Sie sind auf Seite 1von 3

Research Briefs

IN ECONOMIC POLICY

April 1, 2020 | Number 208

The Consumption Response to


Trade Shocks
Evidence from the U.S.-China Trade War

W
By Michael E. Waugh, New York University
hat are the distributional impacts The research design is simple: I exploit variation in a
of trade shocks? Evidence suggests county’s exposure to Chinese retaliatory tariffs on U.S. prod-
that trade has had important distri- ucts between 2017 and 2018 and correlate it with changes in
butional effects on the labor market. consumption at the county level. The focus on Chinese tar-
From a welfare perspective, how- iffs on U.S. products stems from a desire to measure a trade-
ever, labor market outcomes may not reflect how economic induced change in labor income/production opportunities;
welfare is allocated among those who are differentially im- for example, soybean farmers in Iowa may lose the ability to
pacted by trade. Abrupt changes in trade policy will have dif- sell their product due to Chinese retaliation. Measuring con-
ferent welfare consequences depending on the opportunities sumption at the microeconomic level is, in general, difficult.
households have to adjust to these shocks. One solution to My approach to measuring consumption is to use a unique
these issues is to study how consumption responds to trade data set with the universe of new auto sales at the U.S. county
shocks and learn about households’ ability to adjust to them. level, at a monthly frequency, over the period 2017–2018.
My research moves beyond the labor market and provides Results using data up to January 2019 show that changes
new evidence on the consumption effects of trade shocks. I in U.S.-China trade policy had large effects on consumption.
exploit changes in Chinese trade policy toward the United Visual and simple comparisons of means show that auto sales
States between 2017 and 2018 and study how a measure of growth is about 2.5 percentage points lower in high-tariff
consumption—new auto sales—responds to these trade counties relative to low-tariff counties (see Figure 1) after the
shocks. Both visually and through formal econometric speci- start of the trade war in July 2018. In my most basic econo-
fications, I find that changes in trade policy had large effects metric specification, I find the elasticity of consumption
on consumption, with high-tariff counties experiencing at growth to tariffs to be around −1—that is, one percentage
least a 3.8 percentage point decline in new auto sales growth point increase in a county’s exposure to Chinese retaliatory
relative to low-tariff counties. tariffs leads to a 1 percentage point decrease in auto sales

Editor, Jeffrey Miron, Harvard University and Cato Institute


2
Figure 1
U.S. county-level auto sales and Chinese retaliatory tariffs
0.03
New auto sales compared between high- and low-tariff

0.02
counties, year-over-year log difference

August to September 2018


0.01
China imposes second and third
phases of retaliatory tariffs
0

-0.01

-0.02

-0.03 April 2018 nited States July 2018 China


announces intention to announces first phase
-0.04 impose 301 tariffs on China of retaliatory tariffs

-0.05
81

81

81

81

81

81

81

81

81

81

81

81

91
02

02

02

02

02

02

02

02

02

02

02

02

02
yr

yr

hc

lir

ya

en

ylu

ts

re

re

re

y
e

r
a

au
pA

ug

bm

bo

bm

bm
M
ra

uJ

J
un

ur

na
M

uA

tc
be

et

ev

ec
aJ

J
pe

oN

eD
F

Difference between top and bottom quartile of county-level Chinese tariff change Average pre- and posttariff increase
Source: Author's calculations.

growth. In terms of magnitudes, this elasticity implies a near- empirical evidence that measures the labor-market-induced
ly 3.8 percentage point decline in auto sales growth for coun- consumption effects of trade. Evidence on the response of
ties in the upper quartile of the tariff distribution relative to consumption is important for evaluating the consequences
counties in the lower quartile. Under certain assumptions, of and appropriate policy responses to trade exposure for
these estimates imply a decrease in aggregate consumption the following reason: The consumption response reveals
of up to $54 billion. While modest in aggregate, this effect the extent to which households can adjust to trade shocks.
is concentrated with high-tariff counties experiencing a de- For example, if consumption does not change much—even
crease in aggregate consumption of up to $1,600 per worker. though trade negatively affects the labor market—this sug-
I connect the decline in consumption with exports and gests that these shocks are insurable and that the distri-
employment growth. Using the same empirical strategy, I butional consequences and welfare losses associated with
find that Chinese retaliatory tariffs reduced a county’s to- exposure to trade are small. In contrast, if consumption
tal exports and negatively affected the labor market, espe- changes a lot, this suggests that the labor market conse-
cially so for segments of the labor market that are the most quences are passing through to consumption and that there
sensitive to trade. In particular, I estimate a 1.7 percentage are important distributional consequences for welfare asso-
point decline in goods-producing employment growth for ciated with trade. My main result is more consistent with
high-tariff counties relative to low-tariff counties. This evi- the latter interpretation: Chinese retaliation is leading to
dence suggests that the decline in consumption is related to welfare losses.
the negative labor market consequences caused by Chinese A second motivation is simply to understand the eco-
retal­iatory tariffs. nomic consequences of the U.S.-China trade war. A unique
What motivates my research is the desire to measure feature of the data used is the combination of geographic
how trade-induced changes in labor income or production detail and high frequency. Given the many abrupt chang-
opportunities feed into consumption. While prior work has es in policy (and announced policy), high-frequency data
traditionally focused on labor market outcomes, there is no provide a unique perspective on how communities and
3

households are quickly reacting to these changes. The geo- mechanism—reduced consumption in response to Chinese
graphic and high-frequency nature of my paper comple- retaliation—is as large as the aggregate effects.
ments related analyses of the U.S.-China trade war that
study the aggregate effects of tariffs on U.S. imports and
prices of goods from China. I focus on a different mecha- NOTE:
nism: how Chinese tariffs on U.S. exports affect consump- This research brief is based on Michael E. Waugh, “The Con-
tion, depending on changes in a county’s exposure to the sumption Response to Trade Shocks: Evidence from the U.S.-
retaliation. While the focus is on these distributional issues, China Trade War,” NBER Working Paper no. 26353, October
a simple back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests that this 2019, http://www.nber.org/papers/w26353.

The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and should not be attributed to the Cato Institute, its
trustees, its Sponsors, or any other person or organization. Nothing in this paper should be construed as an attempt to
aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Congress. Copyright © 2020 Cato Institute. This work by Cato Institute is
licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 International License.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen