Sie sind auf Seite 1von 20

informs ®

Vol. 27, No. 6, November–December 2008, pp. 1036–1054


issn 0732-2399  eissn 1526-548X  08  2706  1036 doi 10.1287/mksc.1080.0358
© 2008 INFORMS

Building Brands
M. Berk Ataman
Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands, bataman@rsm.nl

Carl F. Mela
Fuqua Business School, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina 27708, mela@duke.edu

Harald J. van Heerde


Waikato Management School, University of Waikato, Hamilton 3240, New Zealand,
and CentER, Tilburg University, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands,
heerde@waikato.ac.nz

W hich marketing strategies are most effective for introducing new brands? This paper sheds light on this
question by ascribing growth performance to firms’ postlaunch marketing choices. We decompose the
success of a new brand into its ultimate market potential and the rate at which it achieves this potential. To
achieve this aim we formulate a Bayesian dynamic linear model (DLM) of repeat purchase diffusion wherein
growth and market potential are directly linked to the new brand’s long-term advertising, promotion, distribu-
tion, and product strategy. We perform the analysis on 225 new-brand introductions across 22 repeat-purchase
product categories over five years to develop generalized findings about the correlates of new-brand success.
We find that access to distribution breadth plays the greatest role in the success of a new brand, and that
investments in distribution and product innovation lead to greater marginal increases in sales for new brands
than either discounting, feature/display, or advertising. Moreover, distribution interacts with other strategies
to enhance their effectiveness. These findings underscore the utility of extending marketing mix models of
new-brand performance to include product and distribution decisions.
Key words: diffusion; new products; marketing mix; dynamic linear model; empirical generalization
History: This paper was received January 16, 2007, and was with the authors 6 months for 1 revision;
processed by Gary Lilien. Published online in Articles in Advance May 15, 2008.

1. Introduction literature (Hauser et al. 2006). Recent research on


Markets are often characterized by extensive new- new-brand diffusion has advanced our understand-
brand activity, and the pace of innovation is accel- ing of how external factors such as economic con-
erating. For example, 1,521 new consumer packaged ditions (Van den Bulte 2000), consumer differences
goods (CPG) brands were introduced to the United (Van den Bulte and Joshi 2007), competitive setting
States in 2004, double the number of brands intro- (Steenkamp and Gielens 2003), and product and coun-
duced in 1997 (Figure 1). Manufacturers use new try characteristics (Tellis et al. 2003) affect diffusion
brands to drive growth in otherwise stable environ- of new products across space and time. Moreover, a
ments because innovation is often envisioned as piv- number of new-product diffusion studies have incor-
otal to the success of firms. However, the performance porated internal, manageable factors in the diffusion
of new brands varies markedly across their roll-outs. process. Specifically, these studies have led to impor-
In CPG markets, only 20% of new brands earn more tant insights into how marketing affects the growth
than $7.5 million in first year sales, and less than 1% and/or market potential of durable goods (see Bass
enjoy revenues in excess of $100 million (Information et al. 2000 for a review).
Resources, Incorporated (IRI) 2005). Although essen- In spite of these advances, prior research has
tial to firms’ overall performance, few new brands focused on aspects of the marketing mix in isola-
reach the status of an established brand; the major- tion (promotion, product, price, and place), often
ity eventually fail. The IRI survey shows that failure used durable goods brands, and typically considered
rates have reached 55%. The tension arising between only one or a few products per study. When vari-
the need to innovate and the low success rate coupled ous aspects of marketing strategy (e.g., advertising
with innovation begs the question of how to facilitate and distribution) are coincidental, considering strate-
the success of new brands. gies in isolation can give a misleading picture of
Perhaps as a result, the growth of new brands which tools are most conducive to a successful launch
has received substantial interest in the marketing because the effect of one coincidental strategy can
1036
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1037

Figure 1 Number of New CPG Brand Introductions, 1997–2004 advertising. Much less emphasis has been placed on
1,521 distribution and product line, due in part to a paucity
1,361 of data. As noted by Muller et al. (2007, p. 72). “Of
the four P’s of the marketing mix, diffusion research
1,054
991 973
so far has created a sound body of knowledge con-
939
884 cerning the effects of price and promotion, yet little
736 has been done concerning the other two elements:
product and place.” By considering launch strategies
in their entirety, we control for potential correlations
across various marketing instruments, and we can
gauge their relative effect to assess which are most
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 efficacious.
Year • Second, we develop a diffusion model for fre-
Notes. The figures include entirely new brands or new-brand extensions but quently purchased CPG brands that simultaneously
exclude stock-keeping unit (SKU)-level variety introductions. All food, drug (a) considers the effect of repeat purchases, (b) accom-
and mass merchandising categories in the U.S. market are included.
Source. Information Resources, Inc. (2005). 2004 New Product Pacesetters.
modates a variety of potential diffusion trajectories,
(c) separates short-term fluctuations in sales from
long-term changes in brand performance arising from
be mistakenly attributed to another. Accordingly, lit- various marketing strategies (e.g., Mela et al. 1997),
tle information exists on the drivers of diffusion for and (d) controls for endogeneity in the marketing mix
nondurable goods. In this paper, we shed light on and models the role of past performance on mar-
diffusion in repeat-purchase contexts by offering an keting spend. We do this by formulating a Bayesian
integrated view across the entire marketing mix, and DLM of repeat purchase diffusion. In this approach,
we afford insights into introduction strategies that we model long-term effects by considering the growth
enhance the potential for successful roll-outs. process underpinning a brand’s baseline sales. We
We advance the literature on new-brand diffusion posit that growth in baseline sales follows a diffu-
in two ways: by conducting an empirical generaliza- sion process that is affected by changes in long-term
tion pertaining to the efficacy of marketing strategies marketing strategies. These strategies (e.g., distribu-
in the context of new-brand launch, and by develop- tion penetration or advertising stock) are linked to
ing a methodology to achieve these aims. both the rate of growth and the market potential. We
• First, we explore the effect of various marketing further accommodate short-term perturbations about
strategies (advertising spending, feature and display this growth process that arise from short-term mar-
activity, regular price, discount depth, product line keting activity (e.g., weekly discounts).
length, distribution breadth and distribution depth in We find that distribution and product play a greater
unison) on new-brand growth across 225 CPG brands. role than discounting, feature/display, and advertis-
Although some diffusion studies link certain elements ing in the sales performance of new brands in spite
of the marketing mix to growth and/or market poten- of a focus on these factors in the preceding litera-
tial of a new brand (see Table 1), most previous work ture. Overall, we find that access to distribution plays
focuses almost exclusively on the role of price and the greatest role in the success of a new brand. Our

Table 1 Selected Studies from Diffusion Literature Incorporating Marketing Mix Instruments

Growth Market potential

Price Eliashberg and Jeuland (1986), Parker (1992), Parker and Kalish (1983, 1985), Kalish and Lilien (1986), Kamakura
Gatignon (1994)a , Mesak and Berg (1995), Mesak (1996) and Balasubramanian (1988), Horsky (1990), Jain and
Rao (1990), Bass et al. (1994), Mesak and Berg (1995),
Mesak (1996)
This paper This paper
Promotion Lilien et al. (1981)a , Horsky and Simon (1983), Kalish (1985), Dodson and Muller (1978), Mesak (1996)
Simon and Sebastian (1987), Rao and Yamada (1988)a , Hahn
et al. (1994)a , Parker and Gatignon (1994)a , Mesak (1996)
This paper This paper
Place Mesak (1996) Jones and Ritz (1991), Mesak (1996)
This paper This paper
Product This paper This paper

Notes. The studies listed in the table consider diffusion of durable goods unless marked by an “a” for frequently purchased consumer product
categories. Promotion includes advertising expenditure.
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1038 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

results also show that advertising plays a greater role this stream of repeat-purchase modeling and extend
in accelerating brand growth than increasing market the earlier work by addressing the second challenge
potential, and that discounting has a positive effect on (flexible diffusion patterns) and the third challenge
the time to maturity but a negative effect on long-term (short- versus long-term fluctuations), as we discuss
market potential. We consider the marginal profits next.
associated with various marketing launch strategies Second, the sales trajectory of repeat-purchase
and find that distribution has the highest payoff; if the goods can follow a litany of diffusion patterns. Ear-
marginal cost of additional distribution is less than lier applications of repeat-purchase diffusion mod-
23% of marginal retail revenue, then it is profitable to els link growth to marketing activity, allowing for
expand distribution. In contrast, on average, adver- some degree of flexibility, but assume a constant
tising is profitable only when its marginal costs are market potential. The assumption of constant market
less than 0.8% of marginal retail revenue. Increasing potential implies a relatively quick increase in sales
product line length is profitable when the marginal followed by flatness once the brand’s market poten-
cost of doing so are less than 5% of the marginal retail tial is reached. However, when actual sales follow a
revenue. diffusion pattern with slow take-off, perhaps due to
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. First, limited initial availability, repeat-purchase diffusion
we review the extant literature on repeat-purchase models with constant market potential are ill-suited to
diffusion models. Next, we outline our modeling capture this phenomenon. Moreover, constant market
approach and provide a brief overview of the esti- potential precludes sales declines following the initial
mation process. After discussing the data, we provide success of a new brand. Such declines can arise from
variable operationalizations and develop expectations cuts in marketing support. A flexible market potential
about the role of marketing strategy on new-brand definition, such as the one proposed in this research,
performance. The results are given next followed by overcomes these concerns.
managerial implications drawn from several simula- Third, short-term fluctuations in sales might mask
tions. We conclude with some overall thoughts on the true long-term performance of the new brand (Mela
this paper, its limitations, and possibilities for future et al. 1997). Previous applications of repeat-purchase
research. diffusion models for nondurable goods calibrate the
diffusion model using monthly or quarterly data for
2. Modeling New-Brand Diffusion in products with relatively smooth sales patterns, such
as therapeutic drugs (e.g., Rao and Yamada 1988,
CPG Categories Hahn et al. 1994). Such sales data do not often exhibit
Though ubiquitous in marketing, the preponder-
short-term fluctuations given that these may be aggre-
ance of diffusion models has been developed for
gated out over the data interval, particularly as short-
durable goods categories. Modeling new-brand diffu-
term marketing activity is uncommon and seasonal
sion in frequently purchased nondurable goods cate-
patterns are not strong. However, for frequently pur-
gories requires a somewhat different approach given
chased CPG brands, data sampling rate is typically
the existence of repeat purchases, flexibility of diffu-
high, short-term oriented marketing activity is com-
sion patterns, and separating short-term fluctuations
mon, and seasonality assumes greater importance.
from long-term performance. We address these issues
Therefore, the series are far from being smooth. Ear-
subsequently.
lier work in the area recommends that the data be
First, sales arising from repeat purchases are espe-
cially relevant when considering the diffusion of fre- smoothed prior to estimation to eliminate short-term
quently purchased new CPG brands. In contrast, fluctuations (Lilien et al. 1981). Such smoothing pro-
traditional models of diffusion consider only the cedures will bias the parameters, especially when the
first purchases of the consumers and use aggre- variables that build market potential are correlated
gate category- or brand-level adoption sales data. with the variables that create the short-term fluctu-
Parameter estimates of traditional diffusion mod- ations in sales. We propose a model that separates
els are biased when replacement purchases are not short-term fluctuations from long-term performance
separated from first-time purchases (Kamakura and during estimation.
Balasubramanian 1987). To prevent such biases and
provide improved sales forecasts, several diffusion
3. Modeling Approach
model alternatives with replacement purchases have
been developed for durable goods (see Ratchford 3.1. General Approach
et al. 2000 for a review) as well as non-durable Consistent with the foregoing discussion, we seek
goods (Lilien et al. 1981, Rao and Yamada 1988, Hahn to determine (1) the rate of new-brand growth (and
et al. 1994). Given our research context, we follow the attendant implications for the time to reach peak
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1039

sales) and (2) the new brand’s ultimate market poten- where t indicates the base sales for the brand at
tial. Accordingly, we predicate our model formula- time t and
is the base market potential. The first
tion on the marketing literature on diffusion (Mahajan term captures retention effects, as a certain fraction, ,
et al. 1990). Given our emphasis on repeat-purchase of the past period’s base t−1 will continue to buy on
goods, our modeling approach closely parallels that the subsequent purchase occasions. The second term
of Lilien et al. (1981), Hahn et al. (1994), and Rao captures the attraction of the remaining potential cus-
and Yamada (1988) but with several key extensions: tomers, as a certain fraction, , of the remaining mar-
(1) our model is cast in a dynamic Bayesian setting ket (given by the deviation between the total market
to accommodate greater modeling flexibility and sta- potential
and past base sales t−1 ) will buy on the
tistical efficiency; (2) we link both growth and market subsequent purchase occasion. The second term there-
potential to marketing strategy, given the central aims fore represents the diffusion process governing the
of our paper; (3) we incorporate performance feed- long-term evolution of baseline sales potential. The
back to control for the role of past sales on future parameters and
have an additional interpreta-
marketing spending; (4) we consider potential com- tion, as is reflective of the time of adjustment to the
petitive effects; and (5) we control for endogeneity market potential while
reflects that potential. We
of price and the other marketing instruments. Like assume t ∼ N 0 W .
Lilien, Rao, and Kalish (henceforth LRK), we assume Figure 2 depicts growth trajectories in baseline sales
two market segments drive the base demand for a for various parameterizations of Equation (2). As sug-
new brand—those generated from new purchases and gested by this figure, baseline sales can grow quickly
those from retention. early in a brands’ life cycle and then asymptote as the
To formalize this notion, we begin by positing a brand diffuses through the population. This asymp-
linear model of brand sales, given by tote is given by ·
/1 −  +  if 0 < 1 −  +  < 1.
As increases, sales reach their asymptote faster. As
Salest = t + Xt  + t  (1)

increases, the sales potential grows. All else being
where Xt is a matrix of regressors containing short- equal, faster growth and greater potential lead to
term-oriented marketing activity that capture short- higher total sales.
term changes in sales around the brand’s growth Following LRK we allow the growth parameter to
trajectory and a control for seasonality. t is a parame- vary over time  → t  and specify this parameter as
ter that captures the long-term growth in brand sales, a function of the long-term marketing strategy used
which is governed by the diffusion process noted by the firm that introduces the brand, t ≡ Zt . For
above. Because the Xt include weekly discounts, fea- example, advertising stock might lead to increased
ture and display, and seasonality, t can be inter- awareness, thus accelerating trial rates. Like Xie et al.
preted as baseline sales (which we again presume to (1997), who consider the durables context, we allow
evolve following a diffusion process). The distinction the market potential to change over time 

t .
between long-term and short-term marketing effects In our application, though, we posit market potential
follows Jedidi et al. (1999), as short-term effects are to be a function of the long-term marketing strategy
captured by the effect of a given week’s marketing of a brand,
t ≡ Zt
. For example, advertising stock
activity, Xt , such as a promotion, and long-term effects might attract new buyers to the brand by changing
are captured by the effect of repeated exposures to their preferences. After substituting the new growth
marketing, Zt , on the time-varying parameter t (to and market potential definitions in Equation (2) we
be discussed later). We assume t ∼ N 0 V . obtain
We seek to capture nonlinearity in the baseline sales
t = t−1 + Zt Zt
− t−1  + t  (3)
over time using a diffusion-modeling approach. Fol-
lowing LRK we assume1
are not consumed the same week of purchase (e.g., detergent has
t = t−1 + 
− t−1  + t  (2) an eight-week purchase cycle), and (3) limited occasion for social
interactions within a week, word-of-mouth effects are likely min-
1
imal. In contrast, we note that the LRK model applied directly to
The diffusion model as developed by LRK applies to pharmaceu- CPG implies that incremental weekly sales drive word of mouth
tical detailing and can be expressed as follows: and that these effects last one week—which are strong assump-
t = t−1 + 
− t−1  + t−1 − t−2 
− t−1  − t−1 + t  tions in our context. We tested the assumption of no word-of-mouth
effects using a classical approach and find that the fit of the model
where is the innovation parameter, is the imitation parame-
with word-of-mouth effects is not significantly better than that
ter, and is the effect of competition. We modify this model in
of the model without word-of-mouth effects (likelihood ratio test
two key respects to make it suitable to the packaged goods con-
statistic = 789, p = 0444). Taken together, these arguments indi-
text we consider. First, we specify word-of-mouth effects to be neg-
cate the lack of word-of-mouth effects in frequently purchased CPG
ligible ( ≈ 0). This specification is consistent with the findings
markets. Second, we capture the effect of competition via the
of Hardie et al. (1998), who find no word-of-mouth effects across 19
baseline repeat parameter,  = 1 − ; that is,
different CPG data sets. Given (1) high variability in weekly sales
arising from weekly promotions, (2) the fact that most products t = t−1 + 
− t−1  − t−1 + t ≡ t−1 + 
− t−1  + t 
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1040 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

Figure 2 Growth Trajectory Illustrations Equation (3) therefore implies the rate of innovation
(a) 3.0 growth is affected by  and Z  , with lower values
of  − Z  implying faster adjustment to the long-
term sales level, given by Z  · Z 
/1 −  + Z  ) if 0 <
2.5 1 −  + Z   < 1. The steady-state sales equation fur-
ther implies that an increase in Z yields an increase
in the long-term sales level of a brand when
is
2.0 positive.
The interaction of the growth and market potential
parameters admit innumerable paths for brand sales.
Sales

1.5 For example, as  − Z  approaches 0 and Z  · Z 

becomes sufficiently large, sales will adjust immedi-


ately to a high mean but also fall again quickly when
1.0 marketing support is withdrawn. Conversely, a low
value for and a low value for
imply that the brand
μ0 = 3.75 γ = 0.2 will neither generate large sales nor increase sales
0.5 μ0 = 3.12 γ = 0.4
quickly (see Figure 2). The model further allows dif-
μ0 = 2.92 γ = 0.6
μ0 = 2.81 γ = 0.8
fusion speed and market potential to move in oppo-
site directions, as parameters
and are estimated
0 freely: Marketing activities that increase the market
0 5 10 15 20
Week potential might slow the speed to reach that higher
market potential. In sum, Equation (3) provides a flex-
(b) 3.0
ible model of baseline sales growth, which can change
in response to the marketing mix.
2.5
The model defined in Equations (1) and (3) belongs
to a family of Bayesian time-series models known as
the DLMs (West and Harrison 1997). In the next sec-
2.0 tion, we discuss model specification and provide a
brief overview of the estimation procedure.

3.2. Model Specification


Sales

1.5
Our goal is to explain how marketing mix activity
generates growth and builds market potential for a
1.0 new brand. We achieve this by estimating the trans-
fer function DLM developed in the previous section
μ0 = 3 γ = 0.2
(see Bass et al. 2007; Van Heerde et al. 2007, 2004 for
0.5 μ0 = 3 γ = 0.4 other DLM applications in marketing). The observa-
μ0 = 3 γ = 0.6 tion equation, which separates short-term fluctuations
μ0 = 3 γ = 0.8 from long-term sales, is specified as a linear sales
0 model,
0 5 10 15 20   j +  S 
Salesjt = jt + X (4)
Week jt jt

Notes. Figures assume  = 09. Note that it is also possible to accommodate where Salesjt is the vector of sales of brand j at
sigmoidal sales trajectories when market potential  varies over time t .
time t, and X jt includes variables that might gener-
ate short-term fluctuations in sales. We standardize
where  is the repeat-purchase rate, which we esti- all variables within brands and indicate this with a
mate without imposing any restrictions. is the superscripted bar. jt is the baseline sales for brand j
vector of growth parameters, and
is the vector and evolves over time, following the repeat-purchase
of market potential parameters associated with each diffusion process as specified in the following evolu-
marketing variable. tion equation:
The Zt in Equation (3) play a long-term role in the
trajectory of brand growth as a result of the carry-  Z
jt = j jt−1 + Z 
− jt−1  + 0jt  (5)
jt jt
over implied by the lagged t in Equation (3). Condi-
tioned on Zt constant at Zt = Z, Equation (3) becomes Zjt is a vector of standardized marketing strategy
a Koyck model whose carryover is given by  − Z  variables posited to affect diffusion. The standard-
(to see this, note (3) is equivalent to t = t−1 + ization ensures we can pool different units across
Z  · Z 
+ t where  =  − Z  ). The model in categories and control for unobserved time-invariant
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1041

brand effects.2 The parameter j captures the brand- where Zijt is the ith marketing mix instrument of
specific repeat-purchase rate, whereas and
cap- brand j in week t, and CZkct−1 is the sales-weighted
ture growth and market potential due to marketing average of the kth marketing mix instrument for com-
effort, respectively. petitors in category c (j ∈ c in week t − 1.3 Equa-
The observation equation and the evolution equa- tion (8) posits that observed marketing spending is a
tion specified in (4) and (5) can be compactly writ- manifestation of an underlying latent national strat-
ten as egy (ijt ), and deviations from this strategy arise from
random shocks. Equation (9) defines the evolution of
Yjt = Fjt jt + Xjt j + jt  (6) this latent strategy as a function of its past value, the
jt = Gjt jt−1 + hjt + jt  (7) past performance of the focal brand, and past mar-
keting activities of competition. The parameter 1ij is
where Yjt is the standardized sales of brand j in week t, associated with the lagged national strategy and cap-
and Fjt = 1. Xjt is the matrix of standardized regres- tures inertia in the marketing spending. Salesjt−1 is the
sors that create short-term fluctuations in sales. We focal brand’s lagged standardized national sales. Thus
assume jt ∼ N 0 V , where V is the observation the parameter 2ij captures own-performance feed-
equation error variance. The time-varying parameter back effect for the marketing mix instrument i. Finally,
vector jt = jt evolves as described in Equation (7). the parameters k+2 ij capture correlations between
Rearranging the terms in Equation (5) gives Gjt = j − the focal brand’s marketing and that of its competi-
jt . Then the second term on the right-hand side of
Z tors. The superscripted bar indicates that the variable
jt Z
Equation (7) is hjt = Z jt
. The stochastic term is standardized.
jt are distributed N 0 W , where W is the evolution
equation error variance. 3.4. Estimation
We estimate Equations (8) and (9) together with Equa-
3.3. Marketing Mix Endogeneity, Performance tions (4) and (5) and let error terms jtS and ijt Z

Feedback, and Competition be correlated to account for common unobserved


We specify an additional equation for each market- shocks in the observation equations.4 We place nor-
ing mix instrument to control for endogeneity in the mal priors on all parameters of the observation equa-
marketing mix, partial out the role of past perfor- tion, the evolution equation, and the marketing mix
mance, and control for competitive effects. To address equations. The evolution equation error covariance
endogeneity, we follow an approach analogous to matrix is assumed to be diagonal, and we place
instrumental variables wherein lagged endogenous an inverse Gamma prior on its diagonal elements.
variables serve as instruments. Moreover, we allow As we allow for correlation between the observa-
for correlation between the demand-side error term tion equation error terms and the marketing mix
and the supply-side error term to account for com- equation error terms, the associated error covari-
mon unobserved shocks in the system. ance matrix is full. Therefore, we place an inverse
We control for performance feedback (i.e., sales gains Wishart prior. Given these priors, the estimation is
lead to increased marketing) by including lagged carried out using DLM updating within a Gibbs sam-
national sales in each marketing equation. Past suc- pler. Conditional on , , V , W , ht , and Gt , the
cess in distribution—and hence sales, for example— time-varying intercepts are obtained via the forward-
might lead to increased distribution in subsequent filtering, backward-sampling procedure (Carter and
periods. Given that firms might also react to changes Kohn 1994, Frühwirth-Schnatter 1994). The param-
in the competitive landscape, we also consider com- eters of the baseline sales evolution are estimated
petitive marketing activity in the category. using a random walk Metropolis-Hastings algorithm,
For each marketing mix instrument the foregoing because the evolution equation is nonlinear in param-
discussion results in a time-varying mean DLM, eters. The details of the sampling chain are provided
in the appendix.
ijt = ijt +  Z 
Z (8)
ijt

ijt = 0ij + 1ij ijt−1 + 2ij Salesjt−1 3


The kth marketing mix instrument of the composite competitor in
a given category is computed as the weighted average of marketing

K
mix instruments of top five brands in that product category. We
+ k+2 ij CZ kct−1 + ijt  (9) use average market share in the most recent 13 weeks (t − 1 t −
k=1
2     t − 13) as rolling weights in the aggregation.
4
We estimated an alternative diagonal error correlation. The log
2
Standardization does not affect the ease of managerial interpreta- Bayes factor (BF) (West and Harrison 1997) favored the full
tion because we can always convert standardized values back to matrix specification over the diagonal matrix specification log BF =
their original scale. 18642.
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1042 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

4. Data and Variables or display support FoDjt , and average weekly tem-
perature (Tempt . Thus, Xjt = Discjt  FoDjt  Tempt . We
4.1. Data measure the SKU store-level depth of promotion by
We calibrate our model on a novel data set pro- one minus the ratio of the actual price to the regu-
vided by IRI (France). The data cover more than five lar price. The brand store-level promotion depth vari-
years (1/1/1999 to 2/1/2004) of weekly SKU store- able is chosen as the maximum discount depth across
level scanner data for 25 product categories sold in a SKUs (e.g., Mela et al. 1997), and the national brand
national sample of 560 stores operated by 21 differ- level variable is calculated as the store ACV-weighted
ent chains. We also use matching monthly brand-level average of the brand store-level data. The brand store-
advertising data provided by TNS Media Intelligence level feature and display variable take the value of
(France). one if at least one SKU from the brand’s product line
Data are aggregated from the SKU store level to is on promotion in a given week. The national brand-
national brand level following the procedures out- level averages for these variables are calculated across
lined in Christen et al. (1997) to avoid any biases stores in a linear fashion using lagged store ACV
due to aggregation. Because the sales model in Equa- as weights. We expect discounts and feature/display
tion (7) is linear, we first aggregated the data from intensity to have a positive short-term effect on sales,
SKU-store to brand-store level in a linear fashion (dis- while temperature affords a parsimonious control for
cussed in §4.2). Using lagged all commodity volume seasonality.
(ACV), we then calculated an ACV-weighted average
of brand-store level independent variables to obtain 4.2.2. Evolution Equation Variables. We now dis-
national-brand level data. cuss the operationalization of the marketing mix vari-
Between January 1, 1999 and February 1, 2004, ables in Zjt in the evolution Equation (5), along
we observe 365 new national brand introductions in with our expectations about the role they play in
25 product categories. Of these new brands, 55 fail growth and market potential. Table 3 summarizes our
expectations.
within the mentioned time window. For a single cat-
Price. We define the price of a brand as the regular
egory, the number of new-brand introductions varies
price in a given store week. Consistent with previous
between 5 and 38, with an average of 17 brands. On
studies (e.g., Mela et al. 1997), we select the minimum
average, we observe the first 152 weeks of the new
regular price per 1,000 volume units across SKUs of a
brand’s life cycle, with a minimum of 15 weeks and a
brand. The national brand-level average price is cal-
maximum of 264 weeks. We select brands with at least
culated across stores in a linear fashion, using lagged
two years of data, regardless of whether they succeed
store ACV as weights.
or fail, which leaves us with 225 new-brand introduc-
Previous research provides unequivocal evidence
tions in 22 categories (as opposed to line extensions
that regular price reductions influence the growth of
within existing brands).5 See Table 2 for descriptive
new-brand sales (Parker and Gatignon 1994, Parker
statistics.
1992). However, there is a lack of consensus on
4.2. Variables whether price also affects the market potential. Bass
The selection of variables is linked to our goal of con- et al. (1994) and Kamakura and Balasubramanian
trasting the relative efficacy of the marketing mix in (1987, 1988) find no impact from price, whereas
generating new-brand growth. The variables consid- Mesak and Berg (1995) and Kalish and Lilien (1986)
ered represent the conjunction of those suggested by report negative impact. However, like Eliashberg and
theory and those available in the data. In this section Jeuland (1986), we expect that lower prices stimu-
we detail each variable and its anticipated effect on late additional demand as the brand matures. More-
the diffusion of new brands. We first discuss the vari- over, the brand can achieve high market-penetration
ables in the observation, or sales, equation and then rate rather quickly because lower initial prices moti-
vate the potential buyers to make the purchase earlier
consider the variables in the growth equation.
(Bass and Bultez 1982). In sum, we expect lower prices
4.2.1. Sales Equation Variables. The dependent to facilitate growth and increase market potential for
variable in Equation (1), Salesjt , is the sales volume of a new brand.
a new brand, which is calculated as the sum of sales Discounts. Discounts encourage trial purchases for
across all stores in a given week. We posit the sales the first-time buyers. They reduce search costs for
to be affected by a number of short-term variables, the consumer, generate awareness, and increase the
including brand-level discount depth Discjt , feature likelihood of adoption (Kalish 1985). Anderson and
Simester (2004) find that deep discounts also increase
5
Of these 225 new brands, 8 are brand extensions and 217 are repeat rates of first time buyers; thus, discounts accel-
entirely new brands. The substantive results are robust to the exclu- erate growth. However, the effect of discounting on
sion of these eight brands. market potential is not clear. Discounting can build
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1043

Table 2 Descriptive Statistics


Sales volume Sales volume
No. of new No. of brands new brand (×1000) Sales value Advertising Price Distribution Product Distribution Discount Feature/display
Category brands in category (×1000) category mean (×1000) (×1000) (per 1,000) breadth (%) line length depth (%) depth (%) /100

Bath products
M 25 326 500 6393 629 750 133 23 27 08 31 184
SD 1192 25639 1082 1128 77 48 19 04 24 129
Beer
M 36 961 10304 22639 2493 275 39 45 23 10 22 183
SD 23302 268265 4402 478 22 98 11 05 14 120
Butter
M 12 382 21836 20299 19797 409 50 97 30 20 27 211
SD 21825 66099 20946 698 20 199 20 10 24 196
Cereals
M 7 118 6471 24540 4018 27 61 46 39 23 25 62
SD 11940 122908 5856 — 30 52 43 14 44 54
Chips
M 5 86 41430 61441 14562 — 23 99 52 42 28 135
SD 80118 161995 30412 — 09 191 84 24 11 86
Coffee
M 16 306 932 14445 1212 — 90 19 40 15 70 340
SD 1432 73090 1756 — 29 28 56 08 108 315
Feminine needs
M 3 65 490 1808 7215 — 717 187 26 17 09 47
SD 301 4266 6613 — 277 142 09 02 06 49
Frozen pizza
M 3 72 20029 18611 15143 324 57 118 68 60 20 136
SD 10131 44921 9988 — 35 29 78 25 09 30
Ice cream
M 19 211 10463 24651 8052 23 50 82 60 13 23 115
SD 15211 76159 11469 — 26 111 76 07 19 95
Mayonnaise
M 9 234 2486 8799 2503 639 107 83 22 19 16 162
SD 5728 47731 4993 884 45 179 19 14 09 121
Mineral water
M 3 143 74 199 6519 823 53 103 28 34 11 228
SD 111 656 5539 — 69 125 11 08 11 333
Paper towel
M 2 66 252 311 9917 — 2690 26 10 142 15 185
SD 66 718 3093 — 138 02 00 25 10 130
Pasta
M 16 334 6566 25628 931 17 43 24 62 17 32 172
SD 16751 173003 1248 13 34 30 52 08 26 106
Shampoo
M 9 172 12119 11430 20137 890 98 228 61 15 10 70
SD 19502 28952 31369 958 47 266 66 13 06 49
Shaving cream
M 4 51 1384 5294 2138 — 104 77 19 39 09 82
SD 1307 12652 3061 — 86 62 11 15 06 63
Soup
M 21 333 16435 22443 5848 312 33 89 66 19 18 124
SD 37141 181350 12358 507 20 162 73 10 14 96
Tea
M 8 178 138 1092 1791 43 640 54 44 24 19 140
SD 110 4813 1599 67 269 63 19 11 20 134
Toothpaste
M 1 84 03 5220 538 — 8772 67 10 18 05 100
SD — 17209 — — — — — — — —
Water
M 14 189 587 884 29386 936 34 220 35 26 07 99
SD 542 3421 31014 556 46 204 17 06 03 126
Window cleaner
M 1 54 988 7520 139 — 09 30 10 122 11 109
SD — 19903 — — — — — — — —
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1044 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

Table 2 (cont’d.)
Sales volume Sales volume
No. of new No. of brands new brand (×1000) Sales value Advertising Price Distribution Product Distribution Discount Feature/display
Category brands in category (×1000) category mean (×1000) (×1000) (per 1,000) breadth (%) line length depth (%) depth (%) /100

Yogurt
M 8 226 5341 107620 2797 1320 47 48 24 09 13 70
SD 8467 372291 3637 — 17 62 08 03 09 63
Yogurt drink
M 3 37 17771 50435 7514 — 36 107 21 58 07 33
SD 12481 141076 4954 — 22 46 10 19 01 13

Notes. M, mean; SD, standard deviation of average marketing support across all brands. The mean and standard deviation of advertising, discount depth, and
feature/display are calculated using nonzero observations.

customer loyalty through rewards and thus might persuasion functions simultaneously in the context
help the brand build baseline sales through increased of new brands, produces high awareness levels, dif-
familiarity and experience, or simply through pur- ferentiates brands, and builds brand equity (Aaker
chase reinforcement or habit persistence (Ailawadi 1996). Thus, it helps build market potential. Elberse
et al. 2007, Keane 1997, Pauwels et al. 2002, Slotegraaf and Eliashberg (2003) find that advertising is crucial
and Pauwels 2006). On the other hand, discounting for new-brand performance, especially in the early
can also have a negative long-term impact because it stages of introduction. Moreover Lodish et al. (1995)
could erode brand equity (Ataman et al. 2006, Jedidi find that advertising works better when brands are
et al. 1999). new, implying a positive growth effect.
Feature/Display. We also consider the role of non- Distribution breadth. We use ACV-weighted dis-
price promotions in the diffusion of a new brand. tribution as a measure of distribution breadth
Feature promotions, retail displays, and other in-store (Bronnenberg et al. 2000). ACV weights a brand’s dis-
communication tools are manufacturer-retailer joint tribution by the total dollar volume sold through a
advertising efforts. Such nonprice promotions make particular store, giving more distribution credit to a
the new brand salient and promote it to the shop- large dollar volume store than it does to a small dollar
per traffic (Gatignon and Anderson 2002). In a sense, volume store.
they work in the same way that advertising does. Early work on new-product diffusion tended to
Therefore, we expect features and displays to facili- overlook the role distribution plays in building new
tate growth and increase market potential at the same brands. These studies typically explain the success of
time. a new brand by factors such as advertising or price,
Advertising. We construct the weekly advertising and they assume that the brand is always available
support variable from the available monthly advertis- to the consumers. A notable exception is the study by
ing expenditure data by dividing the monthly figures Jones and Ritz (1991), where the authors note that a
by the number of days in a month, and then totaling new brand cannot build sales if the consumers can-
across days for the corresponding weeks (Jedidi et al. not find a store in which they can purchase it. Recent
1999). This enables us to model marketing response research on new products devotes more attention to
at the highest frequency available in the data, avoid- distribution decisions and explains realized demand
ing the potential for data aggregation bias (Tellis and conditional on product availability. Such an approach
Franses 2006).
is appropriate especially in competitive environments
A number of studies have investigated the role of
where customers visit the retail stores and decide
advertising in new-product diffusion (e.g., Dodson
what to buy based on which brands are available
and Muller 1978, Horsky and Simon 1983, Kalish
(Krider et al. 2005). Taking this view Bronnenberg
1985, Simon and Sebastian 1987). National brand-
et al. (2000) show that in new repeat-purchase prod-
oriented advertising, which serves information and
uct categories market shares are strongly influenced
by retailer distribution decisions. Other studies con-
Table 3 Summary of Expectations firm that distribution is a critical factor influenc-
Growth Market potential ing new-product performance (Elberse and Eliashberg
2003, Gatignon and Anderson 2002, Neelamegham
Advertising + +
and Chintagunta 1999). In light of these findings,
Regular price − −
Discounting + 0 we expect distribution to be an important element
Feature and display + + in explaining the new brand’s growth and market
Distribution breadth ++ ++ potential.
Distribution depth ++ ++ Distribution depth. We measure distribution depth
Line length ++ ++
as the number of SKUs a brand offers in the category
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1045

in a given store relative to the total number of SKUs in Mela 2004, Jones and Ritz 1991), and (2) said con-
that category in that store. This measure reflects how sumer will also be unlikely to purchase goods if there
many different SKUs of a particular brand are carried, are not variants or items that match her needs. Yet
on average, at each point of ACV distribution. We cal- availability and alternative options require awareness,
culate the distribution variables at the store level and hence advertising and feature/display should be in
then calculate national averages. the second tier of critical elements of the diffusion
Any marketing activity that spreads information in process.
proportion to the number of products in the market,
such as self-advertising by just being on a supermar-
ket shelf, could generate awareness for a new brand
5. Results
We estimate the DLM specified above using a Gibbs
(Eliashberg and Jeuland 1986). Therefore, we expect
sampler and run the sampling chain for 30,000 iter-
distribution depth to facilitate growth and build mar-
ations (15,000 for burn-in and 15,000 for sampling
ket potential.6
with a thinning of 10). The repeat-purchase diffu-
Line length. We measure the brand line length by
sion model with flexible growth and market poten-
the number of SKUs a brand offers in a given week. tial specification, coupled with the ability of the DLM
Our discussion about the role that brand line length methodology to accommodate potential nonstationar-
plays in the diffusion process of a new brand is ity in brand launch, provides excellent fit to the data
rather tentative because theoretical and empirical evi- (see Figure 3). Across 225 brands we analyze in the
dence on this issue is virtually nonexistent. We argue paper, the median correlation between actual and pre-
that, holding all else constant, more SKUs provide dicted sales is 0.88.
assortment and increase the probability of trying an For all 225 brands we consider three sets of param-
item from the new brand’s line. Also, having more eters: (1) the short-term marketing effects () on sales
alternatives might serve more segments. Therefore, model specified in Equation (4); (2) the long-term
we expect line length to increase market potential marketing strategy effects on growth ( ) and mar-
and facilitate growth. Because the marginal change in ket potential (
), as well as the repeat-purchase rate
baseline arising from the addition of new SKUs might
decrease, we specify log-transformed line length in
the model.7 Figure 3 Actual vs. Predicted Sales of Two Selected Brands
Relative effects. As indicated in Table 1, thus far no Brand A
research has incorporated all marketing mix instru- 2.0
Actual
ments into a single diffusion framework, let alone 1.5
Predicted
into a repeat-purchase diffusion framework for CPG 1.0 Confidence interval
Sales (standardized)

categories. Therefore, the relative importance of mar- 0.5


keting instruments in building new CPG brands is
0
undocumented. However, relative effects sizes are of
–0.5
central interest to managers because they point out
areas in which it might be more desirable to allocate –1.0

marketing funds. We argue that line length and distri- –1.5


bution (breadth and depth) should assume the great- –2.0
est importance (denoted by ++ in Table 3) because –2.5
(1) a consumer, given her reluctance to shop across 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200
Week
stores or markets, will not adopt a brand if it is not
available in the stores she visits (Bronnenberg and Brand B
1.5
1.0
6
Distribution depth and line length capture different aspects of
0.5
brand strategy, as reflected in a relatively modest correlation of
Sales (standardized)

0.35. The correlation is modest because line length is the number 0


of products a brand offers at the national level, while distribution –0.5
depth is the fraction of a store’s category assortment that belong –1.0
to the brand, which is thus measured at the store level (and next
–1.5
averaged across stores). As a consequence, line length is a decision
variable that is under direct control for a manufacturer, whereas –2.0
distribution depth depends to a large extent on the willingness of –2.5
the retailer to carry the brand’s products. Hence, a high line length
–3.0
does not necessarily coincide with a deep distribution.
7
–3.5
The log BF (927.5) favored the model with decreasing returns over 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200
the model with constant return. Week
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1046 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

parameter () in the baseline sales evolution model from product categories that are expected to exhibit
as shown in Equation (5); and (3) the marketing mix seasonal patterns (e.g., soup and ice cream), whereas
inertia, performance feedback, and cross-marketing the coefficient is negligible for others.
mix parameters () in the marketing mix endogeneity
model specified in Equation (9). We discuss each set 5.2. The Baseline Sales Evolution Model
of parameters in sequence. Of central interest to this research are the estimates
on the evolution of baseline sales (t ), including
5.1. The Sales Model (1) repeat-purchase effects , how marketing mix
Table 4 shows the inverse-variance weighted aver- instruments correlate to sales growth ( ) for new
age (to afford more weight to more reliable esti- brands; and (2) the role these instruments play in
mates) of discounting, feature/display, and average the market potential (
) for a new brand. Table 4
weekly temperature estimates at the category level. indicates that increases in advertising support, dis-
Both discounting and feature/display parameter esti- tribution breadth, line length, and discount correlate
mates exhibit face validity because each stimulates with faster growth for new brands, whereas increases
same-week sales (average estimates across all brands in regular prices inhibit the diffusion process. These
are 0.03 and 0.05, respectively). The 90% posterior findings are in line with the expectations. The effect
confidence interval of the average weekly temper- of distribution depth on growth is negligible. Sur-
ature coefficient typically excludes zero for brands prisingly, we find that feature and display intensity

Table 4 Parameter Estimates (Sales Model)

Category Discounting Feature/display Temperature Repeat rate


a
Observation equation parameters
All categories 003 005 −000 094
Bath products 004 014 −000 089
Beer 002 009 000 086
Butter 000 002 −001 094
Cereals 009 −001 −001 098
Chips 006 000 −002 092
Coffee 004 004 −000 085
Feminine needs 005 002 000 098
Frozen pizza 022 −008 −001 092
Ice cream 005 010 000 095
Mayonnaise −000 011 −000 091
Mineral water 003 001 000 099
Paper towel 024 005 −000 091
Pasta 000 004 −000 091
Shampoo 004 011 000 094
Shaving cream 003 004 −001 097
Soup 003 006 −001 094
Tea 000 008 −001 095
Toothpaste 003 001 −001 102
Water 000 000 −000 100
Window cleaner 003 010 −000 101
Yogurt 003 005 −001 098
Yogurt drink 001 003 −001 097

Growth Market potential

Marketing activity Median 5th and 95th percentile Median 5th and 95th percentile

Growth and market potential parametersb


Constant 00948 00868 01035 01008 00760 01288
Advertising 00077 00003 00153 00275c −00036 00609
Regular price −00110 −00147 −00074 −00793 −01098 −00488
Discounting 00148 00116 00183 −00323 −00515 −00102
Feature and display −00088 −00106 −00071 02971 02517 03517
Distribution breadth 00231 00194 00268 07951 07418 08507
Distribution depth −00003 −00041 00037 01344 01056 01698
Line length (log) 00089 00049 00132 00998 00668 01312

Notes. (a) Variance-weighted average of median estimates across brands. (b) Bold indicates that 90% posterior confidence interval
excludes zero. (c) The market potential effect of advertising crosses zero at 92nd percentile.
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1047

slows diffusion of new brands, although the effect is effect sizes of the marketing mix variables by comput-
quite small. When combined with positive short-term ing the ratio of (1) the standardized coefficient for a
effects and the large effect of feature/display on mar- given marketing mix instrument to (2) the sum of all
ket potential, the net effect is positive (as we show in standardized marketing mix coefficients. In the cal-
the subsequent section). culation, we use the absolute values of the standard-
Table 4 further reveals that feature and display ized coefficients for the growth and market potential
activity, brand line length, distribution breadth, and parameters, respectively. Figure 4 presents the relative
distribution depth correlate positively with market effects of the marketing mix instruments.
potential for new brands, whereas the 80% posterior Figure 4 makes it apparent that distribution breadth
predictive interval for advertising excludes zero (tan- is the single most important marketing mix instru-
tamount to a one-sided p-value of 10% in classical ment in generating growth (relative effect of 31%) and
statistics). As expected, low prices are associated with building market potential (relative effect of 54%) for
higher market potential. Consistent with the literature a new brand. Although the result is not altogether
on the long-term effect of discounts, the effect of dis- surprising (a brand cannot have sales without dis-
counting on market potential is negative (Mela et al. tribution), the precise effect of size relative to other
1997). Note the dual role of discounts in leading to variables is less obvious as (1) the effect of distribu-
faster growth but lower market potential. tion exceeds all other strategies combined in generating
Across the 225 brands, the repeat-purchase param- growth; and (2) it is also the case that a brand can-
eters, , range between 0.83 (25th percentile) and 0.98 not have sales without a product line, yet this effect
(75th percentile), with a median of 0.94. The varia- is not as considerable. Distribution breadth and depth
tion of repeat purchase parameter estimates across assume greater importance in building market poten-
product categories does not reveal major differences. tial (jointly 63%) than accelerating growth (jointly
This median repeat-purchase rate across all brands 31%). After distribution, discounting has the second-
suggests that for most brands, 90% of the long-term largest impact on growth (20%). Feature and display
sales effect for new brands materializes within the have the second-largest effect on market potential
first 52 weeks (Leone 1995). To our knowledge, this is (20%), which implies that their short-term effect on
the first study to conduct an empirical generalization weekly sales is supplemented by their ability to build
of time to peak sales for new packaged goods brands. long-run demand for new brands.

5.3. Relative Effect Sizes 5.4. Marketing Mix Models


The foregoing discussion reveals that marketing strat- Now we briefly summarize the results of the mar-
egy plays a role in the diffusion of new brands but keting mix instrument equations presented in Equa-
affords little insight into which strategies explain the tions (8) and (9). First, we find that past sales typically
greatest amount of variation in the sales performance has little effect on current marketing. A notable excep-
of new brands. Accordingly, we consider the relative tion is the effect of past sales on distribution breadth.

Figure 4 Relative Effects Across Marketing Mix Instruments


54%
Growth
Market potential

31%

20% 20%

15%
12% 12%
10%
9%
7%
5%
2% 2%
0%

Distribution Discounting Regular price Line length (log) Feature/display Advertising Distribution depth
breadth
Note. The bars represent the size of the instrument’s absolute parameter estimate divided by the sum of the absolute parameter estimates.
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1048 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

In 57% of all cases, we observe that past sales have and rate of growth. Our analysis proceeds by using
a positive effect on future distribution. Second, the our model to forecast a brand’s sales with all market-
coefficients for the inertial effect of past marketing ing mix variables set to their historical means. Denote
range from 0.39 (for feature/display) to 0.80 (for dis- this estimate as S0 . S0 serves as the basis for a compar-
tribution breadth), indicating the largest effect again ison to sales forecasted under an alternative strategy.
arises from distribution breath. Collectively, these two In this strategy, we increase the considered market-
results underscore the importance of controlling for ing activity by 10% and calculate a new level of sales,
performance feedback and amplify our finding that denoted S1 . One can then obtain the percentage of
distribution plays a major role in brand building. sales change due to 10% permanent marginal increase
Finally, we find that competitor effects are pre- in marketing spending by comparing the sales level
dominantly zero for the marketing mix instruments. of the new case to the base case S1 − S0 /S0  ≡ .
Steenkamp et al. (2005) observe a similar result in the In these calculations, we considered only the first
context of advertising and pricing for mature brands, 52 weeks after launch because, as noted above, 90%
and Pauwels (2007) observes the same in discounting of the long-term marketing effects materialize within
and feature/display. We extend this finding across the 52 weeks (see also Leone 1995). Table 6 summarizes
marketing mix. the results of our policy simulation.
Findings. The first column in Table 6 reports the
5.5. Model Comparison average sales change across 225 brands analyzed in
Our analysis presumes that (1) baseline sales fol-
this study. The large variation in effect sizes across
low a dynamic growth process, and (2) this pro-
brands is largely driven by variation in marketing
cess is linked to marketing strategy. To test the
spending across brands. The table indicates three
first assumption, we contrast our full model (M0)
strata of effect sizes. The most effective stratum
to one wherein no dynamics are exhibited in base-
jt  + 0jt . To test comprises distribution breadth (a 10% arc elasticity
line growth (M1), that is jt = Z
of 7.6%), regular price (5.1%), and distribution depth
the second assumption, we contrast our full model
(3.1%). The implied average regular price elasticity
(M0) with one wherein observed growth is indepen-
(0.51) is low relative to meta-analytical results for
dent of long-term marketing strategy (M2), that is
regular prices and new brands (Bijmolt et al. 2005).
jt = j jt−1 + 
− jt−1  + 0jt . Table 5 indicates the
This result might reflect the lower price sensitivity of
full model outperforms these benchmarks on the log
consumers who try new brands (Ghosh et al. 1983,
BF for one-step-ahead forecasts.
Parker 1992). The next stratum includes line length
and feature/display (1.5%). The least effective group
6. Managerial Implications of strategies for affecting new-brand sales includes
We next consider the ramifications of our analysis discounting (which actually has a negative marginal
for new-brand launch marketing strategies. As a pre- effect) and advertising. This finding is notable, as
lude, we note limits inherent in the archival data Table 1 also suggests these are the most-often consid-
analysis that we propose, namely that parameter esti- ered instruments in past research.
mates might not be invariant to our policy simula- Marginal Profit Analysis. Table 6 illuminates a mar-
tions. That said, in the context of a dynamic problem ginal profit approximation. Let C0 denote the cost
with many agents, states, and controls, the imposi-
tion of assumptions to identify a more structural solu-
tion may induce more problems (dimensionality of Table 6 Equilibrium Sales Value Impact of 10% Permanent Increase
in Marketing Support (%)
the state-space, restrictive assumptions, etc.) than it
redresses. Standard
Mean deviation 1st Quartile Median 3rd Quartile
6.1.Long-Term Marketing Mix Elasticities for
Advertising 025 024 008 016 031
New Brands spending
Procedure. Using our model, one can assess how Regular price −513 372 −687 −445 −281
marketing strategies affect brands’ steady-state sales Distribution 761 406 527 661 880
breadth
Line length 153 111 076 125 173
Table 5 Predictive Fit of Focal Model and Nested Benchmark Models Distribution 318 191 198 268 378
depth
Model Time-varying parameters Log BF
Discount depth −024 140 −018 −012 −007
M0 Dynamics and marketing — Feature/display 153 109 078 121 199
M1 No dynamics 9870
Note. As a result of a 10% permanent increase in regular prices, sales
M2 No marketing 408
reaches a 5.1% lower equilibrium level than it would have reached had the
Note. Log Bayes factor is relative to M0. price been kept constant at its mean.
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1049

of the base marketing strategy,  denote the sales instruments. We use a 52-week duration because most
increase in Table 6 arising from a 10% increase in brands reach their maximum sales by this time. Ini-
the marketing mix, R0 indicate the revenue of the tializing new-brand sales at zero, we forecast demand
base strategy, MM denote the manufacturer gross for all 225 brands over the 52 weeks after launch using
margins, and RM denote the retailer gross margins. the parameters estimated in our model.
Then the manufacturer profits under the base case Price Skimming vs. Penetration Pricing. Penetration
are 0 = 1 − RM ∗ MM ∗ R0 − C0 . With a 10% pricing is considered optimal for new durable goods
increase in the marketing expenditure, profits become (e.g., Horsky 1990, Kalish 1985, Mesak and Berg
1 = 1 +  ∗ 1 − RM ∗ MM ∗ R0 − 1 + 010 ∗ C0 1995). Our skimming/penetration condition contrasts
(assuming that a percent increase in costs leads to (1) a strategy wherein the launch price is one standard
a percent increase in marketing). The condition that deviation above the historical mean price at launch
1 > 0 therefore implies that it is profitable to and one standard deviation below the historical mean
increase marketing spend on the margin when the price at 52 weeks (price skimming) to (2) a strategy
resulting increase in marginal revenue, 1 − RM ∗ wherein the regular price is held constant one stan-
MM ∗  ∗ R0  is greater than the resulting increase in dard deviation below the mean (penetration).
marginal cost, 01 ∗ C0 . Assuming a retailer gross mar- Constant vs. Monotonically Decreasing Advertising
gin of RM = 25% of retail sales (Agriculture and Food Spending. Prior literature argues that decreasing
Canada Report 2005) and a manufacturer gross mar- returns to scale in advertising favors a monotoni-
gin of MM = 40% (Grocery Management Association cally decreasing advertising strategy (Dockner and
2006), this condition reduces to C0 /R0 < 3 ∗ . Jørgensen 1988, Horsky and Mate 1988, Horsky and
Stated differently, the marginal profits of market- Simon 1983, Kalish 1985). Our constant/decreasing
ing investment become positive when costs as a advertising manipulation contrasts (1) advertising
percent of retail revenue are less than 3 ∗ . For held at one standard deviation above its histori-
distribution ( = 0076), this implies it is profitable cal mean (constant) to (2) a case where advertis-
on the margin to invest in distribution when dis- ing decreases from one standard deviation above the
tribution costs are less than 23% of retail revenue. mean to one standard deviation below (decreasing).
On the other end of the spectrum, it is profitable to National Launch vs. Phased Roll-Out. Despite the
advertise ( = 00025) only when the marginal cost pivotal role distribution plays in new-brand diffu-
of advertising is less than 0.8% of revenue. Given sion, little academic research exists on distribution
most firms budget about 5% of manufacturer sales strategies over time in the context of new-brand dif-
for advertising (or 3.75% of retail sales), this sug- fusion (Bronnenberg and Mela 2004, Jones and Ritz
gests that further increases in advertising are, on aver- 1991). Our national launch/regional condition manip-
age, unwarranted (though variation across categories ulation contrasts (1) holding distribution at one stan-
imply different strategies dominate in different cate- dard deviation above its historical mean (national
gories). The thresholds for line length and distribution launch) with (2) increasing distribution from one stan-
depth are 5% and 10%, respectively, while the thresh- dard deviation below the mean to one standard devi-
old for feature display is 5%. ation above the mean (phased roll-out).
Simultaneous vs. Phased Brand Entry. Moorthy and
6.2. Strategic Launch Options Png (1992) and Wilson and Norton (1989) argue that it
Prior research has speculated on the relative merits of is effective to release all variants early in the brand life
various marketing strategies in the context of product cycle except when cannibalization is present. In the
diffusion (skimming versus penetration pricing, con- simultaneous/phased entry manipulation we com-
stant versus decreasing advertising, national versus pare (1) an increase from one standard deviation
phased brand roll-out, and simultaneous versus below the mean to one standard deviation above the
sequential product line entry). Our empirical general- mean (phased) to (2) a constant level of brand line
izations not only afford empirical insights into these length held at one standard deviation above the his-
strategies, but also extend prior work to consider their torical mean observed in the data (simultaneous).
interactions. In particular, we contend that the effi- Table 7 reports the sales and growth effects of the
cacy of marketing strategies is amplified by strong strategic launch options. The sales impact is expressed
distribution. as percentage gains relative to a base case wherein
Simulation Design. To explore these interactions marketing activity is held fixed at historical mean
we generate a 2 (skimming/penetration pricing) × 2 levels over the 52-week duration (see Panel A). In
(constant/decreasing advertising) × 2 (national dis- this case, sales peak at week 41, with 90% of growth
tribution/phased roll-out) × 2 (simultaneous/phased within 14 weeks. We express the growth impact as
brand entry) design and ensure the strategies are the difference between the time it takes a brand to
well within the observed range of the marketing mix reach 90% of maximum sales in the base case and the
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1050 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

Table 7 Sales and Growth Impact of Strategic Trade-Offs

Marketing mix instruments Sales Growth

Pricing Advertising Distribution Brand line M SD M SD

Panel A: Base case


At mean At mean At mean At mean 401 × 107 105 × 108 14 —

Marketing mix instruments Sales impact Growth impact

Pricing Advertising Distribution Brand line M SD M SD

Panel B: Interaction effects (relative to base case)


Penetration Decreasing National Simultaneous 611 333 −49 02
Penetration Constant National Simultaneous 636 348 −40 00
Skimming Decreasing National Simultaneous 529 293 −13 08
Penetration Decreasing National Phased 523 288 −10 10
Skimming Constant National Simultaneous 555 307 03 16
Penetration Constant National Phased 549 303 08 21
Skimming Decreasing National Phased 442 249 60 39
Skimming Constant National Phased 468 264 84 49
Penetration Decreasing Phased Simultaneous 89 47 273 41
Penetration Constant Phased Simultaneous 113 61 277 38
Skimming Decreasing Phased Simultaneous 30 24 285 36
Penetration Decreasing Phased Phased 22 17 286 36
Skimming Constant Phased Simultaneous 54 37 288 34
Penetration Constant Phased Phased 46 30 290 34
Skimming Decreasing Phased Phased −31 01 296 32
Skimming Constant Phased Phased −07 12 299 30

Notes. M (mean) and SD (standard deviation) are computed across 225 brands. For example, with penetration pricing, decreasing
advertising, national launch, and simultaneous line entry, an average brand enjoys 61.1% more sales in the first year and reaches the
90% mark 4.9 weeks earlier than it does in the base case.

time to reach 90% of maximum sales under an alter- successful brands in terms of sales and time to pen-
native strategic option. Of note, distribution effects etrate the market. In contrast to prior research per-
are considerably larger than the effect of all other taining to the effects of marketing strategy on the
strategies. Moreover, national launch interacts with sales of new brands, we generalize our analysis across
(1) low price and broader lines to enhance market many categories and incorporate an array of mar-
potential and growth and (2) advertising to facilitate keting strategies that span the entire marketing mix.
growth.8 Taken together, these interactions suggest Moreover, we use statistical controls for marketing
broad access to distribution is a necessary condition mix endogeneity and performance feedback in our
for effective marketing. analysis. We contend an empirical generalization that
assesses the relative efficacy of launch strategies has
remained heretofore unaddressed in the marketing
7. Conclusions literature.
Although new brands are central to the success of To achieve this aim, we formulate a Bayesian
organizations, large numbers of these brands fail DLM of repeat-purchase diffusion. The methodology
extends the literature on repeat-purchase diffusion
each year. For example, Hitsch (2006) reports that
models (e.g., Lilien et al. 1981) to incorporate dynam-
75% of new-product introductions fail in the ready-
ics in the growth process over time and the endogene-
to-eat breakfast cereal category. It is therefore a
ity of marketing spend. Our state-space formulation
long-standing and central question in marketing to
of the repeat-purchase model enables us to achieve
explain why some brands fail and some succeed. these goals. This innovation also enables a multitude
This research seeks to be a step in that direction of additional potential specifications given its inherent
by linking the sales outcomes for 225 new brands flexibility in estimation. Using this approach, we find:
across 22 product categories over a five-year period • The relative effect sizes of the various strategies
to ascertain which marketing strategies discriminate (standardized to sum to one) on market potential are
as follows: distribution breadth 54%, feature/display
8
We tested for these interactions using a classical analysis of vari- 20%, distribution depth 9%, line length 7%, regular
ance of the sales and growth columns in Table 7 on the design price 5%, advertising 2%, and discounting 2%. Thus,
variables in the rows of Table 7. over the range of our data, the effect of distribution
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1051

exceeds the combined effect of all other marketing inherent in empirical models of sales response pred-
effects. This underscores the importance of obtaining icated on secondary data. These extensions/limits
distribution for new brands.9 This finding supple- include the following. First, we focus exclusively
ments that of Ataman et al. (2007), who find that dis- on national brand introductions and exclude private
tribution plays a central role in explaining differences labels; presumably, retailers would be quite inter-
in sales across geographic regions in France. The ested in private label brands and the strategies that
result further underscores the desirability of ascer- ensure their viability. Second, brand extensions are
taining the antecedents of distribution including, for an important topic in their own right, and compar-
example, the use of slotting allowances (Sudhir and ing marketing strategy efficacy of brand extensions
Rao 2006) and suggests the study of penetration into to that of entirely new brands can further enhance
distribution is an substantially under-researched area our understanding of successful roll-out strategies.
in marketing (we suspect this might be due in part Third, traditional models of diffusion in repeat pur-
to a lack of good data). The relative effect sizes of chase contexts separate growth due to word of mouth
the various strategies on the growth parameter (stan- effects from innovation effects. We focus on the latter,
dardized to sum to one) are as follows: distribution given that word-of-mouth effects are largely absent
breadth 31%, discounting 20%, regular price 15%, line in packaged goods (Hardie et al. 1998). Nonethe-
length 12%, feature/display 12%, advertising 10%, less, it would be desirable to extend this model
and distribution depth 0.1%. for durable goods contexts in which word-of-mouth
• With the exception of discounting, all strategies plays a greater role. Fourth, the data preclude us from
have a positive total effect on sales. Discounts quicken taking a more nuanced view of innovation and diffu-
diffusion but have a negative effect on long-term mar- sion. For example, we do not consider how personal
ket potential. and product characteristics or organizational capabil-
• Not only does distribution have the largest direct ities moderate diffusion rates (Cooper 1998, Gatignon
impact on sales, but it also interacts with other strate- and Robertson 1986, Rogers 1976). Sixth, our model
gies to enhance their efficacy. does not provide a formal accounting of retailer deci-
• Using a simulation predicated on our data, we sion making. A national roll-out strategy is not only
find the breakeven thresholds to be lowest for distri- incumbent on a firm’s choice to distribute nationally,
bution breadth and depth and highest for advertising but also on the willingness of retailers to adopt a new
and discounting. brand (Bronnenberg and Mela 2004).
Our findings have a number of managerial impli- Our analysis is a step toward a more complete
cations. First, the results of our analysis can be view of the role of postlaunch marketing strategy on
informative to firms seeking to allocate funds across the diffusion of frequently purchased CPG brands. In
the mix in a means consistent with their growth light of our findings and the foregoing limitations,
objectives. Given that discounting accelerates growth we hope this work will stimulate further research on
at half the rate of distribution breadth, firms can new-brand launch, especially with regard to the role
trade off the cost of a two-standard-unit increase in distribution plays in the success of new brands.
discounting with a one-standard-unit increase in dis-
tribution breadth. Second, like all diffusion models, Acknowledgments
The authors thank Information Research, Incorporated and
the model developed herein can be used to fore-
TNS Media Intelligence for providing the data; and Jason
cast the sales growth of new brands; however, in
Duan, Vithala Rao, Song Yao, and seminar participants at
this instance the model can be used under various the 2007 Marketing Science Conference, the 2007 Marketing
marketing scenarios for repeat-purchase goods. Given Dynamics Conference, the 2007 Yale Center for Customer
the empirical generalization, firms can choose ana- Insights Conference, and the 2007 European Marketing
log products to engage these forecasts even with lit- Academy Conference, as well as the editor-in-chief, the area
tle data and then update them as new data become editor, and four anonymous reviewers for their comments.
available; the Bayesian nature of our model allows the The first and third authors thank Netherlands Organization
modeler to readily update the parameter estimates. for Scientific Research for research support.
As with any research, the findings summarized Appendix. Model Estimation
above are subject to several extensions/limitations. The observation equation and the evolution equation of the
Many limitations are not unique to this study but are multivariate DLM for brand j (j = 1     225) are

9
Yjt = Fjt jt + Xjt j + jt  (10)
The finding that feature/display is the second most important
instrument to build market potential coincides with results from jt = Gjt jt−1 + hjt + jt  (11)
Pauwels and Hanssens (2007), who find that promotional vari-
ables are especially effective in turning brand performance around. where Yjt is a vector that stacks standardized sales and mar-
Together, these results imply that “marketing strategy is in the keting mix instruments. From now on, we drop the brand
details.” We thank an anonymous reviewer for this observation. subscript j for simplicity. Ft = IM+1 , where M =7 is the
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1052 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

number of marketing mix variables. Xt is the matrix of and · is conditional likelihood of Equation (11) evaluated
regressors that create short-term fluctuations in sales. For at each draw.
a given brand, we assume t ∼ N 0 V  and t ∼ N 0 W , Step 5.   t , W .
where V and W are full and diagonal matrices, of size To obtain the conditional posterior distribution of the
M + 1 × M + 1, of error variances, respectively. The time- brand-specific evolution equation parameters associated
varying parameter vector, t = t  t , evolves as described with the ith marketing mix instrument i , we define KiT =
in (11). 1T −1 iT −1 SalesjT −1 Salesj  T −1  and WiT = Wi ⊗ IT −1 . We place a
Step 1. t  Yt , V , W , , Gt , ht . normal prior on the parameters, i ∼ N 
   . Then the
For each brand we sample from the conditional distri- full conditional posterior is also normal with i ∼ N 
¯ ,
  
bution of  using the forward-filtering, backward-sampling where
¯ −1 −1
 =  
 + KiT WiT iT , and  =  +¯ −1
algorithm proposed by Carter and Kohn (1994) and
KiT WiT−1 KiT
−1 .
Frühwirth-Schnatter (1994). First, for t = 1     T we for-
Step 6.   t , V .
ward filter to obtain the moments mt and Ct . Conditional
To obtain the brand-specific conditional posterior distri-
on Y t , V , W , , Gt , ht and 0  D0 ∼ N m0  C0 , where Y t =
bution of the nontime-varying observation equation param-
Yt − Xt :
• The prior at time t is t  Dt−1 ∼ N at  Rt , where at = eters , we define Y t = Yt − Ft t and VT = V ⊗ IT . We
Gt mt−1 + ht and Rt = Gt Ct−1 Gt + W . place a normal prior on the parameters,  ∼ N 
   .
• One-step-ahead forecast at time t is Y t  Dt−1 ∼ Then the full conditional posterior is also normal with  ∼
N 
¯ , where
 =  ¯ −1
+ X V −1 Y , and  ¯ =
N ft  Qt , where ft = Ft at and Qt = Ft Rt Ft + V .     t T t 
• The posterior distribution at time t is t  Dt ∼ −1 −1  −1
 + Xt VT Xt  .
N mt  Ct , where mt = at + Rt Ft Qt−1 Y t − ft , and Ct = Rt −
Rt Ft Qt−1 Ft Rt .
At t = T we sample a matrix of evolution parameters
References
from the distribution N mt  Ct . Next we sequence back-
Aaker, D. A. 1996. Measuring brand equity across products and
ward for t = T − 1     1 sampling from pt  t+1  rest ∼
markets. California Management Rev. 38(3) 102–120.
N qt∗  Qt∗ , where qt∗ = mt + Bt t+1 − at+1 , Qt∗ = Ct − Bt Rt+1 Bt ,
Agriculture and Food Canada Report. 2005. Overview of the
and Bt = Ct Gt+1 R−1 t+1 . We select m0 = 0 and C0 = 01 as the retail grocery market in the U.S. south central states. http://
initial values. www.ats.agr.gc.ca.
Step 2. V  t , Yt , .
Ailawadi, K. L., K. Gedenk, C. Lutzky, S. A. Neslin. 2007. Decom-
For a given brand, we assume that the observation equa- position of the sales impact of promotion-induced stockpiling.
tion error variance matrix, of size M + 1 × M + 1, is full. J. Marketing Res. 44(3) 450–467.
We place an inverse Wishart prior, with (nV 0  SV 0 . Then Anderson, E., D. Simester. 2004. Long run effects of promotion
the full conditional posterior distribution  is also inverse depth on new versus established customers: Three field stud-
Wishart, with nV 1 = nV 0 + T and SV 1 = SV 0 + Tt=1 Yt − Xt  − ies. Marketing Sci. 23(1) 4–20.
Ft t  Yt − Xt  − Ft t . We use a diffuse prior with nV 0 = Ataman, M. B., C. F. Mela, H. J. Van Heerde. 2007. Consumer pack-
M + 1 + 2 and SV 0 = 0001 × IM+1 . aged goods in France: National brands, regional chains, local
Step 3. W  t , , , . branding. J. Marketing Res. 44(1) 14–20.
We assume that the evolution equation error-variance Ataman, M. B., H. J. Van Heerde, C. F. Mela. 2006. The long-term
matrix, of size M + 1 × M + 1, is diagonal for a given effect of marketing strategy on brand performance. Working
brand. We place an inverse Gamma prior on the elements paper, RSM Erasmus University, Rotterdam, The Netherlands.
of this matrix, with nW 0 /2 degrees of freedom and a scale Bass, F. M., A. V. Bultez. 1982. A note on optimal strategic pricing
parameter of SW 0 /2. The full conditional posterior distribu- of technological innovations. Marketing Sci. 1(4) 371–378.
tion is also distributed  inverse Gamma with nW 1 = nW 0 + Bass, F. M., D. Jain, T. V. Krishnan. 2000. Modeling the marketing
T − 1 and SW 1 = SW 0 + Tt=1 t − Gt t−1 − ht  t − Gt t−1 − ht . mix influence in new product diffusion. V. Mahajan, E. Muller,
We use a diffuse prior with nW 0 = 3 and SW 0 = 0001. Y. Wind, eds. New-Product Diffusion Models. Kluwer Academic
Step 4.   t , W , ,
,  t , W , ,
, and
 t , W , , . Publishers, Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 99–122.
Conditional on the sampled baseline sales series across Bass, F. M., T. V. Krishnan, D. Jain. 1994. Why the Bass model fits
all brands, the evolution equation is nonlinear in parame- without decision variables. Marketing Sci. 13(3) 203–223.
ters and there is no closed-form density for the parameters. Bass, F. M., N. Bruce, S. Majumdar, B. P. S. Murthi. 2007. Wearout
Therefore, we use a random walk Metropolis-Hastings step effects of different advertising themes: A dynamic Bayesian
model of advertising-sales relationship. Marketing Sci. 26(2)
within the Gibbs sampler to obtain the parameter estimates.
179–195.
We discuss only the estimation of the brand-specific repeat
Bijmolt, T. H. A., H. J. Van Heerde, R. G. M. Pieters. 2005. New
rates. The estimation of   t , W ,
,  and
 t , W , , 
empirical generalizations on the determinants of price elastic-
follows directly. We generate the candidate repeat purchase ity. J. Marketing Res. 42(2) 141–156.
m m−1
rate draw by j = j + z, where m denotes mth iter- Bronnenberg, B. J., C. F. Mela. 2004. Market roll-out and retailer
ation, and z is a random draw from N 0 I. We select adoption for new brands. Marketing Sci. 23(4) 500–518.
such that the acceptance rate is between 20%–50% (Chib Bronnenberg, B. J., V. Mahajan, W. R. Vanhonacker. 2000. The emer-
and Greenberg 1995). The candidate draw is accepted with gence of market structure in new repeat-purchase categories:
the probability ∗ = min1 , where The interplay of market share and retailer distribution. J. Mar-
m keting Res. 37(1) 16–31.
j  t  W  

= m−1
 (12) Carter, C. K., R. Kohn. 1994. On Gibbs sampling for state space
j  t  W  
 models. Biometrika 81(3) 541–553.
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS 1053

Chib, S., E. Greenberg. 1995. Understanding the Metropolis- Kamakura, W. A., S. Balasubramanian. 1987. Long-term forecasting
Hastings algorithm. Amer. Statist. 49(4) 327–335. with innovation diffusion models: The impact of replacement
Christen, M., S. Gupta, J. C. Porter, R. Staelin, D. R. Wittink. 1997. purchases. J. Forecasting 6(1) 1–19.
Using market-level data to understand promotion effects in a Kamakura, W. A., S. Balasubramanian. 1988. Long-term view of the
nonlinear model. J. Marketing Res. 34(3) 322–334. diffusion of durables: A study of the role of price and adoption
Cooper, R. G. 1998. Product Leadership Creating and Launching Supe- influence process via tests of nested models. Internat. J. Res.
rior New Products. Perseus Books, Reading, MA. Marketing 5 1–13.
Dockner, E., S. Jørgensen. 1988. Optimal advertising policies for Keane, M. 1997. Modeling heterogeneity and state dependence in
diffusion models of new product innovations in monopolistic consumer choice behavior. J. Bus. Econom. Statist. 15(3) 310–327.
situation. Management Sci. 34(1) 119–130. Krider, R. E., T. Li, Y. Liu, C. B. Weinberg. 2005. The lead-lag puzzle
Dodson, J., E. Muller. 1978. Models of new products diffusion of demand and distribution: A graphical method applied to
through advertising and worth-of-mouth. Management Sci. movies. Marketing Sci. 24(4) 635–645.
24(15) 1568–1578. Leone, R. P. 1995. Generalizing what is known of temporal aggre-
Elberse, A., J. Eliashberg. 2003. Demand and supply dynamics for gation and advertising carryover. Marketing Sci. 14(3, Part 2)
sequentially released products in international markets: The G141–G150.
case of motion pictures. Marketing Sci. 22(3) 329–354. Lilien, G. L., A. Rao, S. Kalish. 1981. Bayesian estimation and con-
Eliashberg, J., A. P. Jeuland. 1986. The impact of competitive entry trol of detailing effort in a repeat-purchase diffusion environ-
in developing market upon dynamic pricing strategies. Mar- ment. Management Sci. 27(5) 493–506.
keting Sci. 5(1) 20–36. Lodish, L. M., M. Abraham, S. Kalmenson, J. Livelsberger,
Frühwirth-Schnatter, S. 1994. Data augmentation and dynamic lin- B. Lubetkin, B. Richardson, M. E. Stevens. 1995. How T.V.
ear models. J. Time Ser. Anal. 15(2) 183–202. advertising works: A meta-analysis of 389 real world split cable
Gatignon, H., E. Anderson. 2002. Inter-channel competition and T.V. advertising experiments. J. Marketing Res. 32(2) 125–139.
new product diffusion: Market making, market taking, and Mahajan, V., E. Muller, F. M. Bass. 1990. New product diffusion
competitive effects in several European countries. Working models in marketing: A review and directions for research.
paper, INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France. J. Marketing 54(1) 1–26.
Gatignon, H., T. Robertson. 1986. A propositional inventory for new Mela, C. F., S. Gupta, D. R. Lehmann. 1997. The long-term impact of
diffusion research. J. Consumer Res. 11(4) 849–867. promotion and advertising on consumer brand choice. J. Mar-
Ghosh, A., S. A. Neslin, R. W. Shoemaker. 1983. Are there asso- keting Res. 34(2) 248–261.
ciations between price elasticity and brand characteristics? Mesak, H. I. 1996. Incorporating price, advertising and distribution
P. E. Murphy, E. R. Laczniak, eds. AMA Educators’ Conf. Proc., in diffusion models of innovation: Some theoretical and empir-
American Marketing Association, Chicago, 226–230. ical results expectations in diffusion models. Comput. Oper. Res.
Grocery Managament Association. 2006. Insights into the 23(10) 1007–1023.
food, beverage and consumer products industry. http:// Mesak, H. I., W. D. Berg. 1995. Incorporating price and replace-
www.gmabrands.com. ment purchases in new products diffusion models for con-
Hahn, M., S. Park, L. Krishnamurthi, A. A. Zoltners. 1994. Analy- sumer durables. Decision Sci. 26(4) 425–449.
sis of new-product diffusion using a four-segment trial-repeat Moorthy, K. S., I. P. L. Png. 1992. Market segmentation, cannibal-
model. Marketing Sci. 13(3) 224–247. ization, and the timing of product introductions. Management
Hardie, B. G. S., P. S. Fader, M. Wisniewski. 1998. An empirical com- Sci. 38(3) 345–359.
parison of new product trial forecasting models. J. Forecasting Muller, E., R. Peres, V. Mahajan. 2007. Innovation diffusion and new
17(3–4) 209–229. product growth: Beyond a theory of communications. Working
Hauser, J., G. J. Tellis, A. Griffin. 2006. Research on innovation: A paper, Leonard Stern School of Business, New York University,
review and agenda for marketing science. Marketing Sci. 25(6) New York.
687–717. Neelamegham, R., P. Chintagunta. 1999. A Bayesian model to fore-
Hitsch, G. J. 2006. An empirical model of optimal dynamic product cast new product performance in domestic and international
launch and exit under demand uncertainty. Marketing Sci. 25(1) markets. Marketing Sci. 18(2) 115–136.
25–50. Parker, P. M. 1992. Price elasticity dynamics over the adoption life
Horsky, D. 1990. A diffusion model incorporating product benefits, cycle. J. Marketing Res. 29(3) 358–367.
price, income and information. Marketing Sci. 9(4) 342–365. Parker, P. M., H. Gatignon. 1994. Competitive effects in diffusion
Horsky, D., K. V. Mate. 1988. Dynamic advertising of competing models. Internat. J. Res. Marketing 11 17–39.
durables good producers. Marketing Sci. 7(4) 356–367. Pauwels, K. 2007. How retailer and competitor decisions drive
Horsky, D., L. Simon. 1983. Advertising and the diffusion of new the long-term effectivness of manufacturer promotions for fast
products. Marketing Sci. 2(1) 1–17. moving consumer goods. J. Retailing. Forthcoming.
Information Resources, Inc. 2005. 2004 New Product Pacesetters. Pauwels, K., D. M. Hanssens. 2007. Performance regimes and mar-
Chicago. keting policy shifts. Marketing Sci. 26(3) 293–311.
Jain, D., R. C. Rao. 1990. Effect of price on the demand for durables. Pauwels, K., D. M. Hanssens, S. Siddarth. 2002. The long-term
J. Bus. Econom. Statist. 8(2) 163–170. effects of price promotions on category incidence, brand
Jedidi, K., C. F. Mela, S. Gupta. 1999. Managing advertising and choice, and purchase quantity. J. Marketing Res. 39(4) 421–439.
promotion for long-run profitability. Marketing Sci. 18(1) 1–22. Rao, A., M. Yamada. 1988. Forecasting with a repeat purchase dif-
Jones, J. M., C. J. Ritz. 1991. Incorporating distribution into new fusion model. Management Sci. 34(6) 734–752.
product diffusion models. Internat. J. Res. Marketing 8 91–112. Ratchford, B. T., S. K. Balasubramanian, W. A. Kamakura. 2000.
Kalish, S. 1983. Monopolist pricing with dynamic demand and pro- Diffusion models with replacement and multiple purchases.
duction cost. Marketing Sci. 2(2) 135–160. V. Mahajan, E. Muller, Y. Wind, eds. New-Product Diffusion Mod-
Kalish, S. 1985. A new product adoption model with pricing, adver- els. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, The Netherlands,
tising and uncertainty. Management Sci. 31(12) 1569–1585. 123–140.
Kalish, S., G. L. Lilien. 1986. A market entry timing model for new Rogers, E. M. 1976. New product adoption and diffusion. J. Con-
technologies. Management Sci. 32(2) 194–205. sumer Res. 2 290–301.
Ataman, Mela, and van Heerde: Building Brands
1054 Marketing Science 27(6), pp. 1036–1054, © 2008 INFORMS

Simon, H., K.-H. Sebastian. 1987. Diffusion and advertising: The Van den Bulte, C. 2000. New product diffusion acceleration: Mea-
German telephone company. Management Sci. 33(4) 451–466. surement and analysis. Marketing Sci. 19(4) 366–380.
Slotegraaf, R. J., K. Pauwels. 2008. The impact of brand equity Van den Bulte, C., Y. V. Joshi. 2007. New product diffu-
and innovation on the long-term effectiveness of promotions. sion with influentials and imitators. Marketing Sci. 26(3)
J. Marketing Res. Forthcoming. 400–421.
Steenkamp, J.-B. E. M., K. Gielens. 2003. Consumer and market Van Heerde, H. J., K. Helsen, M. G. Dekimpe. 2007. The impact of a
drivers of the trial probability of new consumer packaged product-harm crisis on marketing effectiveness. Marketing Sci.
goods. J. Consumer Res. 30 368–384. 26(2) 230–245.
Steenkamp, J.-B., V. R. Nijs, D. Hanssens, M. Dekimpe. 2005. Com- Van Heerde, H. J., C. F. Mela, P. Manchanda. 2004. The dynamic
petitive reactions to advertising and promotion attacks. Mar- effect of innovation on market structure. J. Marketing Res. 41(2)
keting Sci. 24(1) 35–54. 166–183.
Sudhir, K., V. R. Rao. 2006. Do slotting allowances enhance effi- West, M., J. Harrison. 1997. Bayesian Forecasting and Dynamic Models,
ciency or hinder competition? J. Marketing Res. 43(2) 137–155. 2nd ed. Springer-Verlag, New York.
Tellis, G. J., P. H. Franses. 2006. Optimal data interval for estimating Wilson, L. O., J. A. Norton. 1989. Optimal entry timing for a product
advertising response. Marketing Sci. 25(3) 217–229. line extension. Marketing Sci. 8(1) 1–17.
Tellis, G. J., S. Stremersch, E. Yin. 2003. The international takeoff Xie, J., M. Song, M. Sirbu, Q. Wang. 1997. Kalman filter estima-
of new products: The role of economics, culture and country tion of new product diffusion models. J. Marketing Res. 34(3)
innovativeness. Marketing Sci. 22(2) 188–208. 378–393.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen