Sie sind auf Seite 1von 2

september 25, 2010

Jobless Growth
The years of rapid economic growth have been years of jobless growth; does the government care?

T
he latest National Sample Survey (NSS) estimates of em- Eleventh Plan, has not yielded any results with the 2007-08
ployment and unemployment in the country indicate that estimates showing almost no non-farm employment diversifica-
in an overall complex employment picture the rate of job tion compared to 2004-05.
creation during the years of rapid growth has been poor. The These trends are also confirmed by the daily status measure of
estimates in the recently released NSS report on the 64th round employment – which better reflects the extent of employment and
(2007-08) are the first ones after the UPA government took over in unemployment from day to day – that show that the person days
2004 and the first such numbers after the last quinquennial of employment in rural areas declined from 93.8 billion person
round of 2004-05. The 2004-05 NSS survey had suggested that 12 days in 2004-05 to 92.9 billion person days in 2007-08. This de-
million jobs had been created every year or a growth of 2.85% a cline in person days of employment would have been far greater
year between 1999-2000 and 2004-05, which even exceeded the had it not been for the National Rural Employment Guarantee
growth rate of the population. It was this high growth in employ- Scheme (NREGS). The employment created by public works (in-
ment which was reflected in the government’s first “Annual Re- cluding the NREGS) increased from 221 million person days in 2004-
port on Employment” released last July, when it credited itself 05 to 939 million person days in 2007-08. While these estimates do
with creating enough jobs in the economy. However, the results suggest a serious problem in job creation, they also suggest a
of the 64th round not only suggest that the high GDP growth dur- need for careful analysis of the presumed linkage between eco-
ing the 2004-07 period failed to create enough jobs, they also con- nomic growth and employment creation. Seen in conjunction with
firm the earlier consensus that the high growth of employment the very high employment creation during 1999-2005, a large
during 1999-2005 was essentially distress-driven and a result of part of these fluctuations is because of the way women partici-
push factors operating due to the agrarian crisis and a decelera- pate in the labour force. It is clear that a major part of the high
tion in real wage growth. growth rate in employment between 1999-2000 and 2004-05 as
The latest NSS results show that the total employment created, well as subsequent jobless growth is a result of the “income
according to the usual status, between 2005 and 2008 was only effect”. What seems to have happened is that a large majority of
2.4 million, which was just 0.8 million per year or a mere fraction women workers moved into the labour force during 1999-2005
of the 12 million created per year between 1999-2000 and 2004-05. and looked for work outside the home due to the agrarian crisis and
The total number of workers increased from 457.9 million in distress in rural areas. And it is these women workers who have
2004-05 to 460.2 million in 2007-08, a growth rate of just 0.17% moved back into their homes as soon as the situation improved
per year as against the 2.85% per year growth rate achieved because of higher agricultural productivity between 2004-05 and
between 1999-2000 and 2004-05. This is the lowest rate of em- 2007-08. This was also aided by increased incomes due to pro-
ployment generation in the last three decades, even lower than grammes such as the NREGS and the consequent increase in wage
the previous spell of jobless growth of 1993-2000 when employ- rates. The growth in wage rates for casual workers which deceler-
ment increased by less than 1% per year. ated to less than 1% per annum during 1999-2005 shows an increase
What has happened and in which category has employment of more than 4% per annum during 2004-07.
been created? A detailed examination of the trends indicates Even discounting the income effect and the subsequent decline
that while employment generation decelerated considerably in in the size of the female workforce, the aggregate picture does
urban areas, increasing by only 4.4 million between 2005 and confirm apprehensions that economic growth between 2004-05
2008, it actually declined by two million in rural areas. But in and 2007-08 has failed to create enough jobs in the economy.
both rural and urban areas, the decline was largely in the female Not only has male employment growth remained sluggish,
workforce. Overall, employment of males increased by 5.2 million growing at 1.66% per annum, marginally better than during the
per year but declined by 4.4 million per year for females. Sectoral previous episode of jobless growth in the 1990s, it shows almost
trends also suggest that the trend of non-farm diversification no non-farm diversification. The other worrying signal is the
in employment in rural areas, which was also the focus of the slow pace of employment creation in the sectors that are driving
Economic & Political Weekly  EPW   september 25, 2010  vol xlv no 39 7
EDITORIALS

GDP growth. While aggregate employment in the primary sector But more than the issue of employment estimates, the lack of
declined in absolute terms, the growth rate of employment in employment generation in the first three years of the UPA government
the secondary sector and services was only 1% per annum. is a serious question mark on its commitment to inclusive growth.
The NSS numbers are nowhere close to the claims of employ- Available evidence also points to an increasing inequality in in-
ment creation made in the Mid-Term Appraisal of the Eleventh comes and opportunities. Not only has the intersectoral productivity
Plan of the Planning Commission. These also betray the tall gap widened, the share of wages in value added has continued to
claims made by the Economic Advisory Council of the Prime show a decline with that of profits rising. The 64th round of the
Minister which said a few years ago that a growth rate of NSS also suggests a widening of the wage gap between the skilled
9-10% would be sufficient to absorb the annual addition of and unskilled labour force at a faster rate than before. Clearly,
around 12 million to the labour force purely as a result of the the challenge of decent employment creation will prove to be a
demographic dividend. stumbling block in realising any measure of inclusive growth.

Compulsory Licensing of Pharmaceutical Patents


It is scandalous that India is yet to issue a single compulsory licence for a drug after the 2005 amendment.

F
ive years have gone by since the reintroduction of the Declaration and has put up a Discussion Paper on “Compulsory
product patent regime for pharmaceuticals and it is time Licensing of Patents” on the web site of the Department of Industrial
public policy reckoned with the implications of local firms Policy and Promotion of the Ministry of Commerce and Industry,
being debarred from producing and selling a patented drug even soliciting views/suggestions of the public by 30 September 2010.
if they develop the processes of manufacturing the same, unless The paper highlights the fact that “No CLs have been issued in India
they are granted a compulsory licence (CL). The latter is a right under the amended Patents Act”, this despite the fact that “65%
granted by the government that allows parties other than the of the Indian population still lacks access to essential medicines”.
patent holder to produce and sell a patented product or use a pat- The paper draws the attention of the readers to two significant
ented process, without the consent of the patent holder. Even the cross-border acquisitions –Ranbaxy Laboratories by the Japanese
Government of the United Kingdom, where neoliberalism was transnational Daiichi Sankyo and Piramal Health Care by the US
first conceived, takes advantage of CLs in order to reduce costs in transnational Abbot Laboratories, both of which are in the list of
the National Health Service, but the Government of India, which the top 10 pharmaceutical companies operating in India. The
can also avail of CLs for non-commercial purposes, for example, authors of the paper are concerned that “If large Indian generic
to authorise the production of patented medicines for free or sub- companies with the capability to manufacture drugs based upon
sidised distribution in government hospitals, has not done so. a CL ... are themselves taken over, then the regime of cheap and
The interests of the transnational pharmaceutical companies effective drugs may be threatened...” The paper goes on to discuss
holding the patents seem more important than the public interest. what it calls the “flexibilities” incorporated in the Patents Act, 1970
Indeed, in the aftermath of the “Doha Declaration on the TRIPS as amended in 2005 in its Chapter XVI entitled “Working of Patents,
[Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights] Agree- Compulsory Licences and Revocation”, which deals with the issue of
ment and Public Health” of November 2001, a number of coun- CLs. We need not go over this ground, but a few comments are
tries have issued CLs, some of them in the context of the HIV/AIDS called for. Why cannot the government put in place a CL system
crisis. For instance, Brazil, Ecuador, Kenya, Malaysia, South Africa, which is simple and easy to administer and implement? Has the
and Thailand have issued CLs for anti-HIV/AIDS drugs. India has government really taken full advantage of all the “flexibilities”
around 25 lakh persons suffering from HIV/AIDS, but only 12% of that the TRIPS Agreement post-the-Doha-Declaration provides?
them are being treated. The first generation drugs are now less What are of practical importance are the grounds for grant of a CL
effective, and it is time they are all administered the second and and the procedure. The grounds of “reasonable requirements of the
third generation drugs. The National AIDS Control Organisation can public” or “reasonably affordable price” can be legally challenged
distribute these patented drugs to many more of those affected if and such a process can be lengthy and its outcome uncertain. So
the government takes advantage of CLs for non-commercial use. such grounds need to be clearly and unambiguously elaborated
(Of course, a CL can also be granted for commercial purposes upon. As regards the question of a “reasonably affordable price”,
upon a potential licensee not being able to obtain a voluntary the discussion paper has some suggestions, among which are the
licence on reasonable terms and within a definite time frame.) very reasonable guidelines of the Japanese Patent Office.
Surprisingly, it is still not sufficiently clear, though there should What then seems to be holding back the government from tak-
have been no ambiguity on this count after the Doha Declaration ing advantage of the instrument of the CL in the public interest?
(mentioned above), that “Each member has the right to grant com- Frankly, the government seems more bothered about the interests
pulsory licences and the freedom to determine the grounds upon of the large transnational pharmaceutical companies. We are
which such licences are granted”. The government now seems to reminded of the top priority the then Indian Prime Minister Atal
be waking up to the implications of this Section 5(b) of the Doha Behari Vajpayee gave to resolving the issue of “data exclusivity”
8 september 25, 2010  vol xlv no 39  EPW   Economic & Political Weekly

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen