Sie sind auf Seite 1von 12

Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Banking & Finance


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf

Financial instruments with sports betting components: Marketing gimmick


or a domain for behavioral finance?
Wolfgang Breuer *, Guido Hauten, Claudia Kreuz
Department of Finance, RWTH Aachen University, Aachen, Germany

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: We examine theoretically and experimentally a certain class of new financial instruments which are
Received 1 May 2008 designed as lotteries on the outcome of prominent sports events like the Soccer World Cup 2006. From
Accepted 2 June 2009 a theoretical point of view, sports betting products may be superior to a fixed rate investment because of
Available online 6 June 2009
heterogeneous expectations, risk-loving behavior of investors or additional non-monetary utility compo-
nents. In comparison to the direct placement of bets at bookmakers’, sports betting products may be pref-
JEL classification: erable in cases of hedonic framing. Our experimental section, however, reveals the limited practical
G31
relevance of these theoretical arguments for ‘‘average” decision makers. Despite this, financial instru-
G32
G35
ments with sports betting components offer a certain profit potential due to the diversity of preferences
across individuals. Summarizing, the issuance of sports betting products may actually be mainly driven
Keywords: by marketing aspects, nevertheless sports betting products may be considered to be ‘‘viable” niche prod-
Behavioral finance ucts with low cost of capital for banks.
Financial engineering Ó 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Sports betting
Structured products

1. Introduction specialized financial products, e.g. the European Soccer Champion-


ship (for the EURO 2008, see, e.g., Kramer, 2007; Schich, 2008).
What might a big sporting event such as the Soccer World Cup However, as the general product design opportunities are always
in Germany have to do with a descriptive decision theory like the the same, we adhere to the example of the Soccer World Cup
prospect theory? At first glance, certainly very little; at second 2006 as our reference case.
glance, in fact, a great deal. Banks in particular are increasingly With regard to participatory products, these involve participa-
using events of this kind for marketing campaigns, whereby the tion in the economic success of those companies which profit most
spectrum involved ranges from the basic usage of the title of the from the relevant sporting event; in this case, from the Soccer
respective sporting event right up to the supplying of special finan- World Cup. To this end, banks offer baskets of shares from suitable
cial instruments that are in one way or another connected to it. companies in the form of funds or certificates. Examples of partic-
With regard to the latter, two product varieties in particular ipatory products are the Frankfurt Trust Fund’s ‘‘FT Big Sports”, the
emerged during the course of the Soccer World Cup 2006 in WestLB Bank’s ‘‘WM-Select-Zertifikat 7/06” and the Commerz-
Germany. We shall refer to them here simply as ‘‘participatory prod- bank’s ‘‘Top 11 Zertifikat”. The sphere of selected companies varies
ucts” and ‘‘sports betting products”. Such financial instruments are in accordance with who is offering the financial product, so that
by no means limited to the German capital market (see, e.g., De- sponsors and manufacturers of sports goods, but also construction
Jong, 2006, for Korea and Baumann, 2006, for Switzerland). For and travel companies, might be included in the basket of shares.
simplicity reasons, however, we restrict our further exposition to The creation of a portfolio of this kind is only sensible if the capital
financial products of this kind that are issued on the German cap- market is not informationally efficient in the semi-strong sense. In
ital market, although our findings will be of general relevance. other words, commonly available information about the company
Moreover, besides the Soccer World Cup, there are other big sport- in question being in some way related to the sporting event under
ing events which one can use as the starting point for the design of consideration must not find its way directly into the share prices.
Generally speaking, it is highly unlikely that this condition will
be fulfilled, since an event like the Soccer World Cup could never
* Corresponding author. Tel.: +49 241 80 93539; fax: +49 241 80 92163.
E-mail addresses: wolfgang.breuer@bfw.rwth-aachen.de (W. Breuer), guido.
‘‘suddenly” materialize. We should expect that capital market par-
hauten@bfw.rwth-aachen.de (G. Hauten), claudia.kreuz@bfw.rwth-aachen.de (C. ticipants would adapt their supply and demand behavior compar-
Kreuz). atively well to sporting events and the yields therefrom for

0378-4266/$ - see front matter Ó 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.06.001
2242 W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252

particular firms. The resulting price effects imply that a special tive market success of these instruments, a more rigorous analysis
portfolio selection strategy which focuses on shares of this kind would certainly be preferable. As empirical data seems to be hard
has little prospect of realizing positive excess returns. to find, we want to address this issue by way of an experimental
The focus of our analysis will thus be on the second important design. By confronting 385 students of our university with differ-
product variety linked to the Soccer World Cup: Sports betting prod- ent decision situations, we have the opportunity to assess the
ucts as a specific form of structured products (for recent studies on relevance of heterogeneous expectations, risk-loving behavior, non-
other structured products see, e.g., Wilkens and Stoimenov, 2007; monetary utility components as well as hedonic framing. Since we
Entrop et al., 2009). A key characteristic of sports betting products refer to cumulative prospect theory (CPT henceforth) as our refer-
is that the respective investors receive a rate of return which de- ence for descriptive decision making, we are also able to contribute
pends on the outcome of the World Cup, whereby typically, it is to the growing literature that examines the practical relevance of
the performance of the German national soccer team that is para- CPT in financial decision making (see, e.g., Erner et al., 2008).
mount. On the one hand, this might simply be a marketing gimmick Summarizing, we find that – compared to situations with
(in fact, this perception actually seems to be the predominant one of homogeneous expectations as a consequence of exogenously given
practitioners; see, e.g., Mildenberger, 2006; Weiss, 2006; or N.N., probabilities – heterogeneous expectations reduce the demand for
2006). On the other hand, the placement of this kind of instrument sports betting products because of ambiguity effects. Moreover, the
may be understood as a (special, but nevertheless) ‘‘serious” form behavior of ‘‘average decision makers” according to CPT differs
of fund-raising – one which, naturally, has to be financially attractive considerably from the behavior that is actually observable. Non-
for the customer as lender and cost effective for the bank as bor- monetary utility components per se do not play a relevant role,
rower. These two motivations are not mutually exclusive, since but there may be an indirect effect via influencing an investor’s
the more successful the market placement of a finance instrument probability assessments.
of this kind, the more likely a positive marketing effect will be. Up Even without non-monetary utility aspects, with homogeneous
to now, the literature has failed to examine this ‘‘other” view in expectations being in effect and with CPT not being valid, a consid-
any detail, and this paper intends to rectify this omission. erable share of students acts in a risk-loving manner. Although, be-
Unlike the case of conventional deposits with a fixed rate of cause of this diversity in preferences, sports betting products could
interest, with sports betting products there is the problem of an thus be viable even in the light of alternative fixed rate invest-
additional source of risk in the determination of the rate of return, ments, they face the problem of competing with the direct place-
which is practically independent of other cash flows for most ment of bets, as aspects of hedonic framing do not seem to be
investors and also for the issuing bank. Thus, there is no room very important. Moreover, risk-loving behavior seems to be best
for monetary hedging motives as a justification for the supply or exploited by mimicking the direct placements of bets, e.g., through
demand of the relevant financial instrument. Things may be differ- simple binary lotteries, which are quite prone to misestimations of
ent if we take other utility generating sources than money into ac- success probabilities. With bookmakers having a comparative
count. For example, individuals may utilize sports betting to hedge advantage over banks in estimating the probabilities of potential
the disappointment of an unsuccessful outcome of an event they outcomes of sporting events, this problem certainly limits the po-
are emotionally attached to, such as the performance of the Ger- tential success of financial instruments with sports betting compo-
man team in the Soccer World Cup. However, if we restrict our- nents. Against this background, one may indeed consider these
selves to situations where only money counts, then, as a instruments to be niche products that function as marketing gim-
consequence, in the case of homogeneous, that is, identical expec- micks, which explains their quite impressive presence in market-
tations of the investors and of the issuer of a sports betting prod- ing campaigns, but at the same time – and to a limited degree –
uct, the latter’s expected rate of return cannot be attractive for they may also serve as serious financing means with lower cost
both contractual parties at the same time if a specific fixed interest of capital than other financial sources.
rate for the same maturity is available and all participants are risk- The rest of the paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, we
neutral or risk-averse. Every time one of the two participants fa- give a more thorough description of sports betting products. In
vors the sports betting product on account of its expected rate of Section 3, we present our theoretical analysis, while Section 4 is
return over a fixed interest rate instrument, the other party will devoted to the experimental verification of our hypotheses. Section
take just the converse view. To sum up, then, there are only three 5 concludes.
possible reasons for why a sports betting product can simulta-
neously be advantageous to a simple fixed rate investment in the
view of both lenders and borrowers: (1) different expectations 2. Financial instruments with sports betting components
with regard to the probabilities of possible outcomes of a sports
event, which are relevant to the resulting contractual rate of inter- In general, sports betting products consist of two interest com-
est, (2) risk-seeking behavior of at least one of the participants, and ponents: One is a fixed base interest rate r and the other is an
(3) other utility generating sources than money. uncertain bonus payment b ~ P 0 that depends on the outcome of
However, even in the light of these three reasons it remains un- a predefined sporting event. The various products differ in particu-
clear why sports betting products should be preferred to a simple ~ An example of a
lar with respect to the probability distribution of b.
direct placement of bets at bookmakers’. In fact, in situations with financial product with a rate of return which depends on the suc-
individuals having different mental monetary accounts at the same cess of the German national soccer team, is that which was offered
time with integration and segregation among them, according to by the Dresdner Bank: a money market account with a bonus of
certain so-called hedonic framing rules, there may be a relevant 0.75% p.a., should Germany win the World Cup title. Here, as with
difference between sports betting products and direct sports bets. other products, the maximum permissible investment amount was
According to personal information supplied to the authors by restricted (to 20,000 €) and the time period for the potential bonus
the sales director of a Sparkasse bank, the bank successfully sold interest payment was also limited (up to August 31, 2006). The
the ‘‘Sparkassen-KickTipp” (a sports betting product issued by Postbank’s ‘‘Fifa WM 2006 Weltmeister Zertifikat” and the ‘‘DZ
the Sparkasse banks) to private investors, but the overall issuance 11,0 Champion MaxiRend Tracker” not only both have unwieldy
amount was considerably lower than that of traditional fixed term names even for German speakers, they are also participatory prod-
deposit offers during the respective time period. Although such a ucts in the aforementioned sense and they both guaranteed extra
statement is mere anecdotical evidence of a limited, though posi- interest payments subject to the respective World Cup winner
W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252 2243

2006. However, for further deliberations, the ‘‘Postbank Bonus Vol- March 2006 (see time series SUD 102 according to the Deutsche
ltreffer” and the ‘‘Sparkassen-KickTipp” (SKT, henceforth) would Bundesbank, 2008). Apparently, the time deposit offer by the Kre-
appear to be the most interesting. For the former, the Postbank issparkasse Bautzen is rather low, implying a reduced attractive-
guaranteed a base rate of return of 1.75% p.a., with a 0.75% point ness of the SKT in comparison to an average time deposit in
increase for every game won by the German team. A further March 2006. Investors who are willing to leave the Sparkasse Bank
0.75% point increase in interest payments was also possible if a as a customer may thus assume a higher interest rate than 1.90% or
German player were to become top goal scorer. Each customer 2.15% for riskless time deposits.
was able to invest 2500 €, 5000 €, 7500 €, or 10,000 €, and a maxi- Obviously, under such conditions, risk-averse investors will ac-
mum of 9999 contracts were sold. The maturity time of the extra cept the SKT only in the case of heterogeneous expectations. The
rate of return was set at July 17, 2006. The Postbank also offered SKT, version A, is of interest for such investors who believe quite
a ‘‘Bonus Volltreffer” at the 2004 European Soccer Championship, strongly in the success of the German soccer team, while investors
and the SKT for the World Cup 2006 appears to have been modeled with more pessimistic assessments of the strength of the German
on the former’s structural characteristics. The minimum invest- soccer team would prefer the SKT, version B. The SKT, versions A
ment amount for the SKT was 2500 €. At a minimum maturity time and B, thus should be particularly interesting in a situation with
of 12 months and a base rate of return of 1.50% p.a., a bonus pay- pronounced heterogeneous expectations. However, in such situa-
ment was granted for the first 6 months, subject to the German tions, there seems to be much uncertainty or ‘‘ambiguity” with re-
team’s success in the tournament. The SKT was available in two spect to the ‘‘true” values of the probabilities of future states of
varieties, both of which are described in Table 1. In this context, nature. Therefore, ambiguity aversion, as introduced by Ellsberg
we have already taken into account that the bonus payment was (1961), may become an issue and prevent investors from buying
only promised for six out of 12 months minimum maturity so that the SKT to a large extent in situations with heterogeneous
the extra interest rate on a yearly basis is but half the value granted expectations.
for six months. In version A, interest rates are increasing, as the For homogeneous expectations and risk-averse behavior, the
German soccer team forges ahead in the tournament. In contrast, SKT may be acceptable as a hedging device in situations with
version B offers the highest interest rates in the case of an early non-monetary utility components. For supporters of the German
failure of the German team. soccer team, in particular the SKT, version B, would offer monetary
The Sparkasse banks had already offered other products with compensations if the German soccer team drops out in an early
sports betting components. For example, in 2006, the ‘‘Sparkasse stage of the tournament, and thus offers some kind of insurance.
KölnBonn” was offering investments with interest payments, In contrast, from this point of view, a demand by German investors
which were linked to the success of the German soccer team ‘‘1. for the SKT, version A, hardly seems to be justifiable. However, the
FC Köln” and the German basketball team ‘‘Telekom Baskets Bonn”. SKT, version A, offers high returns in cases where supporters of the
Our further investigations, however, will be directed towards the German team realize additional non-monetary utility components.
SKT, since it represents the most differentiated form of sports bet- Unless these investors are able to separate these two aspects, they
ting products. may accept smaller expected rates of return for the SKT, version A,
than for the SKT, version B. To sum up, the influence of non-mon-
3. The SKT, riskless investments, and the direct placements of etary utility components on the attractiveness of sports betting
sports bets: theory products is not unambiguous and needs further examination in
Section 4.
From an investor’s point of view, one at least has to compare the A third possible explanation for preferring sports betting prod-
SKT with a simple fixed interest rate investment and – as a pecu- ucts, although their expected rate of return is smaller than that
liarity of sports betting products – with the direct placement of of a simple fixed interest rate investment, would be risk-loving
sports bets at bookmakers’. With regard to the first aspect, the Kre- behavior on the investors’ side. In particular, CPT as developed
issparkasse Bautzen, for example, which decided to offer its cus- by Kahneman and Tversky (1979) and Tversky and Kahneman
tomers the SKT, was, at the same time, also offering its (1992) implies an overweighting of small probabilities for extreme
customers an interest rate of 1.90% for a minimum investment of outcomes, which may lead to risk-loving behavior.
5000 € and 2.15% for one of more than 10,000 € in a time deposit As a peculiarity of sports betting products, it is generally possi-
with maturity of one year. Under the assumption of risk-neutral ble to replicate them by placing bets at bookmakers’. For example,
behavior on the bank’s side, the SKT would only be an interesting Table 1 presents the odds for the German national team as offered
financing instrument for an expected interest rate smaller than by the Internet bookmaker ‘‘Betandwin” on March 31, 2006.
1.90% (or 2.15%). In contrast, investors will at least compare the Against this background, a potential investor planning to invest
SKT with a simple time deposit investment at the Sparkasse bank 10,000 € in the SKT, version A, can also achieve the same payment
and – in the case of risk-averse behavior – only accept expected consequences by, on the one hand, investing 10,0001.015/
rates greater than 1.90% (or 2.15%). In fact, this seems to be only 1.019 = 9960.75 € at the fixed interest rate of 1.90% and addition-
a rather careful estimation of necessary minimum expected rates ally placing suitable amounts on the German national soccer
of return, as statistics of the Deutsche Bundesbank (the German team’s future performance. For instance, a stake of about 3.90 €
central bank) state an average interest rate for households’ time on Germany being knocked out in the round of 16 would, were it
deposits with an agreed maturity of up to one year of 2.29% in to happen, bring in a win of 12.50 € – which would correspond

Table 1
Conditions for the SKT and odds offered by ‘‘Betandwin” (valid on March 31, 2006) according to the stage reached by the German team in the Soccer World Cup 2006.

(1) Stage reached First-round knockout Round of 16 knockout Quarter-finals knockout Semi-finals knockout Vice world champion World champion
(2) Version A (%) 1.50 1.625 1.75 1.875 2.00 2.50
(3) Version B (%) 2.50 2.00 1.875 1.75 1.625 1.50
(4) Odds 1:7 1:3.2 1:3.6 1:4.75 1:10 1:9

This table presents interest rates p.a. for both versions of the SKT and odds offered by the Internet bookmaker ‘‘Betandwin” on 03/31/2006 depending on the stage reached by
the German team in the Soccer World Cup 2006.
2244 W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252

to the respective bonus payment when holding the SKT. Analo- For (plausible) value functions in line with CPT, it is well known
gously, one could proceed likewise for the other potential results, that segregation will pay when the overall outcome Dx + Dy consists
and it materializes that betting stakes totaling 34.84 € and, alto- of two gains Dx > 0 and Dy > 0 and is always unfavorable for two po-
gether, an amount of (only) 9995.59 €, would suffice to replicate tential losses Dx < 0 and Dy < 0 because of the concavity of the value
the SKT, version A (see Table 2). Certainly, there are other possible function in the region of gains and its convexity in the region of
replicating strategies, but they all require lower levels of riskless losses. Integration will also be favorable for a combination of rather
investments and higher betting stakes. Since, for a certain return high gains and moderate losses. Breuer and Perst (2007) argue that
of 1 €, bets amounting to 1.1548 € have to be placed, the reproduc- in the case of a combination of an uncertain outcome D~ x with possi-
tion of the SKT will be least expensive when maximizing the uti- ble realizations Dx1, Dx2, ... , DxN with a certain outcome Dy, hedonic
lized amount of riskless investment. We do not consider framing should be considered state-dependent, i.e., for each state of
potential additional interest earnings arising from the intermedi- nature, decision makers separately choose between segregation and
ate investment of the betting profits here, but as they would not integration of Dxi (i = 1, . . . , N) and Dy. Under this assumption, it is
be likely to exceed 1 €, we will not heed them in the following. It clear that both kinds of investments, the purchase of the SKT and
is obvious that a fully rational investor will not accept the SKT in its replication through the direct placement of bets, become more
version A for whatever the degree of risk aversion might be. For attractive in comparison to a (pure) fixed term deposit. However,
reproducing version B, betting stakes of 46.85 € and a fixed term it is important to note that decision makers will assess a sports bet-
deposit of 9960.75 € – in total 10,007.60 € are necessary (see once ting product not essentially in the same way, even with the same
again Table 2). This amount is higher than that for version A be- payment consequences, as the corresponding replicating strategies,
cause the prospects of the German national team were – from because the type of mental accounting is not necessarily identical.
the viewpoint of 03/31/2006 – not particularly promising. How- For the SKT, one mental account for the riskless base interest pay-
ever, even a small increase of the relevant riskless interest rate of ment of 1.50% would be expected and a second one for the suc-
fixed investments to only 1.9778% would render replication less cess-related bonus payment, but the mental accounts for the
expensive than a purchase of the SKT, version B. The direct place- replicating strategy would arise from the fixed term deposit on the
ment of sports bets thus seems to be another ‘‘serious” alternative one hand and from the income from the implemented sports bets
to investing in the SKT. on the other. The first manner of mental accounting is relatively
Nevertheless, even in situations with replicating costs below more advantageous, since only gains are possible (implying utility
10,000 €, the SKT in particular and sports betting products in gen- increasing segregations), as, in any case, there are only ‘‘bonus pay-
eral may offer an advantage over the direct placements of bets to ments” in addition to the base interest rate. To be more precise, with
make them sufficiently attractive. To be more specific, so-called xinit as an individual’s initial wealth, for version A of the SKT we
hedonic framing is important for both the sports betting products would have Dy = xinit0.015, because this describes the interest gain
and the corresponding replicating strategies. Thaler (1980) and for an initial wealth (and thus reference point) xinit, and
Tversky and Kahneman (1981) pointed out that decision makers Dxi 2 {0, xinit0.00125, xinit0.0025, xinit0.00375, xinit0.005, xinit0.01}
do not always regard simultaneously occurring income conse- for these are the possible bonus payments. In fact, for sports betting
quences of an alternative in an aggregated (‘‘integrated”) manner products with b ~ P 0 with certainty – as is the case with SKT – segre-
– such as would be expected with unlimited rationality. In con- gation is optimal for all (here: six) possible states of nature under
trast, it may be the case that a separate (‘‘segregated”) assessment consideration. Even a state-independent decision between segrega-
of the individual income consequences on different ‘‘mental ac- tion and integration would thus lead to the same subjective
counts” occurs. Following Thaler (1985, 1999) and with v() as an valuation.
individual’s subjective value function and Dx and Dy as two differ- In the case of the replicating strategy, however, all values
ent (riskless) monetary consequences (defined as changes in com- of Dxi have to be reduced by the overall ‘‘investment” in sports
parison to two separately considered initial wealth levels x and y), bets, which is sb = xinit(0.00125/3.2 + 0.0025/3.6 + 0.00375/4.75 +
both realized at the same time, the decision maker chooses be- 0.005/10 + 0.01/9)  xinit0.0034856542, and hence implies losses
tween integration and segregation in such a way that the subjec- in comparison to the possible earnings from placing these bets in
tively highest possible value results: the case of a first-round knockout, a knockout of the German team
in the round of 16, and a quarter-finals knockout. For these three
v ðDx&DyÞ :¼ maxfv ðDx þ DyÞ; v ðDxÞ þ v ðDyÞg ð1Þ outcomes, state-dependent hedonic framing therefore only leads

Table 2
Replicating SKT (versions A and B).

Stage reached First-round Round of 16 Quarter-finals Semi-finals Vice World World


knockout knockout knockout knockout Champion champion
(1) SKT A (10,000 €) 10,150.00 € 10,162.50 € 10,175.00 € 10,187.50 € 10,200.00 € 10,250.00 €
(2) Income from riskless investment (9960.75 €) at 1.90% 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 €
(3) Necessary income from betting ((1)–(2)) 0.00 € 12.50 € 25.00 € 37.50 € 50.00 € 100.00 €
(4) Necessary amount of betting ((3) divided by the respective odds 0.00 € 3.90 € 6.94 € 7.89 € 5.00 € 11.11 €
according to row 4 of Table 1)
(5) Total amount of betting (sum of (4)) 34.84 €
(6) SKT B (10,000 €) 10,250.00 € 10,200.00 € 10,187.50 € 10,175.00 € 10,162.50 € 10,150.00 €
(7) Income from riskless investment (9960.75 €) at 1.90% 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 € 10,150.00 €
(8) Necessary income from betting ((6)–(7)) 100.00 € 50.00 € 37.50 € 25.00 € 12.50 € 0.00 €
(9) Necessary amount of betting ((8) divided by the respective odds 14.29 € 15.62 € 10.42 € 5.26 € 1.25 € 0.00 €
according to row 4 of Table 1)
(10) Total amount of betting (sum of (9)) 46.85 €

One can replicate an investment of 10,000 € in the SKT, version A, by investing 9960.75 € at a riskless interest rate of 1.90% and additionally placing suitable bets on the
various possible outcomes of the Soccer World Cup 2006 for the German national team. In total, 9960.75 + 34.84 = 9995.59 € are needed. It is possible to apply the same
procedure to replicate the SKT, version B, incurring total costs of 9960.75 + 46.85 = 10,007.60 €.
W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252 2245

to integration instead of segregation, which makes replicating but at the same time increase the bonus. We may call this a ‘‘bonus
strategies less attractive than the direct purchase of the SKT. The payment upgrade”. A second shortcoming of sports betting prod-
same conclusion holds true in the case of state-independent hedo- ucts lies in their lack of flexibility. By placing bets at bookmakers’,
nic framing, as in this case resulting CPT values for replicating an individual is able to design payment structures according to his
strategies are typically even lower than in the case of state-depen- or her specific preferences. This may imply some kind of control
dent hedonic framing. Moreover, in the case of hedonic framing, it illusion on the investor’s side (see for this term, e.g., Langer and
does not suffice to compare replicating costs with the investment Roth, 1975) which makes sports bets particularly attractive.
of 10,000 € in the SKT, as replicating costs below that amount do Enhancing the flexibility of sports betting products regarding their
not necessarily imply the superiority of a replicating strategy payment structure characteristics may thus increase their market
(while it still holds true that replication strategies requiring more chances. We might call such measures ‘‘flexibility enhancements”.
than 10,000 € are in any case inferior). Therefore, in situations with The considerations of this section suggest that sports betting prod-
replicating costs smaller than 10,000 €, one has to take into ac- ucts under bounded investor rationality may indeed have a right to
count the overall CPT value from the replicating strategy and the exist, but that there may also be potentials to make them even
additional investment of the difference between the replicating more attractive for investors. However, one should note that our
costs and the initial wealth of 10,000 €. For the replication strategy, findings will not be restricted to the assessment of the SKT, but
Dy thus changes to (xinitsb)0.019, as we have to assume a con- they will be of relevance for the whole class of sports betting prod-
stant given initial wealth, which is risklessly invested unless it is ~ with b
ucts that offer an overall interest rate of the kind r þ b ~ being
needed for the placement of sports bets. It should be clear that dependent on the outcome of a sporting event. Nevertheless, as
all these implications also hold true with respect to the SKT, ver- empirical evidence regarding the real-life importance of such
sion B. financial instruments is rather scarce, we rely on an experimental
Summarizing, with the SKT (version A or version B), only favor- design to analyze the relevance of our theoretical considerations of
able segregations are possible, whereas the perceived losses in the this section.
case of the replicating strategy enforce the retention of integration
– as with the case of unlimited rationality – at least for some states
of nature, when applying state-dependent hedonic framing. In the 4. Experimental evidence
case of state-independent hedonic framing, the assumed state-
independent decision between integration and segregation typi- In order to assess whether the theoretical findings of the pre-
cally implies even lower subjective valuations for the replication ceding section are actually relevant for real-life decision making
strategy. Therefore, with hedonic framing, the SKT becomes more in retail banking, we perform a computer-based experiment with
interesting in comparison to a simple fixed term deposit and in 385 students from different study programs at our university.
comparison to a direct placement of sports bets at bookmakers’. These students all have in common the fact that they have at-
This is the fourth general theoretical result regarding the attrac- tended the basic compulsory lecture ‘‘Capital Budgeting” and are
tiveness of sports betting products. thus at best at the beginning of their studies in the field of finance.
However, we have to concede that financial instruments like Table 3 summarizes some general descriptive statistics. In particu-
the SKT may have at least two shortcomings in comparison to sim- lar, we ask all these students to tell us their age, the number of uni-
ple sports bets. As payments do not vary much across states, this versity semesters already completed, their sex, their financial
does not exploit the overweighting of small probabilities to the knowledge and their interest in soccer (the latter two based on
same extent as in the case of simple binary bets on a certain event several questions, the answers to which are transformed into a
like betting on ‘‘Germany will become Soccer World Champion number from 0 to 10). Moreover, as a consequence of some consis-
2006”. Therefore, in order to make sports betting products attrac- tency checks undertaken by asking the same questions twice in dif-
tive, one may reduce the number of states with bonus payments, ferent parts of the questionnaire, we are compelled to eliminate 50

Table 3
Some descriptive statistics regarding the participants of the experiment.

Three hundred and eighty-five students are questioned regarding their preferences for several sports betting products. The answers of 50 students are excluded from the
analysis because of too pronounced inconsistencies. However, the sample with and without the exclusion of these 50 students exhibits almost identical characteristics.
a
‘‘Financial knowledge” is scaled to numbers between 0 and 10 and determined in the following way: We award up to 5 points for previous vocational training (depending
on the relationship of such to financial issues), 4 points for any other previous financial education and 1 point if financial decisions are mainly made on one’s own.
b
‘‘Interest in soccer” is scaled to numbers between 0 and 10 and determined in the following way: We award up to 6 points for the general interest in soccer (0 to 6 points,
multiplied by a number between 0.1 and 1, depending on the amount of time spent on soccer), up to 2.5 points, if the proband has a favorite team in the first German
soccer division (0 to 2.5 points, multiplied by a number between 0.1 and 1, depending on the amount of time spent on that team), 1 point for the possession of a season
ticket for that team, and 1 point if there has already been a registration at a sports betting company. With this distribution of points, the maximum value reached is 9.25
points, so we scale all numbers with a factor of 10/9.25 at the end.
2246 W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252

students from our analysis whose answers cast some doubt upon first round, i.e. becoming ‘‘Herbstmeister” (case 7). In both cases
the seriousness of their participation, since quantitative deviations we simply speak of a binary lottery (see rows 3 and 7 of Table 4)
in answers for the same questions are greater than 25%. However, and we take it into account in order to examine the welfare conse-
the sample after the elimination of these 50 students does not dif- quence of bonus payment upgrades in comparison to the ‘‘original”
fer significantly from the sample before this adjustment. BKT.
We ask all the students to answer several questions with re- Finally, we offer a fourth financial product consisting of 9715 €
spect to the desirability of certain financial instruments. In the first riskless investment at 1.90% (in order to avoid too high possible
part of our experiment (‘‘PART 1” in Table 4), we simply postulate losses or gains for the students) plus 285 € at the students’ free dis-
the existence of six (abstract) future states of nature with certain posal for additional riskless investments at 1.90% or for placing
exogenously given probabilities, as displayed in Table 4. In the sec- bets on the different states of nature (see rows 4 and 8 of Table
ond part (‘‘PART 2” in Table 4), we interpret these future states of 4). Once again, we formulate this decision problem for both exog-
nature as the possible outcomes of the first round (i.e. after seven- enous probabilities (case 4) and subjectively estimated ones by the
teen matches for each of the eighteen teams) of the first German students themselves (case 8). The consideration of these two cases
soccer division (the ‘‘Bundesliga”) so that students are forced to enables us to find out something about expected rates of return
estimate subjective probabilities by themselves. We present stu- when subjectively optimal payment structures are achievable.
dents’ average probability estimates for part 2 of our experiment Moreover, it is possible to analyze the relevance of flexibility
in Table 4. We introduce these two different settings to find out enhancements, as defined in the previous section.
whether ambiguity and/or differences in interest in soccer may In cases 1–3 and 5–7, we vary the corresponding base payment
lead to different behavior in both decision situations. x so that a student becomes indifferent between the financial
For both parts of the experiment, students have to evaluate four instrument under consideration and a riskless investment at an
different financial instruments (cases 1–4 for a situation with exog- interest rate of 1.90%. In cases 4 and 8, each student determines
enously given probabilities, cases 5–8 for a situation with subjec- the overall amount of his or her riskless investment and his or
tively estimated probabilities). We start with the introduction of a her additional bets on the different states of nature with the help
financial product that resembles the SKT, version A, as there are of an Excel-like spreadsheet.
six different states of nature with different rates of return. In case Our main interest is in the resulting overall required minimum
5, we introduce this financial instrument as a so-called (fictitious) expected rates of return for the first three financial instruments in
‘‘Bundesliga-KickTipp” (‘‘BKT” henceforth), as it offers different each of the two different settings under consideration. Moreover,
rates of return depending on the outcome of the first round of the with the help of cases 4 and 8, we want to find out which expected
German first soccer division. In case 1, with abstract future states rates of return are acceptable when decision makers are somewhat
of nature, we refrain from explicitly naming this instrument (as well freer in designing their payment structures. For the sake of simplic-
as the other three) in our questionnaire. Nevertheless, in the follow- ity, we speak in all eight cases of ‘‘minimum required expected
ing, for reasons of simplicity, we speak of the BKT for both cases 1 rates of return”, although in cases 4 and 8, these are actually opti-
and 5. In our experiment, we present the overall payment structure mal expected rates of return for the decision problems under
of the BKT in a disaggregated manner consisting of a base payment x consideration.
and state-dependent bonus payments b ~ in order to allow for We question 90 students (77 after elimination of students with
potential hedonic framing effects (see rows 1 and 5 of Table 4). inconsistent answers) on the spot in a computer room of our uni-
The second financial product we offer also consists of a state- versity, while the other 295 students (258 after the elimination of
independent base payment x and additional state-dependent pay- students with inconsistent answers) take part online, working
ments. In contrast to the BKT, we reduce all these state-dependent from their personal computer at home. Participation in the exper-
payments by 34.20 € and, thus, there are three states which actu- iment is voluntary. We promise all students some bonus points for
ally imply penalties for the investor (see rows 2 and 6 of Table their final exam when ‘‘seriously” answering the questions. We
4). We present this financial product as a combination of a riskless point out to the participants that there are in general no correct
investment and the placement of bets at a fictitious bookmaker (as or wrong answers as long as the participants are truly trying to re-
‘‘real” odds are not available) for the situation with exogenous veal their preferences, but that we would interpret greater incon-
probabilities (case 2) and subjectively estimated ones by the stu- sistencies as a potential lack of seriousness in answering the
dents (case 6). Apparently, those bets may lead to additional losses questions.
or gains. We fix the relevant odds (as displayed in the first line of Moreover, we additionally promise on-site participants some
Table 4) in such a way that in the case of exogenous probabilities monetary incentive of about 20 € on average, depending on the
about 1.15 € is necessary in order to generate 1 € certain income ‘‘success” of their investment strategy. We determine payments
from sports bets, as this relation held at the end of March 2006 by randomly selecting one of the financial instruments for which
for the odds offered by ‘‘Betandwin”, according to Section 3 of a student has revealed his or her preferences. In the case of the
our paper. For the situation with probability assessments by the selection of one of the four financial products with payments
students, we keep these odds, since the probabilities of the first depending on the outcome of the German Bundesliga, we base
part of our experiment are identical to our (i.e., the authors’) payoffs on the real results as available on December 14, 2008. With
subjective assessments of the outcome of the first round of the a fictitious ‘‘initial wealth” of 10,000 €, for each 20 € of interest
Bundesliga. For both cases 2 and 6, in what follows, we simply payment from the respective financial instrument, a student gets
speak of a ‘‘replicating strategy” with respect to the BKT. By way 1 € ‘‘real” payoff. Moreover, there is a fixed payment per student
of these two cases, we want to examine the relevance of hedonic of 10 € in order to prevent students from ending up with a negative
framing, as a simple increase of x by 34.20 € in cases 2 and/or 6 overall income from their participation in the experiment. Our on-
would ceteris paribus merely replicate the overall payments line experiment took place from November 6 to November 8, 2008,
achievable by any BKT in cases 1 and/or 5. 3.00 p.m., with six out of 17 matches for each team left before the
The third financial product is a straightforward binary lottery completion of the first round (the scores of the Bundesliga teams as
with an exogenous success probability of 24.04% in the situation of 11/06/2008 are available as Table Ad1 from the authors on
with given probabilities (case 3). In the second part of our request and were accessible to all students during the experiment).
experiment, it is a bet on Bayern Munich (the most prominent The on-site experiment took place on November 8, 2008, from
German soccer team) reaching the top of the Bundesliga after the 10.00 a.m. to 2.00 p.m.
Table 4
Decision situations under consideration.

Six future states of nature with s1 (odds 1:6.5) s2 (odds 1:3.5) s3 (odds 1:3.6) s4 (odds 1:4.3) s5 (odds 1:8.9) s6 (odds 1:10.7)
. . . either . . .
Part 1
. . .exogenous probabilities. . .(cases 1–4) p1 = 0.1331 p2 = 0.2472 p3 = 0.2404 p4 = 0.2012 p5 = 0.0972 p6 = 0.0809
(1) ‘‘Bundesliga-KickTipp” (CASE 1) x € base interest payment and 0 € x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest
bonus payment and 12.5 € payment and 25 € bonus payment and 37.5 € payment and 50 € bonus payment and 100 €
bonus bonus bonus

W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252


(2) Given replication of BKT (CASE 2) x € base interest payment and 34.20 € x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest
penalty payment and 21.70 € payment and 9.20 € payment and 3.30 € payment and 15.80 € payment and 65.80 €
penalty penalty bonus bonus bonus
(3) Binary lottery (CASE 3) 0 € interest payment 0 € interest payment x € interest payment 0 € interest payment 0 € interest payment 0 € interest payment
(4) Free combination of riskless investment 9899.59 €, x € from riskless 9899.59 €, x € from 9899.59 €, x € from 9899.59 €, x € from 9899.59 €, x € from 9899.59 €, x € from
and betting (CASE 4) investment and x1 € from bets placed riskless investment and riskless investment and riskless investment and riskless investment and riskless investment and
on s1 x2 € from bets placed on x3 € from bets placed on x4 € from bets placed on x5 € from bets placed on x6 € from bets placed on
s2 s3 s4 s5 s6
. . .or. . .
Part 2
. . .a description as possible outcomes of the Other ‘‘Herbstmeister” (first round Bayer Leverkusen Bayern Munich TSG 1899 Hoffenheim Schalke 04 Hamburger SV
first round of the German Bundesliga champion) than Leverkusen, Munich, ‘‘Herbstmeister” ‘‘Herbstmeister” ‘‘Herbstmeister” ‘‘Herbstmeister” ‘‘Herbstmeister”
(probabilities estimated by students) (cases Hoffenheim, Schalke, and Hamburg
5–8)
avg. prob. assessment (cases 5–8) p1 = 0.0438 p2 = 0.2237 p3 = 0.2584 p4 = 0.3267 p5 = 0.0628 p6 = 0.0845
(5) ‘‘Bundesliga-KickTipp” (CASE 5) x € base interest payment and 0 € x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest
bonus payment and 12.5 € payment and 25 € bonus payment and 37.5 € payment and 50 € bonus payment and 100 €
bonus bonus bonus
(6) Given replication of BKT (CASE 6) x € base interest payment and 34.20 € x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest x € base interest
penalty payment and 21.70 € payment and 9.20 € payment and 3.30 € payment and 15.80 € payment and 65.80 €
penalty penalty bonus bonus bonus
(7) Binary lottery (CASE 7) 0 € interest payment 0 € interest payment x € interest payment 0 € interest payment 0 € interest payment 0 € interest payment
(8) Free combination of riskless investment 9899.59 €, x € from riskless 9899.59 €, x € from 9899.59 €, x € from 9899.59 €, x € from 9899.59 €, x € from 9899.59 €, x € from
and betting (CASE 8) investment and x1 € from bets placed riskless investment and riskless investment and riskless investment and riskless investment and riskless investment and
on s1 x2 € from bets placed on x3 € from bets placed on x4 € from bets placed on x5 € from bets placed on x6 € from bets placed on
s2 s3 s4 s5 s6

We confront students with eight different decision situations, which vary with respect to the financial instrument under consideration and the origin of the probabilities for the six different future states of nature. In cases 1–4,
probabilities are exogenously given, in cases 5–8 students have to estimate explicitly probabilities for the possible outcomes of the first round of the first German soccer division (the ‘‘Bundesliga”). Cases 1 and 5 ask for the
desirability of a so-called Bundesliga-KickTipp (‘‘BKT”), cases 2 and 6 look at its replication by way of placing sports bets and investing risklessly at 1.90% p.a. Cases 3 and 7 analyze the attractiveness of a binary lottery, and in cases
4 and 8, students can create almost arbitrarily a combination of a riskless investment and sports bets. For cases 1–3 and 5–7, we design instruments in such a way that the student under consideration is eventually indifferent
between the respective financial instrument and a sole riskless investment at 1.90% p.a. We present cases 1–8 sequentially to our probands, i.e., for example, case 1 is presented before case 2, and it is not possible to skip back to
‘‘previous” cases.

2247
2248 W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252

All univariate comparisons reported in this paper rely on t-tests. are in line with our previous theoretical considerations. To this
However, in all cases, results for Wilcoxon signed-rank and rank- end, we state several hypotheses, as displayed in Table 5.
sum tests are almost completely identical and are available as Ta- Obviously, with the help of Hypothesis 1, we are able to assess
bles Ad6 to Ad8 from the authors upon request. the relevance of CPT for issues of practical financial engineering.
Due to organizational reasons, we selected students for the on- Hypothesis 2 aims at identifying the relevance of hedonic framing
site questioning from a certain program of studies, which explains in financial decision making, a phenomenon which would be par-
why some characteristics are different from those of the students ticularly relevant to explain the advantage of sports betting prod-
who perform the online version of our questionnaire. In particular, ucts in comparison to the direct placement of bets. With the help
on average, on-site participants have completed three semesters of Hypothesis 3(a), we want to find out whether investors behave
less, are about one year younger, more often female, possess more on average in a risk-loving manner so that sports betting products
financial knowledge, but are less interested in soccer than their become viable in comparison to a fixed rate investment. Hypothe-
‘‘online” counterparts. According to a two-sided t-test, the first sis 3(b) examines whether simple (relatively risky) binary bets as
three differences are significant on a 1% level and the last two on typically offered by bookmakers are indeed preferable to complex
a 5% level. Nevertheless, despite such distinctive features, there (and relatively less risky) financial instruments like the SKT or
are hardly any differences in the answers of both subgroups of stu- here: the BKT.
dents (see Table Ad2, available from the authors upon request). While Hypotheses 1–3 address the issue of risk-loving decision
Simple univariate t-tests merely hint at the possibility that there behavior and its origins, Hypothesis 4 aims at examining the rele-
are significant differences between both groups only for the case vance of non-monetary utility components as a cause for a benefi-
of a binary lottery with exogenous probabilities (on a 1% signifi- cial issuance of financial instruments with sports betting
cance level) and for the replicating strategy with exogenous prob- component. In particular, supporters of Bayern Munich may accept
abilities (on a 5% significance level). smaller premia for Bayern Munich becoming ‘‘Herbstmeister” than
The same holds true for multivariate analyses, when we simulta- the other investors, as Bayern Munich winning the first round of
neously take into account all six personal characteristics (including the Bundesliga may generate positive utility for its supporters,
an ‘‘online” variable) in order to explain optimal expected rates of re- and individuals are not able to separate such non-monetary re-
turn in cases 4 and 8 of free payment structure design opportunities wards from corresponding monetary ones. This should be particu-
and to explain minimum required expected rates of return to reach larly true when referring to investors’ subjective probability
indifference between the uncertain financial instrument under assessments. However, it would be more interesting for the issuer
consideration and a riskless investment at 1.90% p.a. in cases 1–3 of such financial instruments if supporters of Bayern Munich were
and 5–7 (see Table Ad3, available from the authors upon request). also willing to accept lower expected rates of return even on the
Moreover, these multivariate linear regression approaches suggest basis of the average probability assessments across all individuals
the limited relevance of (general) personal characteristics for the (as a proxy of the unknown ‘‘true” probability distribution). If,
decision problems at hand. When we perform eight regressions for however, supporters of Bayern Munich are driven by hedging
the eight decision problems under consideration, with each having considerations, Hypothesis 4 should be rejected at least on the ba-
six regression variables plus a constant, we get only six variables sis of personal probability assessments with minimum required
that are significantly different from zero on a significance level of expected rates of return for supporters of Bayern Munich being
at least 5%, with two of them being the online variable. Similar re- significantly greater than for other individuals. Certainly, for case
sults hold true when we look separately at the online students (only 3 with exogenously given probabilities we would expect no
four significant variables on a 5% level or better) or the other ones differences in behavior between supporters of Bayern Munich
(only one significant variable on a 5% level or better) (see Tables and the other individuals.
Ad4 and Ad5, available from the authors upon request). In addition, Closely connected to Hypothesis 4(a), Hypothesis 4(b) examines
global significance of all regressions is generally quite poor. Only one the issue of whether supporters of Bayern Munich are overly
out of all 24 regressions is globally significant on a 1% level, two are optimistic with respect to ‘‘their” soccer team. Apparently, this last
globally significant on a 5% level and another one on a 10% level. aspect in particular tackles the problem of heterogeneous expecta-
The influence of general personal characteristics for the decision tions, which is also the object of Hypothesis 5.
problems under consideration seems to be quite unsystematic and Hypothesis 5 states that, due to ambiguity aversion, minimum
thus of only limited relevance. We therefore present all our main required expected rates of return in a situation with exogenously
results in Tables 6–9 without making any distinction between dif- given probabilities should be smaller than in situations with
ferent subgroups of students and examine whether our findings ‘‘unknown” objective probabilities.

Table 5
Hypotheses with respect to the demand for sports betting products.
Hypothesis 1: cumulative prospect theory Average minimum expected interest rates in cases 1–3 and 5–7 are equal to those values as implied on average by CPT for
either low or high subjectively felt competence levels and with or without hedonic framing
Hypothesis 2: hedonic framing In cases 1 and 5, minimum required expected rates of return are smaller than in the corresponding cases 2 and 6
Hypothesis 3: general risk-loving behavior (a) Minimum required expected rates of return in cases 1–3 and 5–7 are smaller than the riskless interest rate of 1.90%
(b) Binary lotteries are acceptable for smaller expected rates of return than the BKT
Hypothesis 4: non-monetary utility (a) With respect to case 7, supporters of the FC Bayern Munich will accept a smaller expected rate of return from their
components personal view as well as for the average probability assessment across all individuals. With respect to case 3, such dif-
ferences are not observable
(b) Supporters of the FC Bayern Munich estimate a higher probability of Bayern Munich becoming ‘‘Herbstmeister” than
the other investors
Hypothesis 5: heterogeneous expectations and In cases 1–3, individuals on average accept lower expected rates of return than in cases 5–7 on the basis of their personal
ambiguity aversion probability assessments
Hypothesis 6: flexibility enhancement Minimum required expected rates of return in cases 4 and 8 are smaller than those in the corresponding cases 1–3 and 5–7
Hypothesis 7: profit potential of sports betting For an issuing bank, it is possible to realize a positive expected net return from selling the BKT (or its replicating strategy)
products and the binary lottery in cases 1–3 and 5–7
W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252 2249

By way of Hypothesis 6, we want to find out something about use parameter estimates according to Abdellaoui et al. (2005)
the relevance of control illusion on the students’ side by allowing (d+ = 0.975 and d = 1.345 as well as c+ = 0.832 and c = 0.842) to
them to fine-tune future payment structures. characterize an individual with a high level of subjectively felt
Hypothesis 7 then points to the question of whether it is possi- competence. Apparently, higher competence levels coincide with
ble to earn money with the issuance of sports betting products. higher values for both parameters d and c.
We start our testing with Hypothesis 1, as this is the most spe- Moreover, we have to specify an individual value function v().
cific one, because we want to examine whether CPT may be of From empirical observations of Tversky and Kahneman (1992)
practical use in a quantitative manner on an aggregated level. Re- and of Abdellaoui (2000), we may conclude
cent experimental findings by Erner et al. (2008) cast some doubt
(
upon the possibility of forecasting individual investment behavior ðDxÞa ; Dx P 0;
on the basis of CPT. To this end, Erner et al. (2008) derive value v ðDxÞ ¼ ð3Þ
k  ðDxÞb ; Dx < 0
functions and probability weighting functions for each of their pro-
bands and then examine whether their successive experimental
investment choices are in line with their optimal behavior accord- With a  b  0.88 and k  2.25 as typical parameter estimates.
ing to CPT. Although CPT is a descriptive decision theory, its fore- With these parameter values in mind, in cases 1–3, we rely on
casting power turns out to be rather poor. Complementing Erner the exogenously given probability assessments, while in cases 5–
et al. (2008), in our study we want to examine the practical value 7, we refer to students’ subjective probability estimates and com-
of CPT on a more aggregated level. pute average minimum required expected rates of return across
In order to do so, we define four ‘‘ideal” candidates, who follow all four ideal candidates and all 335 subjective probability esti-
CPT with a low (lc) or a high (hc) subjectively felt competence level mates. In Table 6, we compare our results according to CPT for
and with (hf) or without hedonic framing (nhf). The respective com- these four ideal candidates with the actual results of our question-
petence levels can be identified with different parameters of an ing for the cases 1–3 and 5–7. Apparently, for ideal candidates 2–4
individual’s probability weighting function w. According to Latti- in cases 1, 2, 5, and 6, we observe risk-loving behavior. Moreover,
more et al. (1992), and with pcum as a shortcut for cumulative prob- the consequences of hedonic framing do seem to be quite pro-
abilities like pi þ    þ pN or p1 þ    þ pi , respectively, we have: nounced. Our theoretical conjectures of the previous section with
respect to the consequences of CPT are thus verified. However,
d  pccum with only one exception, results according to CPT differ signifi-
wd;c ðpcum Þ :¼ cantly on very high significance levels from the actual results
d  pcum þ ð1  pcum Þc
c
8 þ c
þ according to students’ answers. Similar results would emerge for
>
< wþ ðpcum Þ :¼ þ cþ d pcum ðDx > 0Þ ð2Þ
d pcum þð1pcum Þc
þ other parameter constellations, e.g., utilizing median values
:¼ according to Erner et al. (2008) without or with hedonic framing,
>
: w ðp
c
d pcum
cum Þ :¼ d pc c ðDx < 0Þ: and would only in case 1 not imply statistical differences from
cum þð1pcum Þ
our experimental findings on very high significance levels as in
Parameter d mainly determines the absolute values of probabil- Table 6 for ideal candidates 1–4 (though median investors accord-
ity weights and thus is also called ‘‘attractiveness”, because proba- ing to Erner et al., 2008, violate parameter constellations deemed
bilities become more attractive (i.e. lead to higher probability plausible for CPT, see for the latter Gurevich et al., 2009). Despite
weights) for higher values of d. Parameter c determines in particu- its empirical nature, CPT seems to fail to forecast actual behavior
lar the slope of the probability weighting function in the range of for our decision problem. Summarizing, Hypothesis 1 has to be
medium-sized probabilities and is therefore called ‘‘discriminabil- rejected.
ity”, because differences in probabilities are more pronounced for Nevertheless, it may still be that hedonic framing is relevant for
higher values of c. In general, d and c may assume different values the decision problem at hand, but, according to Table 7, by compar-
in the region of gains Dx > 0 (w+) and in the region of losses Dx < 0 ing minimum required expected interest rates in cases 1 and 2
(w) and for different decision situations with a decision maker’s (difference: 0.020%) as well as in cases 5 and 6 (difference:
subjectively felt ‘‘competence” being a predominant influential fac- 0.010%), we learn that hedonic framing is not really a relevant
tor. We follow Breuer and Perst (2007) in applying the parameter issue for the decision problems under consideration, although
estimates of Abdellaoui (2000) (d+ = 0.65 and d = 0.84 as well as cases 2 and 6 indeed require somewhat higher minimum expected
c+ = 0.6 and c = 0.65) as a description of a representative decision rates of return than their counterparts in cases 1 and 5. Thus, we
maker with a low level of subjectively felt competence, while we cannot verify Hypothesis 2, either.

Table 6
Minimum required expected rates of return according to CPT in comparison to students’ answers.

(a) CASE 1: (b) CASE 2: (c) CASE 3: (d) CASE 5: (e) CASE 6: (f) CASE 7:
++ +++ +++ +++
(1) Avg. min. required expected rates of return (students’ answers) 1.904% 1.924% 2.657% 1.955% 1.965% 2.625%+++
(2) Ideal candidate 1 (lc,nhf) 1.925%*** 1.925% 2.250%*** 1.929%*** 1.929%*** 1.908%***
(3) Ideal candidate 2 (hc,nhf) 1.888%** 1.888%*** 2.000%*** 1.895%*** 1.895%*** 2.120%***
(4) Ideal candidate 3 (lc,hf) 1.837%*** 1.889%*** 2.250%*** 1.824%*** 1.897%*** 1.908%***
(5) Ideal candidate 4 (hc,hf) 1.784%*** 1.852%*** 2.000%*** 1.780%*** 1.860%*** 2.120%***

This table presents minimum required expected rates of return for four different ‘‘ideal” candidates according to CPT (with either low (‘‘lc”) or high competence (‘‘hc”) level
and either hedonic framing (‘‘hf”) or not (‘‘nhf”)). For rows 2–5, values in columns a to c are based on exogenously given probabilities so that we compute only one CPT-based
minimum required expected rate of return for each ideal candidate. We calculate respective values in columns d to f on the basis of students’ individual probability
assessments so that there are 335 CPT-based rates of return for each ideal candidate 1–4 with corresponding average values presented in this table. We then compare the
individual results for the ideal candidates to individual minimum expected rates of return according to students’ actual answers (we present average minimum required rates
of return according to students’ answers in row 1). *** (**, *) stands for significant differences between ideal and actual results on a 1% (5%, 10%) level according to t-test results.
One should note that for simple binary lotteries with a base payment of 0 €, hedonic framing is not an issue so that in cases 3 and 7 ideal candidates 3 and 4 behave like their
respective counterparts 1 and 2. +++ (++, +) stands for significant differences between students’ minimum expected rates of return and the fixed interest rate of 1.90% on a 1%
(5%, 10%) level.
2250 W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252

Table 7
Differences between minimum required expected rates of return for different cases according to students’ answers.

Differences CASE 1: CASE 2: CASE 3: CASE 4: CASE 5: CASE 6: CASE 7: CASE 8:


(‘‘rowcolumn”) 1.904% 1.924% 2.657% 1.643% 1.955% 1.965% 2.625% 2.821%
CASE 1 xxx 0.020%* 0.751%*** 0.261%*** 0.051%*** 0.061%*** 0.721%*** 0.917%***
CASE 2 0.020%* xxx 0.733%*** 0.281%*** 0.031%** 0.041%*** 0.701%*** 0.897%***
CASE 3 0.751%*** 0.733%*** xxx 1.014%*** 0.702%*** 0.692%*** 0.032% 0.164%
CASE 4 0.261%*** 0.281%*** 1.014%*** xxx 0.312%*** 0.322%*** 0.982%*** 1.178%***
CASE 5 0.051%*** 0.031%** 0.702%*** 0.312%*** xxx 0.010% 0.670%*** 0.866%***
CASE 6 0.061%*** 0.041%*** 0.692%*** 0.322%*** 0.010% xxx 0.660%*** 0.856%***
CASE 7 0.721%*** 0.701%*** 0.032% 0.982%*** 0.670%*** 0.660%*** xxx 0.196%
CASE 8 0.917%*** 0.897%*** 0.164% 1.178%*** 0.866%*** 0.856%*** 0.196% xxx

This table presents differences between minimum required expected rates of return as a result of the pairwise comparison (‘‘row versus column”) for all eight cases under
consideration. For cases 5–8, we compute expected rates on the basis of the students’ respective subjective probability assessments. *** (**, *) stands for significant differences
between observed minimum required expected rates of return for the two cases under consideration on a 1% (5%, 10%) level (according to t-tests). ‘‘xxx” denotes constel-
lations which are not considered.

Although CPT and hedonic framing do not seem to be of partic- certain teams. However, this issue already carries over to the gen-
ular relevance, it nevertheless might be that individuals overweigh eral question of what impact heterogeneous expectations may
small probabilities and thus exhibit risk-loving behavior. However, have on investor behavior.
according to row 1 of Table 6, individuals on average do not exhibit In fact, according to Table 7, in cases 1 and 2, minimum required
risk-loving behavior in any of the cases 1–3 and 5–7. Moreover, as expected rates of return (based on individual expectations) are sig-
revealed by Table 7, minimum required expected rates of return nificantly smaller than in corresponding cases 5 and 6. Only for
are significantly higher for binary lotteries than for the BKT. case 3 versus case 7 (difference: 0.032%) does this not hold. Never-
Hypotheses 3(a) and (b) have, then, to be rejected as well. In fact, theless, it might be a consequence of the rather simple structure of
the rejection of Hypothesis 3(b) is also valid for our ideal decision the binary lottery, which may reduce the problem of ambiguity
makers 1–4 who act according to CPT with a subjectively felt low aversion. Generally speaking, we may accept Hypothesis 5.
or high competence level (see Table 6). The reason for this is simply Following Table 7, Hypothesis 6 is obviously true for the case of
that the probability of success is not small enough. It thus seems exogenously given expectations. Some kind of control illusion may
that the overweighting of small probabilities may favor binary lot- reduce minimum required rates of return in such a way that indi-
teries only for more extreme outcomes. viduals behave in a risk-loving manner. Based on individual expec-
Table 8 reveals that in case 7 supporters of Bayern Munich are tations in case 8 however, we have to reject Hypothesis 6. The
indeed satisfied with significantly lower expected rates of return reason for this finding may be a more pronounced ambiguity aver-
than other investors on the basis of average probability assess- sion in quite complex decision situations. However, and even more
ments. Corresponding extreme differences are not prevalent in plausible, a flexibility enhancement, as defined in this paper,
case 3, so that we may conjecture that this finding is a direct con- makes it easy for investors to exploit deviations in expectations
sequence of the specific characteristics of the binary lottery in case from those we suggest by the odds offered. Probabilities as implied
7. Moreover, supporters of Bayern Munich estimate the success of by these odds in case 8 are identical to those that we state in the
‘‘their” team in becoming ‘‘Herbstmeister” significantly higher than row ‘‘exogenous probabilities. . .” of Table 4 (calculated as odds/
the remaining investors (see Table 8, column d). However, based 1.1557, e.g. (1/6.5)/1.1557 = 0.1331, as this assures the sum of all
on individual probability assessments, there are no significant probabilities adding up to 1). The average student estimates the
differences between supporters of Bayern Munich and other indi- probability of Hoffenheim becoming ‘‘Herbstmeister” much higher
viduals. This means that non-monetary utility components per se than the probability as suggested by the corresponding odds
do not play a major role for the decision problem under consider- (0.3267 versus 0.2012) and one can exploit such discrepancies best
ation, but the degree of sympathy for a future uncertain sporting in situations with ‘‘flexibility enhancement”, thus leading to high
outcome may influence probability assessments. Thus, we can subjectively expected rates of return.
partially verify Hypothesis 4 and may highlight a comparative Summarizing, up to now, our experimental results offer only
disadvantage of a rather complex financial instrument like the weak support for our theoretical hypotheses. On average, people
BKT in comparison to simple binary lotteries. The latter are more do not behave in a risk-loving way, there is no relevant hedonic
suited to exploit overly optimistic expectations of supporters of framing, and CPT does not play any important role. Non-monetary

Table 8
Minimum required expected rates of return and probability assessments by supporters of Bayern Munich (BM) and ‘‘other” individuals in cases 3 and 7.

CASE 3 CASE 7
Minimum required expected rates of return
(a) . . .for exogenously given (b) . . .for individual subjective (c) . . .for average probability (d) Average probability assessment for
probabilities (p3 = 24.04%) probability assessments assessments (p3 = 25.84%) BM becoming ‘‘Herbstmeister”
(1) Supporters 2.283% 2.939% 2.092%*** 46.96%***
of BM
(2) Other 2.688% 2.599% 3.195% 24.06%
individuals

This table presents minimum required expected rates of return for cases 3 and 7 as well as corresponding probability assessments for the event of Bayern Munich (BM)
becoming ‘‘Herbstmeister” (first round champion). *** (**, *) in row 1 stands for significant differences between supporters of Bayern Munich and other individuals on a 1% (5%,
10%) level (t-test results). In column b, we compute average expected rates of return for case 7 across all supporters of BM and all other individuals on the basis of students’
respective individual probability assessments. In column c, we compute average expected rates of return for case 7 across all supporters of BM and all other individuals on the
basis of a probability of BM becoming ‘‘Herbstmeister” of 25.84%, which equals the average probability assessment for this event across all individuals. In case 3, because of
exogenously given probabilities, such a distinction of probability assessments is not necessary.
W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252 2251

utility components may only work in an indirect way by influenc- buy the financial instrument at given return conditions for 10,000 €
ing probability estimates, and ambiguity aversion leads to increas- (and their personal probability assessments in cases 5–7), we
ing minimum required expected rates of return in situations with determine that corresponding expected rate of return r (as seen
heterogeneous expectations. Flexible product design opportunities from the bank’s point of view; with expectations in cases 5–7
may be advantageous from a bank’s point of view in situations according to average probability assessments across all probands),
with homogeneous expectations, but make the issuer particularly which maximizes the bank’s expected net profit (0.019  r)
vulnerable in situations when probabilities are not common 10,000 n for the bank’s lending rate (i.e. expected gross return)
knowledge. of 1.90% p.a. Apparently, according to the last three columns of
Rather unexpectedly, in spite of these quite disillusioning re- Table 9, there is indeed a potential for buying sports betting
sults, it seems possible to make money with sports betting prod- products and thus we can verify Hypothesis 7.
ucts. The reason for this is that, even if individuals behave on At first glance, somewhat surprisingly, in order to exploit
average in a risk-averse manner, there may be a considerable share individuals’ risk-loving behavior, binary lotteries are much more
of risk-loving people. The fact of a pronounced diversity in prefer- suited than payment structures like that of the BKT. The reason
ences is already well-known from the literature on experimental is simply that such extreme payment structures like that of a
decision theory so far. For example, in Abdellaoui et al. (2007), binary lottery lead to much more varying minimum required
there is a coefficient of variation of m = 0.457892 for their experi- expected rates of return across individuals, even in situations with
mental results with respect to parameter a in (3). Taking the homogeneous expectations (see the standard deviations of
þ
parameter values aIC1 = 0.88, cþ IC1 ¼ 0:6, and dIC1 ¼ 0:65 of ideal minimum required rates of return in case 3 versus cases 1 and
candidate 1 (the one whose required rates in Table 6 seem to be 2). This effect is even more pronounced for heterogeneous expecta-
nearest to the findings of our experiment) as our starting point, tions (case 7 versus cases 5 and 6) and may thus explain the
we re-compute minimum required expected rates of return for practical relevance of binary lotteries even in situations with
cases 1 and 3 with values of a, c+, and d+ being identical to aIC1, success probabilities not being extremely small.
cþIC1 , and dþIC1 plus or minus once or twice v times aIC1, cþIC1 , and These results highlight the fact that the overall assessment of

IC1 , respectively. Under the simplifying (ad hoc) assumptions of sports betting products (and presumably of other financial instru-
the coefficient of variation for parameters c+ and d+ of Eq. (2) being ments as well) is not necessarily driven by the average investor’s
identical to m as well and all three parameter values being behavior but by the diversity of investors. Nevertheless, the deci-
þ
approximately normally distributed with aIC1, cþ IC1 , and dIC1 as their sion problem underlying Table 9 only takes riskless lending and
3
respective expectation values, the range of all 5 = 125 different borrowing as an alternative into account. Compared to the simple
constellations under consideration encompasses for each placement of bets at bookmakers’, however, such financial instru-
parameter the corresponding 95% confidence interval of possible ments seem to offer no advantage, as hedonic framing does not
realizations. For case 1 (3), in 51.20% (36.00%) of all parameter play a crucial role in assessing the desirability of sports betting
constellations, we observe risk-loving behavior. In spite of the products and one may better exploit potential causes for risk-lov-
shortcomings of the CPT with respect to a direct quantitative ing behavior by way of direct sports bets. In this respect, sports
evaluation of sports betting products, this finding may hint at the betting products are somewhat ‘‘stuck in the middle”. Certainly,
possibility of a sufficient diversity among individuals so that a banks may mimic the supply of bookmakers by way of bonus pay-
(risk-neutral) bank may gain money by the issuance of sports bet- ments upgrades or flexibility enhancements, as defined above.
ting products. In fact, as Table 9 reveals, in our experiment, there is However, the problem of subjective probability assessments may
always a considerable share of persons who behave in a risk-loving be severe on the bank’s side. As already mentioned, the standard
manner, i.e. individuals who accept expected rates of return below deviation of minimum required expected rates of return across
the riskless interest rate of 1.90%. Actually, this implies that there all individuals is significantly lower for the BKT than for the binary
is room for issuing sports betting products, so that there will be a lottery and – for the binary lottery – differs considerably between
positive net gain for the issuer even in the case where the riskless case 3 (homogeneous expectations) and case 7 (heterogeneous
lending and borrowing rates are both identical to 1.90%. To be expectations) while this is not true for the BKT. These results hint
more precise, based on the distribution of minimum required ex- at the problem that the consequences of differences in expecta-
pected rates of return in the cases 1–3 and 5–7 of our experiment tions are much more severe for binary lotteries than for the BKT.
and with n standing for the number of investors who are willing to A similar result is true for case 8, i.e. for flexibility enhancements

Table 9
Optimal pricing policy for a risk-neutral bank in cases 1–3 and 5–7.

Average minimum required Standard deviation of Share of Bank’s profit maximizing expected Share of Bank’s maximum expected net
expected rate of return (as seen minimum required rates of risk-loving rate of return offer (as seen from buyers profit (as seen from bank’s
from students’ view point) (%) return across students (%) students (%) bank’s viewpoint) viewpoint)
CASE 1 1.904 0.14 39.10 1.70% 8.96% 600.00 €
CASE 2 1.924 0.19 32.24 1.65% 8.36% 691.63 €
CASE 3 2.657 1.13 26.27 1.22% 11.04% 2516.00 €
CASE 4 1.643 0.17 80.00 xxx xxx xxx
CASE 5 1.955 0.16 25.97 1.70% 11.94% 659.70 €
CASE 6 1.965 0.16 25.97 1.76% 10.75% 377.73 €
CASE 7 2.625 1.51 32.54 1.21% 15.82% 3471.10 €
CASE 8 2.821 1.38 13.73 xxx xxx xxx

For all eight cases, this table presents average minimum required expected rates of return as seen from the students’ (= investors’) point of view as well as corresponding
return standard deviations across students and the share of risk-loving students. Based on this information, we determine a risk-neutral bank’s optimal price-setting behavior
for an expected gross return of 1.90% under the assumption of maximizing its expected overall net return. For cases 5–7, we assume that the bank’s expectations are identical
to the average probability assessments across all probands. The last three columns present for each of the eight cases the bank’s profit maximizing expected rate of return
offered to investors for their money (achieved by an adjustment of the base interest payment x according to Table 4 in cases 1, 2, 5, and 6 and the interest payment x in state s3
according to Table 4 in cases 3 and 7), the percentage of all individuals accepting this offer, and the bank’s resulting expected net profit. ‘‘xxx” denotes cases which are not
considered.
2252 W. Breuer et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 33 (2009) 2241–2252

in situations with heterogeneous expectations. With banks not micro level is not able to explain the demand for financial instru-
possessing the expertise of bookmakers, bonus payment upgrades ments, either. Thus, one should directly ask a representative
or flexibility enhancements of financial instruments with sports cross-section of investors for their preferences regarding a new
betting components will be quite ‘‘risky”. Based on these findings, financial instrument in question. Future research should focus
it should become hard for such sports betting products to achieve a more on the diversity of preferences in order to better assess the
major relevance on capital markets that goes beyond the role of a potential success of financial innovations.
mere marketing gimmick. However, it would be interesting to
support our conjecture by a quantitative empirical analysis of the References
market for such financial instruments.
Abdellaoui, M., 2000. Parameter-free elicitation of utility and probability weighting
functions. Management Science 46, 1497–1512.
Abdellaoui, M., Bleichrodt, H., Paraschiv, C., 2007. Loss aversion under prospect
5. Conclusion theory: a parameter-free measurement. Management Science 53, 1659–1674.
Abdellaoui, M., Vossmann, F., Weber, M., 2005. Choice-based elicitation and
The object of this paper is a detailed analysis of so-called sports decomposition of decision weights for gains and losses under uncertainty.
Management Science 51, 1384–1399.
betting (financial) products on a decision-theoretical and experi- Baumann, C., 2006. Wetten, dass. . . Weltwoche, no vol., issue 17, <http://
mental grounding. Sports betting products are ‘‘en vogue” – in www.weltwoche.ch/artikel/?AssetID=13819&CategoryID=84> (12.13.07).
particular in connection with sports ‘‘mega events”. Quite often, Breuer, W., Perst, A., 2007. Retail banking and behavioral financial engineering: the
case of structured products. Journal of Banking and Finance 31, 827–844.
the literature declares such offers as being nothing but a mere
De-Jong, D., 2006. World Cup marketing campaign Korean style – money in the
marketing gimmick. The reason is that such financial instruments bank!, <http://debradejong.blogspot.com/2006/06/world-cup-marketing-
must – at the same time – prove their superiority to simple fixed campaign-korean.html> (05.11.08).
term investments and to the offers of professional bookmakers. Deutsche Bundesbank, 2008. Deposits from households, <http://www.bundesbank.
de/statistik/statistik_zeitreihen.en.php?func=list&open=zinsen&tr=www_s11b_
At first glance, this proves particularly difficult in situations with ne1> (05.11.08).
homogeneous expectations. However, for the ‘‘Sparkassen-Kick- Ellsberg, D., 1961. Risk, ambiguity and the savage axioms. Quarterly Journal of
Tipp” as a typical example of a financial instrument with a sports Economics 75, 643–669.
Entrop, O., Scholz, H., Wilkens, M., 2009. The price-setting behavior of banks: an
betting component, we are able to identify theoretically several analysis of open-end leverage certificates of the German market. Journal of
potential reasons which may make this instrument an attractive Banking and Finance 33, 874–882.
investment. Besides the phenomenon of heterogeneous expecta- Erner, C., Klos, A., Langer, T., 2008. Can prospect theory be used to predict investor’s
willingness to pay? (August 20, 2008), Unpublished working paper, available at
tions, such instruments may be interesting because of the simulta- SSRN: <http://ssrn.com/abstract=1099928> (03.10.09).
neous existence of non-monetary utility components (as is the case Gurevich, G., Kliger, D., Levy, O., 2009. Decision-making under uncertainty – a field
for supporters of a certain team), the overweighting of small study of cumulative prospect theory. Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 1221–
1229.
probabilities and hedonic framing effects. Kahneman, D., Tversky, A., 1979. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk.
Unfortunately, by way of an experiment, we are able to find out Econometrica 47, 263–291.
that the average investor does not behave in a risk-loving manner, Kramer, A., 2007. Beobachtet: Wo Sparbuch draufsteht, muss kein Sparbuch drin
sein, <http://www.wirtschaftsblatt.at/home/news/meinung/264853/index.do>
and that heterogeneity in expectations is more a problem than an
(12.13.07).
advantage. Moreover, hedonic framing does not seem to be of any Langer, E.J., Roth, J., 1975. Heads I win, tails it’s chance: the illusion of control as a
significant relevance. Non-monetary utility components may be function of the sequence of outcomes in a purely chance task. Journal of
only of indirect importance by influencing probability assessments. Personality and Social Psychology 34, 191–198.
Lattimore, P.M., Baker, J.R., Witte, A.D., 1992. The influence of probability on risky
Nevertheless, in spite of these average results, diversity of prefer- choice. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 17, 377–400.
ences and expectations may indeed give rise to a profitable issu- Mildenberger, M., 2006. Banken entdecken den Fußball. Kölner Stadtanzeiger, 03/
ance of sports betting products to a – rather limited – share of 13/2006, no Vol., Issue 61, 12.
N.N., 2006. Bank-Produkte zur Fußball-WM nur selten sinnvoll. FAZ-Net, <http://
investors. In any case, one would exploit the demand for sports www.faz.net/s/Rub09A305833E12405A808EF01024D15375/Doc~ E611A8B5C-
betting products by such investors best with financial instruments 9891450B87EA2C6E9820C54B~ATpl~Ecommon~Scontent.html> (09.12.07).
that mimic a direct placement of bets. With most bankers not pos- Schich, K., 2008. Konditionen nicht immer meisterhaft. Kölner Stadtanzeiger, 05/26/
2008, no vol., issue 120, 11.
sessing a special expertise in the field of sports bets, they should Thaler, R.H., 1980. Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of
better leave such offers that react quite sensitively to misspecifica- Economic Behavior and Organization 1, 39–60.
tions of probabilities to bookmakers. But then, the market for Thaler, R.H., 1985. Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science 4,
199–214.
sports betting products should be of only limited relevance and
Thaler, R.H., 1999. Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral Decision
thus the characterization of them as ‘‘marketing gimmicks” may Making 12, 183–206.
be adequate. Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., 1981. The framing of decisions and the psychology of
choice. Science 211, 453–458.
Moreover, the results of this paper may be of general impor-
Tversky, A., Kahneman, D., 1992. Advances in prospect theory: cumulative
tance. When trying to assess the profit potential of a new financial representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5, 297–323.
instrument, it seems necessary to determine the distribution of Weiss, R., 2006. Boom am Derivatemarkt (Interview). ideas – Ihr Magazin für
preferences for this instrument across possible buyers. Referring Optionsscheine, Zertifikate und Aktienanleihen, no vol., issue 50, 2-3.
Wilkens, S., Stoimenov, P.A., 2007. The pricing of leverage products: an empirical
to ‘‘average” investors may imply quite misleading results. More- investigation of the German market for ‘long’ and ‘short’ stock index certificates.
over, according to Erner et al. (2008), the application of CPT on a Journal of Banking and Finance 31, 735–750.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen