Sie sind auf Seite 1von 18

Heterogeneity and Aggregation:

Implications for Labor-Market Fluctuations

By Yongsung Chang and Sun-Bin Kim*

This paper addresses two related issues from technology shock and there is no distortion
the business cycle literature. One is the low cor- in the labor market. Our model extends Per
relation between hours and productivity. The Krusell and Anthony Smith’s (1998) heteroge-
second is the large cyclical movement in the neous-agent model with incomplete capital mar-
wedge derived from the optimality condition kets (S. Rao Aiyagari 1994) to indivisible labor
for the intratemporal choice of commodity con- supply (Richard Rogerson 1988). The interac-
sumption and hours worked. The equilibrium tion between incomplete capital markets and
business cycle models (e.g., Robert E. Lucas, indivisible labor breaks the tight link between
Jr., and Leonard A. Rapping 1969; Finn E. employment and wages at the aggregate level.
Kydland and Edward C. Prescott 1982) impose The optimality conditions for the choice of con-
strong restrictions on movements in consump- sumption and hours worked hold as inequality
tion, hours, and productivity. According to these at the individual level. Individual optimality
models, the economy puts in more work effort conditions do not aggregate nicely. In particu-
and consumes more goods when productivity lar, aggregate employment is not highly corre-
is high (i.e., when the commodity is cheap rela- lated with productivity. As a result, we obtain a
tive to leisure). However, the lack of systematic significant wedge between the marginal rate of
movement among consumption, hours worked, substitution and labor productivity. Moreover,
and productivity in aggregate data has resulted the wedge computed from the model-generated
in the measurement of a considerable wedge aggregate consumption, hours, and productivity
between the marginal rate of substitution and exhibits properties similar to those in the wedge
labor productivity—e.g., Robert E. Hall (1997) measured from the actual aggregate time series
and Varadarajan V. Chari, Patrick J. Kehoe, and data. The wedge is strongly correlated with
Ellen R. McGrattan (2005). Previous research hours and is almost as volatile as hours worked.
has offered various explanations for the low Our results caution against viewing the mea-
correlation between hours and productivity. sured wedge as an inefficiency due to the failure
For example, explanations range from exog- of labor-market clearing or as a fundamental
enous shocks to the labor-supply schedule, such driving force behind business cycles.
as the shifts in home production technology in The paper is organized as follows. Section I
Jess Benhabib, Richard Rogerson, and Randall briefly discusses the labor-market wedge in the
Wright (1991) to frictions in labor supply, such as aggregate data. Section II lays out a benchmark
the wage rigidities in Jordi Galí, Mark Gertler, model economy in which the capital market is
and J. David Lopez-Salido (2007). incomplete and labor supply is indivisible. In
In this paper, we obtain a low correlation Section III, we calibrate the model economy
between hours worked and productivity, where and study the cyclical properties of the aggre-
the only aggregate disturbance is a (market) gate variables in the face of productivity shocks.
In Section IV, we investigate economies with
* Chang: Department of Economics, University of Roch­ and without complete capital markets and indi-
es­ter, Rochester, NY 14627, and Yonsei University (e-mail: visible labor, in order to distinguish the separate
ychang14@mail.rochester.edu); Kim: Department of Eco­
nom­ics, Korea University, Anam-Dong, Seongbuk-Gu,
Seoul, Korea 136-701 (e-mail: sunbink@korea.ac.kr). We
 
would like to thank Mark Bils, Huberto Ennis, Bob King, Jose Sheinkman and Laurence Weiss (1986) show that
Per Krusell, the editor, two anonymous referees, and the capital-market incompleteness can lead to a stochastic
members of the Research Department at the Federal term in aggregate preferences. Tomoyuki Nakajima (2005)
Reserve Bank of Richmond for their helpful comments. derives aggregate preference shocks and total factor pro-
Sun-Bin Kim’s research is supported by a Korea University ductivity (TFP) variation in a two-type household model
research grant. with capacity utilization and government spending shocks.
1939
1940 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

 
MO.34
MO:)
















 
          

Figure 1. Cyclical Components of MRS and Labor Productivity

Notes: Output and hours worked represent the nonagricultural private sector. Consumption reflects expenditure on nondu-
rable goods and services. The MRS is defined by equation (1).

role of incomplete capital markets and indivis- hours worked Ht: U 1 Ct, Ht 2 5 ln Ct 2 B 3H111/g/
ible labor. Section V concludes. 11 1 1/g 2 4 . The parameter g represents the (com-
pensated) labor-supply elasticity and B is a con-
I.  Labor-Market Wedge in Aggregate Data stant. Under the assumption that the aggregate
production technology is Cobb-Douglas (with
One of the leading research topics in macro- the labor-income share denoted by a), at the
economics is the identification of the fundamen- competitive equilibrium, the MRS should be
tal driving forces behind economic fluctuations. equal to the MPL:
Economists adopt accounting procedures that
H1/g
t Yt
combine aggregate time-series data with the (1)  B 5a .
equilibrium conditions of a prototype model. Ct21 Ht
For optimal allocation of consumption and
hours worked, the marginal rate of substitu- Figure 1 shows the cyclical components of the
tion (MRS) has to equal the marginal product MRS (the left-hand side of (1)) and labor productiv-
of labor (MPL). To illustrate, suppose that the ity (the right-hand side of (1)) for the US economy
stand-in household has the following utility for 1958:I–2002:II. In computing the MRS, we
function over commodity consumption Ct and assume that the aggregate labor-supply elasticity
VOL. 97 NO. 5 CHANG AND KIM: Heterogeneity and Aggregation 1941

 
MO)
MO8FEHF








¢

¢

¢

¢

¢ 
          

Figure 2. Cyclical Components of Hours and Labor-Market Wedge for the United States

Note: The wedge is computed from equation (2) with the aggregate labor-supply elasticity 1g2 of 1.5.

g is 1.5. Output and hours worked are based on and its volatility is the same order of magnitude
the private business sector. Consumption reflects as hours worked. The aggregate labor-supply
expenditures on nondurable goods and services. elasticity of 1.5 is higher than a typical estimate
Both the MRS and labor productivity are logged in the micro data, which is usually less than 0.5
and detrended using a Hordrick-Prescott filter. (e.g., Thomas MaCurdy 1981). If we assume
The MRS is more volatile than hours and, more an inelastic labor supply (a smaller value of g),
importantly, often moves in the opposite direc- we obtain a bigger wedge as the MRS becomes
tion to productivity, suggesting a serious depar- more volatile. Conversely, using an elastic labor
ture from the competitive equilibrium. supply (a bigger value of g) tends to produce a
We now define the labor-market wedge as the smaller wedge. Nevertheless, there is no choice
gap between the MRS and labor productivity: of g that eliminates the wedge completely. In
Yt essence, the wedge arises because hours worked
(2)  ln Wedget 5 ln MRSt 2 ln 1 constant. are not highly correlated with productivity—the
Ht ­correlation coefficient between the two time
Figure 2 shows the time series of this wedge. series is virtually zero (0.08).
The wedge is highly correlated with hours worked,

 
The choice of this value will be explained in Sec­ For example, Hall (1997) uses g51/1.7. We have also
tion IVB. computed the wedge based on the real wage (instead of
1942 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

The existing literature offers various interpreta- of labor and earns wt xt h, where wt is the wage
tions for this wedge. They range from exogenous rate per effective unit of labor xt, which varies
shocks to the labor-supply schedule, e.g., prefer- exogenously according to a stochastic process
ence shifts in Hall (1997) and Allison Holland with a transition probability distribution func-
and Andrew Scott (1998); changes in home pro- tion px 1 xr 0 x 2 5 Pr(xt11 # x9Zxt 5 x). Individual
duction technology in Benhabib, Rogerson, and productivity xt represents idiosyncratic risks
Wright (1991); shifts in government spending in that agents face in our model economy and is
Lawrence Christiano and Martin Eichenbaum the only source of heterogeneity.
(1992); and changes in labor-income taxes in The representative firm produces output
Casey B. Mulligan (2002), to various frictions according to a constant returns-to-scale Cobb-
in the labor market, e.g., wage rigidity in Galí, Douglas technology in capital, Kt (which depre-
Gertler, and Lopez-Salido (2007); households’ ciates at rate d each period), and effective units
market power in labor supply in Diego Comin and of labor, Lt 1 5e ht xt dm 2 , where m is the distribu-
Gertler (2003); search frictions in Hall (1997); and tion of workers:
labor unions and suspension of antitrust policy in
Harold L. Cole and Lee. E. Ohanian (2002) and Yt 5 F 1 Lt, Kt ,lt 2 5 lt Lat K12a
t .
Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2005). In the next
section, we present a model economy in which The aggregate productivity lt evolves with
the labor-market wedge arises endogenously, a transition probability distribution function
despite there being neither exogenous shocks to pl 1 lr 0 l 2 5 Pr 1lt11 # lr 0 lt 5 l 2 .
the labor supply nor distortions to the allocation The value function for an employed worker,
of hours and consumption. denoted by V E , is:

II.  The Model (3)  V E 1a, x; l, m 2


2 111/g
h
The model economy is a simplified version of    5 max Uln c 2 B 
Chang and Kim (2006) which extends Krusell ar[A 1 1 1/g
and Smith’s (1998) heterogeneous-agent model
1 bE CmaxEV E 1a9, x9; l9, m92, 
with incomplete capital markets to indivisible
labor supply. There is a continuum (measure
V N 1a9, x9; l9, m92FZx, lDV,
one) of workers who have identical preferences
but different productivity. A worker has separa- subject to
ble preferences over consumption, ct, and hours
worked, ht: ln ct 2 B 3ht1 1 1/g/ 11 1 1/g 2 4 . Workers c 5 w 1 l, m 2 xh 1 1 1 1 r 1 l, m 2 2 a 2 ar,
trade claims for physical capital, at, which
yields the rate of return, rt. The capital mar- ar $ a,
kets are incomplete. Physical capital is the only
mr 5 T1l, m 2 ,
asset available to workers, and workers face a
borrowing constraint: at $ a for all t (Aiyagari
1994). The labor supply is indivisible (Rogerson where T denotes a transition operator that
1988). If employed, a worker supplies h units defines the law of motion for the distribution of


labor productivity) and the main conclusion of our analysis This implicitly assumes that workers are perfect substi-
does not change. We prefer using labor productivity, since tutes for each other. While this assumption abstracts from
the standard argument that wages are not allocational sug- reality, it greatly simplifies the labor-market equilibrium.

gests that the implications for wages are not fundamental. In this model economy, a productivity shock is the only

In general, the labor-supply decision operates on aggregate disturbance. This does not necessarily reflect our
both the extensive and intensive margins. However, it is view on the source of business cycles. Since we would like
rare for workers to be allowed to choose completely flex- to show that the wedge contains a significant specification
ible work schedules or to supply a small number of hours. error, rather than true shifts in labor supply, we intentionally
Furthermore, it is well known that the variation in the exclude shocks that may shift the labor-supply schedule itself
­number of employees is the dominant source of fluctuations (e.g., shifts in home production technology, government
in total hours worked (e.g., James J. Heckman 1984). spending, or the income tax rate) from the present analysis.
VOL. 97 NO. 5 CHANG AND KIM: Heterogeneity and Aggregation 1943

workers m 1 a, x 2 . The value function for a non- III.  Quantitative Analysis


employed worker, denoted by V N 1a, x; l, m 2 , is
defined similarly with h 5 0. Then, the labor- A. Calibration
supply decision is characterized by
We briefly explain the choice of the model
max2 5V E 1a, x ; l, m 2, V N 1a, x ; l, m 26.
V 1a, x ; l, m 2 5 h[ parameters. The unit of time is a business quar-
50, h 6
ter. We assume that individual productivity x
Equilibrium consists of a set of value functions, follows an AR(1) process: ln xr 5 rx ln x 1 ex,
EV E 1a,  x; l, m2 , V N 1a, x ; l, m2 , V 1a, x; l, m2 F, a set where ex , N 1 0, s2x 2 . We estimate rx and sx by
of decision rules for consumption, asset holdings, estimating the AR(1) process of wages from
and labor supply, 5c 1a, x; l,  m 2 , a91a, x; l, m 2 , the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID)
h 1a, x ; l, m 26, aggregate inputs, 5K1l, m 2, L 1l, m 26, for 1979–1992. We control for time effects by
factor prices, 5w 1l, m 2 , r 1l, m 2 6, and a law of annual dummies and individual fixed effects by
motion for the distribution mr 5 T1l, m 2 such sex, age, schooling, age2, schooling2, and age
that: 3 schooling. We then convert the annual esti-
mates to quarterly values. The quarterly values
• Individuals optimize: given w1l, m2 and r 1l, m2, we obtain are rx 5 0.929 and sx 5 0.227. The
the individual decision rules c 1 a,  x ; l,  m 2 , other parameters are in accordance with the
a9 1 a , x ; l,  m 2 , and h 1 a , x ; l, m 2 solve business cycle analysis and empirical labor-
V  E 1a,  x ; l,  m 2, V  N 1a,  x ; l,  m 2, and V  1 a,  x ; l,  m 2. supply literature. A working individual spends
one-third of discretionary time: h 5 1/3. The
• The representative firm maximizes profits: intertemporal elasticity of hours at the individ-
for all (l, m), ual level, g, is 0.4. The labor-income share, a, is
0.64, and the depreciation rate, d, is 2.5 percent.
w 1 l, m 2 5 F1 1 L 1 l, m 2 , K 1 l, m 2 , l 2 , We search for the weight parameter in the disu-
tility from working, B, such that the steady-state
r 1 l, m 2 5 F2 1 L 1 l, m 2 , K 1 l, m 2 , l 2 2 d. employment rate is 60 percent, the average of
the Current Population Survey (CPS) for 1964:
• The goods market clears: for all (l,  m), I–2003:IV. The discount factor b is chosen so

2 5a91a, x ; l, m 2 1 c 1a, x ; l, m 2 6 dm


that the quarterly rate of return to capital is 1
percent. The aggregate productivity shock, lt,
follows an AR(1) process: ln lr 5 rl ln l 1 el,
5 F 1L 1l,  m 2 , K1l,  m 2 , l2   1 112 d 2K. where el , N 1 0, s2l 2 . We set rl 5 0.95 and sl
5 0.007 following Kydland and Prescott (1982).
• Factor markets clear: for all (l, m), Table 1 summarizes the parameter values of the

L 1 l, m 2 5 2xh 1a, x ; l, m 2 dm,


model economy.

K 1 l, m 2 5 2a dm.
B. Cross-Sectional Distributions for Earnings,
Wealth, and Reservation Wages

• Individual and aggregate behaviors are con- Since we investigate the aggregation issue, it
sistent: for all A0 , A and X 0 , X, is desirable for the model economy to possess a
reasonable amount of heterogeneity. We compare
m91A0, X 02 cross-sectional earnings and wealth—two impor-

   5    2A , X  U  2A, X 11a95a91a, x; l, m 2 dpx 1x9Zx2 dmV da9dx9.


tant observable dimensions of ­ heterogeneity in
0 0


We estimate the AR(1) process of the wage residual
using Heckman’s (1979) maximum-likelihood estimation

Let A and X denote sets of all possible realizations of procedure, correcting for a sample selection bias because
a and x, respectively. The measure m(a, x) is defined over a productivities (wages) of workers who did not work are not
s-algebra of A 3 X. reported. See Chang and Kim (2006) for details.
1944 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

Table 1—Parameters of the Benchmark Model Economy

Parameter description
a 5 0.64 Labor share in production function
b 5 0.98267 Discount factor
g 5 0.4 Individual labor-supply elasticity with divisible labor
Utility parameter
–B 5 166.3
h 5 1/3 Labor supply if working
a{ 5 22.0 Borrowing constraint
rx 5 0.929 Persistence of idiosyncratic productivity shock
sx 5 0.227 Standard deviation of innovation to idiosyncratic productivity
rl 5 0.95 Persistence of aggregate productivity shock
sl 5 0.007 Standard deviation of innovation to aggregate productivity

the labor market—found in the model and in the ratios are 0.16, 0.61, 1.30, and 3.08 according
data. to our model. Households in the second, third,
Table 2 summarizes both the PSID and the fourth, and fifth quintiles of wealth distribu-
model’s detailed information on wealth and tion earn, respectively, 14.67, 20.08, 25.07, and
earnings. As we control for the observed fixed 25.86 percent of total earnings, according to the
effects in estimating individual productivity, we PSID. The corresponding groups earn 17.87,
will compare our model to the PSID statistics 20.50, 22.65, and 25.46 percent, respectively, in
after conditioning on educational attainment and the model. We argue that the model economy
age. The category “PSID primary households” presented in this paper possesses a reasonable
denotes households whose head is a high-school degree of heterogeneity, thus making it possible
graduate and whose age is between 35 and 55 to study the effects of aggregation in the labor
as of 1983 (1984 survey). Family wealth in the market.
PSID reflects the net worth of houses, other real In our model, labor-market participation is
estate, vehicles, farms and businesses owned, determined by market opportunity (wage) and
stocks, bonds, cash accounts, and other assets. wealth (asset holdings). We plot the steady-state
For each quintile group of wealth distribution, reservation wage schedule in Figure 3. Panel A
we calculate the wealth share, the ratio of group graphs the reservation wage for all asset levels
average to economy-wide average, and the earn- and panel B for assets less than $200,000. At a
ings share. given asset level, workers with a wage (produc-
In both the data and the model, the poorest 20 tivity) above the line choose to work. The reser-
percent of families in terms of wealth distribu- vation wage increases as the asset level increases.
tion were found to own virtually nothing. The To illustrate, we adjust the units such that the
PSID found that households in the second, third, mean asset of the model matches the average
fourth, and fifth quintiles own 7.07, 13.01, 21.10, asset of the comparison group (household head is
and 57.76 percent of total wealth, respectively, a high-school graduate and is between 35 and 55
while, according to the model, they own 3.27, years of age) in the 1984 PSID survey, $102,744;
12.21, 26.05, and 60.93 percent, respectively. thus, the values are in 1983 dollars.10 Consider
The average wealth of those in the second, third, a worker whose assets are $61,563, the median
fourth, and fifth quintiles is, respectively, 0.36, of the wealth distribution from the model.
0.64, 1.06, and 2.97 times larger than that of a According to the model, he is indifferent about
typical household, according to the PSID. These working and not working at quarterly earnings of
$6,927. Another worker whose assets are equiv-
alent to the average asset holding of the econ-

One should note that the unconditional wealth distri- omy, $102,744 (which belongs to the sixty-third
bution is much more skewed than that of “primary house-
holds.’’ For example, according to the unconditional wealth
10
distribution (i.e., all households in the 1984 PSID), the first The mean asset in our model is 11.59 units. The res-
to fifth quintiles own, respectively, –0.52, 0.50, 5.06, 18.74, ervation wages in the vertical axis of Figure 3 reflect quar-

and 76.22 of total wealth. terly earnings (the reservation wage rate multiplied by h ).
VOL. 97 NO. 5 CHANG AND KIM: Heterogeneity and Aggregation 1945

Table 2—Characteristics of Wealth Distribution

Quintile
1st 2nd 3rd 4th 5th Total
PSID–primary households
Share of wealth 1.03 7.07 13.01 21.10 57.76 100
Group average/population average 0.05 0.36 0.64 1.06 2.97 1
Share of earnings 14.29 14.67 20.08 25.07 25.86 100
Participation rate 0.86 0.84 0.83 0.87 0.79 1
Benchmark model
Share of wealth 22.46 3.27 12.21 26.05 60.93 100
Group average/population average 20.12 0.16 0.61 1.30 3.08 1
Share of earnings 13.52 17.87 20.50 22.65 25.46 100
Participation rate 0.86 0.63 0.56 0.50 0.43 1
Notes: The PSID statistics reflect the family wealth and earnings in the 1984 survey. The statistics of “primary households”
are those for household heads whose education was 12 years and whose age is between 35 and 55. The participation rate is
based on individual employment status (household heads and spouse) for the same group.

Y  ""MMBTTFUMFWFMT



3FTFSWBUJPOXBHFT






       
Y 

#"TTFUTMFTTUIBO 

 
3FTFSWBUJPOXBHFT





 .FBO8FBMUI
.FEJBO8FBMUI



          
Y 
"TTFUTJOEPMMBST

Figure 3. Reservation Wages from the Benchmark Model

Note: The graph denotes the reservation wages from the benchmark model. Wages (quarterly earnings) and assets are in
1983 dollars.
1946 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

Table 3—Volatilities of Aggregate Variables actual output volatility. This is not very different
Variable US data Model
from the findings of the standard representative-
2.06 1.28
agent models (e.g., Kydland and Prescott 1982).
sY
sC ysY 0.45 0.39 Other statistics are also similar to those found
sI ysY 2.41 3.06 in the standard models: consumption is about 40
sH ysY 0.82 0.76 percent as volatile as output, and investment is
sL ysY — 0.50 about three times as volatile as output.
sY yHysY 0.50 0.50
sH ysYyH 1.64 1.72 A distinguishing feature of our model lies in
sMRS ysY 0.90 0.83 the labor-market fluctuations. The volatility of
swedge ysY 0.92 0.76 hours relative to output is 0.76 (0.82 in the data),
Notes: All variables are logged and detrended by the H-P
and the volatility of labor productivity relative
filter. The volatility of output is measured by its standard to output is the same as that in the data (0.50).
deviation and that of all other variables are measured by The relative volatility of hours to productivity
the standard deviations relative to output. The variable L is 1.72, very close to that in the data (1.64). In
denotes the effective unit of hours. The MRS and wedge are our model, the aggregate labor supply is quite
defined, respectively, by equations (1) and (2).
elastic, despite the fact that individual intertem-
poral substitution elasticity for hours is assumed
to be 0.4. As Chang and Kim (2006) show, in
p­ ercentile of the wealth distribution in our model a model economy like this, the aggregate labor
and to the sixty-ninth percentile in the PSID), is supply elasticity depends on the shape of the
indifferent about working at $7,890 per quarter. reservation wage distribution. In our model,
The model predicts a fairly strong wealth effect based on the steady-state reservation wage dis-
on participation. The labor-market participation tribution, the elasticity of the participation rate
rates are 0.86, 0.63, 0.56, 0.50, and 0.43, respec- with respect to the reservation wage is 1.5 at the
tively, from the first to fifth quintiles. According steady-state employment rate of 60 percent. The
to the PSID, however, the wealth effect seems composition effect also increases the volatility
much weaker. The labor-market participation of aggregate hours relative to average produc-
rates are 0.86, 0.84, 0.83, 0.87, and 0.79, respec- tivity. On average, less-productive workers par-
tively, from the first to fifth asset quintiles. ticipate in the labor market during expansions
and exit during contractions. This makes the
C. Cyclical Properties of the Model measured hours more volatile than the hours in
effective units and the average wage less volatile
To study the business cycle properties of the than individual wages. When we measure hours
model, we solve the equilibrium of the model worked in effective units, they are half as vola-
using the “bounded rationality” method devel- tile as output (0.50).
oped by Krusell and Smith (1998): agents make Table 4 shows the cyclicality of key aggre-
use of a finite set of moments of m in forecasting gate variables. The correlations between output,
aggregate prices. The detailed description of our consumption, investment, and labor produc-
computation procedure is given in the Appendix. tivity are higher than those in the data, a fea-
As in Krusell and Smith (1998), we achieve a ture common in standard real business cycle
fairly precise forecast using the first moment of (RBC) models. The correlation of hours with
m only (i.e., the mean asset). We also find that output is 0.84, close to that in the data (0.86).
the results do not change significantly when we A surprising aspect of the model is that hours
allow for the second moment of assets in fore- worked and labor productivity exhibit a fairly
casting functions (see Table A in the Appendix low correlation (0.23) in our model—it is 0.08
for the comparison of these results). in the data—despite the fact that the only driv-
Table 3 shows the volatility of the key aggre- ing force in the simulation is the aggregate pro-
gate variables of our model economy. In the ductivity shock. This is a striking result because
face of aggregate productivity shocks whose the failure to generate a low correlation between
stochastic process resembles that of TFP in hours and labor productivity is known to be one
the United States, the model output exhibits a of the most salient shortcomings of the RBC
­volatility of 1.28, slightly less than two-thirds of models. In our model, the interaction between
VOL. 97 NO. 5 CHANG AND KIM: Heterogeneity and Aggregation 1947

Table 4—Cyclicality of Aggregate Variables total hours. The standard deviation of the wedge
Variable Data Model
relative to output (swedge/sY) is 0.76 (0.92 in
Corr(Y, C) 0.69 0.84
the data). Given that the output volatility of the
Corr(Y, I) 0.90 0.98 model is about two-thirds of that in the data, the
Corr(Y, H) 0.86 0.87 wedge from the model is about half as volatile as
Corr(Y, L) — 0.92 the one in the data. The correlation between the
Corr(Y, YyH) 0.57 0.68 wedge and total hours worked 1Corr 1H, wedge 2 2
Corr(H, Y/H) 0.08 0.23
Corr(YyH, MRS) 0.25 0.43 is 0.87 (0.85 in the data). Despite there being
Corr(Y, wedge) 0.55 0.56 no inherent preference shifts or distortions, the
Corr(H, wedge) 0.85 0.87 wedge arises endogenously because of imper-
Note: See the note in Table 3 for description of the variables. fect aggregation and a time-varying reservation-
wage distribution. In computing the wedge, we
use the aggregate labor-supply elasticity of 1.5,
the same value we used to compute the wedge
incomplete capital markets and indivisible labor in the actual data. A bigger (smaller) value of
breaks the tight link between employment and aggregate labor-supply elasticity produces a
wages at the aggregate level.11 Because of indi- smaller (bigger) wedge. Nevertheless, in our
visible labor, the optimality conditions for the model (as well as in the actual data), there is
choice of consumption and hours worked hold no choice of g that eliminates the wedge com-
as inequality at the individual level. Owing to pletely. The wedge arises not only because pro-
the partial insurance of idiosyncratic risks, ductivity is not as volatile as the marginal rate
individual optimality conditions do not aggre- of substitution but also because they are not cor-
gate nicely. Moreover, the labor-supply curve is related with each other. For example, even with
time-varying in the face of aggregate productiv- g 5 10, the measured wedge from the model is
ity shifts as the reservation wage distribution still about half as volatile as output (swedge/sY 5
(wealth distribution) evolves over time.12 0.56) and highly correlated with hours worked
1Corr 1H, wedge 2 2 5 0.53).13
D. Labor-Market Wedge from the Model
IV.  Role of Incomplete Markets and  
From the perspective of an optimizing agent Indivisible Labor
in a competitive market, a lack of systematic
movement among consumption, employment, The interaction between incomplete markets
and productivity is manifested by measurement and indivisible labor results in a wedge between
of a stochastic wedge between the MRS and the MRS and productivity. To investigate the
productivity. When we apply a fictitious rep- marginal contributions of each, we consider
resentative agent’s optimality condition to the three additional model economies. For com-
model-generated aggregate time series, we also parison, we refer to the benchmark economy as
find a time-varying wedge. HII, which stands for “heterogeneity-incomplete
Figure 4 shows total hours worked and the markets-indivisible labor.”
wedge from the model-generated aggregate time
series under the assumption that the aggregate A. Alternative Model Specifications
labor-supply elasticity is 1.5. Similar to the mea-
sured wedge from the actual data, the wedge is Heterogeneity 1 Complete Market 1 Indi­
as volatile as hours and is highly correlated with visible Labor.—The second model we consider

11
Jang-Ok Cho and Rogerson (1988) also obtain a nega-
13
tive productivity-hours correlation from the heterogeneity According to Sungbae An, Chang, and Kim (2007),
of productivity in a two-member household model. the GMM estimation of the static first-order condition
12
Francois Gourio and Pierre-Alexander Noual (2006) using aggregate hours, consumption, and wages based on
report that the implied Frisch elasticity of aggregate labor this model economy often yields a negative labor-supply
supply, estimated from the National Longitudinal Survey elasticity—a nonconcave utility—similar to the finding in
of Youth (NLSY) data for 1979–1992, exhibits significant N. Gregory Mankiw, Julio J. Rotemberg, and Lawrence H.
variations over time. Summers (1985) based on the actual aggregate data.
1948 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

 
MO)
MO8FEHF











 
          

Figure 4. Total Hours and Labor-Market Wedge from the Benchmark Model

Note: The wedge is computed from equation (2) with the aggregate labor-supply elasticity 1g2 of 1.5.

allows for complete capital markets but main- The equilibrium of this economy is identical
tains indivisible labor: heterogeneity-complete to the allocation made by a social planner who
markets-indivisible labor (HCI). This is similar maximizes the equally weighted utility of the
to Cho (1995), which incorporates ex post het- population. The planner chooses the sequence
erogeneity into a standard real business cycle of consumption {Ct}qt50 and the cut-off produc-
framework.14 Thanks to perfect risk sharing, tivity {x*t }qt50 for labor-market participation.
agents enjoy the same level of consumption To ensure an efficient allocation, the planner
regardless of their employment status, produc- assigns workers who have a comparative advan-
tivity, or asset holdings.15 tage in the market (more productive workers) to
work. If –a worker’s productivity is above x*t , he
14
The difference between Cho’s model and ours is the supplies h hours of labor.
cross-sectional distribution of productivity. Cho uses a uni- The planner’s value function in the complete
form distribution, whereas we use a log-normal distribu- market, denoted by V C 1 K, l 2 , and the decision
tion, closer to the cross-sectional income distribution in the rules for consumption, C 1 K, l 2 , and cut-off
data.
15
The distribution of workers is no longer a state variable
in the individual optimization problem. Moreover, because productivity, the cross-sectional distribution of workers is
of the ergodicity of the stochastic process for ­idiosyncratic always stationary.
VOL. 97 NO. 5 CHANG AND KIM: Heterogeneity and Aggregation 1949

productivity, x* 1 K, l 2 , satisfy the following the benchmark model with the worker’s value
Bellman equation: function with divisible labor, V D 1a, x; l, m 2:
2 111/g
h VD 1a, x; l, m 2
V  1K, l2 5 max* Uln C 2 B 
C
C, x 1 1 1/g h111/g
   5 max Uln c 2 B 
1 1 1/g
3 3 f 1x 2 dx
` ar[A, h[ 1 0, 1 2


x*t 1 bE CV D 1a9, x9; l9, m92 Zx, lD V

1 bE CV C 1K9,  l92 ZlD V subject to

subject to c 5 w 1l,  m 2 xh 1 11 1 r 1l, m 2 2 a 2 a9,

a9 $ a–,
Kr 5 F 1 K, L, l 2 1 1 1 2 d 2 K 2 C,
m9 5 T1l,  m 2.
– `
where L 5 h ex* xf 1x 2 dx is the aggregate effec-
tive unit of labor, and f 1x 2 is the productivity Representative-Agent Model.—The last model
distribution of workers. The planner chooses the we consider is the “representative-agent” (RA)
cut-off productivity x* so that: model. The value function of the representative
agent, V R 1K, l2 , is:
(4) 
H111/g
1
2 111/g
h V R 1K; l2 5 maxUln C 2 B


 FL(K, L, l) h x* f 1x*2 5 B  f 1x*2. C, H 1 1 1/g
C 1 1 1/g
1 bE CV R 1a9, x9; l9, m92 Zx, lD V
The left-hand side is the (society’s) utility gain subject to
from assigning the marginal worker to produc-
tion. There are f 1x*2 number of workers with K9 5 F 1K, H, l2 1 11 2 d 2K 2 C.
productivity
– x in the economy. Each of them
*

supplies h x* units of effective labor, and the mar-


ginal product of labor is FL . The right-hand side B. Comparison of Four Model Economies
represents the disutility incurred by these work-
ers. The key point here is that, under complete Except for b and B, the same parameter val-
markets, the first-order condition for the choice ues are used across all models. In the RA model,
between hours and consumption is exactly b is 0.99 and B is chosen so that the steady-state
defined in terms of effective units of labor and hours worked are the same as the aggregate
wages at the aggregate level. Thus, the wedge hours
– in the benchmark economy, which is 0.2
reflects the “measurement error” in aggregate (5 h 3 60 percent). For HCI, b is 0.99 and B is
wages and hours. As we show in Section IVB, chosen to be consistent with 60 percent employ-

the wedge would be zero with an appropriate ment along with h 5 1/3.16 For HID, b and B
choice of aggregate labor-supply elasticity. are jointly searched to be consistent with aver-
age hours of 0.2 and an interest rate of 1 percent
Heterogeneity 1 Incomplete Market 1 Divis­ in a steady state. The equilibrium of the HCI
ible Labor.—The third model economy we economy is solved by Albert Marcet and Guido
consider allows for a divisible labor supply, but Lorenzoni’s (1999) parameterized expectation
capital markets are incomplete: “heterogene-
ity-incomplete markets-divisible labor (HID). 16
Specifically, we find the steady-state cutoff produc-
This is essentially the same specification as in tivity, x*, from the sixtieth percentile of the cross-sectional
Krusell and Smith (1998). The equilibrium of productivity distribution, f(x) : ex * (x)f(x) dx 5 0.6. Then,
`

this economy can be defined similarly to that of we find B that satisfies the labor-supply equation, (4).
1950 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

algorithm, while the equilibrium of HID is productivity shocks, hours are highly correlated
solved by Krusell and Smith’s (1998) “bounded across households, allowing for a fairly precise
rationality” method, and the equilibrium of RA aggregation. On the other hand, with indivisible
is solved by a value function iteration. labor, the intratemporal optimality condition for
One must assume an aggregate labor-supply the choice between commodity consumption
elasticity to compute the MRS. For the divis- and leisure does not hold with equality for most
ible-labor economies (RA and HID), the natural households. Individual choices are at the corner,
choice is 0.4, which is the same as the individual and the aggregation of inequalities does not lead
elasticity. However, when the labor supply is us to meaningful aggregate relationships among
indivisible (HII and HCI), the aggregate labor- hours, consumption, and productivity.
supply elasticity can depart from the individual The HCI model shows that indivisible labor
elasticity. We compute the wedge for indivisible- alone cannot account for the wedge we observe
labor economies assuming that the aggregate in the data either. Under complete capital mar-
elasticity is 1.5 for the following reasons. First, kets the consumption-hours choice holds exactly
according to the steady-state reservation wage in effective units at the aggregate level—recall
distribution, the elasticity of the participation equation (4). Thus, in the complete market model,
rate with respect to the reservation wage is 1.5 the wedge reflects the “specification error” in the
at the steady-state employment rate of 60 per- aggregate labor-supply elasticity (or “composi-
cent.17 Second, this value is close to the empiri- tional bias” in hours and wages). In other words,
cal estimates of aggregate Frisch elasticity (e.g., with an appropriate choice of aggregate elasticity,
Francois Gourio and Pierre-Alexander Noual one can eliminate the wedge completely. In fact,
2006). Third, it provides a direct comparison if we assume an aggregate labor-supply elasticity
with the wedge computed from the actual data of 2.09 in HCI, there is virtually no wedge.18
in Section I. It is well known that low-wage and less-
For the complete market model (HCI), as skilled workers enter the labor market during
discussed later in this section, an appropriate expansions and exit during recessions, making
choice of g can eliminate the wedge completely. aggregate hours more volatile than the effec-
Thus, g 5 1.5 is only for convenience. tive unit of hours (Hansen 1993), and making
Figure 5 shows the sample paths (percentage the aggregate wages less volatile than indi-
deviations from the steady states) of the wedges vidual wages (Mark Bils 1985; Gary Solon,
from four model economies. These sample paths Robert Barsky, and Jonathan A. Parker 1994).19
are comparable to each other because all model However, the compositional bias has an impact
economies are subject to an identical sequence mostly on the volatilities, not on the correlations.
of aggregate productivity shocks. As expected, In both the model and the data, the wedge arises
there is no wedge in the RA model. The wedges because of low correlation between employment
of the HID and HCI are not large enough to and ­productivity. From the data (as well as our
account for the wedge in the data. The volatili- benchmark model), we find the wedges regard-
ties of the wedge relative to output are 0.09 for less of the value for the aggregate labor-supply
both HID and HCI, which are, respectively, only elasticity. Moreover, the aggregate labor-­supply
one-tenth of that found in the data (0.92). curve is no longer an invariant parameter in
As the HID model shows, capital-market
incompleteness alone does not generate a wedge 18
The aggregate elasticity in the complete market
comparable to what we observe in the data. economy, such as HCI, depends on the ratio of the mar-
With divisible labor, in response to aggregate ginal density relative to the cumulative distribution of x at
the participation cutoff point x*. For example, in Gary D.
Hansen (1985) where agents are identical, the cross-sec-
tional distribution of x is degenerate and the aggregate elas-
17
In an environment similar to the one in this paper, ticity becomes an infinity.
19
Chang and Kim (2006) obtained an aggregate labor-sup- Bils (1985) and Solon, Barsky, and Parker (1994),
ply elasticity of around one. Since we control for observed based on the individual panel data, find that aggregate wages
fixed effects here, we obtain smaller values for persistence are less cyclical than individual wages. Hansen (1993) com-
and variance of idiosyncratic productivity. This makes the putes the effective unit of hours based on the worker char-
reservation-wage distribution less dispersed and results in a acteristics provided by the CPS. He finds that while the
slightly higher aggregate labor-supply elasticity. effective unit of hours adjusted for quality exhibits a greater
VOL. 97 NO. 5 CHANG AND KIM: Heterogeneity and Aggregation 1951

 













)FUFSPHFOFJUZ *ODPNQMFUF.BSLFU *OEJWJTJCMF-BCPS



)FUFSPHFOFJUZ $PNQMFUF.BSLFU *OEJWJTJCMF-BCPS
)FUFSPHFOFJUZ *ODPNQMFUF.BSLFU %JWJTJCMF-BCPS

 3FQSFTFOUBUJWF"HFOU.PEFM

 
          

Figure 5. Labor-Market Wedges from the Models

Note: The wedge is computed from equation (2). We use the aggregate labor-supply elasticity 1g2 of 0.4 and 1.5, respectively,
for divisible- and indivisible-labor models.

our benchmark model, since the shape of the c­ orrelated with labor productivity has been con-
­reservation-wage distribution varies over time. sidered one of the most salient shortcomings of
the equilibrium business cycle theory. We demon-
V.  Conclusion strate that a heterogeneous-agent economy with
incomplete capital markets and indivisible labor
The cyclical behavior of aggregate consump- can generate a low ­ employment-­productivity
tion, hours worked, and productivity is hard to correlation. When we apply the optimality con-
reconcile with the equilibrium outcome of the dition implied by the representative agent to
representative agent with standard preferences. the model-generated aggregate time series, we
The fact that hours worked are not strongly find a time-varying wedge between the mar-
ginal rate of substitution and labor productivity,
despite the fact that our model has neither dis-
volatility, such an adjustment does not significantly change tortion nor exogenous labor-supply shocks. Our
the cyclical property of hours. In practice, estimating qual- results caution against viewing the measured
ity-adjusted hours is not easy since observed characteristics
account for only a fraction of a worker’s productivity. For wedge as a failure of labor-market clearing or as
example, the R2 of the cross-sectional wage regression is a fundamental driving force behind aggregate
usually well below 0.4. fluctuations.
1952 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

Appendix A: Computational Procedures for Steady-State Equilibrium

The distribution of workers, m(x, a), is invariant in the steady state, as are factor prices. In find-
ing the invariant, m, we use the algorithm suggested by José-Víctor Ríos-Rull (1999). We search for
the discount factor b that clears the capital market, given the quarterly rate of return of 1 percent.
Computing the steady-state equilibrium amounts to finding the value functions, the associated deci-
sion rules, and the time-invariant measure of workers. Details are as follows:
1. First, we choose the grid points for asset holdings (a) and idiosyncratic productivity (x). The
number of grids is denoted by Na, and Nx. We use Na 5 1,163 and Nx 5 17. The asset holding ai is in
the range of [22,250], where the average asset holding is 11.6. The grid points of assets are not equally
spaced. We assign more points on the lower asset range to better approximate the savings decisions of
workers with lower assets. For example, at the asset range close to the borrowing constraint, the grid
points are as fine as 0.02, which is approximately 2.5 percent of the average labor income. At the high
end, the asset grid increases by 0.4, which corresponds to 42 percent of the average labor income.
For idiosyncratic productivity, we construct a grid vector of length Nx of which elements, ln xj ’s,
are equally spaced on the interval C23sx / "1 2 r2x , 3sx / "1 2 r2x D .
Then, we approximate the transition matrix of the idiosyncratic productivity using George
Tauchen’s (1986) algorithm.
2. Given b, we solve the individual value functions V E , V N, and V at each grid point of the indi-
vidual states. In this step, we also obtain the optimal decision rules for asset holding a91ai, xj 2 and
labor supply h 1ai, xj 2. This step involves the following procedure:
(a) Initialize value functions V0E 1ai, xj 2 and V0N 1ai, xj 2 for all i 5 1, … , Na and j 5 1, … , Nx .
(b) Update value functions by evaluating the discretized versions
– –
V1E 1ai, xj 2 5 max Uu 1wh xj 1 11 1 r2 ai 2 a9, h 2 ,

1 b a V0 1a9, xj92 px 1xj9 Zxj 2 2V,


Nx

jr51

where px 1xj9 Z xj 2 is the transition probabilities of x, which is approximated using Tauchen’s algorithm.
V1N is computed in a similar way. Then, update V1 1ai, xj 2 as follows:

V1 1ai, xj 2 5 max UV1E 1ai, xj 2 , V1N 1ai, xj 2V.

(c) If V1 and V0 are close enough for all grid points, then we have found the value functions.
Otherwise, set V0E 5 V1E (likewise for V N), and go back to step 2(b).
3. Using a91ai, xj 2 , px 1xj9|xj 2 obtained from step 2, we obtain time-invariant measures u* 1ai, xj 2 as
follows:
(a) Initialize the measure m0 1ai, xj 2.

(b) Update the measure by evaluating the discretized version of (5):

m1 1ai9, xj92 5 a a 11ai95a9(ai , xj ) m0 1ai, xj 2 px 1xj9 Zxj 2.


Na Nx

i51 j51

(c) If m1 and m0 are close enough for all grid points, then we have found the time-invariant measure.
Otherwise, replace m0 with m1 and go back to step 3(b).
VOL. 97 NO. 5 CHANG AND KIM: Heterogeneity and Aggregation 1953

K1b 2 5 g i51 g j51 ai m* 1ai, xj 2 and L 1b 2 g i51 g j51


(4) We calculate the real interest rate as a function of b, i.e., r 1b 2 5 a 1K1b 2/ 1L 1b 2 2 12 a2 d, where
Na Nx Na Nx
5xj h 1ai, xj 2 6m* 1ai, xj 2 . Other aggregate variables
of interest are calculated using m and decision rules. If r 1b 2 is close enough to the assumed value
*

of the real interest rate, we have found the steady state. Otherwise, we choose a new b and go back
to step 2.

Appendix B: Computational Procedures for Equilibrium with Aggregate Fluctuations

Approximating the equilibrium in the presence of aggregate fluctuations requires us to include


the measure of workers and the aggregate productivity shock in the list of state variables and to
keep track of the evolution of the measure m over time. Since m is an infinite dimensional object,
it is almost impossible to implement these tasks as they are. We follow the procedure suggested by
Krusell and Smith (1998): agents are assumed to make use of its first moment of assets (i.e., the mean
asset K 5 Em[a]) only in predicting the law of motion for m. We are implicitly assuming that the aver-
age productivity of workers Em[x] is constant due to the law of large numbers. Therefore, computing
the equilibrium with aggregate fluctuations amounts to finding the value functions, decision rules,
and law of motion for the aggregate capital within the class of log-linear functions in K and l.

1. In addition to the grids for individual state variables specified above, we choose 11 equally
spaced grid points for the aggregate capital, K, in the range of [0.9K *, 1.1K *], where K * denotes the
steady-state aggregate capital. In our numerous simulations, the capital stock has never reached the
upper or lower bound. For aggregate productivity, we choose nine grid points of log l that are equally
spaced on the interval of C23sl / "1 2 r2l , 3sl / "1 2 r2l D . The transition probability matrix of the
aggregate productivity is approximated by Tauchen’s algorithm as for the idiosyncratic productivity
shocks.
2. Let the parametric law of motion for the aggregate capital take a log linear function in K and l:

(B1) ln Kt11 5 k00 5 k01 ln Kt 1 k02 lnlt.

In order for individuals to make their decisions on savings and labor supply, they have to know (or
forecast) the interest rate and wage rate for an effective unit of labor. While the factor prices depend
on aggregate capital and labor, aggregate labor input is not known to individuals at the moment when
they make decisions. Thus, individuals need to predict the factor prices. These forecasts of factor
prices, in turn, must be consistent with the outcome of individual actions and the factor market-clear-
ing conditions. We also assume that individuals forecast the market wage and the interest rate using
a log-linear function of K and l:

(B2) ln wt 5 b 00 5 b 01 ln Kt 1 b 02 lnlt.

(B3) ln 1rt 1 d 2 5 d 00 1 d 01 ln Kt 1 d 02 lnlt.

3. We chose the initial values for the coefficients k0’s, b 0’s, and d0’s. Good initial values may come
from a representative-agent model.

4. Given the law of motion for the aggregate capital and the forecast functions for factor prices,
we solve the individual optimization problem. This step is analogous to step 2 in the steady-state
computation:

(a) We have to solve for the value functions and the decision rules over a bigger state space. Now
the state variables are 1a, x, K, l2.
1954 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

(b) Computation of the conditional expectation involves the evaluation of the value functions not
on the grid points along the K dimension, since K9 forecasted by (B1) need not be a grid point.
We polynomially interpolate the value functions along the K dimension when necessary.

5. Using a91ai, xj, Kl, lm 2 , h 1ai, xj, Kl, lm 2 , px 1xj9 Zxj 2 , and pl 1lm9 Zlm 2 , we simulate the saving and
labor supply decisions of 200,000 individuals for 3,500 periods. We then generate a set of aggregate
time series data {Kt, wt, rt} by aggregating these individuals’ decisions each period. We discard the
first 500 observations in order to reduce the effect of initial condition.

6. We obtain new values for coefficients k1’s, b1’s, and d1’s by the OLS from the simulated data.
If k1’s, b1’s, and d1’s are close enough to k0’s, b 0’s, and d 0’s, respectively, we have found the law of
motion. Otherwise, we update coefficients by setting k0 5 k1’s, b 0 5 b1’s, and d 0 5 d1’s, and go back
to step 4.
The estimated law of motion for capital and forecast functions and their accuracy, measured by R2
for the prediction equations, are as follows.

• Law of motion for aggregate capital in equation (B1):

(B4) ln Kt11 5 0.1133 1 0.9537 ln Kt 1 0.0997 lnlt,  R2 5 0.999937.

• Wage rate in equation (B2):

(B5) ln wt 5 2.02370 1 0.4494 ln Kt 1 0.7997 lnlt,  R2 5 0.997669.

• Interest rate in equation (B3):

(B6) ln 1rt 1 d 2 5 21.3936 2 0.7989 ln Kt 1 1.3559 lnlt,  R2 5 0.988726.

The law of motion for aggregate capital provides the highest accuracy. The wage function is more
accurate than the interest rate function. Overall, forecast functions are fairly precise as R 2’s are close
to one. As the agents make decisions based on the forecast prices, the actual employment may not
be necessarily consistent with the predicted prices. We also used the method suggested in Ríos-Rull
(1999) in which labor-market clearing is imposed as an extra step. The result with a two-step process
was very similar to the one reported here, since the forecast prices approximate the actual prices very
closely.

Appendix C: Labor-Market Wedge and Forecast Errors

The capital-market incompleteness (partial insurance of idiosyncratic risks) forces us to compute


the equilibrium of the benchmark model by the approximation method of Krusell and Smith (1998),
which assumes that agents use the limited number of moments of the asset distribution 1m 2 in fore-
casting aggregate prices. In particular, we assume that the agents forecast K9, w, and r by the log-lin-
ear function of the mean asset 1K 5 Em[a]2 and aggregate productivity (l) in equations (B1)–(B3). As
in Krusell and Smith (1998), these forecasts are highly precise, since R2’s are close to one. According
to Table A below, the standard deviations of the forecast errors are (0.02456, 0.13621, and 0.24217
percent, respectively, for K9, w, and r2 , much smaller than that of the labor-market wedge (1.23)—i.e.,
by a order of magnitude. Given that the wedge is a gap between the MRS and labor productivity
(which is in the same unit as the wage rate), the measured wedge cannot be completely accounted
for by forecast errors. While the wedge is nonlinear in nature (aggregation and indivisibility), we ask
whether the measurement of the wedge changes if we allow for higher-order moments of the distri-
bution in the forecasting functions. We compute the equilibria of the benchmark economy assum-
ing that the agents make use of the second moment (Em[a2]) as well as the first moment of the asset
VOL. 97 NO. 5 CHANG AND KIM: Heterogeneity and Aggregation 1955

distribution in forecasting functions. Table A Table A—Accuracy of Forecasts


shows that adding the second moment of asset
distribution to the forecast functions improves Moments of m(a) used Em[a] Em[a] and Em[a2]
the measure of fit (in terms of the R2 and the 2
R of forecasts
standard deviation of the forecast error) in all K9 0.9999372 0.9999397
forecasting functions, but only marginally. As w 0.9976695 0.9976698
a result, the labor-market wedge remains vir- r 0.9887260 0.9887277
tually the same as the linear approximation S.D. of forecast error (%)
case. For example, the standard deviation of K9 0.024564 0.024118
w 0.136219 0.136210
the wedge decreases by only 0.03 percent (from
r 0.242171 0.242153
1.23452 to 1.234074) with the addition of the
second moment in all forecasting functions. swedge 1.234520 1.234074

REFERENCES and Aggregate Labor-Market Fluctuations.”


American Economic Review, 82(3): 430–50.
Aiyagari, S. Rao. 1994. “Uninsured Idiosyncratic Cole, Harold L., and Lee E. Ohanian. 2002. “The
Risk and Aggregate Savings.” Quarterly Jour- U.S. and U.K. Great Depressions through the
nal of Economics, 109(3): 659–84. Lens of Neoclassical Growth Theory.” Ameri-
An, Sungbae, Yongsung Chang, and Sun-Bin Kim. can Economic Review, 92(2): 28–32.
2007. “Estimating Preferences Using Aggre- Comin, Diego, and Mark Gertler. 2003. “Medium
gate Data.” Unpublished. Term Business Cycles.” National Bureau of
Benhabib, Jess, Richard Rogerson, and Ran- Economic Research Working Paper 10003.
dall Wright. 1991. “Homework in Macroeco- Gali, Jordí, Mark Gertler, and J. David Lopez-
nomics: Household Production and Aggregate Salido. 2007. “Markups, Gaps, and the Wel-
Fluctuations.” Journal of Political Economy, fare Costs of Business Fluctuations.” Review of
99(6): 1166–87. Economics and Statistics, 89(1): 44–59.
Bils, Mark. 1985. “Real Wages over the Business Gourio, Francois, and Pierre-Alexander Noual.
Cycle: Evidence from Panel Data.” Journal of 2006. “The Marginal Worker and the Aggre-
Political Economy, 93(4): 666–89. gate Elasticity of Labor Supply.” Unpublished.
Bils, Mark, and Peter J. Klenow. 1998. “Using Hall, Robert E. 1987. “Productivity and Busi-
Consumer Theory to Test Competing Business ness Cycles.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference
Cycle Models.” Journal of Political Economy, Series on Public Policy, 27: 421–44.
106(2): 233–61. Hall, Robert E. 1997. “Macroeconomic Fluctua-
Chang, Yongsung, and Sun-Bin Kim. 2006. tions and the Allocation of Time.” Journal of
“From Individual to Aggregate Labor Supply: Labor Economics, 15(1): S223–50.
A Quantitative Analysis Based on a Heteroge- Hansen, Gary D. 1985. “Indivisible Labor and the
neous Agent Macroeconomy.” International Business Cycle.” Journal of Monetary Eco-
Economic Review, 47(1): 1–27. nomics, 16(3): 309–27.
Chari, Varadarajan V., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Hansen, Gary D. 1993. “The Cyclical and Secu-
Ellen R. McGrattan. 2005. “Business Cycle lar Behaviour of the Labour Input: Comparing
Accounting.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minne- Efficiency Units and Hours Worked.” Journal
apolis Staff Report 328. of Applied Econometrics, 8(1): 71–80.
Cho, Jang-Ok. 1995. “Ex-post Heterogeneity and Heckman, James J. 1979. “Sample Selection Bias
the Business Cycle.” Journal of Economic as a Specification Error.” Econometrica, 47(1):
Dynamics and Control, 19(3): 533–51. 153–61.
Cho, Jang-Ok, and Richard Rogerson. 1988. Heckman, James J. 1984.“Comments on the Ashen-
“Family Labor Supply and Aggregate Fluctua- felter and Kydland Papers [Macroeconomic
tions.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 21(2– Analyses and Microeconomic Analyses of
3): 233–45. Labor Supply] [Labor-Force Heterogeneity
Christiano, Lawrence J., and Martin Eichenbaum. and the Business Cycle].” Carnegie-Rochester
1992. “Current Real-Business Cycle Theories Conference Series on Public Policy, 21: 209–24.
1956 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

Holland, Allison, and Andrew Scott. 1998, “The Mulligan, Casey B. 2001. “Aggregate Implica-
Determinants of UK Business Cycles.” Eco- tions of Indivisible Labor.” National Bureau of
nomic Journal, 108(449): 1067–92. Economic Research Working Paper 8159.
Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. 1998. Mulligan, Casey B. 2002. “A Century of Labor-
“Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Leisure Distortions.” National Bureau of Eco-
Macroeconomy.” Journal of Political Econ- nomic Research Working Paper 8774.
omy, 106(5): 867–96. Nakajima, Tomoyuki. 2005. “A Business Cycle
Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. 2006. Model with Variable Capacity Utilization and
“Quantitative Macroeconomic Models with Demand Disturbances.” European Economic
Heterogeneous Agents.” Unpublished. Review, 49(5): 1331–60.
Kydland, Finn, and Edward Prescott. 1982. Ríos-Rull, José-Víctor. 1999. “Computation of
“Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations.” Equilibria in Heterogeneous-Agents Models.”
Econometrica, 50(6): 1345–70. In Computational Methods for the Study of
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., and Leonard A. Rapping. Dynamic Economies, ed. Ramon Marimon
1969. “Real Wages, Employment, and Infla- and Andrew Scott, 238–64. New York: Oxford
tion.” Journal of Political Economy, 77(5): University Press.
721–54. Rogerson, Richard. 1988. “Indivisible Labor, Lot-
MaCurdy, Thomas. 1981. “An Empirical Model teries and Equilibrium.” Journal of Monetary
of Labor Supply in a Life-Cycle Setting.” Economics, 21(1): 3–16.
Journal of Political Economy, 89(6): 1059– Sheinkman, Jose A., and Laurence Weiss. 1986.
85. “Borrowing Constraints and Aggregate Eco-
Mankiw, N. Gregory, Julio J. Rotemberg, and nomic Activity.” Econometrica, 54(1): 23–45.
Lawrence H. Summers. 1985. “Intertemporal Solon, Gary, Robert Barsky, and Jonathan A.
Substitution in Macroeconomics,” Quarterly Parker. 1994. “Measuring the Cyclicality of
Journal of Economics, 100(1): 225–51. Real Wages: How Important Is Composi-
Marcet, Albert, and Guido Lorenzoni. 1999. “The tional Bias?” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Parameterized Expectations Approach: Some 109(1): 1–25.
Practical Issues.” In Computational Meth- Tauchen, George. 1986. “Finite State Markov-
ods for the Study of Dynamic Economies, ed. Chain Approximations to Univariate and
Ramon Marimon and Andrew Scott, 143–71. Vector Autoregressions.” Economics ­Letters,
New York: Oxford University Press. 20(2): 177–81.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen