Sie sind auf Seite 1von 21

Chapter 4

Demand Analysis

• Where does demand come from? How can managers have any predictive tools about how
changes in certain variables will impact their demand?

• Demand ultimate derives from the individual consumer or firm. Consumers demand
products to satisfy their wants and needs. Firms demand products to produce other
goods and services to sell in a market.

• Consumers derive utility from their consumption of goods and services.

• Firms derive profit from their consumption of goods and services.

• It is thought that consumers seek to maximize the utility they gain from consumption
just as firms seek to maximize profit.

• Households are limited in their quest to maximize utility. They only have so much money
to spend on consumption and they face a lot of different wants/needs.

• Ultimately, the income and the prices of the goods determine a household’s choice set. The
income/prices combined with household preferences determine household consumption
bundle.

• The market demand curves are the aggregation of the individual household demand
curves.

• How much does quantity demanded change when there is a change in price (perhaps from
a supply-side influence), a change in income, other prices, population, etc.?

49
50 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

4.1 Elasticity
• Discussing how much quantity demanded changes due to a supply shock or some other
demand shock is difficult to do across markets because prices and other influences on
demand are measured in different units and take on different importance.

• Economists developed the concept of elasticity to get around these problems of units and
market differences.

• An elasticity measures the percentage change in one variable due to a percentage change
in another variable. Elasticity measures are unit-less and can be compared across markets
and time.

• Elasticity is mathematically defined as

%∆Y
%∆X

• A point elasticity is calculated at a particular point on the demand/supply curve and is


written as
%∆Y ∂Y X
²X = =
%∆X ∂X Y

• For example, if ²X = 3 then a 1% increase in X yields a 3% increase in Y (and vice-versa).

• Point elasticities are useful when analyzing a single point on a demand/supply curve.

• At other times we will be working with two different points on a demand/supply curve.
In these cases we use the arc elasticity:

%∆Y ∂Y X̄
²X = =
%∆X ∂X Ȳ
where X̄ is the average X of the two points and Ȳ is the average Y of the two points.

4.1.1 Price Elasticity of Demand


• The most common elasticity used in microeconomics is the own-price elasticity of demand.

• Own-price elasticity measures the percentage change in quantity demanded due to a


percentage change in price:
4.1. ELASTICITY 51

%∆QD ∂QD P
²Pd = =
%∆P ∂P QD

• If ∆Q/∆P → 0 or ∆P/∆Q → −∞ then ²pd → 0 (from below) or demand is relatively


inelastic.

• If ∆Q/∆P → −∞ or ∆P/∆Q → 0 then ²pd → −∞ or demand is relatively elastic.

• If |∆Q/∆P | = |P/Q| then ²pd = −1 or demand is unitary elastic.

• Because the demand curve is downward sloping, and therefore ∆Q/∆P is negative, it is
common to take the absolute value of the price elasticity of demand.

• An example: Assume Q = 60, 000 − 5, 000P . Consider the following scenarios:

P=8 ²pd = −5000(8/20000) = −2 Relatively elastic


P = 10 ²pd = −5000(10/10000) = −5 Relatively elastic
P=2 ²pd = −5000(2/50000) = −1/5 Relatively inelastic
P=6 ²pd = −5000(6/30000) = −1 Unitary elastic

• Generally, the higher the price the more elastic the demand. The lower the price, the
more inelastic (less elastic) the demand.

• How does the price elasticity help managers? Consider the following general results

If |²pd | > 1 Raising price will lower total revenue


If |²pd | = 1 Raising price will not change TR (TR is maximized)
If |²pd | < 1 Raising price will increase total revenue

Perfectly inelastic demand and perfectly elastic demand


52 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

• Total revenue can be written as T R = P × Q which implies that

∆P
MR = Q+P
∆Q

• For most firms, ∆P/∆Q = 0 because the individual firm is very small. However, if we
consider the market for the product:

∆P
≤ 0 ⇒ MR ≤ P
∆Q
∆P
If = 0 ⇒ MR = P
∆Q

• When M R = 0 we have

∆P
P = − Q
∆Q
∆P Q
1 = −
∆Q P
∆Q P
1 = −
∆P Q
P
−1 = ²d

• When M R = 0, T R is maximized and price elasticity of demand is one in absolute value


4.1. ELASTICITY 53

• Elasticity measures can help firms determine optimal pricing so to maximize profit:

Π = TR − TC
mΠ = M R − M C
∆T R ∆P
MR = =P +Q
∆Q ∆Q
" #
Q ∆P
= P 1+
P ∆Q
∆Q P
Recall: ²pd =
∆P Q
54 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

1
⇒ M R = P [1 + ]
²

• From this, when the firm sets M R = M C it obtains

1
P [1 + ] = M C (4.1)
²
MC
P∗ = (4.2)
1 + 1²

• Example: Let a 2% drop in price yield a 4% increase in sales:

+4%
²pd = = −2
−2%

If M C = $100 then
100
P∗ = 1 = $200
1 + −2

If M C = $90 then
90
P∗ = 1 = $180
1 + −2

• Price falls faster than marginal cost because demand is elastic.

• If demand is inelastic, then price would fall slower than marginal cost.

• As costs decline, it is profit enhancing for the firm to lower price and produce more.

• What if ²Pd = −20 and M C = $100?

$100
P∗ = 1 = $105.26
1 + −20

• What if ²Pd = −1000 and M C = $100?

$100
P∗ = 1 = $100.10
1 + −1000

In other words, with very elastic demand there is very little profit. In this example profit
is $0.10 on $100 of cost.

• The greater the demand elasticity, the closer is price to marginal cost.
4.1. ELASTICITY 55

• Why do firms want inelastic demand? Greater markups over marginal cost, for one thing.

• How to reduce price elasticity of demand?

1. Fewer substitutes
2. Greater quality
3. Brand loyalty
4. Infrequent purchases
5. Lower percentage of household budget
6. Expectations that prices will increase dramatically in the future

4.1.2 Examples from the real world


Major League Baseball

• Opening day 2002 for the Montreal Expos: All tickets to the Montreal Expos vs. the
Florida Marlins were $1 and attendance was 34,351.

• The next day, the same two teams played again: average ticket price was $9 and atten-
dance was 4,771.

• With these two games, the price elasticity for the Montreal Expos:

∆Q P̄ −29580 5
²Pd = = = −0.945
∆P Q̄ +8 19561

• In essence, the arc-elasticity between these two prices was negative one.

• Montreal Expos might have been revenue maximizers in their tickets (consistent with
price elasticity equal to one in absolute value).

• Question: Why not price at $1 and make a lot of money on beer?

Price of Oil

• What is the short-run price elasticity of gasoline?

• From the Energy Information Agency (www.eia.gov)


56 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

• Sales to end users, Millions of gallons per day from 2008:


Month Qty Price %∆Q %∆P 1 mo ²Pd 2 mo ²Pd
Jan-08 45,099.00 3.095
Feb-08 46,935.10 3.078 0.041 -0.005 -7.412
Mar-08 46,666.30 3.293 -0.006 0.070 -0.082 0.551
Apr-08 47,662.40 3.507 0.021 0.065 0.328 0.118
May-08 48,092.00 3.815 0.009 0.088 0.103 0.205
Jun-08 47,963.30 4.105 -0.003 0.076 -0.035 0.040
Jul-08 46,912.60 4.114 -0.022 0.002 -9.992 -0.329
Aug-08 47,335.80 3.833 0.009 -0.068 -0.132 0.192
Sep-08 45,027.10 3.756 -0.049 -0.020 2.428 0.451
Oct-08 47,004.00 3.112 0.044 -0.171 -0.256 0.034
Nov-08 45,680.50 2.208 -0.028 -0.290 0.097 -0.028
Dec-08 45,237.20 1.745 -0.010 -0.210 0.046 0.068
Averages 0.001 -0.042 -0.015
• The price elasticity of demand between Feb and March 2008 was -0.08, or essentially zero.
By June 2008, the elasticity had jumped to -10.11 but by November and December it was
essentially zero again.

• In November 2010, only 36,594.8 thousand gallons per day of gasoline were sold in the
United states and the price was 2.859. Compared to November 2008, this implies a
longer-run price elasticity of

∆Q P̄ −9, 085.7 2.208+2.859 5.074


²Pd = = 2
45,680.5+36,594.8 = −13, 808.05 × = −0.860
∆P Q̄ +0.658 2
82.275.3

• Could it be that today our response to changes in the price of gasoline are much more
elastic and therefore do not elicit the same angst as similar price changes did in 2008?
If price of gasoline goes back to $4 do we anticipate that the quantity demanded would
actually increase in equilibrium (in the short run)?

Increasing the Gasoline Tax

• In a 1996 article in the Energy Journal, authors Jonathan Haughton and Soumodip Sarkar
attempt to answer the question of what impact a $1 gasoline tax increase would have on
driving and accidents. They submit that with a gas tax of $1, miles driven would decrease
by up to 12% and fatalities by up to 18%.
4.1. ELASTICITY 57

• How do they get to these results? By estimating and using the own-price elasticity of
gasoline to calculate the impact on gasoline consumption.

• The retail price of gasoline in 1991 was $1.13, of which 28% or $0.32 was tax. Assuming
that the entire tax increase is applied to the price, this means a price increase of $0.68,
or 46%. The long run own-price elasticity of demand for gasoline over a ten-year period
was calculated to be in the range -0.23 to -0.35. Using this knowledge we can calculate
the change in consumption:

Low end: %∆Q/46% = −0.23


%∆Q = −0.23 × 46% = −10.6%
High end: %∆Q/46% = −0.35
%∆Q = −0.35 × 46% = −16.1%

• Without going into the effect on accidents, we can still determine that a gas tax of $1
would have been expected to decrease gas consumption by between 10.6% and 16.1%.

• Source: Haughton, J. and Sarkar, S. (1996), “Gasoline Tax as a Corrective Tax: Estimates
for the United States, 1970-1991,” Energy Journal, 17(2), pp. 103-26.

Escorts vs. Civics

• Ford and Honda cater to the subcompact segment of the automobile market with their
Escort and Civic models, respectively. Are Ford Escort buyers more or less price sensitive
than buyers of Honda Civics? One way to answer this question is to estimate the change
in quantity demanded from a $100 increase in the price of each make. But this does not
compare like with like.

• A consistent way of comparing the price sensitivity of Escort and Civic buyers is to use
the own-price elasticities of the demands. The own-price elasticities of the demands for
Escorts and Civics have been estimated to be both −3.4. For a 1% increase in price, both
groups would reduce purchases by 3.4%.

• Source: Pinelopi Koujianou-Goldberg (1995), “Product Differentiation and Oligopoly in


International Markets: the Case of the U.S. Automobile Industry,” Econometrica, 63(4),
pp. 891-951.
58 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

Higher Education

• From Eric Steger, East Central University. Consider the following table:
Tuition Number Semester Total
Price/ of Hours Semester Total
Hour Students Hours Revenue
$25 4000 15 60,000 60, 000 × 25 = $1, 500, 000
$30 3900 15 58,500 58, 500 × 30 = $1, 755, 000
−1500 30+25
• The elasticity in this example is then = 5 60,000+58,500
= −0.139

• Bezmen and Depken (1998, Economics of Education Review): estimate the short-run
tuition elasticity of enrollment in U.S. public colleges to be -0.02.

4.2 Other Elasticity Measures


4.2.1 Cross Price Elasticity
• This elasticity measures the relative response to the quantity demanded for Good A due
to a relative change in the price of Good X.

• Mathematically this looks like:


%∆QD
A
²xd =
$∆PX
4.2. OTHER ELASTICITY MEASURES 59

• If ²xd < 0: The price of Good X increases and the quantity demand of Good A decreases.
This implies that Good A and Good X are complements in consumption or are used
together.

Examples: iPhones and iPhone docking stations; tennis balls and tennis rackets; cars and
tires; computers and printers.

• If ²xd > 0: The price of Good X increases and the quantity demand of Good A increases.
This implies that Good A and Good X are substitutes in consumption or are used in place
of one another.

Examples: Hondas and Toyotas; Samsung and Sony televisions; Dell and HP computers;

• If ²xd = 0: The price of Good X increases and the quantity demand of Good A does
not change. This implies that Good A and Good X are not related to each other in
consumption or are independent goods.

Examples: Corn and telephones; X-box games and allergy medicine.

There is a saying in America: “What does that have to do with the price of tea in China?”
This would be used in a situation where two things were completely independent of each
other.

• If cross price elasticity is high (positive or negative) then the two goods are strong sub-
stitutes or complements.

• If cross price elasticity is close to zero, then the two goods are weak substitutes or com-
plements.

Cross-price elasticity example: cars and gasoline

• In 2008 the price of gasoline spiked above $4 per gallon. This made a lot of people
reconsider the type of vehicles they would purchase and drive. A New York Times article
from May 2, 2008 provided the following data for select vehicles.

• The April 2007 to April 2008 percentage change in the price of gasoline was (3.458 −
2.845)/2.845 = 21.5%)
60 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

Make Model April 08 Sales %Change from Apr-07 ²xd


Ford F-series 44,813 -27.0 -1.25
Toyota Camry 40,016 -2.6 -0.12
Chevrolet Silverado 37,231 -30.5 -1.42
Honda Accord 35,075 11.9 0.55
Toyota Prius 21,757 53.80 2.50

4.2.2 Income Elasticity of Demand


• The income elasticity of demand reflects the percentage change in the quantity demanded
due to a percentage change in income.

• Mathematically this looks like


%∆QD
²M
d =
%∆M

If ²M
d > 0 ⇒ Normal good
If ²M
d < 0 ⇒ Inferior good
If ²M
d > 1 ⇒ Luxury good
If ²M
d = 1 ⇒ Necessary good
If ²M
d < 1 ⇒ Vital good
4.2. OTHER ELASTICITY MEASURES 61

• Firms are likely concerned about how the demand for their product will change with
exogenous changes in household income. In the current economic slowdown in the United
States, Walmart has experienced an increase in demand whereas Macy’s has experienced
a decline in demand.

• Here is the five year trend line of the stock price for Walmart (blue) and Macy’s (red):

• We can see when times were good, before the recession, Macy’s was doing much better
than Walmart. As times turned bad, Walmart outperformed Macy’s. This suggests that
Macy’s sells normal/luxury goods and Walmart sells inferior goods.

4.2.3 Other elasticities


• Can you think of other elasticities that might be useful to firms?

• Advertising elasticity of demand:

%∆QD
²A
d =
%∆Adv

• We might expect advertising elasticity to be positive and, in equilibrium, less than one.

• Population elasticity of demand

%∆QD
²Pd OP =
%∆P OP

• As population increases we might expect to see quantity demanded increase, holding


technology fixed.
62 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

• If population elasticity is greater than one this would imply network externalities or what
are called relational goods/mob goods.

4.2.4 Advertising
• To explore the concepts of multivariate optimization and the optimal level of advertising,
consider a hypothetical multivariate product demand function for CSI, Inc., where the
demand Q is determined by the price charged, P , and the level of advertising, A:

Q = 5, 000 − 10P + 40A + P A − 0.8A2 − 0.5P 2

where Q is measured in units, P is measured in price, A is measured in hundreds of


dollars.

• When analyzing multivariate relations such as these, one is interested in the marginal
effect of each independent variable on the quantity sold, the dependent variable. Opti-
mization requires an analysis of how a change in each independent variable affects the
dependent variable, holding constant the effect of all other independent variables. The
partial derivative concept is used in this type of marginal analysis.

• In light of the fact that the CSI demand function includes two independent variables, the
price of the product itself and advertising, it is possible to examine two partial derivatives:
the partial of Q with respect to price, or ∂Q/∂P , and the partial of Q with respect to
advertising expenditures, or ∂Q/∂A. In determining partial derivatives, all variables
except the one with respect to which the derivative is being taken remain unchanged. In
this instance, A is treated as a constant when the partial derivative of Q with respect to
P is analyzed; P is treated as a constant when the partial derivative of Q with respect to
A is evaluated. Therefore, the partial derivative of Q with respect to P is:

∂Q/∂P = 0 − 10 + 0 + A − 0 − P = −10 + A − P

The partial with respect to A is:

∂Q/∂A = 0 − 0 + 40 + P − 1.6A − 0 = 40 + P − 1.6A

• Solving these two equations simultaneously yields the optimal price-output-advertising


combination.
4.2. OTHER ELASTICITY MEASURES 63

• Because −10+A−P = 0, P = A−10. Substituting this value for P into 40+P −1.6A = 0,
gives 40 + (A − 10) − 1.6A = 0, which implies that 0.6A = 30 and A = 50 or $5,000.

• Given this value, P = A − 10, 10 = 50 − 10 = $40.

• Inserting these values for P and A into the CSI demand function yields Q = 5, 800.

4.2.5 Problems and Questions


Q4.1 From Ralph T. Byrns:
Describe in words and provide a predicted sign for the following elasticities

1. The TV football game elasticity of divorce rates.


2. The snow elasticity of ski lift ticket sales;
3. The temperature elasticity of lemonade sales;
4. The homerun elasticity of beer sales at a ballpark;
5. The condom elasticity of STDs;
6. Name and describe three additional elasticities of your own.

P4.5 The demand for personal computers can be characterized by the following point elastic-
ities: price elasticity = 5, cross-price elasticity with software = 4, and income elasticity
= 2.5. Indicate whether each of the following statements is true or false, and explain your
answer.

A. A price reduction for personal computers will increase both the number of units
demanded and the total revenue of sellers.
B. The cross-price elasticity indicates that a 5% reduction in the price of personal
computers will cause a 20% increase in software demand.
C. Demand for personal computers is price elastic and computers are cyclical normal
goods.
D. Falling software prices will increase revenues received by sellers of both computers
and software.
E. A 2% price reduction would be necessary to overcome the effects of a 1% decline in
income.

SOLUTION
64 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

A. True. A price reduction always increases units sold, given a downward sloping de-
mand curve. The negative sign on the price elasticity indicates that this is indeed
the case here. The fact that price elasticity equals 5 indicates that demand is elastic
with respect to price, and that a price reduction will increase total revenues.
B. False. The cross-price elasticity indicates that a 5% decrease in the price of software
programs will have the effect of increasing personal computer demand by 20%.
C. True. Demand is price elastic (see part A). Since the income elasticity is positive,
personal computers are a normal good. Moreover, since the income elasticity is
greater than one, personal computer demand is also cyclical.
D. False. Negative cross-price elasticity indicates that personal computers and soft-
ware are compliments. Therefore, falling software prices will increase the demand
for computers and resulting revenues for sellers. However, there is no information
concerning the price elasticity of demand for software, and therefore, one does not
know the effect of falling software prices on software revenues.
E. False. A 2% reduction in price will cause a 10% increase in the quantity of personal
computers demanded. A 1% decline in income will cause a 2.5% fall in demand.
These changes will not be mutually offsetting.

P4.6 In an effort to reduce excess end-of-the-model-year inventory, Harrison Ford offered a 1%


discount off the average price of 4WD Escape Gas-Electric Hybrid SUVs sold during the
month of August. Customer response was wildly enthusiastic, with unit sales rising by
10% over the previous month’s level.

A. Calculate the point price elasticity of demand for Harrison Ford 4WD Escape Gas-
Electric Hybrid SUVs sold during the month of August.
B. Calculate the profit-maximizing price per unit if Harrison Ford has an average whole-
sale (invoice) cost of $23,500 and incurs marginal selling costs of $350 per unit.

SOLUTION

A.

∆Q/Q
² =
∆P/P
= 10%/ − 1%
= −10(Highly elastic)
4.2. OTHER ELASTICITY MEASURES 65

B. The profit-maximizing price can be found using the optimal price formula:

P ∗ = M C/(1 + 1/²P )
= ($23, 500 + $350)/[1 + 1/(−10)]
= $26, 500

P4.7 The South Beach Cafe recently reduced appetizer prices from $12 to $10 for afternoon
”early bird” customers and enjoyed a resulting increase in sales from 90 to 150 orders per
day. Beverage sales also increased from 300 to 600 units per day.

A. Calculate the arc price elasticity of demand for appetizers.

B. Calculate the arc cross-price elasticity of demand between beverage sales and appe-
tizer prices.

C. Holding all else equal, would you expect an additional appetizer price decrease to $8
to cause both appetizer and beverage revenues to rise? Explain.

SOLUTION

A.
∆Q P2 + P1 150 − 90 10 + 12
²p = = = −2.75
∆P Q2 + Q1 10 − 12 150 + 90
B.
∆Q Px2 + Px1 600 − 300 10 + 12
²x = = = −3.67
∆Px Q2 + Q1 10 − 12 600 + 300
C. Yes, the |²p | = 2.75 > 1 calculated in part A implies an elastic demand for appetizers
and that an additional price reduction will increase appetizer revenues. ²x = −3.67 <
0 indicates that beverages and appetizers are complements. Therefore, a further
decrease in appetizer prices will cause a continued growth in beverage unit sales and
revenues.
Alternatively, If P = a + bQ, then $12 = a + b(90) and $10 = a + b(150). Solving
for the demand curve gives P = $15 − $0.033Q. At P = $12, total revenue is
$1, 080(= $1290). If P = $10, total revenue is $1, 500(= $10150). At P = $8,
total revenue is $1, 680(= $8210). In any case, to determine the profit effects of
appetizer price changes it is necessary to consider revenue and cost implications of
both appetizer and beverage sales.
66 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

P4.8 Ironside Industries, Inc., is a leading manufacturer of tufted carpeting under the Ironside
brand. Demand for Ironside’s products is closely tied to the overall pace of building and
remodeling activity and, therefore, is highly sensitive to changes in national income. The
carpet manufacturing industry is highly competitive, so Ironside’s demand is also very
price-sensitive. During the past year, Ironside sold 30 million square yards (units) of
carpeting at an average wholesale price of $15.50 per unit. This year, household income
is expected to surge from $55,500 to $58,500 per year in a booming economic recovery.

A. Without any price change, Ironside’s marketing director expects current-year sales
to soar to 50 million units because of rising income. Calculate the implied income
arc elasticity of demand.

B. Given the projected rise in income, the marketing director believes that a volume of
30 million units could be maintained despite an increase in price of $1 per unit. On
this basis, calculate the implied arc price elasticity of demand.

C. Holding all else equal, would a further increase in price result in higher or lower total
revenue?

SOLUTION

A.
∆Q M1 + M2 50 − 30 58, 500 + 55, 500
²M = = = 9.5
∆M Q1 + Q2 58, 500 − 55, 500 50 + 30
B. Without a price increase, sales this year would total 50 million units. Therefore, it
is appropriate to estimate the arc price elasticity from a before-price-increase base
of 50 million units:

∆Q 30 − 50
²p = P2 + P1 Q1 + Q2 = 16.50 + 15.5030 + 50 = −8
∆P 16.50 − 15.50

C. Lower. Since carpet demand is in the elastic range, ²p = 8, an increase (decrease) in


price will result in lower (higher) total revenues.

P4.9 B. B. Lean is a catalog retailer of a wide variety of sporting goods and recreational
products. Although the market response to the company’s spring catalog was generally
good, sales of B. B. Lean’s $140 deluxe garment bag declined from 10,000 to 4,800 units.
During this period, a competitor offered a whopping $52 off their regular $137 price on
deluxe garment bags.
4.2. OTHER ELASTICITY MEASURES 67

A. Calculate the arc cross-price elasticity of demand for B. B. Lean’s deluxe garment
bag.
B. B. B. Lean’s deluxe garment bag sales recovered from 4,800 units to 6,000 units
following a price reduction to $130 per unit. Calculate B. B. Lean’s arc price elasticity
of demand for this product.
C. Assuming the same arc price elasticity of demand calculated in Part B, determine
the further price reduction necessary for B. B. Lean to fully recover lost sales (i.e.,
regain a volume of 10,000 units).

SOLUTION

A.
4, 800 − 10, 000 85 + 137
²x = = 1.5 (Substitutes)
85 − 137 4, 800 + 10, 000
B.
6, 000 − 4, 800 130 + 140
²p = = −3 (Elastic)
130 − 140 6, 000 + 4, 800
C.
10, 000 − 6, 000 P2 + 130
²p = −3 =
P2 − 130 10, 000 + 6, 000
which implies that

−12P2 + 1, 560 = P2 + 130


13P2 = 1, 430
P2 = $110

This implies a further price reduction of $20 because:

∆P = $130 − $110 = $20

P4.10 Enchantment Cosmetics, Inc., offers a line of cosmetic and perfume products marketed
through leading department stores. Product Manager Erica Kane recently raised the
suggested retail price on a popular line of mascara products from $9 to $12 following
increases in the costs of labor and materials. Unfortunately, sales dropped sharply from
16,200 to 9,000 units per month. In an effort to regain lost sales, Enchantment ran a
coupon promotion featuring $5 off the new regular price. Coupon printing and distribution
costs totaled $500 per month and represented a substantial increase over the typical
68 CHAPTER 4. DEMAND ANALYSIS

advertising budget of $3,250 per month. Despite these added costs, the promotion was
judged to be a success, as it proved to be highly popular with consumers. In the period
prior to expiration, coupons were used on 40% of all purchases and monthly sales rose to
15,000 units.

A. Calculate the arc price elasticity implied by the initial response to the Enchantment
price increase.
B. Calculate the effective price reduction resulting from the coupon promotion.
C. In light of the price reduction associated with the coupon promotion and assuming
no change in the price elasticity of demand, calculate Enchantment’s arc advertising
elasticity.
D. Why might the true arc advertising elasticity differ from that calculated in part C?

SOLUTION

A.
∆Q P1 + P2 9, 000 − 16, 200 12 + 9
²p = = = −2
∆P Q1 + Q2 12 − 9 9, 000 + 16, 200
B. The effective price reduction is $2 since 40% of sales are accompanied by a coupon:

∆P = −$5(0.4) = −2 or P2 = $12 − $5(0.4) = 10

∆P = $10 − $12 = −$2

C. To calculate the arc advertising elasticity, the effect of the $2 price cut implicit in
the coupon promotion must first be reflected. With just a price cut, the quantity
demanded would rise to 13,000, because:

Q∗ − Q1 P 2 + P 1
²p =
P2 − P1 Q∗ + Q1
Q∗ − 9, 000 10 + 12
−2 =
10 − 12 Q∗ + 9, 000
−11(Q∗ − 9, 000
−2 =
Q∗ + 9, 000
−2(Q + 9, 000) = −11(Q∗ − 9, 000)

9Q∗ = 117, 000


Q∗ = 13, 000
4.2. OTHER ELASTICITY MEASURES 69

Then, the arc advertising elasticity can be calculated as:

Q1 − Q∗ A1 + A2
²A =
A2 − A1 Q2 + Q∗
15, 000 − 13, 000 3, 750 + 3, 250
= =1
3, 750 − 3, 250 15, 000 + 13, 000

D. It is important to recognize that a coupon promotion can involve more than just
the independent effects of a price cut plus an increase in advertising as is implied in
Part C. Synergistic or interactive effects may increase advertising effectiveness when
the promotion is accompanied by a price cut. Similarly, price reductions can have a
much larger impact when advertised. In addition, a coupon is a price cut for only the
most price sensitive (coupon-using) customers, and may spur sales by much more
than a dollar equivalent across-the-board price cut. Synergy between advertising
and the implicit price reduction that accompanies a coupon promotion can cause
the estimate in Part C to overstate the true advertising elasticity. Similarly, this
advertising elasticity will be overstated to the extent that targeted price cuts have
a bigger influence on the quantity demanded than similar across-the-board price
reductions, as seems likely.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen