Sie sind auf Seite 1von 4

ESSAYS ON ISSUES

THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANK MAY 2011


OF CHICAGO NUMBER 286

Chicag­o Fed Letter


What are the implications of rising commodity prices
for inflation and monetary policy?
by Charles L. Evans, president and chief executive officer, and Jonas D. M. Fisher, vice president and director of macroeconomic research

The recent run-ups in oil and other commodity prices and their implications for infla-
tion and monetary policy have grabbed the attention of many commentators in the
media. Clearly, higher prices of food and energy end up in the broadest measures
of consumer price inflation, such as the Consumer Price Index. Since the mid-1980s,
however, sharp increases and decreases in commodity prices have had little, if any,
impact on core inflation, the measure that excludes food and energy prices.

Some economists argue that rising examine its contribution to improving


commodity prices are inflationary and, forecasting performance. Using this
therefore, require a tightening of mon- approach, we find evidence from some
etary policy.1 Others say rising commod- single equation models that we track at
ity prices have sometimes led to inflation the Chicago Fed that suggests commod-
and sometimes not. Therefore, a mon- ity prices are poor predictors of changes
etary policy response may not be re- in future core inflation. However, this
quired.2 In this Chicago Fed Letter,3 we might be because, as a credible inflation-
empirically assess these views by con- fighting central bank, the Federal Re-
ducting a statistical analysis of quarterly serve has historically tightened policy
We study the influence of data on commodity prices, inflation, and to eliminate the inflationary conse-
monetary policy since 1959. We find quences of large changes in commodity
a credible inflation-fighting
that since the mid-1980s, after the big oil prices. Accounting for such monetary
central bank by comparing shocks and the tenure of Paul Volcker policy reactions is an interesting and
responses of core inflation as chairman of the Federal Open Market subtle issue, and there are several valid
and the monetary policy Committee (FOMC), the reactions of approaches. Here, we employ a reduced-
both core inflation and the federal funds form statistical framework.4 To identify
instrument in the pre- and
rate (the monetary policy instrument) the influence of monetary policy, we
post-Volcker periods. to shocks in oil and other commodity estimate the typical response of core in-
prices have been extremely modest. We flation and the monetary policy instru-
use our estimates to assess the current ment following an unexpected change
stance of monetary policy. in commodity prices. We study the in-
fluence of a credible inflation-fighting
Methodology central bank by comparing responses
To assess inflationary pressures in the in the pre- and post-Volcker periods.
economy, we can look at many potential
We consider three distinct hypotheses:
indicators of future inflation, such as
rising commodity prices. But how do • Weak central bank credibility hypothesis:
we determine the relative importance If commodity prices have a substan-
of these indicators? One objective ap- tial effect on actual inflation and the
proach is to include an indicator in an policy response is inadequate, we
inflation-forecasting relationship and should see an increase in inflation
1. Responses to CRB price shocks following a commodity price in-
crease. Presumably, this evidence
A. Core PCE inflation, pre-Volcker B. Federal funds rate, pre-Volcker would be most apparent during the
basis points basis points
pre-Volcker period (1959–79).
100 100
75 75 • Strong central bank credibility hypothesis:
50 50 If commodity prices have a substan-
25 25 tial effect on inflation and the policy
0 0 response is adequate, we should see
–25 –25 no significant increase in inflation
–50 –50 following a commodity price increase.
–75 –75 However, we should see a response
–100 –100 in the fed funds rate, reflecting the
2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
tightening of monetary policy. This
C. Core PCE inflation, post-Volcker (to 2008:Q4) D. Federal funds rate, post-Volcker (to 2008:Q4) might be apparent in the post-Volcker
basis points basis points sample period (1982–2008).
100 100

75 75
• A generally uninformative indicator
50 50
hypothesis: If commodity prices were
25 25
truly uninformative for inflation, ­
0 0
they would generate insignificant ­
–25 –25
responses of both inflation and the
policy instrument.
–50 –50

–75 –75 We estimate these hypotheses with the


–100 –100 vector autoregressive (VAR) model that
2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
Bernanke, Gertler, and Watson used to
Notes: The blue lines are 68% posterior probability bands. CRB indicates Commodity Research Bureau; PCE indicates
personal consumption expenditures. study monetary policy and the effect of
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from Haver Analytics.
oil price shocks.5 We use quarterly data
for core PCE inflation (personal con-
sumption expenditures without food
2. Responses to oil price shocks and energy), growth in real gross do-
mestic product (GDP), growth of the
A. Core PCE inflation, pre-Volcker B. Federal funds rate, pre-Volcker
Commodity Research Bureau’s (CRB)
basis points basis points
150 150
Commodity Price Index (which consists
100 100
of commodities other than oil), growth
50 50
of the Producer Price Index (PPI) for
0 0
crude petroleum, and the federal funds
–50 –50
rate (FFR).6 Following the literature, we
assume the Fed (via the FFR) is able to
–100 –100
respond contemporaneously to all the
–150 –150
other variables in the model, but the
–200 –200
–250 –250
other variables are affected by the funds
2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 rate only with a lag of one quarter. Infla-
C. Core PCE inflation, post-Volcker (to 2008:Q4) D. Federal funds rate, post-Volcker (to 2008:Q4)
tion is assumed to depend on lags only.
basis points basis points Under these assumptions, we examine
150 150 how unanticipated changes in com-
100 100 modity prices influence inflation and
50 50 monetary policy. We identify two com-
0 0 modity price shocks. The CRB shock is
–50 –50 identified with the residuals from a re-
–100 –100 gression of growth in the CRB price on
–150 –150 four lags of itself and all the other vari-
–200 –200 ables in the system, plus current values
–250 –250 of core inflation and GDP. The oil price
2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
shock is identified by a regression with
Notes: The blue lines are 68% posterior probability bands. CRB indicates Commodity Research Bureau; PCE indicates
personal consumption expenditures.
the same conditioning variables, plus cur-
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from Haver Analytics. rent CRB price growth. While we focus
post-Volcker period, when the bound comes into play. How-
3. Recent monetary policy and commodity prices
the same size CRB ever, to get at least a rough idea of the
A. Actual FFR and predicted by post-Volcker rules shock leads to virtually importance of commodity prices for
6 6
no change in inflation monetary policy in the current period,
5 5
(panel C). Whatever we conducted a dynamic simulation
4 4
is driving the non- of the post-Volcker rule, ignoring the
3 3
2 2 response of inflation existence of the zero lower bound.9
1 in the post-Volcker
1 Figure 3 shows the actual path of the
0 0 period, it does not
FFR since 2005:Q1 (blue line), along
–1 –1 appear to be an ag-
with the values predicted by our esti-
–2 –2 gressive response
–3 mated post-Volcker monetary policy
of monetary policy—
2006 ’07 ’08 ’09 ’10 rule for 2009:Q1 forward (black line)
Actual With commodities Without commodities the FFR response
and a version of this policy rule that
(panel D) is a small
excludes commodity prices (light blue
B. Recent oil and non-oil commodity prices fraction of the reac-
line). The predicted values for FFR
220 220 tion in the earlier
are from simulations in which variables
200 200 period.
180
other than FFR are set at their realized
180
160
In figure 2, the re- values, but FFR is determined dynami-
160
sponses to the oil cally.10 The last data point is for 2011:Q1,
140 140
shock follow a broadly and was fitted based on our own esti-
120 120
similar pattern. In the mates for GDP and core PCE inflation
100 100
pre-Volcker sample, and the commodity and oil prices in
80 80
60 60 core inflation and the that quarter.11
2006 ’07 ’08 ’09 ’10 FFR respond by a rel-
If we focus on the policy rule that in-
Oil Other commodities atively large amount
cludes commodity prices, after 2008:Q4
to the oil shock, al-
Note: FFR indicates federal funds rate.
the fitted funds rate quickly goes nega-
Source: Authors' calculations based on data from Haver Analytics. though the statistical
tive, reaching as low as –2.66% in 2009,
significance of the
whereas actual policy is constrained by
on a limited set of results, our findings FFR response is marginal. In the post-
the zero lower bound. The predicted
appear to be quite robust.7 Volcker period, the core inflation re-
policy rate gradually rises as data on
sponse is virtually zero. Some case may
Findings be made here that the non-response of
The median dynamic responses of in- inflation is in part due to monetary Charles L. Evans, President ; Daniel G. Sullivan,
policy reacting to the oil shock (figure 2, Executive Vice President and Director of Research;
flation and FFR to these identified shocks Spencer Krane, Senior Vice President and Economic
are displayed in figures 1 and 2 for the panel D). However, we discount this in- Advisor ; David Marshall, Senior Vice President, financial
CRB shock and oil shock, respectively. terpretation because the magnitude of markets group ; Daniel Aaronson, Vice President,
microeconomic policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher,
These plots display the predicted quar- the response is tiny—a surprise increase Vice President, macroeconomic policy research; Richard
terly time paths of inflation and the FFR in oil prices of 10% at best merits a rise Heckinger, Assistant Vice President, markets team;
Anna Paulson, Vice President, finance team; William A.
following an unanticipated increase in in the FFR of only 10 basis points. Testa, Vice President, regional programs, and Economics
CRB prices of 3% and oil prices of 10%, Editor ; Helen O’D. Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors  ;
In sum, figures 1 and 2 provide some Rita Molloy and Julia Baker, Production Editors ;
implied by our estimated VAR and iden-
evidence for the “weak central bank Sheila A. Mangler, Editorial Assistant.
tification scheme. The blue lines rep-
8
credibility” hypothesis during the pre- Chicago Fed Letter is published by the Economic
resent 68% posterior probability bands, Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
Volcker period. In the post-Volcker era,
a measure of our uncertainty in the of Chicago. The views expressed are the authors’
neither core inflation nor monetary and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
estimated paths. Panels A and B of the
policy has been very sensitive to surprises Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal
figures show estimates based on the pre- Reserve System.
in commodity prices, consistent with the
Volcker sample, 1959:Q1 to 1979:Q2, © 2011 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
“uninformative indicator” hypothesis. Chicago Fed Letter articles may be reproduced in
and panels C and D show estimates based
whole or in part, provided the articles are not
on the post-Volcker sample, 1982:Q3 to Finally, we quantify the effects that re- reproduced or distributed for commercial gain
2008:Q4. cent oil and CRB shocks should have and provided the source is appropriately credited.
Prior written permission must be obtained for
on policy according to the estimated
In the pre-Volcker period, core inflation any other reproduction, distribution, republica-
policy rules. The fact that we’ve been tion, or creation of derivative works of Chicago Fed
rises significantly following an unantici- Letter articles. To request permission, please contact
constrained by the zero lower bound
pated increase in CRB commodity prices Helen Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or
(i.e., FFR close to zero) makes this email Helen.Koshy@chi.frb.org. Chicago Fed
(figure 1, panel A). This occurs despite
exercise problematic. The estimated Letter and other Bank publications are available
a significant reaction of the FFR to the at www.chicagofed.org.
rules clearly do not hold in a period
same CRB shock (panel B). In the ISSN 0895-0164
GDP growth improved in late 2009 and in oil and CRB shown in the bottom price increases tend to slow the econo-
2010, reaching 1.15% for the current panel of figure 3, estimated policy rules my even without any policy rate increases.
quarter. It is important to note that the from the post-Volcker period do not Of course, if commodity and energy
policy rule depends on growth rates and suggest a large response of policy. prices were to lead to a general expec-
contains no GDP or inflation gap vari- tation of a broader increase in inflation,
ables. In this respect it is not a tradition- Conclusion more substantial policy rate increases
al Taylor rule. The modest dependence of policy on would be justified. But assuming there
energy and other commodity prices is a generally high degree of central-
The most important point to take away
implied by our analysis is not surprising. bank credibility, there is no reason for
from figure 3 is that the difference be-
The shares of firm costs accounted for such expectations to develop—in fact,
tween the policy rules with and with-
by energy and commodities are not large in the post-Volcker period, there have
out commodity prices is quite small,
and, in fact, have fallen over time. been no signs that they typically do.
averaging only 40 basis points over the
Moreover, at least in the case of oil,
period. Even with the very large run-up

1 See Allan H. Meltzer, 2011, “Ben Bernanke’s Dynamics, Vol. 14, No. 1, January, pp. 8
These shocks are roughly one standard
’70s show,” Wall Street Journal, February 5, 101–121, for some of the challenges in- deviation for the CRB shock in both sam-
available at http://online.wsj.com/article/­ volved in proceeding with a structural model. ples and in the post-Volcker period for the
SB100014240527487047093045761240337 5
Ben S. Bernanke, Mark Gertler, Mark oil shock. The standard deviation of the
29197172.html. Watson, Christopher A. Sims, and Benjamin oil shock is about five times smaller in the
2
For an elaboration of this view, see M. Friedman, 1997, “Systematic monetary pre-Volcker period, primarily because there
Laurence H. Meyer, 2011, “Inflated wor- policy and the effects of oil price shocks,” is virtually no growth in the oil price over
ries,” New York Times, March 24, available Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. the first half of this sample.
at www.nytimes.com/2011/03/25/opinion/ 1997, No. 1, pp. 91–157. 9
In a figure available on our website, we
25meyer.html?_r=2&ref=opinion. 6
The CRB Commodity Price Index and show that the fitted values of the estimat-
3
We thank Helen Koshy, Spencer Krane, the federal funds rate are quarterly aver- ed policy rules with and without commod-
David Marshall, and Daniel Sullivan for ages of monthly data. The PPI for crude ity prices track actual monetary policy very
improving this article. petroleum is the quarterly average of closely. The figure is located on the Other
monthly data. Core PCE inflation is mea- Resources page at www.chicagofed.org/
4
One could also formulate a structural eco- webpages/people/fisher_jonas_d_m.cfm.
nomic model. See Lawrence J. Christiano, sured as 400 times the log differences in
Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans, the series levels. Growth rates are calcu- 10
That is, from 2009:Q2 forward, the lagged
2005, “Nominal rigidities and the dynamic lated as log first differences. predicted values of FFR are used to calcu-
effects of a shock to monetary policy,” 7
The results are robust to including various late the current- period fitted FFR.
Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 113, No. 1, financial spreads and unemployment, in- 11
We assume annualized GDP growth, annu-
February, pp. 1–45; and Alejandro Justiniano, cluding from two to eight lags, using levels alized core inflation, quarterly growth in
Giorgio Primiceri, and Andrea Tambalotti, or growth rates of the variables, and the CRB, and quarterly growth in oil prices of
2011, “Investment shocks and the relative ordering of the two commodity price ­ 3.3%, 1%, 16.2%, and 12.8%, respectively,
price of investment,” Review of Economic series in the VAR. during 2011:Q1.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen