumulate resources, they can place pressure on Maharashtra

bureaucrats to gain access to these funds. Because politicians Chhattisgarh

control the movement of officials between positions within the Punjab


West Bengal
bureaucracy, and because these postings are typically not reg-
Orissa
ulated in a formal manner, the potential arises for manipula-
Uttarakhand
tion of bureaucratic positions and appointments based not on Uttar Pradesh
policy requirements but on political connections (Bardhan Delhi
1997; Vithal 1997). A market for job postings can then emerge Tamil Nadu
in which bureaucrats are incentivised to pay for job transfers, Haryana
leading to an increased demand from politicians for illicit Jharkhand
funds (de Zwart 1994; Wade 1985). Rajasthan

Where bureaucrats also have discretionary power over the Karnataka


Madhya Pradesh
provision of public services to citizens, as is often the case,
Bihar
bribes from citizens offer a source for acquiring the funds
expected by politicians. Bureaucrats can channel a share of The same motivations are likely to shape many elements of
bribe income to politicians, either in hopes of a transfer or sim- policy implementation. Politicians accustomed to higher levels
ply to satisfy a political boss’ demands (Bardhan 2005; Davis of petty corruption, if they do implement reforms, should be
2004; de Zwart 1994; Wade 1985). Politicians then have access less willing to implement a wide range of technology-enabled
to additional funds with which to finance future elections. public services, so as to minimise the overall threat to incom-
ing bribes. In particular, leaders should resist inclusion in com-
Petty Corruption puterised service centres of those services that offer the great-
As a result of these institutional dynamics, if greater trans- est potential for bribes, either due to their high demand by citi-
parency from computerisation plausibly disrupts politicians’ zens, their typical value in terms of bribes, or both. These poli-
established sources of bribes, then this is a threat to their ticians are also more likely than their peers to resist the com-
ability to be re-elected. Politicians in areas with lower pre- prehensive automation of the service-delivery process, so as
existing levels of petty corruption should anticipate that re- to retain non-computerised steps of service delivery that may
forms will only minimally affect their access to income, as the offer opportunities for extraction of bribes.
availability of bribes is low from the outset. However, where The demand for economic resources can be magnified in
there are higher levels of petty corruption, the opposite is the states led by a coalition government. In single-party systems,
case. Political incumbents who are more dependent on corrup- party leaders, in particular the chief minister, can implement
tion to run their re-election campaigns will perceive improved reforms according to expectations about the overall costs and
service delivery as a threat to their illicit income. Thus, politicians benefits of reform to the ruling party. In coalition-led states,
Economic & Political Weekly EPW June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 79
SPECIAL ARTICLE

however, the formation of the coalition may be based on ex- months since implementation, do not display statistically signi-
pectations about ministerial posts for party members and the ficant relationships with the quantity of services made available.
opportunities for bribe-taking associated with those posts. Perhaps more important than the number of services made
Any threat to the expected economic resources of participat- available is the type of services offered by state governments
ing in a coalition will change the incentives of coalition part- in computerised centres. If politicians in higher corruption
ners to participate in government. When coalition members states are concerned with the threat of computerised service
have enough seats to destabilise the coalition, they can use delivery to bribe-taking, then we would expect those services
this power to resist policy directives, by threatening defection with high potential for corruption not to be included in
from the coalition, and so can influence policy outcomes. computerised centres.
With these potential cost considerations in mind, politicians This is indeed the case, both for services that have the poten-
are also likely to attempt to maximise the electoral benefits of tial to deliver a high magnitude of income from bribes, based
reform by targeting improvements in service delivery to their on the demand for the services and the average bribe paid
preferred constituents. Administrative reform in this context (“high corruption potential” services), and for those services
does not merely provide a “public good” enjoyed by all citizens; with high frequency of bribe payments (“high bribe” services).8
instead, the benefits of digitisation can be highly targeted. By In a regression of high corruption potential services on the state
making available services that will benefit particular groups – level of corruption, using a Poisson model to account for the
such as building licences for business elites or welfare benefits for fact that the dependent variable is a count variable, I find a
those below the poverty line – policymakers can increase the strong and statistically significant relationship. A move from
chances that factions needed for their political survival are the below-average corruption states to above-average corruption
beneficiaries of computerised centres. At the same time, politi- states reduces the likelihood of providing a service with high
cians must balance their efforts to provide targeted goods with
Table 1: Provision of High Corruption Potential Services*
their desire to minimise the threat to existing rents, resulting IV Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7
in a trade-off between those services with the highest potential Above average corruption .38** .38** .36** .38** .41* .38** .29***
for acquiring bribes and those offering the greatest potential (-3.30) (-3.32) (-3.43) (-3.30) (-2.50) (-3.27) (-3.91)
benefit to key constituents. As shown below, these political con- Coalition 1.13
siderations strongly shape the particular services that are selected (.42)
Electoral competition (ENPS) .88
for inclusion in one-stop, computerised service centres. (-.98)
SDP per capita .97
Analysing Policy Outcomes (-.04)
Months since initiation (12/2006) 1.00
The effects of threats to corrupt rents from improvements in (.40)
service delivery become evident in an analysis of policy char- Human development .47
acteristics. Of the 20 major Indian states,6 16 states imple- (-1.12)
mented computerised service centres of some type during the Historic land tenure .98
(-.04)
period 1999-2006. However, politicians in those states with N 16 16 16 16 16 16 13
higher levels of petty corruption7 were more likely to delay the Prob > Chi2 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00
implementation of these policies, or not implement them at all, *Poisson models with incidence rate ratios reported and z-statistic in parentheses.
*p < .05 **p < .01 *** p < .001.
than leaders of less corrupt states (Bussell 2010). States led by Sources: Election Commission of India, Reserve Bank of India, Indian 2001 Human
coalition governments also implemented service centre poli- Development Report, Banerjee and Iyer (2005), and author’s calculations.
cies later than their single-party-led peers, all else equal. Table 2: Provision of High Bribe Services*
Other characteristics, such as state domestic product per cap- IV Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 Model 7
ita, pre-existing technology infrastructure, and electoral com- Above average corruption .37*** .37*** .36*** .37*** .34*** .38*** .31***
petition, showed no strong relationships with the timing of (-4.09) (-4.08) (-4.21) (-4.10) (-3.76) (-4.07) (-4.49)
policy implementation (ibid). Coalition .99
(-.05)
The implementation of policies can tell us even more about Electoral competition (ENPS) .91
the quality of reforms. An initial measure of implementation (-.95)
quality is the number of services made available in state serv- SDP per capita 1.28
ice centres. For example, some states with service centres pro- (.41)
Months since initiation (12/2006) .99
vide only a few services, implying that citizens must still go to (-.62)
myriad government offices to acquire any other public services. Human development .56
Generally speaking, when governments make more services (-1.06)
available in one-stop centres, the benefits to a wide range of Historic land tenure 1.29
(.67)
citizens should increase. N 16 16 16 16 16 16 13
Here we see that those states with higher levels of corruption Prob > Chi2 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00
tend to make fewer services available to citizens in computerised * Poisson models with incidence rate ratios reported and z-statistic in parentheses.
*p < .05 **p < .01 *** p < .001.
service centres (Bussell 2010). In contrast, measures of alterna- Sources: Election Commission of India, Reserve Bank of India, Indian 2001 Human
tive explanations, such as state domestic product per capita and Development Report, Banerjee and Iyer (2005), and author’s calculations.

80 June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
SPECIAL ARTICLE

potential for corruption by 62%. These findings hold in multi- in which ruling government support bases play an important
variate models, in which no measures of alternative explanations role in choices over service provision.
showed statistically significant relationships with high
corruption potential services (Table 1, p 80). Among those Chhattisgarh
high bribe services for which more than 25% of the popula- Despite the diverse set of issues facing Chhattisgarh, including
tion surveyed reported paying a bribe (Transparency Interna- below average income per capita and the Naxalite movement,
tional India and CMS 2005), the level of corruption is also the state implemented one of the most comprehensive service
strongly related to the likelihood of provision. Above-average centre reforms in India. During the initial Congress government,
corruption states are 63% less likely to provide a high-bribe the information technology (IT) secretary, Sunil Kumar, and an-
service than their lower corruption peers. These findings hold other IT department official, Amit Aggarwal, proposed opening
in multivariate models testing for the effects of alternative citizen service centres for acquiring government certificates,
explanations (Table 2, p 80). similar to eSeva in Andhra Pradesh. The goal of the project was
Figure 3: Percentage of Services in Centres Targeted to Different to reduce the burden on citizens of accessing services, because,
Socio-economic Groups in the Indian States9 as one bureaucrat put it, “people had to go to lots of different
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90
offices and pay lots of bribes in order to get their services from
Uttarakhand
government”.10 The initial system put in place, called Chhattis-
Andhra Pradesh
garh online information for citizen empowerment (Choice), was
Karnataka
a relatively simple automation of existing service delivery pro-
Rajasthan
cesses that provided services in a one-stop shop.
Kerala
Shortly after implementation, however, the Bharatiya Janata
Tamil Nadu
Poor
Party (BJP) took power in the state and Raman Singh was chosen
Uttar Pradesh Middle/upper
All citizens to be chief minister. It was unclear whether Singh would con-
Chhattisgarh
tinue to support the Choice centre initiative. The chief minister
Delhi
set out a strategic agenda of good governance for the state and
Himachal Pradesh
according to people associated with service reforms, Singh saw
West Bengal
the use of IT to reform service delivery as a key component of
Gujarat
delivering governance reforms to citizens.11 Despite the fact
Maharashtra
that, “when the second state government came in they had ap-
Punjab
prehensions regarding continuing a project that had been
Haryana
started by the previous government” (ibid), Singh did not close
Orissa down the Choice centres. Instead, he became a supporter of
computerisation. When asked explicitly if the chief minister be-
Services also provide differing benefits to citizens across socio- lieved that the overall electoral benefits were greater than any
economic categories. For example, ration cards and welfare potential electoral costs from transparency in service delivery, a
schemes are more likely to benefit poorer citizens, while top official in the information technology department replied,
wealthier individuals are likely to utilise passport applications or yes, the chief minister sees the benefits as greater than the costs...
business licences. Policy choices over whether or not to offer spe- [because] the CM...is focused on good governance, on accountability,
cific services in computerised centres will affect the benefits for transparency, and responsiveness…he does not even question the
political costs (ibid).
any given individual. Figure 3 shows the percentage of available
services in each state targeting different socio-economic groups This support from the chief minister contributed to the state’s
and highlights the diversity of service provision. ability to offer more services in its Choice centres than nearly any
Table 3: State Cases other state. This includes high corruption potential and high
Lower Petty Corruption Higher Petty Corruption bribe services such as ration cards and land records. The state
Single party government Chhattisgarh Tamil Nadu also utilises private entrepreneurs to run Choice centres, a deci-
Coalition government Kerala Uttar Pradesh
sion state representatives say is partially based on a desire to fur-
These cross-state analyses provide a general picture of the ther reduce corruption in the state. As one official noted,
primary relationship between pre-existing petty corruption and this does not mean that citizens should not be able to access their govern-
the nature of service reforms, as well as the secondary effects of ment, but rather that they should not have to interface with a government
electoral incentives to target service provision. However, these officer for every service. This can only help with reducing corruption.
dynamics, and in particular the effects of coalition government, The CM is very clear on this, which sends a message to everyone (ibid).
are best illustrated through evaluations of individual states. At the same time, citizen service centres provided the ruling
Here I consider four states representing variation in levels of government with an opportunity to improve services for spe-
corruption and the character of the ruling government. In do- cific portions of the population. In contrast with the services
ing so, I am able to provide insights into the effects of both made available under the Congress government, which re-
petty corruption and coalitions on the emergence and imple- flected a strong preference for poorer constituencies, such as
mentation of computerised service centres, as well as the ways caste and income certificates, the services made available by
Economic & Political Weekly EPW June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 81
SPECIAL ARTICLE

the BJP reflect quite different strategic priorities. In particular, and veterinar y advice provided at the centres.16 No similar ini-
the BJP shaped computerised service delivery to target its own tiative was launched in urban areas and it seems clear that the
core constituencies.12 Of the additional services made availa- ruling party politicians used this technology-enabled service
ble, 42% benefit middle and upper class income groups (in- centre initiative to appeal to their rural base.
cluding building plan approval, passport applications, and The number of centres introduced in Tamil Nadu also belies
driving licences) while only 16% target lower classes (includ- the relevance of RASI to citizens. While many citizens may
ing ration cards and information on government schemes) and have found a RASI centre near to where they lived, very few
18% benefit all groups (e g, electoral role status). government services were available in the centres. Only some
The BJP government also focused on urban areas of the state, information on government schemes, in addition to bill pay-
where it has strong support. During the period of study, Choice ments and basic certificates, was provided.
centres had been opened in only six of the state’s 26 districts, This failure to offer comprehensive government services
those with urban municipalities.13 While the state is now imple- through the RASI centres is somewhat surprising, given analyses
menting the national government’s common service centre in recent years that highlight Tamil Nadu as a technologically
programme in rural areas, and so should eventually have advanced state (Government of India 2006b). In contrast, a rep-
government service centres in all parts of the state, there was resentative of the state information technology department
no plan for rural centres prior to the initiation of the national posited that RASI had “failed” because the state had not been
government initiative. ready at the time to provide technology-enabled services.17
Overall, Chhattisgarh’s technology-enabled service reforms are One explanation for the discrepancy between the views of
some of the most robust in India. The programme is limited by its analysts and state officials is that while the state has imple-
presence only in urban areas, but the high quantity of services mented a number of e-Governance initiatives across multiple
made available reflects the strategic preferences of a chief min- departments, these projects have rarely been fully completed
ister with minimal need to maintain corrupt income from petty or maintained.18 Computerisation of some services, such as
corruption and an electoral strategy that is aligned with the gen- land records, was initiated, but these projects were rarely fol-
eral goals of service reform. At the same time, the selection of lowed through to full computerisation, making it difficult to
specific services to be included in service centres also highlights offer the services in RASI centres. Politicians seem to have
the opportunity that these reforms offer ruling politicians to direct made no effort to pressure departments to include their serv-
the benefits of computerisation to their preferred constituents. ices in service centres, even in those cases where initial com-
puterisation of government processes was already initiated.
Tamil Nadu Politicians may have promoted technolog y initiatives to the
Now consider an above-average corruption state, Tamil Nadu, public and analysts, but they felt little need to risk any possible
which was also ruled during this period by single party gov- income flows through comprehensive reforms.
ernments. The first service centre initiative in the state, the There is evidence for this same trend in the RASI centres
Sustainable Access in Rural India (SARI) programme, was themselves. An assessment in early 2008 found that the majority
launched in 2001 by a coalition of private actors and eventu- of the centres had stopped operating. While the public had
ally implemented 51 “kiosks” in the Melur taluk of Madurai responded positively to the centres, state representatives did not
district (Srinivasan 2005). These centres provided both basic provide the necessary support to ensure their success. “The set-
government documents, such as birth certificates, as well as ting up of RASI Centres…virtually eliminated harassment and
computer education, email, and other private services. corruption in government offices as it avoided the people-staff
In 2002, the state government, ruled at the time by the All interface” (Manikandan 2008). As a result, “the e-Governance
India Anna Dravida Munnetra Kazhagam (AIADMK), decided project became a hit among people, much to the annoyance of
to expand the initiative as an element of state policy. In doing government staff, elected representatives and political big-
so, the government also changed the name to Rural Access wigs” (ibid). Government officials failed to support continued
to Services in India (RASI), which some observers felt was in- operation of the centres, leading to a reduced number of appli-
tended to ensure that the current government received credit cations from citizens, forcing most centres to shut down.
for the project.14 Centres were planned for all areas of the state Overall, the introduction of computerised service centres in
and by 2006 more than 2,000 had been implemented.15 Tamil Nadu failed to live up to the expectations of both analysts
The allocation of centres in the state, however, reflects the and citizens in terms of improving service delivery through com-
specific preferences of the ruling party. While results of elec- puterised, village-level access points. Despite the government’s
tions during the period show that the AIADMK and its main perceived interest in utilising information technology to improve
opposition the Dravida Munnetra Kazhagam (DMK) had gener- service delivery, the largely failed implementation of initiatives
ally consistent support across economic groups (Prasad et al highlights underlying interests in support of the status quo.
2004), votes for the parties were divided across geographic
regions with the AIADMK typically doing better in rural areas Kerala
(Thirunavukkarasu 2001). The AIADMK’s RASI programme Kerala has received much positive media attention as a result
provided services that were focused on the needs of rural citizens, of its initiatives in the areas of IT and governance, but the ef-
with many non-governmental services such as telemedicine fects of the state’s one-stop centre initiatives on the quality of
82 June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
SPECIAL ARTICLE

public service provision to citizens are minimal. The services services reflects coalition dynamics within both the LDF gov-
offered in Kerala’s two main service centre initiatives, FRIENDS ernment and its successor UDF government. As one analyst
(Fast, Reliable, Instant, Efficient, Network for Disbursement of argues, the difficulty associated with negotiations between
Services) and Akshaya, pale in comparison to their counter- departments over provision of services through service centres
parts in many other states. Through FRIENDS centres, only 10 “was particularly evident in Kerala, which is ruled by a coali-
government services have been offered, and just three were tion government, with different political parties in charge of
available in Akshaya centres. different departments” (Kiran 2002).
The limited introduction of computerised services in Kerala The importance of coalition politics implies that the alloca-
is initially surprising, given low levels of petty corruption rela- tion of ministerial posts should be related to the selection of
tive to other states. However, the explanation for Kerala’s pol- services provided in technology-enabled centres. The CPI(M)
icy outcomes lies in the relationship between corruption and led the LDF coalition with its partner the Communist Party of
the dynamics of coalition politics. Kerala’s government is re- India (CPI) holding the next largest number of seats in the state
nowned for the persistence of a bi-polar coalition party system assembly. The coalition in total held 76 seats, five more than the
(Heller 2000; Kumar 2004; Nirmala 2006).19 Between 1996 necessary majority of 71. When FRIENDS was launched, the cen-
and 2001, the Left Democratic Front (LDF), led by the Commu- tres offered six main services, bill payments for electricity, tele-
nist Party of India (Marxist) (CPI(M)), controlled the Kerala phone, water, property tax, driving licences, and vehicle regis-
state assembly. This government’s eventual emphasis on IT tration. Of these services, two of the responsible departments
was unexpected. During the mid-1990s, leftist parties in the were overseen by supporting coalition members, the water de-
state opposed computerisation of the bureaucracy, expecting it partment and transport, held by the Revolutionary Socialist
would lead to job losses in the state (Mathew 1998). However, Party (RSP) and an independent member of the legislature, re-
in 1998 the government introduced its first IT policy, which spectively. However, because the RSP held only five assembly
included an e-Governance mandate, “to identify the govern- seats and the independent held only one, neither minister had
ment departments that have a high level of public interface the power to bring down the coalition government on their
and to introduce Information Technology to ensure effective own: even defection by all five RSP legislators would leave the
delivery of citizen services” (Madon and Kiran 2002: 2). Not coalition with sufficient seats to maintain its majority. The
only did the LDF want to promote the growth of an IT sector in remaining services were delivered by departments overseen by
the state, it also wanted to ensure that these technologies were CPI(M) ministers. No services controlled by the CPI – the only
used in ways that benefited the “masses”. party with enough assembly seats to threaten coalition stability
The Kerala State Information Technology Mission (IT Mis- – were made available. This is despite the fact that the CPI con-
sion) was tasked with implementing government technology trolled 15 services that have been offered in other states.
programmes. The first major services initiative was FRIENDS, a During this same period, a second major service centre ini-
set of computerised centres implemented in district headquar- tiative, Akshaya, was launched to provide more affordable ac-
ters during 2000-01. These were “single window” service cen- cess to information technologies in rural areas of the state,
tres where “citizens have the opportunity to pay all taxes and through the implementation of village level computer centres.
other dues to the Government under one roof at no extra cost” The government’s primary agenda for Akshaya was “to achieve
(Kerala State IT Mission 2009). Thus, like most service centre the twin goals of social development through access to com-
reforms, FRIENDS centres were intended to reduce the time puters in rural areas and financial viability through market-
and cost to citizens of interacting with multiple different driven entrepreneurship” (Ministry of Information Technology
government departments. 2005). e-Governance, or computerised services, was a second-
The potential electoral benefits of this improved service ary goal. In the first phase of the project, centres were to focus
delivery seemed obvious to politicians. As one analysis notes, on providing “e-literacy” to at least one member of every
“The project was launched at Thiruvananthpuram [the capital household in the state while e-Governance was to be incorpo-
of Kerala] in 2000, in a rather hasty manner, just before the rated as a service offering in the second phase, which began
Assembly Elections” (APDIP 2003). Then, when the LDF gov- more than a year after the first centres were opened.
ernment lost control of the assembly in those elections, the in- Despite the fact that computerised services were not the
coming United Democratic Front (UDF) coalition, led by the primary goal, it was expected that this would be a core
Indian National Congress, further implemented the initiative element of the initiative as it evolved. By 2008, however,
in other district headquarters. Akshaya centres had virtually no public services in its net-
Political support for the FRIENDS centres, however, had its work of more than 1,000 centres, and all of these were serv-
limits, as is clear when we consider the services made availa- ices available in FRIENDS. Many other services demanded by
ble. First, despite Kerala’s relatively low level of petty corrup- rural citizens remained unavailable, limiting the relevance of
tion, FRIENDS emphasises bill payments, which typically in- centres to citizen needs and reducing potential income for the
volve the lowest levels of corruption.20 Even where payments Akshaya centre owners.
can be made for certain types of certificates, citizens at least Key to understanding the implementation of the Akshaya
initially had to go to the relevant department to pick up the initiative is the nature of the ruling coalition when it was
certificate (Sreekumar 2002). Second, the selection of specific launched. The UDF, led by Congress, was primarily supported
Economic & Political Weekly EPW June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 83
SPECIAL ARTICLE

by the Muslim League with 16 seats and the Kerala Congress(M) only department overseeing a service frequently provided in
with nine seats. The lack of public services in Akshaya centres service centres, ration cards, that a minister from the SP did
is viably linked to the politics of this coalition in two ways. not hold, and this service was not made available in e-Suvidha.
First, the important Kerala Congress(M) controlled both the The independent MLA holding this position was seen as a key
revenue department and rural development, which together supporter of the lead party but he also had a criminal record
account for a large number of citizen-facing services, but none (he was released from prison on terrorism charges when the
of these were provided through Akshaya. government came to power) and it is perhaps not surprising
Second, a number of services provided by FRIENDS were not that the opportunity to increase government transparency in
provided in the Akshaya centres, such as payments for water this department has not translated into any tangible results.
bills, property taxes, driver’s licences, and vehicle registration. Within the SP itself, or its successor the Bahujan Samaj
Other coalition parties controlled the departments overseeing Party, there also seems to have been little interest in providing
these services, with the Kerala Congress (Jacob) and the Ker- comprehensive computerised services in urban areas. The
ala Congress(B) overseeing water and transport, respectively, e-Suvidha initiative was initially met with great optimism,
while Kerala Congress(M) oversaw revenue, which controls with one media report claiming that, “People can now look
property taxes. Even though the basic infrastructure was in forward to a redefined concept of public service that obviates
place to extend these services through Akshaya outlets, this tediousness of long queues moving from one department to
was not done under the Congress administration. Instead, citi- another to procure routine departmental information or pay
zens must either go to the district FRIENDS office or avail of public utility bills” (“Now, e-Suvidha to Redefine Public Service”,
these services through traditional department-based offices. Times of India, 11 February 2005), but this was not to be.
Coalition politics, then, played an important role in shaping Only a short time after the urban centres were launched,
technology-enabled service provision in Kerala. While the reports began to emerge about poor quality service delivery.
state can be seen as an innovator in service reforms, at least in Citizens still have to jostle for space to pay their bills, apart from hav-
terms of early service centre implementation relative to other ing to undergo an endless wait while in queue. And more often than not,
states, the characteristics of the centres themselves reveal the some arrive at the centres only to find out that some of the facilities are
power, and interest, of supporting coalition members to retain not available, as claimed otherwise by the government (“E-Suvidha:
Residents Resent Snag-Fraught Facility”, Indian Express, 26 February 2008).
direct control over the services in their domain.
As one citizen lamented,
Uttar Pradesh I don’t understand how the initiative has been serving its purpose. The
Uttar Pradesh provides a final case for evaluating the effects of queues are still long, and most of the facilities that the centre claims to
both petty corruption and coalition politics on computerised offer are not available here (Kumar quoted in “E-Suvidha: Residents
Resent Snag-Fraught Facility”, Indian Express, 26 February 2008).
service centres. During the period in which centres were initi-
ated, the Samajwadi Party (SP) ruled the state in coalition gov- Given problems with additional services provided in the
ernment. This government supported the expansion of a dis- e-Suvidha centres, including railway tickets and mobile phone
trict level rural service centre initiative and also launched payments, the future of the initiative is highly uncertain (Times
computerised centres in urban areas. However, in both cases of India 2009). Though e-Suvidha was launched with great hope
the number of services offered is highly limited and, particu- for improving service delivery in urban areas, the state govern-
larly in the urban case, the implementation of services within ment has failed to provide a range of high quality, computerised
centres led to limited benefits for citizens. services. The combination of high levels of petty corruption and
A district collector initiated the rural “Lokvani” project and the need to maintain a delicate coalition balance resulted in
was subsequently moved into the department of information service centres offering little more to citizens than a new loca-
technology in order to lead the extension of the initiative into tion for inefficient, and most likely corrupt, service delivery.
other districts. The main goal of Lokvani was to offer an im-
proved platform for citizens to submit grievances to the govern- Conclusions
ment. Additional services were those that were relatively easy to This discussion has highlighted the risks associated with pro-
offer once the centres were online, such as information about moting technology-based reforms without due attention to the
schemes, which was already published online by relevant de- threats and benefits these policies may present to established in-
partments.21 The other services made available are those most terests in the political system. If politicians depend on access to
commonly offered by the district collector, such as certificates. corrupt income to support their re-election campaigns, then we
Additional services overseen by the rural development depart- should expect them to resist any policies that threaten this eco-
ment, which was overseen by a minister from the supporting nomic resource. Even where politicians promote reforms, they
Congress Party, were not made available through Lokvani. are likely to do so in a way that primarily benefits their preferred
A second service centre initiative, e-Suvidha, was later constituents. Efforts to improve the quality of service delivery to
launched to serve urban areas. In this case, it is difficult to all citizens must take the broader causes of problems in service
evaluate the effects of coalition politics, because the SP re- delivery, and in particular the underlying causes of demands for
tained control over nearly all of the departments providing bribes, into consideration in order to achieve significant and
services directly to citizens. Food and civil supplies was the long-term improvements in the quality of public services.
84 June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 EPW Economic & Political Weekly
SPECIAL ARTICLE

Notes Ahuja, M and A P Singh (2006): “Evaluation of on 14 December 2010 (http://expert-eyes.org/


Computerisation of Land Records in Karnataka”, archive/ itcritiq.html).
1 While the analysis continued after 2006, when Economic & Political Weekly, 7 January, 69-77. Mayaram, Baba (2004): “Chhattisgarh: BJP Con-
the NeGP was launched, I consider only those
Banerjee, Abhijit and Lakshmi Iyer (2005): “History, solidates Its Hold”, Economic & Political Weekly,
state government initiatives not originating
Institutions, and Economic Performance”, 18 December, 5516-18.
with the central government programme.
American Economic Review, 95: 1190-1213. Ministry of Information Technology (2005): “Akshaya
2 There are multiple reasons a citizen might pay
Bardhan, Pranab (2005): “An Economist’s Approach – An IT Dissemination Project”, http://www.
a bribe to receive a service, including access to
to the Problem of Corruption”, World Develop- mit.gov.in/sites/upload_files/dit/files/down-
a public benefit to which they are not entitled.
ment, 34: 341-48. loads/eready2005/Chap4.pdf
However, many bribes are paid simply to re-
ceive basic services in a timely manner (Trans- – (1997): “Corruption and Development: A Review NDTV (2010a): “Alleged Commonwealth Games
parency International India and CMS 2005) of Issues”, Journal of Economic Literature, 35: Corruption”, 10 August, viewed on 12 December
and more efficient service delivery should be 1320-46. 2010 (http://www.ndtv.com/article/india/al-
feasible with computerised procedures. Bhatnagar, Subhash and Nupur Singh (2009): leged-commonwealth-games-corruption-kalma-
“Results from a Study of Impact of E-govern- di-defends-himself-in-a-letter-to-mps-43287).
3 Data collected by the author.
ment Projects in India”, Proceedings of the – (2010b): “2G Spectrum Scam: A Raja Meets Karu-
4 Interview. Rajasthan State Administrative,
Third International Conference on ICTD. nanidhi”, 11 December, viewed on 12 December
Officer, 9 May 2007.
Bussell, Jennifer (2010): “Why Get Technical? Cor- 2010 (http://www.ndtv.com/article/india/2g-
5 Interview. Indian Administrative Officer, ruption and the Politics of Public Service Re- spectrum-scam-a-raja-meets-karunani-
Chhattisgarh, 23 January 2009. form in the Indian States”, Comparative Politi- dhi-71983).
6 In 2001, the Indian central government pre- cal Studies, 43: 1230-57. Nirmala, P S (2006): “Assembly Polls 2006: A For-
empted state policies in the north-east and Caseley, Jonathan (2004): “Public Sector Reform and gone Outcome in Kerala?”, Economic & Political
Jammu and Kashmir by implementing a cen- Corruption: CARD Façade in Andhra Pradesh”, Weekly, 11 March, 866-68.
trally designed service centre initiative in these Economic & Political Weekly, 13 March, 1151-56. Oldenburg, Philip (1987): “Middlemen in Third-
states, the Citizen Information Centres (CICs).
Davis, Jennifer (2004): “Corruption in Public Serv- World Corruption”, World Politics, 39, 508-35.
As a result, I was not able to analyse the factors
ice Delivery: Experience from South Asia’s Wa- Pandey, S (2010): “The Hell Diggers”, Tehelka,
influencing sub-national policy characteristics
ter and Sanitation Sector”, World Development, 3 April.
in these states.
32: 53-71. Prasad, G K and CSDS Team (2004): “Alliance Ef-
7 In all analyses, I use the measure of petty cor-
de Zwart, Frank (1994): The Bureaucratic Merry-go- fect, Swing Factor Propelled DPA Victory”, The
ruption discussed above.
round: Manipulating the Transfer of Indian Civil Hindu, 20 May, viewed on 14 December 2010
8 “High Corruption Potential” and “High Bribe” Servants (Amsterdam: Amsterdam University (http://www.hinduonnet.com/elections2004/
services were determined based on data in Press). verdict2004/stories/2004052000180300.htm).
Transparency International India and CMS
Election Commission of India (2007): Handbook for Rekhi, S and G C Shekhar (1996): “Funding the
(2005).
Candidates, Electoral Commission of India, Politician”, India Today, 21: 28-40.
9 Author’s data collection and analysis. Some New Delhi.
states do not add to 100% because services not Sharma, Ravi (2008): “Gaining Currency”, Frontline,
Financial Express (2010): “Beyond Corruption in Ma- 7-20 June.
targeted to socio-economic groups are excluded.
harashtra”, 11 November, http://www.financial- Sreekumar, T T (2002): “Civil Society and State-led
10 Interview, Chhattisgarh IT Society Employee, express.com/news/beyond-corruption-in-ma-
23 January 2009. Initiatives in ICTs: The Case of Kerala”, Infor-
harashtra/711067 /0 mation Technology in Developing Countries, De-
11 Interview, Chhattisgarh IT Department Offi- Frankel, Francine (2005): India’s Political Economy: cember, viewed on 14 December 2010 (http://
cial, 23 January 2009. 1997-2004, second edition (New Delhi: Oxford www.iimahd.ernet.in/egov/ifip/dec2002/arti-
12 Policy documents released during the Con- University Press). cle2.htm).
gress administration allow for a comparison of Heller, Patrick (2000): “Degrees of Democracy: Srinivasan, Janaki (2005): “Sustainable Access in
the initially offered services with those intro- Some Comparative Lessons from India”, World Rural India (SARI) Project, Madurai, India” in
duced after the BJP came to power. Politics, 52: 484-519. Information and Communication Technologies
13 Interview, Chhattisgarh Information Technol- Government of India (2006a): National e-Governance for Development: A Comparative Analysis of Im-
ogy Society Representative, 23 January 2009. Plan, Ministry of Information Technology, viewed pacts and Costs from India, IIIT, Bangalore.
14 Interview, Consultant to Tamil Nadu govern- on 12 December 2010.(http://mit.gov.in/content/ Thirunavukkarasu, R (2001): “Tamil Nadu Elec-
ment, 17 May 2007. national-e-governance-plan). tions 2001: Changing Equations”, Economic &
15 Interview, ELCOT representative, 16 February – (2006b): India: e-Readiness Assessment Report Political Weekly, 7 July, 2486-89.
2006. 2006: For States/Union Territories, Depart- Toyama, Kentaro, Karishma Kiri, M L Ratan,
16 Interview, Tamil Nadu IT Department official, ment of Information Technology, New Delhi. A Nileshwar, Rama Vedashree and R F MacGregor
16 February 2006 Iype, George (2004): “How Much Does an Election (2004): “Rural Kiosks in India”, Microsoft
17 Interview, Tamil Nadu IT Department official, Cost?”, Rediff Election Special, 25 March, Corporation.
18 May 2007. viewed on 14 December 2010. (http://www. Transparency International and CMS (2005): “India
18 Interview, Consultant to Tamil Nadu Govern- rediff. com/election/2004/mar/26espec.htm) Corruption Study 2005”, http://www.transpar-
ment, 17 May 2007. Jenkins, Rob (2006): “Democracy, Development encyindia.org/resource/survey_study/
19 While the Congress and the Communist Party and India’s Struggle against Corruption”, Pub- India%20Corruption%20Study%202005.pdf
of India (Marxist) are constant leaders of the lic Policy Research, September. Uppal, Yogesh (2009): “The Disadvantaged Incum-
two major coalitions, the parties that support Kiran, G R (2002): “Front-End First: Citizen Pay- bents: Estimating Incumbency Effects in Indi-
them in these coalitions are more variable ment at FRIENDS Centres in Kerala”, UNPAN an State Legislatures”, Public Choice, 138: 9-27.
(Nirmala 2006). Because supporting parties eGovernment for Development Success/Fail- Vithal, B P R (1997): “Evolving Trends in the Bureau-
can switch coalitions and because rule of the ure Case Studies, #17, viewed on 14 December cracy” in P Chatterjee (ed.), State and Politics in
state frequently swings from one coalition to 2010 (http://www.egov4dev.org/friends.htm). India (New Delhi: Oxford University Press).
the other, Congress and CPI(M) leaders must Kumar, G G (2004): “Kerala: Verdict against Non- Wade, Robert (1985): “The Market for Public Office:
be conscious of retaining the support of smaller Performance and Congress Factionalims”, Eco- Why the Indian State Is Not Better at Develop-
parties in order to stay in power. nomic & Political Weekly, 18 December, 5498-5501. ment”, World Development, 13: 467-97.
20 Both surveys (Transparency International India Kuriyan, Renee and Isha Ray (2009): “Outsourcing
and CMS 2005) and anecdotal reports find that the State? Public-Private Partnerships and In-
bill payments rarely involve major demands for formation Technologies in India”, World Deve-
bribes. This is likely because a bureaucrat in- lopment, 37: 1663-73.
volved in this type of transaction cannot delay Madon, Shiron and G R Kiran (2002): Information
in giving a document or other service to the citi- Technology for Citizen-Government Interface: available at
zen; they are simply expected to take the citi- A Study of FRIENDS Project in Kerala, World
zen’s money for services already delivered. Bank Global Knowledge Sharing Programme. Delhi Magazine Distributors
21 Interview, Uttar Pradesh IT Department Offi- Manikandan, K (2008): “Innovative Rural e-Gov-
cial, 13 February 2008. ernance Project Plagued by Neglect”, The Hin- Pvt Ltd
du, 21 January, viewed on 14 December 2010. 110, Bangla Sahib Marg
(http://www.thehindu.com/2008/01/21/sto-
References ries/2008 012154300600.htm) New Delhi 110 001
ADPIP (2003): “Friends, Thiruvananthapuram, Mathew, R (1998): “State Information Technology Ph: 41561062/63
Kerala”, Case Study. Policy – A Critique”, lecture, 26 July, viewed

Economic & Political Weekly EPW June 23, 2012 vol xlvII no 25 85

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen