Sie sind auf Seite 1von 16

Austrian Economics Newsletter

Summer 1991 • The Ludwig von Mises Institute

The Antitrust Economists'


Paradox

By Thomas J. DiLorenzo

Today regulation is generally recognized as a


mechanism by which special interests lobby the
government to create barriers to entry or other spe
cial privileges. Research has shown, for example,
that the Civil Aeronautics Board cartelized the air
line industry, the Interstate Commerce Commission
helped monopolize the railroad and the trucking in
dustries, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
sharply limited entry into the banking business, and
occupational licensing created entry barriers into
hundreds of occupations. Much of the history of reg
ulation chronicles monopoly privileges procured
through the auspices of the state, as Adam Smith
pointed out more than 200 years ago in The Wealth of
Nations. Thomas J. DiLorenzo
Oddly, antitrust regulation is still widely viewed
as government's benevolent response to the "failures" trust consultants and expert witnesses often stand to
and "imperfections" of the marketplace. Even econo make a good deal of money, so financial self-interest
mists who are usually skeptical of regulations enacted may preclude criticism of antitrust. Many economists
in the name of the public interest seem to lose their are also unable to voice informed opinions on antitrust.
perspective when it comes to antitrust. George Stigler, If it is not their area of expertise, they may not have
for example, has stated: "So far as I can tell, [the kept up with research over the past 30 years, or exces
Sherman Actl is a public-interest law ... in the same sive concentration on mathematical models may have
sense in which I think having private property, enforce left some economists somewhat detached from eco
ment of contracts, and suppression of crime are pub nomic reality. Finally, it is widely believed that there
lic-interest phenomena. ... I like the Sherman Act."1 was once a "golden age of antitrust" during which
A 1984 survey of professional economists revealed the public was protected from rapacious monopolists
that 83 percent of the respondents believed that "an by benevolent public servants. According to this per
titrust laws should be used vigorously to reduce mo spective, although mistakes have been made, more
nopoly power from its current level."2 This opinion is knowledgeable and public-spirited regulators can
widespread despite common knowledge among anti
trust scholars that in practice the antitrust laws
restrain output and the growth of productivity have
INSIDE
contributed to a deterioration of the competitive po
sition of U.S. industry, and are routinely used to An Interview with Leland B. Yeager 6
subvert competition.
Jack Wiseman (1919-1991) 10
Why then do the antitrust laws continue to com Economics Rankings: A Survey 11
mand such powerful support among economists and Conferences and Conventions 13
legal scholars when the pervasive failures are so well Book Bite 16
known? There are several possible explanations. Anti-
successfully reform antitrust. Once reformed, anti but at a slower rate than the general price level. This
trust policy can then perform its original purpose and produced real income gains for farmers. In addition,
defend competition and free enterprise. the rapidly increasing quality of manufactured goods
Unfortunately, the Sherman Act was never in further improved the farmers' standard of living. The
tended to protect competition. It was a blatantly volatility of farm prices caused the farmers to be
protectionist act designed to shield smaller and less politically active.
efficient businesses from their larger competitors. Many other groups joined the antitrust coalition—
There never was a golden age of antitrust. The stan small business organizations, academics (though not
dard account of the origins of antitrust is a myth. economists), and journalists. They argued that the
"giant monopolies" were creating a "dangerous concen
Interest Group Politics tration of wealth" among the capitalists of the day.
and the Sherman Act Although the conspicuous wealth of entrepreneurs
In the late 1880s, widespread economic change such as Rockefeller, Vanderbilt, Mellon, and Mor
produced myriad pleas from relatively small—but gan added fuel to this charge, it does not appear to
politically active—farmers who sought protection be true. In fact, economic historians have concluded
from larger, corporate competitors. Historian Sanford that from 1840 to 1900, the division of national
Gordon offered an example: "Perhaps the most vio income between labor and property owners (capital
lent reaction [against industrial combinations] of any and natural resource suppliers) remained in a 70-to-
single special interest group came from farmers. ... 30 ratio.5 Over the same time span, both capital and
They singled out the jute bagging and alleged binder developed natural resources increased faster than
twine trust, and sent petitions to both their state the labor force. This means that labor income per unit
legislators and to Congress demanding some relief. of labor rose compared with profit and interest per
Cotton was suggested as a good substitute for jute to unit of property input.
cover their cotton bales. In Georgia, Mississippi, and Although there was no significant redistribution
Tennessee the [farmers'] alliances passed resolutions of wealth from labor to capital owners in the aggre
condemning the jute bagging trust and recommended gate, competitive markets always alter the distribu
the use of cotton cloth."3 tion of income in ways that some do not like. There
Southern farmers were annoyed that consumers was no "dangerous concentration of wealth," but
increasingly preferred jute to the cotton cloth they many supporters of antitrust legislation found that
produced, and they sought antitrust legislation that their own income had fallen (or not increased rapidly
would dissolve their competition. Such special-inter enough). The push for antitrust legislation was an
est behavior was characteristic of the farm lobby. attempt to use the powers of the government to im
During the 51st Congress, Gordon notes that "64 prove their economic status.
petitions and memorials were recorded in the Con Economic conditions were changing rapidly in the
gressional Record, all calling for action against com latter part of the nineteenth century. Expansion of
binations. These were almost* exclusively from farm the railroad and inland shipping industries greatly
groups The greatest vehemence was expressed by reduced the cost of transportation. Technological
representatives from the Midwest."4 developments led to large-scale (and lower-cost) pro
Farmers complained to their national representa duction of steel, cement, and other goods. Communi
tives that the products they bought from the trust cations technology rapidly expanded, especially the
were increasingly expensive relative to the prices of use of the telegraph. And the capital markets became
farm products, but the facts do not support this con more sophisticated. The United States also under
tention. From 1865 to 1900 farm prices were falling, went a rapid transition from a predominantly agrar
ian to an industrial society. In 1810 the ration of farm
to non-farm labor was approximately 4.0. This ratio
fell to 1.6 by 1840, and by 1880 the labor force was
about equally divided between farm and non-farm
endeavors. Meanwhile, individuals and groups un
comfortable with rapid change were becoming in
Thomas J. DiLorenzo holds the Probasco Chair for creasingly adept at using the regulatory powers of the
Free Enterprise at the University of Tennessee. state. In this increasingly mercantilist atmosphere,
Chattanooga. the Sherman Act was passed in 1890.
Peter G. Klein is a graduate student in economics
at the University of California, Berkeley, a Mlses
Were the Trusts Monopolistic?
fellow, and assistant editor of the AEN.
Alexander Tabarrok is a graduate student in eco In introducing federal "antitrust" legislation,
nomics at George Mason University. Mises a fellow, Sen. Sherman and his congressional allies claimed
and correspondent of the AEN.
that combinations or trusts tended to restrict output
and thus drive up prices. If Sherman's claims were
true, then there should be evidence that those indus The average price of steel rails, for example, fell
tries allegedly being monopolized by the trusts had by 53 percent from $68 per ton in 1880 to $32 per ton
restricted output. By contrast, if the trust movement in 1890. The price of refined sugar fell from 9 cents
was part of the evolutionary process of competitive per pound in 1880, to 7 cents in 1890, to 4.5 cents in
markets responding to technological change, one 1900. The price of lead dropped 12 percent, from $5.04
would expect an expansion of trade or output. In fact, per pound in 1880 to $4.41 in 1890. The price of zinc
there is no evidence that trusts in the 1880s were declined by 20 percent, from $5.51 to $4.40 per pound
restricting output or artificially increasing prices. from 1880 to 1890.
The Congressional Record of the 51st Congress
provides a list of industries that were supposedly
being monopolized by the trusts. Those industries for
which data are available are salt, petroleum, zinc,
steel, bituminous coal, steel rails, sugar, lead, liquor, One function of the Sherman Act was
twine, iron nuts and washers, jute, castor oil, cotton to divert attention from a more certain
seed oil, leather, linseed oil, and matches. The avail
source of monopoly—government.
able data are incomplete, but in all but two of the 17
industries, output increased—not only from 1880 to
1890,but also to the turn ofthe century.6Matches and
castor oil, the only exceptions to the general rule,
hardly seem to be items that would cause a national The sugar and petroleum trusts were among the
furor, even if they were monopolized. most widely attacked, but there is evidence that these
As a general rule, output in these industries ex trusts actually reduced prices from what they other
panded more rapidly than GNP during the 10 years wise would have been. Congress clearly recognized
preceding the Sherman Act. In the nine industries for this. During the House debates over the Sherman Act,
which nominal output data are available, output in Congressman William Mason stated, "Trusts have
creased on average by 62 percent; nominal GNP in made products cheaper, have reducedprices', but ifthe
creased by 16 percent over the same period. Several price of oil, for instance, were reduced to one cent a
of the industries expanded output by more than 10 barrel, it would not right the wrong done to the people
times the increase in nominal GNP. Among the more of this country by the 'trusts' which have destroyed
rapidly expanding industries were cottonseed oil (151 legitimate competition and driven honest men from
percent), leather goods (133 percent), cordage and legitimate business enterprises."7 Sen. Edwards, who
twine (166 percent), and jute (57 percent). played a key role in the debate, added, "Although for
Real GNP increased by approximately 24 percent the time being the sugar trust has perhaps reduced
from 1880 to 1890. Meanwhile, the allegedly monop the price of sugar, and the oil trust certainly has
olized industries for which a measure of real output reduced the price ofoil immensely, that does not alter
is available grew on average by 175 percent. The more the wrong of the principle of any trust."8 Perhaps it
rapidly expanding industries in real terms included would be more accurate to describe the Sherman Act
steel (258 percent), zinc (156 percent), coal (153 per as an anti-price-cutting law.
cent), steel rails (142 percent), petroleum (79 per One final argument could be made that the trusts
cent), and sugar (75 percent). were practicing predatory pricing, that is, that they
These trends continued from 1890 to 1900 as were pricing below their costs to drive out competi
output expanded in every industry but one for which tors. But in more than a century of looking for a
we have data. (Castor oil was the exception.) On proven real-world monopoly actually created by pred
average, the allegedly monopolized industries contin atory pricing, an example has yet to be found. More
ued to expand faster than the rest of the economy. over, prices charged by the nineteenth-century trusts
Those industries for which nominal data are avail continued to fall for more than a decade. What ratio
able expanded output by 99 percent, while nominal nal businessman would continue to price below cost
GNP increased by 43 percent. The industries for for more than ten years?
which we have data increased real output by 76 per In sum, the nineteenth-century trusts were not
cent compared with a 46 percent increase in real GNP guilty of the charge levied against them by Sen.
from 1890 to 1900. Sherman. There is no consistent evidence that they
As with measures of output, not all of the relevant restricted output to raise prices.
price data are available, but the information that is
Government:
at hand indicates that falling prices accompanied the
rapid expansion of output in the "monopolized" indus The True Source of Monopoly
tries. In addition, although the consumer price index It appears that one function ofthe Sherman Act was
fell by 7 percent from 1880 to 1890, prices in many of to divert public attention from a more certain source
the suspect industries were falling even faster. of monopoly—government. In the late nineteenth
century, tariffs were a major source of trade re gations of capital to combine and advance prices, they
straints, but the Sherman Act made no provision for might hope for a season of great prosperity.... He did
attacking tariffs or any other government-created hope, the Senator concluded, that the manufacturers
barriers to competitive entry. In fact, evidence exists would open the doors to fair competition and give its
that a major political function of the Sherman Act was benefits to the people.... He hoped the manufactur
to serve as a smoke screen behind which politicians ers would agree to compete one with another and
could grant tariff protection to their big business would refuse to take the high prices that are so easily
constituents while assuring the public that some obtained."
thing was being done about the monopoly problem. It was absurd, of course, for Sen. Sherman to say
In a particularly revealing statement during the that a protective tariff would actually help consumers
debates over the antitrust act, Sen. Sherman at if only manufacturers could be trusted to refrain from
tacked the trusts on the ground that they "subverted raising prices. The whole purpose of tariff protection
the tariff system; they undermined the policy of gov is to allow domestic manufacturers to raise prices, or
ernment to protect... American industries by levying at least to avoid reducing them. Such hypocrisy led
duties on imported goods."9 This is certainly an odd the New York Times to withdraw its support of anti
statement from the author of the "Magna Carta of trust legislation. The Times concluded: "That so-
free enterprise." But increased output and reduced called Anti-Trust law was passed to deceive the
prices in these increasingly efficient industries ap people and to clear the way for the enactment of this
parently dissipated the monopoly profits previously ... law relating to the tariff. It was projected in order
generated by the tariffs. This worked against the that the parly organs might say to the opponents of
objectives of the protected industries and their legis tariff extortion and protected combinations, 'Behold!
lative champions, including Sen. Sherman. We have attacked the Trusts. The Republican party is
the enemy of all such rings.' And now the author of it
Even more damning is the fact that just three can only Tiope' that the rings will dissolve of their own
months after the Sherman Act was passed, Sen. Sher accord." Thus, the Sherman Act seems to have been
man, as chairman of the Senate Finance Committee, passed to help draw public attention away from the
sponsored legislation popularly known as the "Cam process of monopolization through tariff protection.
paign Contributors' Tariff Bill" that sharply raised
tariff rates. On October 1,1890, the New York Times The Sherman Act won legislators votes and cam
reported: "The Campaign Contributors' Tariff Bill paign contributions from farmers and small business
now goes to the president for his signature, which will men who thought antitrust regulation would protect
speedily be affixed to it, and the favored manufactur them from their more efficient competitors, and the
ers, many of whom ... proposed and made the [tariff] tariff bill was supported by all U.S. manufacturers,
rates which affect their products, will begin to enjoy both large and small. In a political sense, then, the
the profits of this legislation." Sherman Act was very efficient. Congress itselfseems
to have been one of the principal special-interest
The New York Times further reported that "the groups to benefit from antitrust legislation.
speech of Mr. Sherman on Monday [September 29,
1890] should not be overlooked, for it was one of Economists and the Emergence
confession." Apparently, Sen. Sherman withdrew his of Antitrust
speech from the Congressional Record for "revision,"
but a reporter obtained an unabridged copy of the Although most economists today favor stricter
original. The New York Times reported: "We direct at antitrust regulation, from the 1880s until the 1920s
tention to those passages [of Sherman's speech] re the economics profession expressed nearly unani
lating to combinations of protected manufacturers mous opposition to antitrust. When Sanford Gordon
designed to take full advantage of high tariff duties surveyed professional journals in the social sciences
by exacting from consumers prices fixed by agree and articles and books written by economists before
ment after competition has been suppressed.... Mr. 1890, he found, "A big majority of the economists
conceded that the combination movement was to be
Sherman closed his speech with some words of warn
ing and advice to the beneficiaries of the new tariff. expected, that high fixed costs made large-scale en
He was earnest enough in his manner to indicate terprises economical, that competition under these
that he is not at all confident as to the outcome of
new circumstances frequently resulted in cut-throat
the law. The great thing that stood in the way of the competition, that agreements among producers was
success of the bill, he said, was whether or not the
a natural consequence, and the stability of prices
manufacturers of this country would permit free com usually brought more benefit than harm to the soci
petition in the American market. The danger was that ety. They seemed to reject the idea that competition
the beneficiaries ofthe bill would combine and cheat the
was declining, or showed no fear of decline."10
people out of the benefits of the law. They were now George Stigler has also noted economists' initial
given reasonable and ample protection, and if they disapproval of antitrust: "For much too long a time
would resist the temptation attaching to great aggre students of the history of antitrust policy have been
at least mildly perplexed by the coolness with which even stronger statement: "What the theory of perfect
American economists greeted the Sherman Act. Was competition discusses has little claim to be called
not the nineteenth century the period in which the 'competition' at all and... its conclusions are of little use
benevolent effects of competition were most widely as guides to policy."14 Moreover, wrote Hayek, "If the
extolled? Should not a profession praise a Congress state of affairs assumed by the theory of perfect compe
which seeks to legislate its textbook assumptions into tition ever existed, it would not only deprive oftheir scope
practice?"11 Stigler offered three possible explanations. all the activities which the verb 'to compete'describes but
First, economists did not appreciate the importance of would make them virtually impossible."15 Advertising,
tacit collusion. Second, they had too much confidence in product differentiation, and price undercutting, for ex
other forms of regulation as a means of dealing with ample, are all excluded by definition from a state of
monopoly. Third, they underestimated the income "perfect" competition which, according to Hayek, "means
they would receive as antitrust consultants. indeed the absence of all competitive activities."
Those economists who use market structure to
measure competition are likely to have a favorable
attitude toward antitrust regulation. Stigler asserted
more than 30 years ago, "One of the assumptions of
Once the economics profession perfect competition is the existence of a Sherman
embraced the "perfect" competi Act."16 To the nineteenth-century economists, how
tion theory, it also embraced anti ever, an antitrust law was incompatible with rivalry
trust regulation. and free enterprise. The perfect competition model
and its corollary, the structure-conduct-performance
paradigm of industrial organization theory, have se
riously misled the economics profession, at least as
far as antitrust policy is concerned.
These explanations are plausible, but there may
be an even more important reason for the transfor Conclusion
mation of economists' attitudes toward antitrust. In
the late nineteenth century most economists viewed The two principal reasons for the "antitrust
competition as a dynamic, rivalrous process, similar economists' paradox," then, are the lack of historical
to the theory of competition embodied in the work of knowledge—particularly about actual economic
Adam Smith and today's Austrian economists. Conse events in the late nineteenth century—and the fail
quently, they tended to regard mergers as a natural ure to appreciate that competition is best viewed as
consequence of the competitive struggle and not a dynamic discovery procedure, as Hayek contends.
something that should be interfered with by antitrust Economists who believe that there was once a "golden
legislation.12 Although some industries were becom age of antitrust" have never produced any evidence of
ing more concentrated in the late nineteenth century, such an age. As this paper has shown, the Sherman
rivalry was still as strong as ever, as the rapid expan Act was a tool used to regulate some of the most
sion of output and the decline in prices attest. Thus, competitive industries in America, which were rap
the economists of the time saw no reason to interfere idly expanding their output and reducing their prices,
in market processes with antitrust regulation. much to the dismay of their less efficient (but politi
cally influential) competitors. The Sherman Act,
Beginning in the 1920s, mathematical economists moreover, was used as a political fig leaf to shield the
developed the so-called perfect competition model, real cause of monopoly in the late 1880s—protection
and it replaced the older theory. To economists com ism. The chief sponsor of the 1890 tariff bill, passed
petition no longer meant rivalry and enterprise. In just three months after the Sherman Act, was none
stead, it meant the equation of price and marginal other than Sen. Sherman himself.
cost. Most important, it meant that there must be
"many" firms in "unconcentrated" industries. Once In the late nineteenth century most economists
economists began to define competition in terms of viewed competition as a dynamic, rivalrous process,
market structure, they became more and more enam much like the contemporary Austrian theory. Ac
ored with antitrust regulation as a way of forcing the cordingly, they nearly unanimously opposed anti
business world to conform to their admittedly unre trust on the grounds that such a law would be
alistic theory of competition. inherently incompatible with rivalry. Once the eco
nomics profession embraced the "perfect" competi
Economist Paul McNulty has noted: "The two con tion theory which, as Hayek has said, means "the
cepts [of competition] are not only different; they are absence of all competitive activities," it also embraced
fundamentally incompatible. Competition came to antitrust regulation. For once competition came to
mean, with the mathematical economists, a hypotheti- mean "many" firms and the equation of price to
cally realized situation in which business rivalry . . . marginal costs, rather than dynamic rivalry, most
was ruled out by definition."13 F.A. Hayek has madean economists became convinced that antitrust laws were
needed to force markets in the direction of their ideal The following discussion is based on Thomas J. DiLorenzo, 'The
ized model of "perfect" competition. Consequently, an Origins of Antitrust: An Interest-Group Perspective," International
Review of Law and Economics (June 1985).
titrust has for over a century been a tremendous drag
Congressional Record, 51st Congress, House, 1st Session (June
on competition, rendering American industry less 20, 1890), p. 4100; emphasis added.
productive and less competitive in world markets.
Ibid., p. 2558; emphasis added.
Robert Bork might not have been exaggerating
when, writing in his book, The Antitrust Paradox, he 9Ibid., p. 4100.
remarked that ifgovernment were to somehow force the 10Sanford Gordon, "Attitudes Toward the Trusts," p. 158.
economy into "competitive equilibrium," it would have George Stigler, "The Economists and the Problem of Monop
approximately the same effect on personal wealth as oly," American Economic Review (May 1982): 1.
several strategically placed nuclear explosions. 12The following discussion is based on Thomas J. DiLorenzo and
Jack C. High, "Antitrust and Competition, Historically Consid
Quoted in Thomas Hazlett, "Interview With George Stigler," ered," Economic Inquiry (Summer 1988).
Reason (January 1984): 46. ' Paul McNulty, "A Note on the History of Perfect Competition,"
Bruno Frey, et al., "Consensus and Dissention Among Econo •Journal of Political Economy (August 1967): 398.
mists," American Economic Review (May 1984): 986-94. ,4F. A. Hayek, "The Meaning of Competition," in F. A. Hayek,
3Sanford Gordon, "Attitudes Toward the Trusts Prior to the Individualism and Economic Order (Chicago: University of Chi
Sherman Act," Southern Economic Journal (July 1963): 158. cago Press, 1948), p. 92.
4Ibid., p. 162. 15Ibid.
R. Gray, and J. Peterson, Economic Development in the United 16George Stigler, "Perfect Competition, Historically Contem
States (New York: Irwin, 1965). plated," Journal of Political Economy (February 1957): 1. •

A: It is a standard caricature that it cannot. Murray


An Interview
Rothbard takes this position. But if we go back to
with Leland B. Yeager Chapter 5 in Mill's Utilitarianism, the one dealing
with justice, we read that justice is a name for that
set of rules and principles guiding our institutions
Leland B. Yeager is professor of economics and behavior which are of utmost importance to
at Auburn University. human happiness. If we set aside justice to give a
thrill to Rothbard's majority—the people who get
Q: Throughout your career as an economist, you their kicks from torturing redheads—then we are
have shown interest in social ethics. setting aside rules and principles that are vital to a
A: I don't see anything peculiar about economists decent society and therefore to human happiness.
being interested in ethics. The two fields overlap. This notion of overriding minority rights to amuse
Both are concerned with how people can function the majority is a caricature version of utilitarianism.
together in society without central direction. Some Respect for minority rights is essential to a decent
how, they pursue their own interests and serve those society. Any reasonable version of utilitarianism
of others at the same time. takes a longer view, considering how a good society
Q: And your interest is utilitarianism. can be sustained. It is not preoccupied with the plea
sures of the moment. In my depressed moments I feel
A: That's right. Among many classical liberals, like not writing anything more on these issues, since
utilitarianism is a bad word. Many don't understand
Hazlitt has already said everything.
what it means. Utilitarianism comes in different va
rieties. Mises and Henry Hazlitt, both utilitarians,
are on the same wavelength, as was David Hume,
who inspired F.A. Hayek.
No sensible version of utilitarianism relies on
interpersonal comparisons of utility. Hume, Mises,
Hazlitt, and Hayek did not make interpersonal com
parisons. Bentham, I suppose, did sometimes, not
always, write as if he imagined they were possible.
The same can be said of Edgeworth in Mathematical
Psychics. He seemed to conceive—either as an expos
itory device or even seriously—of drawing up an ag
gregate utility function.
Q: But how can utilitarianism protect the minor Leland Yeager (right) and Henry Hazlitt (left) at the
Mises Institute's tribute to Hazlitt in 1987.
ity against the majority?
Q: What's wrong with natural rights theory? only bring opportunities for nasty and litigious types
A: Nothing. I consider myself a consistent cham to exploit the law in other ways.
pion of the kind of rights that are mentioned in the Q: Do you wish more economists were interested
Declaration of Independence and the Bill of Rights. in ethics?
But it is wrong to start with some conception of rights A: We can't expect all economists to be interested
and then try to derive everything else from there. The in the same things. But the tradition of economists
importance of respecting human rights follows from being interested in ethics goes way back and carries
how vital they are to a good society and so to human up to the present. Hume, Smith, Sidgwick, Mill,
happiness. Keynes, Mises all were, as do Hayek, and Buchanan.
I get the impression from libertarian rights theo And ethics does indeed seem to be gaining explicit
rists—like Tibor Machan—that they want to just attention in economics discussion these days. The
posit human rights, perhaps mentioning the nature typical economics journal does not deal with the sub
of the individual human being and his responsibility ject, however, since it is supposed to be on the fron
for his own life. The good guys see rights practically tiers and cannot be concerned with the great bulk of
as ultimates, the bad guys don't, and that's that. Such already accepted doctrine.
theorists must think it somehow demeaning to Q: What role has the mathematization of the
human rights to mount a sustained argument for profession had in pushing aside ethical discussion?
them (which, I think, would necessarily be a utilitar
A: It has played a role in pushing aside the over
ian argument).
laps between economics and ethics, for it isn't obvious
My objection to rights theory, as presented by those how one puts ethics into equations. But I don't want
who want to distinguish themselves from utilitarians, is to condemn mathematics, since doing so would be
the basis on which they enunciate rights. Rothbard's engaging in a particular type of methodology. I don't
rights are peculiarly narrow—to one's body and to prop much admire laying down methodological taboos,
erty. Many "rights" being bandied about nowadays telling your colleagues the wrong and right ways to
amount to claims to all sorts of good things, it being left go about their work.
vague just who has the corresponding obligations to
supply these good things, and why. Q: Are you uncomfortable with Mises's views on
the use of mathematics, that they have a limited use
Furthermore, to invoke rights in a discussion is to in doing history but not in economic theory?
use heavy artillery that impairs peaceful discourse. A
rights advocate may say in effect: Morality requires A: I have always been a bit dismayed at Mises's
adhering to my policy, and anyone who denies the rights stern line against mathematics in economics. How
I have announced is an enemy of morality. And that's can one be so farsighted as to see that nothing good
the end of the discussion. This is not scholarship at its can come out of applying it to economics?
best. In general, I think people should be more modest in
Q: But you want to hold on to a notion of rights. their methodological sermonizing. Just because one
theorist doesn't apply certain methods doesn't mean
A: Not as the very starting point, but—yes—as they should be taboo. Mathematics can be a good way
concepts that arise within the field of ethics. The of conveying some ideas. With some concepts, you have
following definition of rights seems to work in most to keep hammering at them to get them across to your
contexts where the word appears: Rights are entitle students. The idea of maximizing utility under con
ments to behavior on the part of others that are straints should be done with words, graphs, and math
binding on those others with a particularly strong ematics. Three ways are better than one. To really
degree of moral force. Rights to life, liberty, and understand these topics, you've got to go over them
property mean that others are particularly obliged several times while using a variety of techniques.
not to invade our own lives, bodies, freedom, and
possessions. Q: You speak about Austrian taboos, but aren't
there taboos in the mainstream?
Q: But in popular discussion, the terms "rights" is
most often used to mean the opposite of your definition. A: Yes. Plenty of methodological taboos are never
even discussed. Tacit methodologizing is even worse
A: True. Civil rights are valid, but people try to than explicit methodologizing. If people are explicit,
sell contrary policies under its name. The so-called they lay out their message for inspection. An implicit
civil-rights bill currently pending, which increases assumption of the mainstream is that if economic
opportunities for anybody who has a grievance to sue reasoning is to be "rigorous"—meaning worth any
the employer or potential employer, is a bad idea. It attention, I guess—it must appear in a formal model
is disingenuous to deny that such laws tend to estab
of maximization of utility, profit, or present value.
lish de facto quotas. If the best way to protect yourself
from suits is to have the statistically "correct" mix of Q: Is any particular school guilty of this?
groups, you're being prodded to staff your firm that A: The New Classicists are my particular bug
way. Many good intentions vaguely written into law bear. They tell us that we must suppose that markets
are always clearing, that we've got to interpret the we cannot know anything about the future, that the
business cycle as if markets are always clearing, that future is being freely invented—why would they pose
we've got to see unemployment as voluntary with as professors of economics? Why do they set out to do
holding of labor from the market. But this notion anything? Lachmann was a dear man, but his doc
that all markets are clearing, or are close enough to trine was negative and destructive.
clearing so that we are required to do our reasoning as Q: How do you see your own role in the Austrian
if they were clearing, has no more merit than a meth school?
odological precept whose basis hardly gets explicitly
A: I don't know whether I am considered a critic
discussed.
of Austrian economics or not. I have criticized the
I am skeptical about all such postulates. What Austrians' business-cycle theory and their method
postulates are legitimate depends on what you are ological preachments. But I have long had a respect
studying. For example, if you are doing an exercise in ful and sympathetic interest in the school. I first came
microeconomics to find the long-run equilibrium con across some books by Mises in the Oberlin College
sequences for a product's price and output of a speci library shortly after World War II—Omnipotent Gov
fied change in taxes or technology, then it only ernment and Bureaucracy, as I recall. I was im
clutters up the analysis to focus on the transition pressed and learned a lot. In fact, I included some of
from the present state of affairs to the future equilib Mises's insights in my answers on a final exam in an
rium state. We then have no particular reason to be antitrust course. A "C" grade testified to my bad
interested in the disequilibrated markets before judgment on when and how to express my enthusi
prices have fully adjusted. But if we are doing macro asm. Once, while visiting the Princeton University
economics—which is concerned with lapses from full library, before Human Action appeared in English, I
coordination and with what accounts for the greater read parts of its earlier version, Nationalokonomie. I
or lesser degree of lapse—then transitional obstacles had already read Hayek's essays in Individualism and
are the center of the topic. What might be merely a Economic Order. But mostly I was very excited about
fringe complication set aside in a micro analysis Mises's doctrine of calculation under socialism. I gave
moves to center stage in macro. Yet New Classical a faculty seminar on that topic in 1949 when I was
economics dismisses all concern with lapses of coor teaching for one year at Texas A & M. I even thought
dination and the failure of markets to clear. It simply about exploring some related topic for my Ph.D. disser
wipes away the problem. tation.
Q: Are you, then, a methodological pragmatist? Q: Did you ever meet Ludwig von Mises?
A: I am a methodological libertarian. I am not A: Yes, several times. Probably around 1948 or
saying that anything goes, or that whatever one 1949, while a graduate student at Columbia Univer
comes up with is automatically valid. Divine inspira sity, I somehow received or wrangled an invitation to
tion is not as good as looking at the facts. But let visit him in his apartment. Our conversation drifted
people work with whatever method works for them onto the alleged intellectual dishonesty of leftist econ
and fits with their talents and inclinations. After all, omists. At one point I asked, "Professor Mises, are
their work is open for public inspection. their any honest leftists?" He pondered for half a
Q: Donald McCloskey has been persuasive in this minute or so and then replied, in all seriousness, 'Yes:
regard. What do you think of his work? Gottfried Haberler."

A: I agree with him at many points when he is


speaking for himself. I haven't read all the people he
cites—those associated with deconstructionism and
hermeneutics—but my impression is not too favor
able. Hermeneutics was a flash in the pan, but it is
an example of what happens quite often in economics.
Economists will latch onto an idea out of some other
field in hopes of making a splash in their own. They'll
dip into engineering, psychology, or mathematics and
try to make a reputation. This way they can look
catholic and widely read.
Q: And what of your view toward Shackle and
Lachmann, the radical subjectivists?
A: They advanced a kind of subjectivism I reject—
nihilism. I know they don't call it that, but that is the
way it comes across to me. If the extreme subjectivists
like Lachmann and Shackle take themselves seri
Leland B. Yeager
ously—that expectations are totally subjective, that
About a year later I took an extracurricular short ket, is a message that should penetrate the main
course in monetary theory that Mises was offering at stream more fully. And the emphasis on legal institu
New York University. I'm afraid I learned more there tions and their role in the coordination of economic
than in all the lectures at Columbia. I credit Mises— activity is also a fruitful framework for study. Hayek
some might say I should blame him—for my basic often gets credit for these concerns, but the knowl
ideas on monetary economics. edge problem is already implicit, at least, in Mises.
I attended a two-week Volker Fund conference in
The planners don't know how to combine the factors
1955 at which Mises was one of the three main lec
of production, even supposing they know what they
turers. I saw him occasionally after that. In 1979, want to produce. Mises's emphasis on meaningful
after his death, when I was working on my transla markets displays his interest in transmitting this
tion of his Nation, Stoat, und Wirtschaft, I received knowledge through the price system, a point that
some advice from Mrs. Mises at their apartment. Hayek elaborated on.
Q: What themes in Austrian economics do you Q: What about the role of entrepreneurship as a
like?
unique Austrian contribution?
A: It does need to be hammered home, but I think
A: I like the concern with the big picture. The
the mainstream has got the message by now. If they
Austrians have shown how the activities of millions
can find an economist who hasn't yet got it, then
of separate people can be coordinated into a system
Austrians should continue. The problem is that en
that has a semblance of logic and structure even
trepreneurship is an idea that is difficult to model
without a central planner. And I also like the Austrian
concern with institutions. Unlike the mainstream,
formally. So far, anyway, working in this area doesn't
which sometimes gets bogged down in details about
provide much opportunity to display technical ability.
I do think that there has been too much Austrian
decision-making within firms and households, Aus
discussion about whether entrepreneurship is equil
trians are primarily concerned with economy-wide
ibrating or disequilibrating. It is clearly both.
relations among such units.
Q: Any thoughts on the anti-socialist revolution
Q: And what don't you like?
in Eastern Europe?
A: I am not a card-carrying Austrian. I don't like
A: Sure. It overwhelmingly demonstrates that
the way the business-cycle theory gets recited again
attempts at central economic direction do not work.
and again without any new evidence or reasoning. On
The experiments made since 1917 and since 1945
capital theory, I find myself disagreeing with some
have been decisive. The advocates of socialism will no
present-day Austrians. Briefly, my view is that if you
longer come from the ranks of economists. It is no
put together Bohm-Bawerk, Cassel, and Fisher and
longer intellectually respectable. •
make the proper selection and combination of their
doctrines, you have the essence of capital theory. The
interest rate is determined by interaction between
time preference and the productivity of roundabout- r
ness. I don't know why this view should be considered
anti-Austrian. Bohm-Bawerk and Hayek explicitly Austrians Expand Program
recognized both time-preference and productivity. I
don't quite understand how the pure subjectivist or at New York University
pure time-preference theory came to be regarded as
a key part of Austrian doctrine. I only have a hunch. The Austrian Economics program at New
Maybe people thought that since subjectivism is good, York University has announced an ambitious
the more subjectivism the better. publication program. Mario Rizzo and Law
rence White (University of Georgia) will co-
Q: You don't regard Austrian economics as a sep edit "Foundations of the Market Economy,"
arate school within economics?
a series of monographs for Routledge Press.
A: It certainly shouldn't separate itself and take Peter Boettke, Israel Kirzner, and Mario
on the mission of doing battle with the mainstream. Rizzo will serve as general editors for JAI
All of us economists have some ideas we hope to Press's annual publication, Advances in Aus
contribute to our fellow economists. The Austrian trian Economics, which will assemble articles
tradition is distinctive in having a favored set of on a general topic. The first volume will focus
topics and perhaps a method. But Austrians should on the topic "Is Change Possible?" Finally, in
be trying to influence the general understanding of conjunction with New York University Press,
how the economy works. a series titled "The Political Economy of the
Q: What can formal Austrian theory add to the Austrian School" has been launched to gather
body of mainstream thought? papers by Austrians on a topic in economic
A: Emphasis on the dispersion of knowledge in policy. •
society, and the need to transmit it through the mar
Jack Wiseman (1919-1991)
By Peter G. Klein

W i t h the death of Jack Wiseman this January


the Austrian school has lost a distinguished
"fellow traveler." Throughout a long career at the
London School of Economics and the University of
York, and through close associations with the Insti
tute of Economic Affairs in London and the Center for
the Study of Public Choice at Virginia Tech and
George Mason University, Wiseman was a tireless
fighter for subjectivism in economics and a vocal
opponent of positivism, undue sub-specialization,
and the esoteric, technique-oriented character of
modern economic theory. He also represented a living
link with the great "London tradition" of the 1930s
and 1940s, perhaps the last period when distinctively
"Austrian" ideas were playing an active role in the
development of mainstream economics.
Born to a poor family in the English midlands, the
cradle of the industrial revolution, Wiseman pro
ceeded by scholarships through the local secondary
schools and later to the L.S.E., which he entered in
1946 only after a seven-year delay for military ser
vice. At the L.S.E. he joined a truly extraordinary Jack Wiseman
group of thinkers: His first economics class was
taught by William Baumol, then a newly arrived thralled with macroeconomics, growth, and "positive
graduate student; the chairholders in economics were economics" (recall that Hayek himself had mostly
F. A. Hayek, Lionel Robbins, James Meade, T. S. given up economic theory by that time). Wiseman
Ashton, R. G. D. Allen, Edmund Phelps-Brown, F. W continued to pursue his own interests, however, de
Paish, and R. S. Sayers, and also teaching were P. T. veloping his "unknowability thesis": The central con
Bauer, Arnold Plant, and Harold Laski; his personal straint we face is our inability to know the future. It
tutor was Ronald Coase. He would later describe the was also during this period that he collaborated with
department as "the best economists' club in the Alan Peacock on a widely read study on The Growth
world."1 Wiseman concentrated on the "core" subject of Public Expenditure in the United Kingdom.3
area, where he worked closely with Robbins with
plans for an academic career. Wiseman continued lecturing at the L.S.E. until
1964, when he joined Peacock to set up a program
After graduation he secured a temporary lecture in public finance at the newly created University of
ship at L.S.E. in Industry and Trade, and was later York, where he remained until retirement in 1987.
promoted to a full lectureship in Business and Public At York he began to work with Stephen Littlechild,
Finance. It was in these two areas (what would today author of The Fallacy of the Mixed Economy, on a
be called industrial organization and public finance), self-described "subjectivist economics textbook."
that Wiseman published his earliest works: first a Sadly, the project was never completed, though its
1953 Economica article on collectivist economic plan
flavor can be gathered from the delightful essay on
ning—a subject with which, unfortunately, the aca "Crusoe economics" that came out of the project and
demic establishment had mostly lost interest—and appeared in a volume honoring George Shackle. He
then his best-known paper, "The Theory of Public also came to develop a close relationship with James
Utility Pricing: An Empty Box."2 Both of these, and Buchanan, whom he had met at the L.S.E. in 1960,
especially the latter, argued along Austrian lines that and with whom he shared interests in both Shackel-
marginal-cost pricing rules cannot be meaningfully ian subjectivism and the public choice approach to
applied to collective decision-making processes or political theory; as a visitor at Buchanan's Public
public resource allocation, because "cost" and "bene Choice Center he began to sketch an outline of a "new
fit" exist solely in the mind of the individual actor, as political economy," a grand reconstruction of eco
anticipated prior to action though realized only after. nomic science that he continued to develop until his
That is, "marginal social cost" is more than a tricky death.
thing to measure; it is impossible even to define.
Perhaps predictably, the work failed to generate He died of cancer at his home in Yorkshire at the
much interest in the profession, which was then en- age of 71. His friends and colleagues remember him

10
as an unpretentious, practical man, an independent was rewarded not only by income but by the relinquishment ofsuch
chores..." (p. 26). Does this sound familiar to the modern American
thinker and, above all, a great talker. He is at least a
student?
writer whose work deserves to be better known.
2JackWiseman, "Uncertainty, Costs and Collectivist Economic
Pricing," Economica (May 1953); idem, "The Theory of Public Util
*In an autobiographical sketch publishedin his bookof essays ity Price: An Empty Box," Oxford Economic Papers (February
Cost, Choice and Political Economy (London: Edward Elgar, 1957). Both reprinted in James M. Buchanan and G. F. Thirlby,
1989), p. 28. There Wiseman singles out as the source of its eds., L.S.E. Essays on Cost (London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson,
excellence not only the L.S.E. people themselves, but also the 1973), and in Cost, Choice and Political Economy, op. cit.
style of teaching, with its emphasis on student participation.
By contrast, he describes a year spent as a visitor at Berkeley 3Alan T. Peacock and Jack Wiseman, The Growth of Public
in 1962 with surprise for the faculty's lack of interest in Expenditure in the United Kingdom (London: Oxford University
students: "After L.S.E., the [American] system seemed remote Press, [1961] 1967).
and uncaring. The first year of undergraduate study was 4S. C. Littlechild and Jack Wiseman, "Crusoe's Kingdom: Cost,
treated as a 'weeding-out'period in which the dropout rate was Choice and Political Economy," in S. Frowen, ed., Unknowledge
very high. Teaching this group was a chore left largely to and Choice in Economics (London: Macmillan, 1989), reprinted
junior staff, teaching assistants and unwary visitors; seniority in Cost, Choice and Political Economy, op. cit. •

Economics Rankings: Top Ten U.S. Economics Departments

A Survey 1. Chicago 6. Minnesota


2. MIT 7. Yale
3. Princeton 8. UCLA
by Alexander Tabarrok 4. Rochester 9. Stanford
5. Harvard 10. Columbia
"The popular subject of discussion among
economists is not so much economics as Source: John Tschirhart, "Ranking Economics Departments in
economists" (Samuelson 1962). Areas of Expertise," Journal of Economic Education (Spring
1989): 199-222.
Economists do love to rank themselves. There is
Explanation: Tschirhart looked at all departments
no doubt a Freudian explanation for this but that will
offering Ph.D's in the United States. The rankings are
have to await further research. For now the Austrian
based upon; the per capita, total number of standard
Economics Newsletter is pleased to report the long- ized and quality adjusted (by journal) articles published
awaited results. during the period 1975 to 1984.

Top Ten Economists Top Ten Economics Journals


in the U. S.
1. Journal of Political Economy
1. Gary Becker (Chicago) 2. Journal of Financial Economics
3. American Economic Review
2. Henri Theil (Florida)
4. Journal of Monetary Economics
3. Martin Feldstein (Harvard)
5. Journal of Finance
4. Robert Lucas (Chicago) 6. Journal of Economic Literature
5. Robert Barro (Harvard) 7. Econometrica
6. Oliver Williamson (Berkeley) 8. BellJournal of Economics
7. Robert Solow (MIT) 9. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
8. Zvi Griliches (Harvard) 10. Review of Economic Studies
9. Thomas Sargent (Hoover Institution) Source: S. J. Liebowitz and J. P. Palmer,"Assessing the
10. Mancur Olson (Maryland) Relative Impacts of Economics Journals,"Journal of Economic
Literature (March 1984): 77-88.
Source: Marshall Medoff, "The Ranking of Economists,"
Journal of Economic Education (Fall 1989):405-15. Explanation: The rankings are based upon the ci
tations from journals (other than the journal being
Explanation: The rankings here are based upon ranked) in 1980 to articles published during the pe
the total number of citations received in the years riod 1975 to 1979. These citations are weighted in an
1971 to 1985 from a population of all economists in iterative procedure so that a citation from the Journal
the top 125 universities in 1985. Nobel prize win of Financial Economics to the JPE is worth more than a
ners have been excluded from this list (Robert citation from the Review of EconomicStudies to the JPE.
Solow received his Nobel prize after Medoff com The citations are also weighted by the number of char
pleted his article) as are economists over 65 years acters a journal publishes, this controls for the size of
of age. the journal.

11
Top Ten Economics Book Publishers pages and the percent change in cites (this was in
with Comparison to JPE order to measure the extent a department has im
1. University of Chicago Press 0.83 proved or worsened.) Seven of Laband's top ten over
2. Cambridge University Press 0.51 lap with Tschirhart's top ten. After Golden,
3. Brookings Institution 0.47 Carstensen, and Weiner (1987) "corrected" for some
4. Basic Books 0.46 statistical oversights in Laband's study, nine of the
5. Hoover Institution Press 0.37 top ten overlap. However, there are exceptions to this
6. Allen and Unwin 0.31 rule. For example, when all articles are included, not
7. North-Holland 0.26 just those in mainstream journals, Tschirhart finds
8. Harvard University Press 0.24 that George Mason University, which specializes in
9. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich 0.24
public choice and Austrian economics, jumps from a
10. Princeton University Press 0.22
ranking of 31 to that of eight! Tschirhart's rankings
Source: David Laband, "Measuring the Relative Impact of are the most recent and probably the most valuable
Economics Book Publishers and Economics Journals," Journal
of Economic Literature Qune 1990):655-60. because he ranks by area of expertise as well as
general rank.
Explanation: The number in the far right column is
The rankings of books vis-a-vis JPE articles may
the relative impact of publishing a book compared to
be misleading. Articles generate cites because they
publishing a JPE article. For example an economics
book published by the Cambridge University Press in tend to be on current and controversial subjects. But
the study period received only about half as many how many of these articles withstand the test of time?
quality adjusted citations as an article in the JPE. How many make permanent contributions and how
The rankings are based upon the number of cita many are cited merely so that they can be refuted? As
tions in the period 1981 to 1985 to books which were a hypothesis I would suggest that books have more
published (and announced in the Journal of Economic long term impact than articles. This could be tested
Literature) in 1980. The citations were weighted accord by examining the relative impact of books published
ing to the rankings established by Liebowitz and 50 years ago and articles published 50 years ago.
Palmer. Textbooks and directories are excluded.

Citations to Austrian Economists


Comments

The numbers reveal one thing for certain—the 1. F.A.Hayek 280


2. Israel Kirzner 47
University of Chicago is by far the most influential
3. Carl Menger 46
and powerful university in the economics profession. 4. W. H. Hutt 29
Chicago has the number one economist, department, 5. Lawrence White 27
journal, and book publisher! The only sign of its 6. Murray Rothbard 24
weakness is in the number of top, young (40 or under) 7. Don Lavoie 23
economists. According to Medoff (1989, p. 413, Table 8. Gerald O'Driscoll 20
3) Chicago has none of the top ten young economists. 9. Ludwig Lachmann 14

MIT leads in this regard with four and Princeton 10. Ludwig von Mises 12

follows closely with three. However, this is not likely to Source: Social Science Citation Index, 1989.
be reflected in Chicago's (statistical) ranking very Explanation: This list includes only 1989 citations.
much. This is because of the immense importance of The sample from which the list was taken was small and
University of Chicago journals. Graves, Marchand chosen on the basis of what I consider to be general
and Thompson (1982) found that two-thirds of the opinion among Austrians about who is an Austrian.
articles published by University of Chicago econo
mists were in three journals published by the Univer
sity of Chicago (Medoff, p. 406). This wouldn't matter
except for the fact that authors from the same school Auburn, George Mason, and
New York Universities
as the editor tend to receive more pages than unaffil
iated authors (Laband, 1985a). Parochialism may Auburn University has been ascending the ranks
therefore effect rankings at least in the short run of economics departments. Its relatively young de
(Stigler and Friedland, 1975). partment ranks third among departments with an
It is interesting to note that the ranking of the top Austrian orientation. According to the various rank
10 departments is fairly invariant to the measures ings, its publishing strengths are in the areas of
used. Laband (1985b) in the Southern Economics history of thought, labor economics, and microeco
Journal ranked the top 50 departments according to nomics. It is difficult to assess George Mason Univer
a composite score of pages published per faculty mem sity over time because it is largely a creature ofrecent
ber, cites per article published, and graduate student imports from other schools. Some early rankings do
placement plus a measure of graduate publication. not have George Mason listed, but some recent rank
He also included the percent change in published ings place George Mason in the top 20. According to

12
the various rankings, its strengths are in the areas of
public finance, welfare economics, and natural re
source economics. The New York University depart
ment has consistently ranked in or near the top 20.
It ranks high in a number of fields including micro-
and macroeconomics, welfare theory, and interna
tional economics.
Now that we know the top ten economists, the
best departments, the most prestigious journals, the
most influential book publishers, and the ranking of
Austrians in the profession there is only one impor
tant question left: Who do you think is going to win
the Nobel prize this year?

Golden, J., Carstensen, F. and P. Weiner. 1987. "An Evaluation


of 50 Ranked Economics Departments: Comment." Modern Eco
nomics Journal 54: 212-15.
Graves, P., Marchand, J. and R. Thompson. 1982. "Economics
Departmental Rankings: Research Incentives, Constraints, and
Efficiency." American Economic Review 72: 1131-41. From left to right, top: Yuri Maltsev,
Laband, D. 1985a. "Publishing Favoritism: A Critique of Depart Hans-Hermann Hoppc, Larry Sechrest.
ment Rankings Based on Quantitative Publishing Performance." Second row: William Breit, John McC-
Southern Economic Journal 52: 510-15.
allie, and Roger Garrison. Third row:
Laband, D. 1985b. "An Evaluation of 50 Ranked Economics
Murray Rothbard.
Departments—By Quantity and Quality of Faculty Publications
and Graduate Student Placement and Research Success." Southern
Economic Journal (July): 216-40.
Medoff, M. 1989. "The Ranking of Economists." Journal of Eco cause of the additional uncertainty it creates for indi
nomic Education (Fall 1989): 405-15.
viduals making long-run decisions.
Samuelson, Paul. 1962. "Economists and the History of Ideas"
American Economic Review (March): 1. Larry Sechrest of Sul Ross State University
Stigler, G. and C. Friedland. 1975. "The Citations Practices of applied Austrian methodology to central bank pol
Doctorates in Economics." Journal of Political Economy 83: 477- icy in "The Impossibility of Rational Monetary Pol
507. •
icy." Parth Shah of the University of Michigan,
Dearborn investigated the role of the Hong Kong
Convention government and "free banking" institutions to de
termine the source of stability of the Hong Kong
dollar.
Austrians Convene at Southwest
John McCallie of the University of Alabama, Bir
Social Science Association mingham presented his historical investigation of
deposit insurance in 'The Crisis in Government De
Two sessions on Austrian economics were organ
posit Insurance." He found that economists warned
ized by Mark Thornton of Auburn University
against government deposit insurance when it was
for the 1991 Southwest Social Science Association
first proposed, predicting in many cases the problems
which took place in San Antonio, Texas, March 27-30.
facing deposit insurance today. Murray Rothbard of
The sessions were on the theme of "Global Change: the University of Nevada, Las Vegas provided com
Investigation, Understanding, Survival." The first ses ments on McCallie's paper. The non-Austrian com
sion, "Financial Crisis in Capitalism," examined the mentators of the session were in general agreement
impact of public sector institutions on the recent perfor with the findings presented.
mance of markets. Roger Garrison of Auburn Univer
The second session, "The Downfall of Commu
sity examined the impact of government deficits on
the economy in his paper, "Public Sector Borrowing nism," was a joint session of economics, international
and Private Sector Performance." Garrison noted
studies, and political science, and was one of the
best-attended sessions of the convention.
that mainstream economists have not been able to
find the effect of deficits on the economy because they Hans-Hermann Hoppe of the University of Ne
typically examine only one possible effect such as vada, Las Vegas presented his "Economic and Socio
inflation or "crowding out." He said that deficits do logical Analysis of the Unification of Germany," and
not cause one particular effect, but many, and be was commented on by Larry Sechrest. Yuri Maltsev
cause of changes in policy and political regimes the of the U.S. Institute of Peace presented "The Political
relative impact of deficits changes over time. This and Economic Institutions of the Soviet Union in
actually makes deficits much worse than taxes be- Transition." Commentator Mark Thornton noted that

13
Maltsev presented an accurate but bleak picture of Las Vegas set the tone of the conference by returning
the future in the Soviet Union. to, and expanding upon, issues he raised in his classic
Rothbard's paper "How and How Not to Desocial- 1970 essay "Freedom, Inequality, Primitivism, and
ize," provided a set of guidelines on how the process the Division of Labor." The fact of human inequality
of desocialization could be successful and how it is not only all pervasive; it is necessarily implied in
could result in failure. Former President on the the very idea of the division of labor. Yet since it
Southwest Social Science Association, William became clear to the Left that the economic side of
Breit of Trinity University began his comments on socialism was destined to fail, it has pursued a war
Rothbard's paper: for forced equality through unfairly privileging un-
derachievers and handicapping successful people.
I am in agreement with much of what Professor He noted that it is nearly impossible to caricature
Rothbard had to say. My words of agreement must this movement because of the ever/expanding list of
sound like strange music to Rothbard's ears be "victims" and the increasingly absurd justification
cause he has for so long been in a tiny minority in for their "claims." He attempted, however, to pro
holding his opinions on most economic issues. He vide a flavor of the absurdity by insisting on affir
is quite right in asserting that for the last half-cen
mative action for short people, a victim group of
tury almpst all western economists believed that
which Rothbard himself is a distinguished member.
there is no calculation problem under socialism
and that the Soviet economy was successful and Llewellyn H. Rockwell, Jr., president of the Lud
would eventually overtake the United States. Of wig von Mises Institute, presented an intellectual
course Murray Rothbard's was almost a lone voice survey of the concept of envy. Although this human
in the wilderness saying nay to this orthodoxy. As emotion has been consistently condemned by great
you can discern from his paper he is not quite a thinkers since the Ancients, it is rarely if ever men
shrinking ego. And yet he has resisted the tempta
tioned in modern public policy discourse, much less
tion to say, "I told you so" even though he would
have been fully justified in saying it. No one could
thoroughly explored. Rockwell theorized that it is
have taken more satisfaction than Rothbard in actually a prime motivation behind the economic and
having lived to see the collapse of communism and social collectivism in the West. For example, why is
socialism around the world. Now, at least on this the welfare state still glorified even though it has
question, Rothbard is in the majority. There are failed to do what it is allegedly supposed to do? The
few people anywhere anymore who hold the view reason is that welfarism actually succeeds in one
that central direction is an efficient way to organ area: institutionalizing envy. That is, it may not help
ized economic activity. the poor, but it hurts the rich, which, in an envious
society, is the point after all.
Austrians have been active at the Southwest So
cial Science Association since at least 1984. These two Joe Salerno of Pace University provided a blister
sessions testify that Austrian economists have a ing attack on the transfer state, snowing how the pur
strong and growing presence in the Association and suit of equality is an ellusive goal, and that the attempt
in the economics profession as a whole. MT • to reach it can cause immeasurable destruction to social
cooperation. He elaborated on Rothbard's thesis that
income transfers are not welfare enhancing and showed
Conference that they always diminish welfare. He put his theory in
the context of work he is doing on the connection be
u
Egalitarianism and the tween the market economy as a coordinating agent and
the "social appraisement process" of economic calcula
Free Society" tion. David Fand of George Mason University's Public
Choice Center discussed other forms of pernicious re
T o combat the growth of "politically correct" distribution.
thinking on campus, and in public discourse, Jeffrey Herbener of Washington and Jefferson
the Mises Institute recently sponsored a scholarly College traced the idea of egalitarianism from the
conference on "Egalitarianism and the Free Society." ancient philosophers, to the economic tradition of the
It explored the relationship between the state-en scholastics, to the modern Austrians, to show that the
forced ideal of perfect equality and its incompatibility subjectivist/free-market tradition has relied on the
with true human liberty. idea of inequality of personal attributes to under
Held in Princeton, New Jersey, from April 11-13, stand how the liberal social order is most conducive
1991, it featured some of the top economists, journal to individual creative potential.
ists, sociologists, and philosophers associated with Paul Gottfried of Elizabethtown College took on
the Austrian school of economics. The speakers pre the nebulous ideas of modern democratic theory and
sented ideas on some of the most controversial aca linked them to the leftist desire for social leveling. He
demic and political trends of our time. argued that not only is democracy not required for the
Murray Rothbard of the University of Nevada, preservation of individual liberty, but that democracy

14
is often the enemy of liberty and of private property. that allows individual talents, always distributed un
Democracy, especially the pursuit of "global democ equally, to be put to their best use. Mises thought that
racy," creates a social calculus of interventionism of the concept of equality is relevant only in terms of
which the primary beneficiaries are interest groups. how the law ought to treat individuals. Gordon fur
He argued that the democratic tradition runs counter ther showed that Mises's anti-egalitarianism is
to the rule of law, making it antithetical to the market rooted in a more general philosophical tradition that
and the constitutional republic. stood against all attempts to uproot the basis of social
Thomas DiLorenzo of the University of Tennes patterns consistent with liberty.
see, Chattanooga argued against the wave of legis Joe Sobran, critic-at-large for National Review,
lation presumably designed to help disabled people, explained how modern notions of civil rights are in
the newest victim group that has achieved official complete contradiction to an older version of rights.
status in Washington. He noted that there are al Modern civil rights are group-directed privileges to
ready 43 different categories of disabilities that coerce private parties and gain access to public funds.
make one eligible for special treatment. The irony Moreover, he argued, this difference is widely under
is that disability legislation—especially the stood by the public, which supports civil rights in the
American's with Disability Act of 1990—ends up abstract, but resents the pressure group tactics of
hurting the most severely disabled persons. It man seizing more legal favors from the state.
dates that employers always accommodate disabil
ities; on the margin, employers will choose the least Thomas Fleming, editor of Chronicles magazine,
disabled to save the expense. Like other groups that spoke on how the premise of equality plays itself out
seek victim status, official legal privilege will set in the world of education. The egalitarian ideology
up barriers to authentic participation in the division has led to the collapse of the public school, the
of labor.
bullying of private schools, and the radical central
ization of education. As an alternative, he sug
Samuel Francis, award-winning editorial writer gested a radical privatization of education and an
for the Washington Times, argued that egalitarian elimination of laws restricting the manner in which
ism in politics is a boon for the managerial elite class private schools conduct their affairs. Barring that,
that runs the bureaucratic State. Far from being an he said, all plans for education reform ought to be
independent unit, this elite group has a symbiotic judged on one criterion: Do they begin to decentral
relationship with corporate business and elected ize the control of education, or do they further
leaders. Since the New Deal, this elite has superim centralize it? He judged President Bush's education
posed its -vision of society on top of traditional pat reform plan—with its promotion of means-tested
terns of social and economic relations. His strategy vouchers and a national curriculum—as going ex
for unseating this managerial elite from its position actly in the wrong direction.
of power is both academic and activist. First, the
governing ideology of egalitarianism must be refuted In honor of the conference, the Mises Institute has
and, second, the elite's designs for society must be republished Rothbard's 1970 essay on egalitarianism,
exposed. but with an extensive new introduction.

Steven Goldberg of the City College of New York Some of the papers from the conference will be
took on the difficult question of equality between the released during the next six months. All will be
sexes, which has been a governing ideal in social published in a volume by Kluwer Academic Publish
legislation for decades. The premise most widely ad ers. J AT •
vanced to support the egalitarian sexual vision is that
it is an arbitrary social choice whether men or women
hold dominant positions in government and business.
Goldberg presented an empirical argument that, con
trary to sociology texts, history presents no example
of a non-patriarchal society. Every supposed example
to the contrary ends up being completely mistaken.
The fact of patriarchy's all pervasiveness should cau
tion social engineers about the limits to legislative
attempts toward sexual leveling.
David Gordon of the Ludwig von Mises Institute
presented Mises's own views about equality and in
equality, showing that egalitarianism was antitheti
cal to his social and economic system. Mises's
Speakers (I to r) Thomas DiLorenzo, Jeffrey Herbener, Joe
world-view, in fact, relied on individual differences Salerno and Sam Francis answer questionsfrom theaudi
working themselves out through the market process. enceat the closing session of the 'Egalitarianismand the
Efficiency can be best defined in terms of a system FreeSociety"conference in April.

15
Freedom, Inequality, Primitivism,
and the Division of Labor
Murray N. Rothbard
The Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1991

H irst published in 1970, Murray Rothbard's pre-


•*- scient essay "Freedom, Inequality, Primitivism,
and the Division of Labor" has just been reprinted by
the Ludwig von Mises Institute in a handsome mono
graph, complete with a new introduction by the au
thor. In this important essay, Rothbard demonstrates
Through the division of labor each man specializes in
his remarkable ability to transcend traditional cate
the tasks at which he is best. "The philosopher, the
gories, defy ordinary analysis, and integrate econom
scientist, the builder, the merchant—none could de
ics, ethics, and sociology into a powerful system of
velop these skills or functions if he had had no scope
social thought.
for specialization ... no individual who does not live
Many so-called free-market economists "defend" in a society enjoying a wide range of division of labor
inequality on the grounds that it is necessary to can possibly employ his powers to the fullest." To
provide incentives that further economic growth and employ one's powers to the fullest in the field of one's
wealth creation. Milton Friedman tries to appease choice is more than an instrumental virtue; it's a key
egalitarians on these grounds in Capitalism, and element to being fully human. "Personality," as Lud
Freedom. Friedman goes so far as to argue that much wig von Mises puts it, "has been acquired in the
of the inequality in a capitalist society is really the course of the evolution of society. What scope is there
result of "true equality." Paying higher wages for for the individual human being—diverse in talents,
more difficult jobs, for example, is required so that thoughts, goals, and desires—in a primitive and stag
the total return on work is truly equal. Similarly the nant society, in which son follows father in back-
inequality in wealth created when some take on en breaking drudgery interrupted only by the
trepreneurial risks with potentially high payoffs is remorseless change of seasons?"
really the result of everyone's equal right to buy Rothbard's tribute to inequality is matched by
lottery tickets. And don't forget, Friedman concludes, devastating attacks on the New (now old) Left, par
that government intervention in the economy creates ticipatory democracy (an underdeveloped area in lib
a lot of inequality. ertarian thought), and most importantly
Now, Friedman is one the great economists of our romanticism and the mythology of the noble savage.
time and he has done much to make classical liberal He couldn't have been more predictive on the domi
ideas respectable in our universities. But this blatant nant themes in our contemporary political culture.
pandering to egalitarianism is a sorry spot on his A great deal could be said about Rothbard's intro
record. It is a great shame that he chooses to accept duction alone. It is a tantalizing glimpse of the devel
the premise of his enemies—that equality is a social opment of his thought since he wrote the essay.
norm worth striving for—in order to argue for capi Several new developments are discussed, such as
talism. If egalitarian social leveling is the goal, after group quotas. Particularly interesting is Rothbard's
all, capitalism cannot compete with the alternatives. revised understanding of Adam Smith and the divi
Rothbard, in contrast, takes the egalitarians head sion of labor, and the roots of romanticism. Rothard
on: He revels in the inequalities of capitalism and now finds Smith's contributions to be misleading and
glorifies them. Of what value would freedom be, he not as seminal as he once thought, and the issue of
asks, if men were all the same? "The glory of the romanticism he now believes should be placed into
human race is the uniqueness of each individual, the the wider context of theology.
fact that every person, though similar in many ways Freedom, Inequality, Priuitiuism, and the Divi
to others, possesses completely individuated person sion of Labor is powerful and fascinating reading. It
ality of his own." The uniqueness of each individual contains many ideas which deserve wider audience
is one of the great arguments in favor of freedom. and a bigger debate; hopefully this new monograph
And it is one of the great benefits of capitalism, will stimulate that debate. ATT •
the social system created when men are left free, that The book is available to full-time students for no
it allows men to extend and amplify their differences. charge (please enclose a copy of your student ID).

Copyright © 1991 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn University, Auburn, Alabama 36849, (205) 844-2500. Volume 12, Number3.
Editor: Mark Thornton (Auburn University). Associate Editor: Jeffrey A. Tucker (George Mason University). Assistant Editor: Peter G.
Klein(UniversityofCalifornia,Berkeley). Correspondents: Amy Marie Marshall (NotreDame University);SofiaBump, Richard R. Hite,
and Alexander Tabarrok (George Mason University); James P. Philbin (UNLV). Managing Editor: Judith F. Thommesen.

16

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen