Sie sind auf Seite 1von 13

Corruption in Asian Countries: Can It Be Minimized?

Jon S. T. Quah

Public Administration Review, Vol. 59, No. 6. (Nov. - Dec., 1999), pp. 483-494.

Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-3352%28199911%2F12%2959%3A6%3C483%3ACIACCI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-W

Public Administration Review is currently published by American Society for Public Administration.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained
prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in
the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/journals/aspa.html.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is an independent not-for-profit organization dedicated to and preserving a digital archive of scholarly journals. For
more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

http://www.jstor.org
Thu Apr 19 03:03:46 2007
Three decades ago, Gunnar Myrdal (1968,
938-939) identified the taboo on research on
South Asian corruption as one of the factors
inhibiting the research of his book, Asian
Drama. However, this taboo no longer exists,
judging from the increasing amount of research
on corruption in Asian countries in recent
years. According to the Far Eastern Economic
Review, corruption was the biggest story of
1996, the Year of the Rat, as a great deal of
Jon S. T Quah, National University of Singapore
"newsprint and television time was devoted to
reports and discussions on corruption in gov-
Can corruption be combatted? Yes, but only under certain cir- ernment" (Ghosh et al., 1997, 18). Further-
cumstances! That appears to be the experienceo f h i a n countries more, the financial crises in Thailand, South
where corruption is ubiquitous with the exception of Singapore- Korea, Malaysia, and Indonesia in 1997 have
a country thatproved to be the only success story with a strong highlighted the problems of corruption, crony-
political leadership and betterpay scales. Can this experience be ism, and nepotism on one hand, and the need
replicated? for more accountability and transparency in
government and banking operations in these
countries on the other hand.
Why is corruption such a serious problem in
Asian countries? Is it possible to control or to
minimize corruption in these countries? This
paper contends that the extent of corruption in
Asian (and other) countries depends on two fac-
tors: (1) the nature of the causes of corruption
in these countries; and (2) the degree of effec-
tiveness of the measures initiated by political
leaders to combat corruption. In order to curb
corruption in Asian countries, the causes of cor-
ruption must first be correctly diagnosed so that
political leaders can take appropriate action to
minimize, if not eliminate, such causes. Asian
countries like Singapore and Hong Kong,
which observe this logic of corruption control,
are more successful in combatting corruption
than other countries (Quah, 1995).

Public Administration Review NovemberlDecember 1999, Vol. 59, No. 6


This paper is divided into three sections. In the first Table 1
section, the different levels of corruption in Asian coun- Perceived Levels of Corruption in Asian Countries
tries are discussed. Section two describes the anticorrup- -- -- - - - -

tion strategies employed in several Asian countries. The Country BII CPI97 GCR197
concluding section focuses on Singapore's experience, (I-loscale)* (1-loscale)* (1-7scale)*
demonstrating that, while it is difficult to curb corrup- Singapore 1.00 2.34 1.24
Hong Kong 3.00 3.72 1.52
tion, it is nonetheless possible to do so if a country's Japan 2.25 4.43 2.07
political leaders have the commitment or will to impar- Taiwan 4.25 5.98 3.22
tially implement effective anticorruption measures. Malaysia 5.00 5.99 3.97
South Korea 5.25 6.71 4.34
Thailand 9.50 7.94 5.55
Levels of Asian Corruption Philippines
People's Republic
6.50 7.95 5.56

In September 1974, the Far East Economic Review fea- of China NA 8.12 4.10
tured the cover story "Corruption: The Asian Lubricant," India 5.75 8.25 5.1 1
Indonesia 9.50 8.28 5.56
which surveyed corruption in 10 Asian countries. The Pakistan 7.00 8.47 NA
article concluded that: Bangladesh 7.00 9.20 NA
If you want to buy a Sherman tank, a Red Cross Source: Wei, 1998, 5.
blanket, or simply speed up the installation of a *According to Wei, the original BII, CPI, and GCRI were re-scaled so
telephone, there is probably no easier place in the that higher scores imply more corruption. Thus, for all three indices,
world in which to do just that than in Asia-if you a higher score means a higher level of corruption.
are willing- to -part with some cash, that is. With
pathetically few exceptions, the countries in this aspects of competitiveness in the host countries where
region are so riddled with corruption that the pay- they invest. Specifically, 2,381 firms in 58 countries were
ing of "tea money" has become almost a way of life asked to rate the level of corruption on a one-to-seven
(Far East Economic Review, 1974,3). scale according to the extent of "irregular, additional pay-
This picture of pervasive corruption in Asia is support- ments connected with import and export permits, busi-
ed by individual portraits of corruption in such countries ness licenses, exchange controls, tax assessments, police
as Bangladesh, the People's Republic of China, Hong protection or loan applications" (ibid., 4).
Kong, India, Japan, Laos, Pakistan, Taiwan, and Thailand Table 1 shows the levels of corruption in 13 Asian
(Far East Economic Review, 1974,22-3 1). countries according to the three indices, the BII, CPI, and
As it is not possible to measure the actual extent of cor- GCRI. Singapore is perceived to be the least corrupt Asian
ruption in a country, scholars usually rely on the reported country by all three indices. This perception is confirmed
extent of corruption. Lancaster and Montinola (1997, 16) by the Hong Kongbased Political and Economic Risk
have observed that students of political corruption use Consultancy Ltd., whose 1996 survey showed that Singa-
written documents (press reports, judicial records, and pore "maintained its reputation as a 'corruption-free'
records from anticorruption agencies) and survey data to haven in a region in which shady practices are all too
measure corruption. As these instruments are not common" (Straits Times, 1996, 3). Conversely, Indonesia
problem-free, they have recommended the use of the Cor- and Thailand were perceived as the most corrupt Asian
ruption Perception Index (CPI), published by Transparen- countries on the BII. The CPI ranked Bangladesh as the
cy International in 1995 and updated in 1996 and 1997, most corrupt Asian country, and the GCRI identified
because it is a "robust" index that "captures more than a Indonesia and the Philippines as the two Asian countries
single indicator" and "combines several measures of politi- with the highest levels of corruption.
cal corruption for each country" (Ibid., 27-28). Table 1 also indicates the different levels of corruption
According to Transparency International, the CPI is in 13 Asian countries. What accounts for the variations
"an attempt to assess the level at which corruption is per- in the extent of corruption in these countries? To answer
ceived by people working for multinational firms and this question, it is necessary to examine the anticorrup-
institutions as impacting on commercial and social life" tion strategies employed by seven of these countries to
(TI Newsletter, 1996, 5 ) . T h e Business International ascertain whether they have observed the logic of corrup-
Index (BII) is based on surveys of experts or consultants tion control.'
conducted during 1980-1 983 by Business International,
which is now a subsidiary of the Economist's Intelligence Anticorruption Strategies
Unit. The BII ranks countries from 1 to 10 according to
"the degree to which business transactions involve cor-
in Asian Countries
ruption or questionable payments" (Wei, 1998, 3). The consequences of corruption can be minimized if
Unlike the CPI and BII, the Global Competitiveness government has an effective anticorruption strategy and
Report Index (GCRI) is based on a 1996 survey of firm implements it impartially. Specifically, the more effective
managers, who were asked questions about different anticorruption measures are, the greater their impact on

484 Public Administration Review NovemberIDecember 1999, Vol. 59, No. 6


Table 2
A Matrix of Anticorruption Strategies
Anticorruption Measures

Adequate Inadequate

Commitment of Strong Effective strategy 1 Ineffective strategy 2


political leadership
Ineffective strategy 1 Hopeless" strategy

Source: Quah, 1982, 175.


the society in terms of reducing the negative effects and "Hopeless" Anticorruption Strategy
the level of corruption. The effectiveness of anticorrup-
tion measures depends on two factors: (1) the adequacy Given the perceived high levels of corruption of Asian
of the measures in terms of the comprehensiveness of countries as indicated in Table 1, it is not surprising that
their scope and powers; and (2) the level of commitment the "hopeless" anticorruption strategy has been used in
of political leaders to the goal of minimizing corruption. countries such as China, Indonesia, and Bangladesh; cor-
In other words, for anticorruption measures to be effec- ruption in these countries has been institutionalized, as
tive, they must be properly designed (to attack the causes their anticorruption measures are inadequate and their
of corruption), and they must be sponsored and upheld political leaders are not at all concerned about minimiz-
sincerely by political leaders. In short, the most elaborate ing corruption.
and well-designed anticorruption measures will be useless People2 Republic of China: The high level of corrup-
if they are not enforced by the political leadership (Quah, tion in the People's Republic of China (PRC) can be
1982, 174-175). attributed to the low wages of civil servants, the many
By juxtaposing these two variables, the adequacy of opportunities for corruption during the last two decades
anticorruption measures and the commitment of political of Deng Xiaoping's modernization policy, and the lack of
leadership, a matrix of anticorruption strategies can be political will in implementing anticorruption measures
obtained (see Table 2). against senior party officials. Indeed, although bribery
Table 2 shows four strategies for combatting corrup- exceeding 100,000 Yuan is a capital offense, the death
tion, depending on the adequacy of the anticorruption penalty has not been imposed on senior party officials
measures employed and the strength of political leaders' found guilty of accepting such bribes.2
commitment. This matrix of anticorruption strategies Several public opinion polls conducted during the late
can be used to analyze the anticorruption efforts of sever- 1980s in the PRC indicated that the public had identi-
al Asian countries. fied corruption as "the most prevailing social crime" and
To be effective, anticorruption strategies must mini- confirmed its resentment of corruption (Gong, 1994,
mize-if not eliminate-the causes of corruption. In his 135). In fact, the corruption issue was an important cata-
comparative study of the control of bureaucratic corrup- lyst for the student demonstrations in the spring of 1989
tion in Hong Kong, India, and Indonesia, Leslie Palmier as "the students' anticorruption banner appealed strongly
(1985, 271) identified three important causes of corrup- to the public." After the Tiananmen Square incident, the
tion in these countries: opportunities (which depended Chinese media "dramatically increased the exposure of
on the extent of civil servants' involvement in the admin- corruption cases to highlight the party's determination
istration or control of lucrative activities), salaries, and and efforts to repress corruptions" (ibid., 137). The Chi-
policing (that is, the probability of detection and punish- nese Communist Party sought to clear its image by intro-
ment). According to Palmier, ducing new anticorruption rules designed to (1) strength-
[Blureaucratic corruption seems to depend not on en centralized control over certain commodities and
any one of the [three] factors identified, but rather production materials; (2) forbid such "unhealthy prac-
on the balance between them. At one extreme, tices" as gift giving in public affairs and squandering pub-
with few opportunities, good salaries, and effective lic funds; and (3) punish offenders through the stipula-
policing, cowuption will be minimal, at the other, tion of disciplinary penalties for embezzlement (ibid.,
with many opportunities, poor salaries, and weak 139-140).
policing, it will be considerable (emphasis added). In 1982, the Central Discipline Inspection Commis-
(272) sion (CDIC) was reestablished to deal with discipline and
Following Palmier's hypothesis, effective anticorrup- anticorruption work. Five years later, the Ministry of
tion strategies should reduce or remove opportunities for Supervision (MOS) was also reestablished "in part to
corruption, raise the salaries of civil servants, and ensure a curb corruption and maladministration within the civil
high degree of policing. service." Even though the MOS had received more than

SICA Jubilee: Corruption in Asian Countries: Can It Be Minimized? 485


700,000 reports in 1993, both the C D I C and M O S
could not stem the problem of corruption because the
"authorities appear[ed] to lack the political will to handle
In .
Indonesia,. traditional t o h n c e for corruption
corruption cases among more senior party members" war eroakd during the postwar period, when corruption
(Burns, 1994, 57-58).
So far, only two senior party officials have been con- wds viewed more critically as the enhanced role ofrhe
victed of corruption in recent years. In 1994, Li Yiaoshi,
former Vice-Minister of the State Science and Technolo- public bumucrary had incredsed opportunitiesfir
gy Commission, was sentenced to 20 years in jail for cor-
ruption (ibid., 58). O n July 31, 1998, the former Beijing
party chief, Chen Xitong, became the highest-ranking
bureaucratic corruption.
party ;ember to be jailed for corruption when he was ident Suharto to review the problem of corruption within
sentenced to 16 years for graft of 555,000 Yuan and dere- the civil service a n d to make recommendations for
liction of duty. As corruption is a capital offense in the improvement.
PRC, Chen's sentence is lenient; more junior party cadres This commission presented seven reports on those
have been sentenced to life imprisonment or even death agencies and areas that were judged to be vulnerable to
for corruption involving smaller sums over 100,000 Yuan corruption to President Suharto from February to June
(Straits Times, 1998, 14). The death penalty is imposed 1970. Perhaps the most important consequence of these
on officials who accept bribes exceeding 100,000 Yuan, reports was the passing of the Prevention Against Cor-
or US$12,000 (Wang, 1998, 5). In short, party officials rupt Criminal Acts Bill in 197 1; previously, corruption
in the PRC can "short-circuit corruption investigations was dealt with as a crime under the penal code. Suharto
by appealing to their protectors in the party hierarchy" accepted the commission's recommendation that civil ser-
(Root, 1996, 752). vants should submit an annual return of their personal
Indonesia: In Indonesia, corruption was a serious assets, and he published an instruction in 1970 requiring
problem during the Dutch colonial period, as it was rife all officials to conform accordingly. However, civil ser-
among the D u t c h East India Company's personnel vants ignored this regulation for nine years, and it was
because of their low salaries. However, this traditional only in 1979 that 90 percent of the officials submitted
tolerance for corruption was eroded during the postwar their annual returns (Palmier, 1970, 12). This example
period, when corruption was viewed more critically as the illustrates clearly that laws in Indonesia are not always
enhanced role of the public bureaucracy had increased implemented, especially anticorruption laws, as the
opportunities for bureaucratic corruption (Quah, 1982, implementation of such laws would prevent corrupt offi-
154-1 55). Corruption became endemic during President cials from continuing their practices.
Sukarno's rule because his "disastrously inflationary bud- In June 1977, the task of combatting corruption was
gets eroded civil service salaries to the point where people transferred by presidential instruction from the Commis-
simply could n o t live o n them and where financial sion of Four to the National Security Agency (Kop-
accountability virtually collapsed because of administra- kamtib), which launched Operation Orderliness (Operasi
tive deterioration" (Mackie, 1970, 87-88). Tertib or Opstib) by making "lightning visits" to govern-
Corruption remained a serious problem and became ment departments known for corruption, dismissing offi-
institutionalized during the 32 years of Suharto's term of cials caught red-handed on the spot. Even though Kop-
office. According to Hanna (1971, I ) , corruption in kamtib had taken action against corrupt officials, its
Indonesia has "become so institutionalized" that "its major handicap was "its inability to take action against
eradication ... might mean the critical dislocation of the those generals and senior government officials involved in
whole shaky national structure." Indeed, Suharto and his corrupt practices" (Quah, 1982, 171).
family had "extensive business interests" and "benefited "The family business," or the corruption involving
from what appears to be privileged access to government Suharto's family, grew without restraint during the 1980s
contracts"(Girling, 1997, 56). and 1990s. Toward the end of Suharto's term, especially
The Indonesian government's first attempt to curb during the late 1990s, public criticism of his family's
corruption occurred after the 1955 election; it resulted in involvement in corrupt practices mounted, culminating
the arrests of those involved, including civil servants and in his relinquishment of power in May 1998. As the sys-
a minister. In June 1968, Suharto assigned the task of tem of corruption in Indonesia has become."deeply
tackling corruption cases to the Tedm Pemberantasan ingrained" during the past 32 years of Suharto's rule, it
Korupsi (Corruption Eradication Team), which was, how- will be difficult for his successor, President B.J. Habibie,
ever, ineffective because its efforts were blocked by influ- to eradicate corruption. In other words, even though
ential men in the regime (Quah, 1982, 170). Student Suharto is no longer in power in Indonesia today, his
protests in January 1970 and press criticism of govern- legacy of widespread corruption will remain for a long
ment corruption resulted in the appointment of a special time. Indeed, according to Shari and Einhorn (1998, 33),
Commission of Four elder statesmen (Komisi II/) by Pres- "the qualities that rank the country as the world's most

486 Public Administration Review + NovemberIDecember 1999, Vol. 59, No. 6


The hck ofcommitment by Bangizdehpolitical little meaning" as "decisions were made on an arbitrary
basis with little accountability or appealn (Kochanek,
1993,266-267).
leaders isjrst manijsted in thefact that 'many elected In his analysis of bureaucratic culture in Bangladesh,
Mohammad Mohabbat Khan (1998, 35) identified cor-
oficialr, including mtmbm ofparliament and ruption as a dominant component, as it has been institu-
tionalized in the public service during the last 25 years.
are known to be involved in hge-scale anuption. "
He attributed Bangladesh's high level of corruption to
four factors:
corrupt after Nigeria won't be erased with a change of First, bureaucrats involved in corrupt practices in
presidency [as]... the bureaucracy runs on miserably low most cases do not lose their jobs. Very rarely . they
.
salaries, so until civil servants make a living wage, bribery are dismissed from service on charges pertaining to
will remain." corruption. Still rarely they are sent to prison for
Bangladesh: In Bangladesh, a 1997 national household misusing public funds. They have never been com-
survey on corruption conducted for Transparency Inter- pelled to return to the state their ill-gotten wealth.
national Bangladesh confirmed the country's perceived Second, the law-enforcing officials including
high level of corruption, as revealed by the following police personnel are extremely corrupt. They are
findings: happy to share the booty with other corrupt
41% of households paid a "donation" and 3.6% a bureaucrats. Third, the people have a tendency
direct payment
- . for the admission of children into not only to tolerate corruption but to show respect
schools, while 36% of households made payments to those bureaucrats who made fortunes through
to or through hospital staff or other "influential dubious means.... Fourth, it is easier for a citizen
persons" to secure admission into hospitals. 65% to get quick service because he has already "paid"
had bribed land registrars for recording a false the bureaucrat rather than wait for his turn.
lower sale price when registering a land transac- (Khan, 1998,36)
tion, while 54% had bribed either bank employees T h e lack of commitment by Bangladesh's political
or "influential persons" to secure bank loans. 33% leaders is first manifested in the fact that "many elected
paid money to obtain electricity connections, officials, including members of parliament and minis-
while 32% paid less for water "by arrangement ters, are known to be involved in large-scale corruption"
with the meter reader." 47% were able to reduce (Khan, 1998, 36). A more important manifestation of
the holding tax assessment on house and property the lack of political will in fighting corruption is the
"by arrangement with municipal staff on payment transfer of t h e director-general o f t h e Bureau o f
of money," while 65% found it impossible to Anti-Corruption to the Ministry of Education because
obtain trade licenses without money or influence. of his "crusade against corruption" and his unwillingness
63% of those involved in litigation had paid bribes to stop the probe against four ministers, many members
to either court officials or the opponents' lawyers, of Parliament, and several senior civil servants in May
89% of those surveyed being of the view that 1995. Khan (1998, 37) concludes pessimistically, but
judges were corrupt. 97% thought the police ser- correctly, that the "bureaucratic and political elite will
vice was corrupt. (Quoted in Jayawickrama, 1998, [not] start a campaign against corruption in public life as
3) it adversely affect their individual, group and coterie
Similarly, businessmen in Bangladesh have complained interests."
that "their high costs are due to the payoffs they have to
make to government officials for sanctions, bank loans,
Ineffective Anticorruption Strategies
and permits" (Kochanek, 1993, 199). Indeed, according
to one businessman, "I get sick in my stomach whenever The second and third cells of the matrix of anticorrup-
I have to see a government official" ( Q u o t e d i n tion strategies in Table 2 represent two types of ineffective
Kochanek, 1993, 199). anticorruption strategies (strategies 1 and 2). Ineffective
The politics of patronage and corruption have plagued strategy 1 occurs when anticorruption measures are ade-
all governments in Bangladesh since 1971, but the quate but the political leadership's commitment is weak,
Ershad government has been described by one business- thus resulting in the nonenforcement of anticorruption
man as "the most centralized and corrupt in the country's measures. This lack of political will can be seen in the
history" (Kochanek, 1993, 264-265). Under General ineffective anticorruption strategies adopted in the
Ershad, corruption was pervasive and included petty cor- Philippines, South Korea, and Thailand.
ruption, project corruption, and programmatic corrup- The third cell of ineffective strategy 2 is possible but
tion (Kochanek, 1993, 259). These three forms of cor- unlikely in reality, as political leaders who are strongly
ruption "led to a massive gap between policy a n d committed to eradicating corruption will probably
implementation," as under Ershad, "law and policy had improve inadequate anticorruption measures, instead of

SICA Jubilee: Corruption in Asian Countries: Can Ir Be Minimized? 487


being satisfied with inadequate anticorruption measures. dering of the country's wealth by the former first family
None of the 13 Asian countries listed in Table 1 fall into was revealed by Pedrosa:
this category. The documents [discovered by the investigators
The Philippines: Corruption was introduced into the for the Aquino government] outlined the Mar-
Philippines during the Spanish colonial period, when coses' formula fir systematic plunder. They had
graft and corruption prevailed because civil servants were amassed their wealth through bribe-taking and
paid low salaries and had many opportunities for corrupt kickbacks from crony monopolies; through the
behavior (Corpuz, 1957, 129). In contrast, the bureau- diversion of government loans and contracts;
cracy of the American colonial period (1898-1913) was through the profits from over-priced goods and
less corrupt, as "the bureaucrats received higher salaries construction; through
- unaudited government
- rev-
and corrupt officials were promptly prosecuted" (Quah, enue, usually raised from taxes; and through the
1982, 159). However, graft and corruption flourished in expedient of taking over businesses by decree and
the Philippines after World War 11, and the bureaucracy the diversion of yet more funds from
suffered from "low prestige, incompetence, meager government-controlled entities. Nothing was
resources, and a large measure of cynical corruption" spared... [The Marcoses had stolen] a staggering
(Corpuz, 1957, 222-223). $15 billion, more than half of the entire national
Bureaucratic corruption was a serious problem during debt of the Philippines (emphasis added). (1987,
the 1950s, especially during the administration of Presi- 221-222)
dent Elpidio Quirino (1948-1953); during his tenure, When President Corazon Aquino took over in Febru-
corruption "permeated the entire Philippine bureaucracy" ary 1986, " there was high expectation that the end of the
(Alfiler, 1979, 323). Accordingly, Quirino created the culture of graft and corruption was near" (Varela, 1995,
Integrity Board in May 1950 to investigate complaints of 174). She created the Presidential Commission on Good
graft and corruption against civil servants. However, the Government (PCGG) to identify and retrieve the money
Integrity Board was dissolved five months later, as it did stolen by the Marcos family and their cronies. Unfortu-
not receive public support. nately, Aquino's "avowed anti-graft and corruption"
When Ramon Magsaysay won the presidential elec- stance was viewed cynically by the public after two of her
tion in 1953, he established the Presidential Complaints Cabinet members and her relatives were accused of cor-
and Action Commission (PCAC) to reduce inefficiency ruption. The PCGG also became a target for charges of
a n d dishonesty i n t h e civil service. However, corruption, favoritism, and incompetence; by mid-1988,
Magsaysay's death in 1 9 5 7 gave rise to the Garcia five PCGG agents faced graft charges and 13 more were
administration (1957-1962), which abolished the under investigation. In May 1987, Aquino established
PCAC and replaced it with the Presidential Committee the Presidential Committee o n Public Ethics and
on Administration Performance Efficiency and the Pres- Accountability in response to increasing public criticism.
idential Fact-Finding Committee in 1958 to implement However, this committee was hindered by a shortage of
the government's anti-graft campaign. In February staff and funds (Timberman, 1991, 233-234). In short,
1960, Garcia created a third anti-graft committee, as Carino has indicated, Aquino's "honesty has not been
known as the President's Anti-Graft Committee (ibid., matched by the political will to punish the corrupt"
331-337). (Quoted in ibid., 235).
Garcia's successor, Diodsdado Macapagal, established In his study of the consequences of low salaries on the
the Presidential Anti-Graft Committee. In 1965, Maca- prestige of the Philippine Civil Service, Padilla (1995,
pagal was replaced by Ferdinand Marcos, who abolished 195-202) found that civil servants augmented their low
that committee and formed the Presidential Agency on wages by vending within the office, holding a second job,
Reforms and Government Operations (PARGO) in Jan- teaching part-time, practicing their profession after office
uary 1966. Three other agencies, the Presidential Com- hours, and engaging in research and consultation pro-
plaints and Action Office, the Complaints and Investi- jects. O n the other hand, civil servants could also aug- -
gations Office, and the Special Cabinet Committee in ment their low salaries by resorting to petty corrupt prac-
Backsliding, were later created to assist the PARGO in tices (ibid., 206). Indeed, as long as civil service salaries
its task ofweeding out corruption (ibid., 339-346). remain low in the Philippines, it will be extremely diffi-
According to Varela (1995, 174), "graft and corrup- cult to minimize corruption. Unfortunately, Aquino's
tion reached its all time high during the martial law successor, Fidel Ramos has failed to minimize corruption,
regime under Marcos," as corruption "had permeated too, as the salaries of civil servants have not been
almost all aspects of bureaucratic life and institutions increased and he did not demonstrate his political will in
which saw the start of the systematic plunder of the fighting corruption.3
country." Indeed, the tremendous amount of "official South Korea: Corruption has been a serious problem
corruption" that was practiced by Marcos, his family, in South Korea since the sixteenth century, when the par-
and friends during his two decades in power was only dis- ticipation of the king's family in politics led to "increas-
covered after his downfall in February 1986. The plun- ing nepotism and corruption in administration" (Rah-

488 Public Administration Review NovemberIDecember 1999, Vol. 59, No. 6


"had become a symbol of corporate-government crony-
ism and the exchange of corrupt gifts." He issued a presi-
dential decree in August 1993 that Koreans must use
I South Korea since the sixteenth centuy their real names for all financial transactions, especially
bank accounts, as the "anonymous or false-name account
man, 1986, 119). As a result of corruption scandals in had been the backbone of the black economy and mas-
recent years, South Korea has been described as "a ROTC sive fraud, corruption and tax evasion schemes" (Sheri-
(Republic of Total Corruption) by the people and mass dan, 1997, 13-15). More importantly, Kim strengthened
media"(Kim, 1994,215). the BAI, which became the first de jure anticorruption
The fight against corruption began with President agency in South Korea. He created the Commission for
Park Chung Hee, who assumed office in May 1961 after the Prevention of Corruption, an advisory body of pri-
ousting the government of Chang Myon because of its vate citizens formed to assist the BAIs chairman in fight-
involvement in corruption, its inability to defend the ing corruption. In March 1993, the government formed
country from communism, and its incompetence in initi- a team of 100 special inspectors within the BAI to imple-
ating economic and social change (Han, 1989, 273). Park ment Kim's anticorruption campaign. By August 1993,
formed the Board of Audit and Inspection (BAI) in 1963 the BAI had 776 officials involved in audit and adminis-
to act as a "direct check on the economic bureaucracy" trative inspection. Article 24 of the BAI Act empowers
(Hart-Landsberg, 1993, 54). In other words, the BAI was the BAI to conduct anticorruption activities by examin-
the first defdcto anticorruption agency in South Korea. In ing civil servants' behavior.
March 1975, Park introduced the Seojungshaeshin (Gen- President Kim's anticorruption campaign confirmed
eral Administration Reform) Movement to curb corrup- that corruption is a way of life in South Korea and
tion in the civil service (Oh, 1982, 324); the number of exposed its pervasiveness in the country. However, Young
civil servants prosecuted for corruption increased from Jong Kim (1994, 207) has lamented the lack of political
21,919 in 1975 to 51,468 in 1976 (Rahman, 1986, will in South Korea's efforts to curb corruption, especially
122). under the regimes of Presidents Rhee, Park, and Chun.
Park's assassination in October 1979 led to the Although Kim's anticorruption drive was hindered by the
assumption of power a year later by his successor, Chun May 17, 1997, arrest of his son for bribery and tax eva-
Doo Hwan, who reaffirmed his government's anticorrup- sion in the Hanbo loan scandal and his sentencing to
tion stance by purging corrupt public officials and intro- three years' imprisonment five months later, Kim has
ducing ethics laws to reward honest officials and to clearly demonstrated his commitment to eliminating cor-
enhance the structures for civil service reform (Jun, 1985, ruption by not obstructing the legal arrest and sentencing
63). However, Chun's government lacked legitimacy of his son. Nevertheless, the Hanbo scandal and his son's
because of opposition by rival political parties, student arrest and imprisonment seriously undermined Kim's
leaders, intellectuals, and progressive Christians (Han, legitimacy and jeopardized the continued success of his
1989, 283-284). Chun's unpopularity led to his retire- anticorruption drive. Whether Kim's commitment to
ment in February 1988 at the end of his seven-year term. curbing corruption will be continued by his successor,
He, his two brothers, and his wife's family were accused Kim Dae Jung, remains to be seen.
of massive corruption, and on November 23, 1988, Thaihnd: Like South Korea, the origins of corruption
Chun and his wife apologized for their misbehavior and in Thailand can be traced to the sixteenth century, when
returned 13.9 billion Won (US$20 million) to the gov- civil servants withheld revenue collected for the king for
ernment. themselves, as they were not paid regular salaries, and
Chun's successor, Roh Tae Woo, was plagued by the sent only a small amount to the king (Chai-Anan, 1977,
"long-festering problem of political corruption," with six 1, 4). The Board of Inspection and Follow-up of Govern-
legislators found guilty of extorting funds from the busi- ment Operations was established as the first de jure anti-
ness community. The 1992 Hanbo scandal shocked the corruption agency in September 1972. It was ineffective,
country when Chung Tae Soo, chairman of the Hanbo however, as its five members were guilty of corruption
Construction Company, was accused of contributing sub- themselves and the group was dissolved after the October
stantial funds to ruling and opposition political parties for 1973 revolution.
favors involving land development ("Korea-South," 1992, In May 1974, Prime Minister Sanya appointed a
138). However, Roh himself was not immune: in Octo- Counter Corruption Committee to investigate charges of
ber 1995 it was discovered that he had received almost corruption against civil servants and to report its find-
$600 million for his private political fund from individu- ings. This committee was required to prepare an anticor-
als and major business conglomerates (Macdonald and ruption draft bill to supplement the inadequate penal
Clark, 1996, 159-160). code. The Cabinet approved the draft bill and in Decem-
When Kim Young Sam assumed power in February ber 1974 sent it to the National Legislative Assembly.
1993, he voluntarily declared his personal assets of 1.7 The Assembly passed the bill, and the Counter Corrup-
billion Won (US$2.1 million) and gave up golf, which tion Act (CCA) was enacted in February 1975. The CCA

SICA Jubilee: Corruption in Asian Countries: Can It Be Minimized? 489


changed the Counter Corruption Committee to the
Commission of Counter Corruption (CCC), which con-
sists of a chairman and between five and nine members.
I Singapore is the least mrm*t in,a ton,
The CCC set out to investigate allegations of corrup-
tion against civil servants and submits to the cabinet pro-
1 according to the three indices, However, the situation was
posals for preventing corruption and for revising admin- 1 quite d@rent in Singapore during the British colonial
istrative practices. However, the C C C was ineffective for
three reasons. First, according to Mulder (1996,
173-174), "the idea of corruption, meaning that the
1period, when corrupion wai a way of l$,
external world should not be exploited for personal gain tution has introduced additional anticorruption mea-
because it constitutes the public interest" was "so baffling sures, including the empowerment of the CCC. Howev-
[to the Thais] that it lames all Anti-Corruption Commis- er, whether Thailand's anticorruption strategy can be
sions at the outset." Second, the C C C could not curb transformed into an effective one will depend on how
corruption because of the constant conflict between the long Chuan Leekpai remains prime minister and the
Cabinet and bureaucracy (Dalpino, 1991, 66). Finally, extent to which the new anticorruption measures are
the C C C was viewed by its critics as a "paper tiger" with- actually implemented.
out real teeth, as "it could only send reports to the prime
minister and the Cabinet" since it lacked "direct authori-
Effective Anticorruption Strategy
ty to punish public officials." Consequently, very few civil
servants have been punished for corruption. The final anticorruption strategy is the effective strate-
The CCC's ineffectiveness led to the CCA's amend- gy, which occurs when adequate anticorruption measures
ment in 1987 to give it more power (Amara, 1992, 240). are in place and political leaders are strongly committed
In spite of this amendment, the C C C still cannot take to eradicating corruption. Of the 13 countries listed in
action against politicians, and it "only has the power to Table 1, only Singapore and Hong Kong, the two least
investigate a bureaucrat following a complaint." Officials corrupt Asian city-states, come under this category. Both
found guilty by the C C C are usually reprimanded or dis- have adequate anticorruption measures (Prevention of
ciplined within the department, as the public prosecutor Corruption Act and the Corrupt Practices Investigation
does not use the evidence collected by the C C C to initi- Bureau in Singapore, and the Prevention of Bribery Ordi-
ate new investigations (Pasuk and Sungsidh, 1994, nance and the Independent Commission Against Cor-
180-181). ruption in Hong Kong); both are blessed with political
Thailand's anticorruption strategy was described as leaders who are determined to remove the problem of
"hopeless" by Quah (1982, 175-176) 16 years ago, as the corruption in their countries (Quah, 1995).
country's anticorruption measures were inadequate and The final section of this paper will discuss Singapore's
its political leaders unconcerned about minimizing cor- effective anticorruption strategy, with the aim of showing
ruption. Indeed, most Thai political leaders (with a few how corruption can be minimized when political leaders
exceptions, such as prime ministers Anand Panyarachun are sincerely committed to this task by impartially imple-
and Chuan Leekpai) have not been committed in the menting comprehensive anticorruption measures.
fight against corruption. However, the situation has
improved recently after Chuan Leekpai replaced General
Chavalit Yongchaiyudh as prime minister in November
Learning from Singapore's Fxperience
1997. Furthermore, the Constitution promulgated on As Table 1 indicates, Singapore is the least corrupt
October 11, 1997, or the "People's Constitution," is con- country in Asia today according to the three indices.
cerned, among other things, with making elected politi- However, the situation was quite different in Singapore
cians and public officials accountable by introducing sev- during the British colonial period, when corruption was a
eral measures to curb corruption. Specifically, codes of way of life. The 1879 and 1886 Commissions found that
conduct for politicians and civil servants have been for- bribery and corruption were prevalent among the Straits
mulated to prohibit conflicts of interest. They are also Settlement Police Force in Singapore. Indeed, an analysis
required to declare their assets, liabilities, and their of the Straits Times from 1845 to 1921 shows that 172
income tax returns (and those of their dependents) to the cases of police corruption were reported during this peri-
C C C when they assume and leave office and one year od (Quah, 1979, 24). Corruption was also widespread
after leaving office. The C C C has been strengthened to during the Japanese occupation (1942-1945), as rampant
"enable it to bring cases to court and to cover the cases of inflation made it difficult for civil servants to live on their
political officials" (Prudhisan, 1998, 275-276). low salaries. The situation deteriorated during the post-
In short, Thailand's anticorruption strategy has been war period, and in his 1950 Annual Report, the Com-
transformed from a hopeless strategy to an ineffective one missioner of Police revealed that graft was rife in govern-
as its current prime minister, Chuan Leekpai, is con- ment departments in Singapore.
cerned about minimizing corruption. The new Consti- When the Peoples Action Party (PAP) leaders assumed

490 Public Administration Review NovemberIDecember 1999, Vol. 59, No. 6


office in June 1959, they realized that corruption had to officers with powers of arrest and search of arrested per-
be curbed to ensure that the Singapore Civil Service sons, and it empowered the public prosecutor to autho-
attained the country's development goals. They also real- rize the CPIB's director and senior staff to investigate
ized that they could not continue the British colonial "any bank account, share account or purchase account"
government's incremental anticorruption strategy if their of anyone suspected of having committed an offense
intention was to minimize corruption. Accordingly, the against the POCA. Section 18 enabled the CPIB officers
PAP government's immediate tasks were twofold-to to inspect a civil servant's banker's book and those of his
minimize corruption and to change the public perception wife, children, or agent, if necessary (Quah, 1978,
of corruption as "a low-risk, high-reward" activity to "a 10-13).
high-risk, low-reward" activity. In 1960, a comprehensive To ensure the POCA's effectiveness, the PAP govern-
anticorruption strategy was introduced with the enact- ment amended it as necessary or introduced new legisla-
ment of the Prevention of Corruption Act and the tion to deal with unforeseen problems. In 1963, the
strengthening of the Corrupt Practices Investigation POCA was amended to empower CPIB officers to
Bureau (CPIB). Because corruption is caused by both require the attendance of witnesses and to question them.
incentives and opportunities to become corrupt, the new This amendment enabled CPIB officers to obtain the
comprehensive strategy was based on the "logic of cor- cooperation of witnesses to help them in their investiga-
ruption control," as "attempts to eradicate corruption tions. In 1966, two important amendments were intro-
must be designed to minimize or remove the conditions duced to further strengthen the POCA. First, section 28
of both the incentives and opportunities that make indi- stated that a person could be found guilty of corruption
vidual corrupt behavior irresistible" (Quah, 1989, 842). even if he did not actually receive the bribe, as the inten-
tion on his part to commit the offense constituted suffi-
cient grounds for his conviction. The second amendment
Reducing the Opportunities for Corruption
(section 35) was directed at those Singaporeans working
Singapore was a poor country in 1960, with per capita for their government in embassies and other government
gross national product of S$ 1,330, or US$443 (Republic agencies abroad: Singapore citizens could be prosecuted
of Singapore, 1986, ix). As such, the PAP government for corrupt offenses committed outside Singapore and
could not afford to combat corruption by raising the would be dealt with as if such offenses had occurred
salaries of its civil servants. It was left with the alternative within the country. In 1981, the POCA was amended for
of strengthening the existing legislation to reduce the the third time to increase its deterrent effect by requiring
opportunities for corruption and to increase the penalty those convicted of corruption to repay the money they
for corrupt behavior. Corruption was first made illegal in received in addition to facing the usual court sentence.
Singapore in 1871 with the introduction of the Penal Those who could not make full restitution would be
Code of the Straits Settlements. The first specific anticor- given heavier court sentences.
ruption law was introduced on December 10, 1937, O n December 14, 1986, then-Minister for National
when the Prevention of Corruption Ordinance (POCO) Development Teh Cheang Wan committed suicide, 12
was enacted. The P O C O was amended in 1946 to days after he was interrogated for 16 hours by two senior
increase the penalty for corrupt offenses from two to CPIB officers regarding two allegations of corruption
three years and/or a fine of S$10,000, and to enable the against him by a building contractor. Teh was accused of
police to arrest corrupt individuals without warrants. accepting two bribes amounting to S$l million in 198 1
The Prevention of Corruption Act (POCA) was enact- and 1982 from two developers to enable one of them to
ed on June 17, 1960, and included five important fea- retain land which had been acquired by the government,
tures to eliminate the POCO'S deficiencies and to and to assist the other developer in purchasing state land
empower the CPIB to perform its duties. First, the for private development. An important consequence of
POCA's scope was increased to 32 sections, in contrast to the Commission of Inquiry that followed was the enact-
the POCO'S 12 sections.4 Second, corruption was explic- ment on March 3, 1989, of the Corruption (Confisca-
itly defined in terms of the various forms of "gratifica- tion of Benefits) Act 1989, which concerned the confisca-
tion" in section 2, which also identified for the first time tion of benefits derived from corruption; it stipulates that
the CPIB and its director. Third, to enhance the POCA's if a defendant is deceased, the court may issue a confisca-
deterrent effect, the penalty for corruption was increased tion order against his estate.
to imprisonment for five years and/or a fine of S$10,000 The CPIB is the anticorruption agency responsible for
(section 5). The amount of the fine was further increased enforcing the POCA's provisions. It has grown in size by
to S$100,000 in 1989. Fourth, a person found guilty of nine times, from eight officers in 1960 to its current
accepting an illegal gatification would be fined the establishment of 71 officers, comprising 49 investigators
amount of the bribe, plus any other punishment imposed and 22 clerical and support staff. The CPIB performs
by the court (section 13). Finally, the fifth and most three functions: (1) to receive and investigate complaints
important feature of the POCA was that it gave the CPIB concerning corruption in the public and private sectors;
more powers and a new lease on life. It provided CPIB (2) to investigate malpractices and misconduct by public

SICA Jubilee: Corruption in Asian Countries: Can It Be Minimized? 491


officers; and (3) to examine the practices and procedures PAP government had to improve the salaries and working
in the public service to minimize opportunities for cor- conditions in the civil service to stem the "brain drain" of
rupt practices (CPIB, 1990, 2). competent senior civil servants to the private sector by
offering competitive salaries and fringe benefits to reduce
the gap between the two sectors. Accordingly, the salaries
Reducing Incentives for Corruption
of civil servants in Singapore were revised upwards in
The PAP government was able to implement only the 1973, 1979, 1982, 1989, and 1994 to reduce the drain
second prong of its comprehensive anticorruption strate- to the private sector and the salary gap in the two sectors.
gy-the reduction of incentives for corruption by As a result of these salary revisions, senior civil servants in
improving salaries and working conditions in the civil Singapore earn perhaps the highest salaries in the world
service-in the 1980s long after it had achieved econom- compared with their counterparts in other countries. For
ic growth. The improvement of wages began in March example, the basic monthly salary of the highest grade
1972, when all civil servants were given a 13-month non- (staff grade V) is S$38,799, or US$25,866 (Straits Times,
pensionable allowance comparable to the bonus in the 1993, 28); this is much higher than the top monthly
private sector. This allowance was not aimed at curbing salary for the United States Federal Service, which is
corruption, but enhancing working conditions in the US$7,224, or S$11,631 (Wright and Dwyer, 1990,6).
civil service in comparison to the private sector. Singapore's experience demonstrates that it is possible to
Perhaps the best justification for the PAP government's minimize corruption if there is strong political will. Con-
approach to combatting corruption by reducing or versely, if such political will is lacking, the situation is
removing the incentives for corruption by improving hopeless, as political leaders and senior civil servants or
political leaders' and senior civil servants' salaries was pro- military officers will pay only lip service to implementing
vided by the former Prime Minister Lee Kuan Yew in anticorruption measures. On the other hand, it might be
Parliament on March 22, 1985, when he explained why difficult for other countries to replicate and transplant Sin-
the wages of the Cabinet ministers had to be raised. He gapore's experience in curbing corruption for two reasons:
contended that political leaders should be paid the top Singapore's unique policy context differs from that of other
salaries that they deserve in order to ensure a clean and countries; and the prohibitive economic and political costs
honest government. If they were underpaid, they would of paying political leaders and civil servants high salaries
succumb to temptation and indulge in corrupt behavior. and reducing the opportunities for corruption.
According to Lee, Singapore needed a corruption-free
administration and an honest political leadership to pre- Jon S. T. Quah is a professor of political science at the
serve its most precious assets. He concluded that the best National University of Singapore. He has published
way to deal with corruption was by "moving with the widely on public administration in Singapore and other
market," which is "an honest, open, defensible and work- Asian countries, with emphasis on administrative reform,
able system" instead of hypocrisy, which results in duplic- anticorruption strategies, and human resource develop-
ity and corruption (Straits Times, 1985, 14-16). ment. He is a member of Transparency International's
Apart from reducing the incentives for corruption, the Governance Council.

1. As space limitations and limited access to data do not per- PRC in recent years. See, for example, Gong (1994), Gong
mit a discussion of all the 13 countries, only the anticorrup- (1997), Kwong (1997), and Mulvenon (1998).
tion strategies of the PRC, Indonesia, Bangladesh, the 3. For a recent treatment of corruption in the Philippines, see
Philippines, South Korea, Thailand, and Singapore will be Coronel (1998).
analyzed in this paper. 4. The POCA now has 37 sections as a result of subsequent
2. A great deal of research has been done on corruption in the amendments.

Public Administration Review + NovemberIDecember 1999, Vol. 59, No. 6


Alfiler, Ma. Concepcion P. (1979). "Administrative Measures Kochanek, Stanley A. (1993). Patron-Client Politics and Busi-
against Bureaucratic Corruption: The Philippine Experi- ness in Bangladesh. New Delhi: Sage Publications.
ence." Philippine Journal of Public Administration 23(3/4): "Korea-South." (1992). In Asia Yearbook 1992. Hong Kong:
321-349. Far Eastern Economic Review: 137-140.
Amara, Raksasataya (1992). "Bureaucracy vs. Bureaucracy: Kwong, Julia (1997). The Political Economy of Corruption in
Anti-Corrupt Practices in Thailand." In Ramesh K. Arora, China. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.
ed., Politics and Administration in Changing Societies. New Lancaster, Thomas D. and Gabriella R. Montinola (1997).
Delhi: Associated Publishing House. "Toward a Methodology for the Comparative Study of
Burns, John P. (1994). "Civil Service Reform in China." Asian Political Corruption." Unpublished paper.
Journal of Political Science 2(2): 44-72. Macdonald, Donald Stone and Donald N. Clark (1996). The
Chai-Anan, Samudavanija (1977). "Problems of Bureaucratic Koreans: Contemporary Politics and Society. 3rd ed. Boulder:
Corruption in Thailand: A Study of Legal Codes, Adminis- Westview Press.
trative and Institutional Arrangements." Paper presented at Mackie, J.A.C. (1970). "The Commission of Four Report on
the Bureaucratic Behavior in Asia Project, Pattaya, Thai- Corruption." Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 6(3):
land. 80-88.
Coronel, Sheila S., ed. (1998). Pork and Other Perks: Corrup- Mulder, Niels (1996). Inside Thai Society: Interpretations of
tion and Governance in the Philippines. Metro Manila: Everyday life. Amsterdam: Pepin Press.
Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism. Mulvenon, James (1998). "Military Corruption in China: A
Corpuz, Onofre D. (1957). The Bureaucracy in the Philippines. Conceptual Examination." Problems of Post-Communism
Quezon City: Institute of Public Administration, University 45(2): 12-21.
of the Philippines. Myrdal, Gunnar (1968). Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the
Corrupt Practices Investigation Bureau (1990). The Corrupt Poverty ofNations, Vol. 11. New York: The Twentieth Cen-
Practices Investigation Bureau. Singapore: CPIB. tury Fund.
Dalpino, Catherin E. (199 I). "Thailand's Search for Account- Oh, Suek-Hong (1982). "The Counter-Corruption Campaign
ability." Journal of Democracy 2(4): 6 1-71. of the Korean Government (1975-1977): Administrative
Far Eastern Economic Review (1974). "Graft: Almost a way of Anti-Corruption Measures of the Seojungshaeshin." In Bun
life." Far Eastern Economic Review September 6: 3, 22-3 1. Woong Kim and Wha Joon Rho, eds., Korean Public
Ghosh, Aparisim et al. (1997). "Corruption: Reform's Dark Bureaucracy. Seoul: Kyobo Publishing Inc.
Side." Far Eastern Economic Review March 20: 18-20. Padilla, Perfecto L. (1995). "Low Salary Grades, Income-Aug-
Girling, John (1997). Corruption, Capitalism and Democracy. mentation Schemes and the Merit Principle." In Proserpina
London: Routledge. Domingo Tapales and Nestor N. Pilar, eds., Public Admin-
Gong, Ting (1994). The Politics of Corruption in Contemporary istration by the Year 2000: Looking Back into Future. Quezon
China: An Analysis of Policy Outcomes. Westport, CT: City: College of Public Administration, University of the
Praeger. Philippines.
(1997). "Forms and Characteristics of China's Cor- Palmier, Leslie (1985). The Control of Bureaucratic corruption:
ruption in the 1990s: Change with Continuity." Communist Case Studies in Asia. New Delhi: Allied Publishers.
and Post-Communist Studies 30(3): 277-288. Pasuk, Phongpaichit and Sungsidh Piriyarangsan (1994). Cor-
Han, Sung Joo (1989). "South Korea: Politics in Transition." ruption and Democracy in Thailand. Bangkok: Silkworm
In Larry Diamond, Juan J. Linz, and Seymour Martin Books.
Lipset, eds., Democracy in Developing Countries: Asia. Boul- Pedrosa, Carmen Navarro (1987). Imelda Marcos: The Rise and
der: Lynne Rienner Publishers. Fall of One of the World? Most Powe@l Women. New York:
Hanna, Willard A. (1971). "A Primer of Korupsi." AUFS St. Martin's Press.
FieldstaffReports 19(8): 1-8. Prudhisan, Jumbala (1998). 'Thailand: Constitutional Reform
Hart-Landsberg, Martin (1993). The Rush to Development: Eco- Amidst Economic Crisis." In Southeast Asian Affairs 1998.
nomic Change and Political Struggle in South Korea. New Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
York: Monthly Review Press. Quah, Jon S. T. (1978). "Administrative and Legal Measures
Jayawickrama, Nihal (1998). "Corruption: Legal and Institu- for Combating Bureaucratic Corruption in Singapore."
tional Reform in Asian Countries." Paper presented at the Department of Political Science, University of Singapore,
United Nations Development Program Regional Workshop Occasional Paper No. 34.
on Integrity in Governance in Asia, Bangkok, Thailand, . (1979). "Police Corruption in Singapore: An Analy-
June 29-July 1. sis of its Forms, Extent and Causes." Singapore Police Jour-
Jun, Jong Sup (1985). "The Paradoxes of Development: Prob- nal lO(1): 7-43.
lems of Korea's Transformation." In Bun Woong Kim, . (1982). "Bureaucratic Corruption in the ASEAN
David S. Bell, Jr., and Chong Bum Lee, eds., Administrative Countries: A Comparative Analysis of Their Anti-Corrup-
Dynamics and Development: The Korean Experience. Seoul: tion Strategies." Journal of Southeast Asian Studies 13(1):
Kyobo Publishing Inc. 153-177.
Khan, Mohammad Mohabbat (1998). Administrative Reforms (1989). "Singapore's Experience in Curbing Corrup-
in Bangkzdesh. New Delhi: South Asian Publishers. tion." In Arnold J. Heidenheimer, Michael Johnston, and
Kim, Young Jong (1994). Bureaucratic Corruption: The Case of Victor T. LeVine, eds., Political Corruption: A Handbook.
Korea. 4th ed. Seoul: Chomyung Press. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.

SICA Jubilee: Corruption in Asian Countries: Can It Be Minimized? 493


Law and Social Change 22: 39 1-41 4. Southeast Asian Studies.
Rahman, A.T.R. (1986). "Legal and Administrative Measures TI Newshtter (1996). "A Briefing on the T I Corruption Per-
against Bureaucratic Corruption in Asia." In Ledivina V. ception Index, 1996."
Carino, ed., Bureaucratic Corruption in Asia: Causes, Conse- Varela, Amelia (1995). "Different Faces of Filipino Adminis-
quences and Control. Quezon City: JMC Press and College trative Culture." In Proserpina Domingo Tapales and
of Public Administration, University of the Philippines. Nestor N. Pilar, eds., Public Administration by the Year
Republic of Singapore (1986). Economic Survey of Singapore 2000: Looking Back into the Future. Quezon City: College
1785. Singapore: Ministry of Trade and Industry. of Public Administration, University of the Philippines.
Root, Hilton (1996). "Corruption in China: Has It Become Wang, Yunhai (1998). "Bribery and its Countermeasures in
Systemic?"&an Suwey 36(8): 741-757. Contemporary China." Paper presented at the 12th Interna-
Shari, Michael and Bruce Einhorn (1998). "Graft won't just tional Congress on Criminology, Seoul, Korea, August
vanish: Suharto may leave, but corruption remains." Busi- 24-29.
ness Week June 1: 32-33. Wei, Shang-Jin (1998). "Corruption in Asian Economies: Ben-
Sheridan, Greg (1994). Tigers: Leaders of the New Asia-Pacific. eficial Grease, Minor Annoyance, or Major Obstacles?"
St. Leonards: Allen and Unwin. Paper presented at the United Nations Development Pro-
Straits Times (1985). March 23, 14-16. gram Regional Workshop on Integrity in Governance in
Straits Times (1993). December 4, 1. Asia, Bangkok, Thailand, June 29-July 1.
Straits Times (1996). April 9, 3. Wright, John W. and Edmund J. Dwyer (1990). The American
Straits Times (1998). August 1, 14. Almanac oflobs and Salaries. New York: Avon Books.

Public Administration Review + November/December 1999, Vol. 59, No. 6

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen