Sie sind auf Seite 1von 21

The AIPLA Antitrust News

A Publication of the AIPLA Committee on Antitrust Law May 2011

What are the implications? The FTC


Chairs’ Corner has clearly set forth its position that its efforts
are directed to enhancing competition and
innovation. But is it, and is it direction
Welcome all, and I hope you will be
consistent with other Administration efforts on
joining us at the Spring Meeting in San
these issues? In this regard, I commend to
Francisco. Our Committee, together with the
you the report issued this past February by the
Corporate Counsel and Licensing Committees,
National Economic Council, Council of
is presenting a fantastic program touching on
Economic Advisors and the Office of Science
some of the most interesting issues involving
and Technology Policy, entitled ―A Strategy
IP and antitrust law. Indeed, this issue of the
for American Innovation.‖ This report makes
AIPLA Antitrust News includes articles on the
plain that for the United States to remain
same subjects - the FTC‘s most recent
globally competitive and for innovation to
commentary on patent issues and the current
flourish, patent holders interests must be
state of play on reverse payments. Thanks, as
reinforced. This report also provides
always, to the authors: Geoff Oliver and
interesting perspectives suggesting that even
David Maiorana; Michael O‘Brien; and
the FTC‘s concept of innovation may be
Robert Pluta and Brandon Helms.
limited, and not sufficiently broad or balanced
as is necessary to support true economic
In considering these issues, it appears
growth and competitiveness.
that we may be witnessing some interesting
developments beyond those specific to
At a minimum, these are interesting
individual matters or even the FTC‘s report
questions, but they do go beyond the
itself. As pointed out by Geoff and David in
academic. We look forward to your
their fine overview of the FTC‘s recent report,
participation in the dialogue.
―An Evolving IP Marketplace,‖ the FTC‘s
focus is not on antitrust law, but on pure
As always, much thanks to David
patent law, and what the FTC believes may be
Swenson, our tireless and committed editor,
competitive issues arising from the application
publisher and guiding light for this Newsletter,
of the patent laws.
for yet another great edition.
But is this a proper direction for the
FTC? Does the FTC‘s focus take the interest
of patent owners properly into account, and
AIPLA Antitrust Committee
does the FTC, an antitrust agency, give proper
deference to the patent laws? Indeed, when
Richard S. Taffet, Chair
we consider the FTC‘s report and its current
Bingham McCutchen, LLP
efforts in the reverse payment area, are we
richard.taffet@bingham.com
witnessing efforts by the agency that are
aimed directly at weakening the established
George Gordon, Vice-Chair
rules and standards for enforcement of patents
Dechert LLP
and the rights and benefits that a strong patent
george.gordon@dechert.com
system provides?

The AIPLA Antitrust News – May 2011 Page 1


Federal Trade Commission Issues Report rights in 1995.2 In 2007, the FTC and DOJ
on the Evolving Intellectual Property together issued a report focusing on antitrust
Marketplace enforcement and intellectual property
rights.3 Each agency has addressed issues of
David M. Maiorana intellectual property law in the context of its
Geoffrey D. Oliver enforcement actions, amicus briefs, speeches
Jones Day and other statements of policy. These
Cleveland, OH sources reflect the agencies‘ positions with
dmaiorana@jonesday.com respect to the question of how the antitrust
gdoliver@jonesday.com laws should be applied to conduct involving
intellectual property that affects
competition.
In March of this year, the Federal
Trade Commission (―FTC‖) issued a long- The Report is different. It does not
anticipated report recommending changes in deal with application of the antitrust laws.
patent law and practice relating to notice and Rather, it addresses issues of pure patent
remedies. The FTC‘s report, entitled ―The law. The FTC chose to comment on these
Evolving IP Marketplace: Aligning Patent issues because it believes the way the patent
Notice and Remedies With Competition‖ laws are implemented can affect
(the ―Report‖),1 focuses on issues of public competition. The FTC recommended
notice of the scope of patent claims changes to the patent laws and the way those
coverage and remedies for patent laws are implemented that, in its opinion,
infringement. It contains multiple specific serve to better preserve competition. The
recommendations for changes in patent law FTC views the Report as continuing the
and practice, summarized in the Executive ―policy engagement with the patent
Summary in the form of 35 system‖4 that it launched in its controversial
recommendations directed to Congress, the October 2003 report regarding the ―proper
Patent and Trademark Office and the courts. balance‖ of competition policy and patent
Many of the FTC‘s recommendations go to law.5
fundamental issues of patent law and, if
adopted and implemented, would have a
significant impact on both patent 2
U.S. Dep‘t of Justice and Fed. Trade Comm‘n,
prosecution and litigation. ―Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual
Property‖ (April 6, 1995) (available at
Background http://www.ftc.gov/bc/0558.pdf).
3
U.S. Dep‘t of Justice and Fed. Trade Comm‘n,
―Antitrust Enforcement and Intellectual Property
The FTC has addressed intellectual Rights: Promoting Innovation and Competition‖
property issues before. Together with the (April 2007) (available at
Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of http://www.ftc.gov/reports/innovation/P040101Prom
Justice (―DOJ‖), the FTC issued guidelines otingInnovationandCompetitionrpt0704.pdf).
4
on the licensing of intellectual property Fed. Trade Comm‘n, Press Release, FTC Report
Recommends Improvements in Patent System to
Promote Innovation and Benefit Consumers (March
7, 2011) (available at
1
Fed. Trade Comm‘n, ―The Evolving IP http://www.ftc.gov/opa/2011/03/patentreport.shtm).
5
Marketplace: Aligning Patent Notice and Remedies Fed. Trade Comm‘n, ―To Promote Innovation: The
With Competition (March 2011) (available at Proper Balance of Competition and Patent Law and
http://www.ftc.gov/os/2011/03/110307patentreport.p Policy‖ (October 2003) (available at
df). http://www.ftc.gov/os/2003/10/innovationrpt.pdf).

2
The FTC began its study in In the first chapter, the FTC describes its
December, 2008, soliciting contributions view of ―open innovation,‖ in which a
from the public and receiving over 50 company does not rely solely on its own
written submissions from companies, internal research and development for
academics and practitioners. It conducted innovation, but rather seeks the inventions it
eight days of hearings in Washington D.C. needs from outside sources as well. The
and Berkeley, California, at which more FTC refers to acquisitions of technology in
than 140 witnesses presented their views. this manner as ―ex ante‖ transactions, in
The FTC supplemented this record with its which the purchaser or licensee first obtains
own independent research. the technology by means of a technology
transfer from the patent owner. The FTC
Twenty-seven months after it began emphasizes that open innovation benefits
its work, the FTC issued the Report. The companies as well as consumers, and points
Report consists of eight chapters: chapters 1 out that many aspects of patent law and the
and 2 describe the FTC‘s view of the patent system help to promote open
evolving IP marketplace; chapter 3 focuses innovation.
on patent notice; and chapters 4-8 deal with
remedies. Chapters 3 and 5-8 contain the In the second chapter, the FTC draws
FTC‘s specific recommendations for a sharp distinction between ―ex ante‖
changes to patent law and practice. transactions and what it refers to as ―ex
post‖ transactions. It defines ―ex post‖
The introduction explains the FTC‘s transactions as situations in which the
specific focus on notice and remedies. The licensee has already invested in creating,
FTC states that notice affects competition at developing or commercializing the
every stage of the R&D process. The technology in question. The Report notes
―ability to identify and assess the scope of that the licensee needs a license from the
relevant patents at an early stage‖ is patent holder to avoid liability for patent
important to firms‘ decisions regarding infringement, but the license is not
investments in potential new products.6 accompanied by any transfer of technology.
Specific product design decisions are According to the FTC, ex post transactions
affected by incomplete knowledge of the have the potential for both beneficial and
costs and availability of different detrimental effects. The FTC attributes ex
technologies. And resolution of patent post transactions in part to problems with
claims after product launch by means of patent notice and quality and with remedies
litigation may not only increase costs but for patent infringement, concluding that
also deprive consumers ―of the full benefit concerns regarding ex post transactions have
of competition among technologies.‖7 increased in recent years because of an
increase in patent litigation and the
Ex Ante v. Ex Post Patent Licensing evolution of patent assertion business
Transactions models. The FTC identifies the primary
driver of this development to be ―patent
The first two chapters set forth the assertion entities,‖ (―PAEs‖) defined as non-
FTC‘s understanding of the evolving nature practicing entities with a business strategy
of the intellectual property ―marketplace.‖ based on patent enforcement. The FTC
describes the respective roles of patent
6
Report at 3. enforcement and licensing companies,
7
Id. litigation finance firms, patent aggregators,
3
defensive buying funds and intermediaries. parties to determine the likely scope of
The FTC intends its report to address ―the claims that may emerge from the
conditions of patent law and policy that have continuation process. The FTC‘s concern is
created conditions where a patent market based in part on the fact that the written
based on ex post transactions has flourished description requirement is not focused on
and . . . that lead to or create incentives for the question of notice to others, and in part
patentees to pursue ex post patent on its perception that the PTO has been lax
transactions rather than technology in enforcing the written description
8
transfer.‖ requirement. According to the FTC, if
competitors are unable to predict the claims
Issues Relating to Patent Notice that might emerge from the continuation
process, competitors‘ investment decisions
Chapter 3 deals with issues relating may be distorted and the competitive efforts
to patent notice to third parties as well as of rivals may be impaired.
patent quality. The FTC sets forth various
recommendations (separated into 16 Obviously, this recommendation, if
separate specific recommendations in the adopted, would have a dramatic impact on
Executive Summary) intended to promote current practice. Patent owners likely would
greater clarity in the scope of patent claims face considerable limits in their ability to
coverage, improve predictability of evolving enforce claims arising out of continuation
or future patent claims, and facilitate more applications. Their ability to enforce
effective patent searches. Four of the amended claims may depend on the nature
recommendations would require legislation. and extent of the amendments. The
Of these, one relates to funding of the PTO; recommendation, if adopted, would inject a
three recommendations would change complicated new factual issue into such
substantive law. Two recommendations are patent litigation: when did the alleged
addressed to the courts, and the remainder infringer first start developing, using, or
are intended for the Patent and Trademark making ―substantial preparation for using‖
Office. the product or process in question? The
recommendation could also affect the patent
The most far-reaching of the prosecution process, as applicants might be
recommendations relating to notice is the more likely to include more claims in initial
proposal that Congress enact legislation ―to applications and, depending on the
protect from infringement actions third circumstances, might resist amending patent
parties who (i) infringe properly described claims more frequently.
claims only because of claim amendments
(or new claims) following a continuation The remaining recommendations for
and (ii) developed, used, or made substantial legislation, if adopted, would require
preparation for using, the relevant product or publication of all patent applications 18
process before the amended (or newly months after filing, regardless of whether
added) claims were published.‖9 This the applicant has filed patent applications
recommendation is based on the FTC‘s abroad, and require public recording of all
concern that the specification may not assignments of patents and published patent
provide sufficient notice to enable third applications. The FTC recommends that the
courts should apply the standard of a person
8
Id. at 72.
having ordinary skill in the art
9
Id. at 16. (―PHOSITA‖) in a manner that is fact-based

4
and appropriately tailored to the specific reward incentivizes innovators to pursue
technology at issue, and that the inventions that will be valued by consumers.
PHOSITA‘s ability to foresee future This, in turn, promotes research and
evolution of the claims in a patent development of those areas most likely to
application should be more fully have consumer value.
incorporated into application of the written
description requirement. In particular, a Chapter 5 focuses on lost profits
patent applicant ―should not be understood damages and offers three recommendations:
to have been in possession of the subject (1) courts should permit a patentee
matter of a new or amended claim of scope ―flexibility‖ in creating the ―but-for‖ world
broader than what the PHOSITA, on the to avoid under-compensation; (2) courts
filing date, could reasonably be expected to should reject the ―entire market value rule‖
foresee from the specification.‖10 altogether, and instead require proof of the
degree of consumer preference for the
Issues Relating to Patent Remedies patented invention over alternatives; and (3)
courts should reject dual awards of lost
Chapter 4 discusses remedies in profits and reasonable royalty damages
general, with Chapters 5-8 analyzing lost when competition from alternatives would
profits damages, the hypothetical have prevented the patentee from making all
negotiation in reasonable royalty damages, of the infringer‘s sales.13
calculating a reasonable royalty, and
permanent injunctions, respectively. On the first point, the FTC urges
courts to reject the ―all-or-nothing‖ Panduit
The FTC begins by noting that, to be test for lost profits14 in favor of a more
effective, encourage innovation and avoid flexible, but less defined, approach. This
distorting competition, patent remedies must approach includes consideration of the
give the patentee what it would have earned extent of consumer preferences for the
in the market absent infringement. To patented feature over alternatives, as
address perceived shortcomings, the FTC opposed to determining whether alternatives
seeks to ―derive an economically grounded fall on either side of a ―bright line dividing
approach‖ for analyzing patent remedies, the acceptable from the unacceptable.‖15
then to evaluate the current system of Such an analysis would recognize a ―degree
damages and permanent injunctions against of substitutability‖ between a patented
that approach.11 product and noninfringing substitutes. The
Report then discusses both ends of this
The FTC repeats an oft-stated spectrum, but not the likely more difficult
criticism of the current system: remedies cases in between. The FTC does, however,
must be proportional to the value of the suggest that an economic analysis of the
invention.12 The patent remedies system type used in antitrust merger review can
must equate the overall value of an help determine where alternatives fall on the
invention with the benefit conferred to the spectrum.16 (If applied, this would introduce
patentee. The FTC believes that aligning the a highly detailed, fact-driven and data-
value of the invention with the patentee‘s
13
Id. at 18-19.
14
Panduit Corp. v. Stahlin Bros. Fibre Works, Inc.,
10
Id. at 15. 575 F.2d 1152 (6th Cir. 1978).
11 15
Id. at 138. Report at 153.
12 16
Id. at 139-40. Id. at 154.

5
intensive analysis into patent damages sue companies for alleged infringement by
calculations.) later-developed products, thus discouraging
innovation, versus (2) reducing patent
The FTC urges courts to reject the damages awards will encourage
―entire market value rule,‖ which is used to infringement, also discouraging investments
determine whether to award lost profits in innovation.19
based on the entire value of the patented
product when the patented invention is only Within this framework, the Report
a small part of that product. Again, the FTC rejects concerns with determination of the
recommends rejection of a bright-line rule in appropriate royalty based on a hypothetical
favor of the potentially more nebulous negotiation between a willing licensor and a
―degree of substitutability‖ test.17 willing licensee. The first concern is the
―counterfactual nature‖ of the hypothetical
Finally, the FTC concludes that negotiation – in reality, the parties had the
courts should reject dual awards of lost opportunity to negotiate a license but chose
profits and reasonable royalties when not to. The FTC dismisses these concerns as
competition from alternatives would have unfounded.20
prevented the patentee from making all of
the infringer‘s sales. In cases where courts A second concern with reasonable
have awarded lost profits damages based on royalty damages is that merely requiring an
a portion of the infringing sales, they have infringer to pay what it would have paid
sometimes awarded reasonable royalties on anyway to license does not deter
the remaining infringing sales. The FTC infringement. The FTC dismisses this
views such awards as an example of over- concern by noting that because the
compensation to patentees because it ignores hypothetical negotiation assumes that the
competition from noninfringing patent is valid and infringed, royalties tend
alternatives.18 to be higher following trial than they would
have been in the absence of litigation, thus
Chapter 6 reviews the hypothetical reasonable royalty awards do have some
negotiation in reasonable royalty damages. deterrent effect. Finally, the FTC notes that
The FTC recommends that courts there are other mechanisms in the law to
considering reasonable royalty damages deter infringement: enhanced damages and
move back to the true purpose of such permanent injunctions. The FTC‘s
damages, compensating the patentee for the recommendation is that courts should
value of the invention, and away from continue to utilize the hypothetical
attempts to punish or deter infringers. negotiation framework, free from any
concerns about deterring infringement or
The chapter begins by describing punishing infringers.21
both sides of the contentious debate on
patent damages reform, which the FTC In Chapter 7, the FTC suggests
views as expressing similar concerns: (1) several steps courts can take to increase the
patent damages have become divorced from accuracy of reasonably royalty calculations.
the economic value of inventions, which has First, the FTC urges courts to recognize that
encouraged the development of PAEs who
19
Id. at 161-64.
17 20
Id. at 155-56. Id. at 170-72.
18 21
Id. at 157. Id. at 176.

6
the universally-applied Georgia-Pacific terms of the comparable and hypothetical
factors22 are only a partial list of available licenses. This is consistent with recent
evidence to be considered in calculating Federal Circuit precedent. The FTC
reasonable royalties. Next, the Report applauds the Federal Circuit‘s rejection of
recommends that courts should include in a ―rule-of-thumb‖ evidence in the recent
reasonable royalty analysis the incremental Uniloc case.26
value of the patented invention over the
―next-best‖ alternative, because this The last aspect of reasonable
establishes the maximum amount a willing royalties that the FTC addressed is the
licensee would pay in a hypothetical choice of the royalty base to which a royalty
negotiation.23 rate is applied to determine the amount of
damages. Not surprisingly given the
The FTC next recommends that recommendation to eliminate the ―entire
courts make clear that the hypothetical market value rule‖ in the context of lost
negotiation occurs at an early stage of profits damages, the FTC recommends that
product development, before investments courts should not use the entire market value
are made and become sunk costs. Including rule when determining the appropriate
in the royalty calculation the cost of royalty base in a reasonable royalty
changing designs after sunk costs are calculation. In addition, courts should select
incurred overcompensates patentees.24 as the base the smallest priceable component
that incorporates the inventive feature.27
The Report next recommends an
increasing role of courts in the gatekeeping Finally, in Chapter 8 the FTC
role of enforcing Rule 702 of the Federal analyzes permanent injunctions in patent
Rules of Evidence. This has two prongs. cases, and makes several recommendations
First, courts must test the admissibility of regarding the eBay equitable framework.28
expert testimony on damages by The overall theme is that permanent
determining whether it will reliably assist injunctions should be awarded in the
the trier of fact in applying the hypothetical majority of cases because (1) exclusivity is
negotiation. Courts should also require a the foundation of the patent system‘s
showing that the expert‘s methodology is incentive to innovate, (2) injunctions deter
reliable, that the expert reliably applies the infringement, and (3) a predictable
methodology to the facts, and that the injunction threat will promote licensing.
testimony is adequately supported by data.25 But these goals must be balanced against the
use of an injunction threat as ―hold-up‖ to
Applying this general extract overcompensation.29
recommendation, the FTC recommends that
courts only admit testimony and evidence of The Report provides some guidance
comparable licenses upon a reliable showing regarding how to determine whether an
of similarity between the licensed and injunction is appropriate or should be denied
infringed patents, and between the non-price due to ―hold-up.‖ Such factors include: (1)

22 26
Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. United States Plywood Uniloc USA, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp., 2011 WL
Corp., 318 F. Supp. 1116 (S.D.N.Y. 1970); Report at 9738 (Fed. Cir. Jan. 4, 2011).
27
179-80. Id. at 212.
23 28
Report at 189. eBay, Inc. v. MercExchange, LLC, 547 U.S. 388
24
Id. at 190-91. (2006).
25 29
Id. at 199. Id. at 223-26.

7
whether the patented technology is a minor determining whether to issue an exclusion
component of a complex product that would order, which is a permanent injunction
have been easy to design around ex ante, (2) against importation of an infringing product.
whether the infringer uses the patented The FTC recommends that the ITC use its
technology to compete with the infringer, domestic industry requirement to prevent
and (3) the absence or presence of access to the ITC by PAEs whose only
copying.30 The FTC next analyzes the four activity is extracting ex post licenses from
eBay factors and provided recommendations products already on the market.33 Second,
for each. the FTC suggests that the ITC should utilize
the public interest factor found in 19 U.S.C.
Courts should not presume § 1337(d)(1) to deny exclusion orders in
irreparable harm based on a finding of cases involving hold-up, especially in cases
infringement, and should recognize that involving standards.34
infringement can irreparably harm certain
non-practicing entities that engage in Conclusion
technology transfer, such as universities and
start-ups. Conversely, PAEs may not have The FTC‘s report comes at a time
the same concerns as other patentees about when these and other issues are being
deterring future infringement and protecting debated in Congress, the courts and the
their reputation as an innovator. Patent and Trademark Office. The Report
does not carry any specific implications for
With respect to balance of the the FTC‘s future antitrust enforcement. It
equities, courts should consider the hardship remains to be seen, however, what, if any,
of an infringer facing ―hold-up,‖ and should impact the FTC‘s report may have on future
reject the notion that an infringer cannot be patent prosecution and litigation. Certainly,
heard to complain if an injunction would as we have seen with recent efforts to reform
destroy its business.31 Regarding the public U.S. patent law, different industries (and
interest, the FTC again focuses on situations even companies within an industry), as well
where ―hold-up‖ occurs, noting that this as non-practicing entities, may have
could adversely affect the public interest.32 divergent views on the wisdom of the FTC‘s
specific recommendations. Much is likely
The Report also notes that if courts to depend on the extent to which individual
deny a request for a permanent injunction, parties seek to use the Report to support
they should apply the hypothetical their own individual arguments in these fora,
negotiation framework to determine an and whether the report and
appropriate on-going royalty rate for post- recommendations are given any weight.
judgment infringement.

In the last section, the FTC makes


recommendations to the International Trade
Commission (―ITC‖) to avoid ―hold-up.‖
The Federal Circuit has held that the ITC is
not constrained by the eBay analysis when

30
Id. at 227-28.
31 33
Id. at 232. Id. at 241-42.
32 34
Id. at 234-35. Id. at 242-43.

8
Developments in Consumer Standing in As a constitutional matter, a plaintiff
Walker Process Claims must have standing in order to sue.
Constitutional standing exists where a
Michael O‘Brien35 plaintiff 1) suffers an injury in fact 2) which
Woodland, CA is caused by the defendant and 3) can be
mobrien@lexmail.com remedied by a favorable court decision.39
However, ―the focus of the doctrine of
‗antitrust standing‘ is somewhat different
The Supreme Court held in Walker from that of standing as a constitutional
Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food Machinery doctrine. Harm to the antitrust plaintiff is
& Chemical Corp., 382 U.S. 172 (1965), sufficient to satisfy the constitutional
that ―the enforcement of a patent procured standing requirement of injury in fact, but
by fraud on the Patent Office may be the court must make a further determination
violative of § 2 of the Sherman Act provided whether the plaintiff is a proper party to
the other elements necessary to a § 2 case bring a private antitrust action.‖40 Antitrust
are present.‖36 The Supreme Court did not standing requires a plaintiff to show a
specify who could assert such a claim and favorable balance of five factors: "(1) the
two views have developed on the matter. nature of the plaintiff's alleged injury; that
The first view finds that the Sherman Act is, whether it was the type the antitrust laws
exists to protect competitors from were intended to forestall; (2) the directness
monopolistic practices in the market place of the injury; (3) the speculative measure of
and would only give standing to competitors the harm; (4) the risk of duplicative
who face a risk of suit for patent recovery; and (5) the complexity in
infringement. In re Remeron Antitrust apportioning damages."41 At issue in direct
Litigation.37 The second view finds that purchaser cases is the second element.
consumers can face higher prices as a result
of a merchant‘s fraud upon the patent office Walker Process claims are
scaring off competition from the commonly asserted as a counterclaim to a
marketplace which is an injury courts may claim of patent infringement. Courts have
address. Ritz Camera & Image v. SanDisk.38 allowed anyone sued for infringement to
This article compares the reasoning of each have standing to counterclaim with Walker
approach. Process, even consumers.42 The two
seminal Federal Circuit decisions involved
I. Constitutional and Statutory defendants directly sued for patent
Standing Requirements infringement, rather than a plaintiff seeking
declaratory judgment of invalidity or non-

35 39
Editor of the Northern District of California Blog Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife, 504 U.S. 555, 560-
(www.ndcalblog.com). 61 (1992).
36 40
Id. at 174; Sherman Antitrust Act, 17 U.S.C. § 2. Associated Gen. Contractors of Cal., Inc. v.
37
335 F.Supp.2d 522 (D.N.J. 2004) (Remeron) Carpenters, 459 U.S. 519, 535 n.31 (1983).
41
(finding a consumer as a direct purchaser does not Amarel v. Connell, 102 F.3d 1494, 1507 (9th
have standing to pursue a Walker Process claim, Cir.1996) (citing Assoc. Gen. Contractors, 459 U.S.
rather it is only available as a cross-claim in a patent at 535).
42
infringement action). Nobelpharma AB v. Implant Innovations, Inc., 141
38
5:10-CV-02787 (N.D. Cal. Feb. 24, 2011) (Ritz F. 3d 1059 (Fed. Cir. 1998); Argus Chem. Corp. v.
Camera) (finding a consumer does have standing to Fibre Glass-Evercoat Co., 812 F.2d 1381 (Fed. Cir.
pursue a Walker Process claim in the first instance). 1987).

9
infringement.43 The sued consumers face an Litigation.47 Mr. Orlofsky consolidated the
extremely palpable injury – infringement case law at the time and determined that the
damages or licensing fees if they settle – injury caused by the antitrust violation is
which conferred them standing to raise a best litigated a competitor who is the party
Walker Process claim. closest to the harm.48

To the contrary, the Supreme Court To get there, Mr. Orlofsky begins
has foreclosed antitrust standing to indirect with a litany of cases that have answered the
purchasers. In Illinois Brick v. Illinois the same question, albeit differently. The first
State brought an antitrust action against a word on the matter was Judge Neal Peters
concrete block manufacturer from whom it McCurn in Indium Corp. of America v.
had indirectly purchased concrete blocks.44 Semi-Alloys, Inc..49 That case involved a
In rejecting the action for lack of standing, declaratory judgment action where the
the Supreme Court interpreted federal plaintiff also raised a Walker Process claim.
antitrust law to prevent indirect purchasers The court extended Walker Process standing
from seeking antitrust damages except in to producers who "were ready, willing, and
certain limited circumstances.45 Those able to produce the article and would have
limited circumstances have not been found done so but for the exercise of exclusionary
in Walker Process litigation.46 In Relafen a power by the defendant."50 However, two
set of plaintiffs sued GlaxoSmithKline years later, Judge Anne E. Thompson in
alleging that it unlawfully delayed the Carrot Components Corp. v. Thomas &
marketing of a generic version of the anti- Betts Corp., reached the exact opposite
inflammatory drug nabumetone though suits conclusion. Carrot Components, much like
alleging infringement of an invalid and Indium, was seeking a declaratory judgment
unenforceable patent. Citing Illinois Brick, of invalidity of two of the defendant‘s
the court found that indirect purchasers had patents and damages under a Walker
no standing and dismissed their case. Process claim.51 The court ruled that with
However, this left the question of direct respect to declaratory judgment claims, only
purchaser consumer standing open, and the parties that have been directly threatened
Federal District Courts have reached with suit or who can demonstrate that they
different results. reasonably anticipate a patent infringement
suit or some effort by the patent holder to
II. The New Jersey Approach to enforce the subject patent against them will
Walker Process Standing have standing to bring such a claim for
relief.
The New Jersey approach is what I
call the legal theory espoused by former Next to speak on the matter was
Federal Judge Stephen Orlofsky, sitting as a Judge Richard Posner, sitting by designation
special master in In re K-DUR Antitrust in Asahi Glass Co., Ltd. v. Pentech Pharma.,

43
Id.
44 47
431 U.S. 720, 726 (1977) (explaining that the no. 01-1652 (D.N.J. Mar. 1, 2007) (K-DUR).
48
concrete blocks pass from the manufacturer to Id. at 17 citing Associated General Contractors,
masonry contractors and to general contractors before 459 U.S. at 542.
49
reaching the governmental entities). 591 F. Supp. 608 (N.D.N.Y. 1984).
45 50
Id. at 728-29. Id. at 614.
46 51
See e.g. In re Relafen Antitrust Litigation, 360 229 U.S.P.Q. 61 (D.N.J. 1986) ("Carrot
F.Supp.2d 166 (D. Mass. 2005) (Relafen). Components").

10
Inc..52 In Asahi Glass, the plaintiff was a The only case Mr. Orlofsky could
supplier of the paroxetine, active ingredient find that cut the other way was Molecular
in a generic version of the drug Paxil. Asahi Diagnostics Labs. v. Hoffman-LaRoche,
sued the defendant, GlaxoSmithKline Inc., which departed from all existing case
(Glaxo) in a declaratory judgment action law at that moment.56 In Molecular
similar to Carrot Components in an effort to Diagnostics, the plaintiff, a direct purchaser
have the patent for Paxil declared invalid. of the subject patented product, brought suit
To show the directness of injury requirement under Section 1 of the Sherman Act
Asahi argued that its potential customers charging that it had been forced to pay
were not purchasing its paroxetine product artificially inflated prices for the product as
because they feared being sued by Glaxo.53 a result of defendants' enforcement of the
Judge Posner observed that if plaintiff's patent, which plaintiffs allege was obtained
potential customers were deterred by by fraud on the PTO. The Court
Glaxo's threat of suit, then those customers distinguished Carrot Companies because
had a cause of action against Glaxo. here the customers were plaintiffs and
However, Asahi had no right to bring an distinguished Remeron by its poor
action on that basis. Asahi Glass notes in reasoning.57 Judge Kennedy explained that
dicta that direct purchasers who face suit the purpose of Illinois Brick was not to limit
have standing to pursue Walker Process antitrust plaintiffs, but to ensure the correct
claims, but a supplier who is not the target one was in court:
of a suit by a patent holder, does not have
standing to bring a Walker Process claim. Examining these factors, the
court sees no reason to limit
Mr. Orlofsky noted that Remeron standing to competitors. While
consolidated Indium and Carrot entities facing enforcement
Components to create what would become actions are more likely to rely
the majority rule: ―Plaintiffs, as direct on Walker Process, this reflects
purchasers, 1) never had the '099 patent more that they are in a stronger
enforced against them, 2) were never position to detect wrongdoing
threatened with such enforcement, and 3) than a Congressional
were not in a position to manufacture a preference. If one believes that
competing generic version of one of the primary purposes of
54
mirtazapine.‖ Essentially, one of those is a treble damages action is
required for Walker Process standing, deterrence, then increasing the
otherwise the plaintiffs are ―donning the number of parties scrutinizing
cloak of a Clayton Act monopolization the actions of potential
claim….‖55 monopolists will further that
goal. Moreover, because direct
purchasers have frequent
52
289 F.Supp.2d 986 (N.D. Ill. 2003) ("Asahi interactions with the
Glass"). defendants, they have a strong
53
Id. at 989.
54
Remeron, 335 F.Supp.2d at 529.
55 56
Id.; Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914, 15 U.S.C. §§ 402 F.Supp.2d 276 (D.D.C. 2005) ("Molecular
12-27. The Clayton Act can be used as a vehicle to Diagnostics").
57
enforce a Sherman Act monopolization claim, but Id. at 280 (―The holding cites no controlling
does not create a claim in itself for fraud upon the precedent, nor offers any compelling justification for
USPTO. Walker Process, 382 U.S. at 178. its conclusion.)

11
incentive to discover and of California Court which is the subject of
litigate the offense. See this author‘s blog has answered that question
William H. Page, The Scope of in the negative.
Liability For Antitrust
Violations, 37 Stan. L. Rev. III. The Northern California
1445, 1488 (1985). Those Approach
against whom a patent is
enforced, by comparison, will The Northern California Approach is
generally have limited contact what I call the legal theory Judge William
with a defendant unless there is H. Alsup used to grant consumer standing in
the suspicion of infringement.58 In re Netflix Antitrust Litigation.62 It is
interesting that the Northern District would
The court ruled that direct purchasers and be receptive to those claims since Bourns,
competitors are equally well-suited to Inc., v. Raychem Corp. found that
pursue Walker Process claims against both competitor plaintiffs who were not prepared
patent holders, those whose patents are to enter the market did not have Walker
obtained through fraud or "inequitable Process standing.63 Though, the dissent
conduct" on the PTO and those who collude noted that the injury itself was specious, not
with them. whether Bourns was a proper plaintiff.64

Mr. Orlofsky outright rejected Judge Nonetheless, the Northern District‘s


Kennedy‘s reasoning. first exposure to the consumer direct
purchaser standing issue was In re Netflix
Against the backdrop of this case Antitrust Litigation. Netflix operates an
law, I conclude that Molecular online DVD rental business and has two
Diagnostics is an isolated patents that cover it – United States Patents
anomaly. The fact that the No. 6,584,450 and 7,024,381. On April 4,
Molecular Diagnostics court 2006 Netflix sued Blockbuster for
found an exception to the general infringement of the ‗381 patent. Dennis
rule of antitrust standing in that Dilbeck tried to intervene in the action, but
case certainly does not mean that the court denied his request and the parties
the "rule" has lost sway in cases subsequently settled. Undaunted, Mr.
where antitrust claims are based Dilbeck filed the current action alleging a
on Walker Process-type Walker Process antitrust violation based on
59
allegations. the Blockbuster lawsuit. He claimed that the
patents prevented others from entering the
So, does Molecular Diagnostics, ―create[] market and that the Blockbuster lawsuit was
an unnecessary [] split of authority, without a sham. Judge Alsup found standing, first
any compelling reason[?]‖60 Is it really ―an distinguishing Bourne on its facts since
isolated anomaly?‖61 The Northern District Bourne did not address consumer standing.
Further, Judge Alsup found Molecular
Diagnostics persuasive because some
58
Id. at 281-82. antitrust cases were arranged such that
59
K-Dur, at 22.
60
Fisher v. City of San Jose, 475 F.3d 1049, 1076
62
(9th Cir. 2007) (Callahan, J. dissent) overruled 558 506 F.Supp.2d 308 (N.D. Cal. 2007).
63
F.3d 1069 (en banc) (2009). 331 F.3d 704, 711-12 (9th Cir. 2003).
61 64
K-DUR at 22. Id. at 713-14 (Pregerson, J. dissenting).

12
consumers were the ones with the most disclose prior art to the Patent Office
direct injury. Finally he found that the New making the patents procured by fraud and its
Jersey cases were simply dealing with effort to enforce those patents with third
something else because those cases had parties affected the market and creates a
better plaintiffs for the actions than the Walker Process claim. SanDisk moved to
current case. dismiss stating that Ritz Camera was not a
competitor and had no standing to sue.
This order finds Molecular Judge Jeremy Fogel disagreed specifically
Diagnostics persuasive. Even though Walker rejecting the reasoning of the Second
Process claims are predicated on Circuit:
enforcement of a fraudulently-obtained
patent, the harm still accrues directly to However, because viable Walker
consumers. Competitors are excluded from Process claims are rare, it is
the market allowing the patentee to create or unlikely that many direct
maintain an unlawful monopoly.65 purchasers will be in the same
Judge Alsup ultimately dismissed the claims position as Ritz is here.
for failure to plead with the particularity Moreover, as the Supreme Court
required by Fed. R. Civ. P. 9(b). observed in Walker Process, ―the
interest in protecting patentees
A few years after Netflix, the Second from ‗innumerable vexatious
Circuit denied Walker Process standing to suits‘ [may not] be used to
direct purchasers generally, but not frustrate the assertion of rights
consumers specifically.66 Subsequently, the conferred by the antitrust laws.‖
Central District of California adopted the 382 U.S. at 176. Id at 7.
rule in Remeron.67 The issue then recently
came before the Northern District of Further, the court notes, ―because of the
California again in Ritz Camera. heightened evidentiary requirements
necessary for a showing of fraud, few
In Ritz Camera, the plaintiff alleged Walker Process claims survive summary
that Eliyahou Harari tortuously converted judgment.‖ Id. at 6-7. Judge Fogel cites no
flash memory technology from his former authority for this proposition and it is
employer which led to SanDisk obtaining unclear how obvious this statement is.
U.S. Patents Number 5,172,338 and
5,991,517. Further, SanDisk failed to The Northern District Cases, Netflix
and Ritz Camera, ask who Congress
65
Id. at 316. intended to protect with the antitrust
66
In re DDAVP, 585 F.3d 677, 689-91 (2d Cir. 2009) statutes. They have also rekindled a debate
(―giving Walker Process standing to… [direct about the scope of permissible Walker
purchaser] plaintiffs … could result in an avalanche Process claims that was absent just five
of patent challenges, because direct purchasers
otherwise unable to challenge a patent‘s validity years ago. They have also embraced the
could do so simply by dressing their patent challenge reasoning of Molecular Diagnostics
with a Walker Process claim.‖) notwithstanding K-DUR‘s charge that
67
Kaiser Found. v. Abbot Labs., 02-2443 (C.D. Cal. Molecular Diagnostics ―is an isolated
Oct. 8, 2009) (―Plaintiff is merely a potential anomaly.‖ No other courts have been
customer of one of Defendant's potential competitors
and, as such, Plaintiff has not claimed and cannot recently asked the same question and
claim that it did or would have competed with answered it in a meaningful way.
Defendant.‖)

13
Until they do, the moral of the story Federal Trade Commission (―FTC‖),69 and
for plaintiffs‘ attorneys is to try to obtain the current White House administration70
venue in the Northern District of California. believe reverse payment settlements
Similarly, defense counsel should seek should be banned. In addition, members
venue in the District of New Jersey. of Congress have criticized such
Attorneys may also follow my blog agreements and have proposed legislation
(www.ndcalblog.com) for the latest to prohibit them.71 Despite criticism from
developments. these governmental branches—or perhaps
the catalyst behind the call to action from
these governmental bodies—the ―least

Louisiana Wholesale Drug Co. and rehearing en banc in the Arkansas Carpenters case,
the Propriety of “Reverse the DOJ reiterated its position that a rule of reason
Payment” Patent Settlements analysis should apply to reverse payment settlements.
Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae in
Support of Rehearing In Banc, No. 05-2851-cv(L)
Robert G. Pluta & Brandon C. Helms (2d Cir. 2010).
Brinks Hofer Gilson & Lione 69
See Jon Leibowitz, Chairman, Fed. Trade Comm‘n,
Chicago, IL Address at the Center for American Progress: ―Pay-
for-Delay‖ Settlements in the Pharmaceutical
rpluta@brinkshofer.com
Industry: How Congress Can Stop Anticompetitive
bhelms@brinkshofer.com Conduct, Protect Consumers‘ Wallets, and Help Pay
for Health Care Reform (The $35 Billion Solution)
(June 23, 2009) available at
http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/leibowitz/090623payfor
The propriety of reverse payment
delayspeech.pdf.
settlements is a hot-button issue, and has 70
See Office of Mgmt. & Budget, Executive Office
been for several years, particularly in the of the President, Budget of the United States
context of Hatch-Waxman litigation. The Government, Fiscal Year 2012, at 81 (2011),
available at http://
Department of Justice (―DOJ‖),68 the
www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/Overview (―The
President‘s Budget included two proposals to
68
See, e.g., Brief for the United States in Response to increase availability of generic drugs by providing
the Court‘s Invitation, Ark. Carpenters Health & the Federal Trade Commission authority to stop drug
Welfare Fund v. Bayer, AG, No. 05-2852-cv (CON) companies from entering into anticompetitive
(2d Cir. 2009). The DOJ‘s position on reverse agreements intended to block consumer access to safe
payment settlements has evolved over the years. In and effective generics, and hastening availability of
2004, the DOJ advocated against a per se standard generic biologics while retaining the appropriate
because the patentee‘s right to exclude permitted it to incentives for research and development for the
restrict the sale of infringing products. See Brief for innovation of breakthrough products.‖).
71
the United States as Amicus Curiae, Andrx Pharm., See, e.g., 148 Cong. Rec. S7565 (July 30, 2002)
Inc. v. Kroger Co., No. 03-779 (2004). Two years (Sen. Hatch) (―As coauthor of the [Hatch-Waxman
later, the DOJ suggested that an appropriate standard Act], I can tell you that I find these type[s] of reverse
would analyze the objective likelihood of success in payment collusive arrangements appalling‖); 146
the underlying patent litigation. See Brief for the Cong. Rec. E1538–02 (Sept. 20, 2000) (Rep.
United States as Amicus Curiae, FTC v. Schering- Waxman) (―requir[ing] companies seeking to reach
Plough Corp., No. 05-273 (2006). In 2007, the DOJ secret, anticompetitive agreements to disclose them
made a case that the per se analysis imposed on a to the FTC … [would] ensure that existing antitrust
patentee‘s right to exclude, but a rule of reason and drug approval laws are enforced to the letter‖); S.
analysis should be applied. See Brief for the United 27 (Feb. 2011) (bill that would render reverse
States as Amicus Curiae, Joblove v. Barr Labs., Inc., payment settlements presumptively in violation of
No. 06-830 (2007). Just last year, in arguing for antitrust laws).

14
dangerous branch‖72 of the government new drug is essentially an information
has largely found reverse payment good—once the formula is known, it is
settlements to be valid. often comparably easy and inexpensive for
potential generic competitors to
When a party pays an opposing manufacture the drug—patent protection is
party in order to settle a patent of the highest import for brand drug
infringement lawsuit, typically it is the manufacturers.75 Pharmaceutical
accused infringer paying the patentee. companies often spend an additional $1
―Reverse payment‖ settlements, however, million to $25 million to enforce their
involve a patent owner paying the accused patents, with the typical Hatch-Waxman
infringer in order to settle the lawsuit. case requiring the drug brand
Reverse payment settlements, also known manufacturer to spend at least $4 million
as ―pay-for-delay‖ agreements, occur most through trial and appeal.76 Reverse
often in Hatch-Waxman litigation, where a payment settlements, it is argued, permit a
brand pharmaceutical company pays a brand drug manufacturer to avoid the costs
would-be generic competitor not to enter of litigation while maintaining its right to
the market.73 Proponents of reverse exclude infringing products.
payment settlements emphasize the
substantial costs involved with researching Critics of reverse payment
and developing new inventions— settlements, however, believe the
particularly in developing new drugs— agreements violate antitrust laws. A
combined with the large fees associated central purpose of the Hatch-Waxman
with patent litigation. Some studies
estimate it may cost a drug company
upwards of $800 million to bring a new
drug to market, and empirical evidence
exists to suggest drug profits are directly a time-consuming process that costs millions of
dollars. Thus, brand drug manufacturers rely heavily
proportional to the extent of the research on patent protection in order to recoup the costs of an
and development efforts.74 And, because a initial investment in the drug. See Richard C. Levin
et al., Appropriating the Returns from Industrial
Research and Development, 1987 BROOKINGS
72
THE FEDERALIST NO. 78 (Alexander Hamilton). PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY (SPECIAL ISSUE) 783,
73
See King Drug Co. v. Cephalon, Inc., 702 F. Supp. 795–96, 819 (illustrating that brand drug
2d 514, 518 (E.D. Pa. 2010) (―[Reverse payment] manufacturers value patents highly as appropriation
settlements are typically entered into as a result of means); see also Eli Lilly & Co. v. Teva Pharms.
patent litigation between a brand name drug USA, Inc., 609 F. Supp. 2d 786, 811 n. 23 (S.D. Ind.
manufacturer and generic drug manufacturers.‖). 2009) (providing examples of steep erosion of brand
74
Joseph A. DiMasi, Ronald W. Hansen & Henry G. sales upon generic entry).
75
Grabowski, The Price of Innovation: New Estimates See C. Scott Hemphill, Paying for Delay:
of Drug Development Costs, 22 J. HEALTH ECON. 151 Pharmaceutical Patent Settlement as a Regulatory
(2003); Carmello Giacatto et al., Drug Prices and Design Problem, 81 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1553 (2006)
Research and Development Investment Behavior in (noting that brand drug companies, compared to
the Pharmaceutical Industry, 48 J.L. & ECON 195 innovators in other industries, cannot as easily rely
(2005). Under the Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act, a upon a head start, complementary assets, and scale of
brand drug manufacturer must demonstrate that a production as means to preserve profits).
76
drug is safe and effective before the FDA will American Intellectual Property Law Association,
approve it for marketing. 21 U.S.C. § 355(d) (2009). Report of the Economic Survey (observing that costs
The brand drug manufacturer makes this showing often rise above $4 million when the patented
through a New Drug Application (―NDA‖), which is product is worth more than $25 million).

15
statute77 is ―to enable competitors to bring reverse payment settlements over the last
cheaper, generic … drugs to market as year.84
quickly as possible.‖78 According to
critics, reverse payment settlements thwart Backdrop of Reverse Payment
this statutory objective by stifling generic Settlement Litigation
competition, resulting in higher drug costs
for consumers.79 According to one The legal issue associated with
antitrust plaintiff, reverse payment reverse payment settlements is whether
settlements cost consumers and taxpayers they are unreasonable—and therefore
$3.5 billion annually.80 illegal—restraints on trade in violation of
the Sherman Act.85 Courts employ one of
Nonetheless, the Supreme Court two tests when considering whether a
recently denied certiorari in a case restraint on trade is unreasonable: (1) a
revolving around whether reverse payment per se analysis or (2) a ―rule-of-reason‖
settlements are valid under antitrust laws.81 analysis.86 Courts apply the per se
Contemporaneously, Senator Herb Kohl analysis when other courts previously have
(D-Wis.) has introduced legislation considered the same type of conduct at
intended to prohibit reverse payment issue and found the likely effects of the
settlements,82 notwithstanding the failure conduct to be significantly
87
of previous attempts to pass similar anticompetitive.
legislation.83 Thus, the status quo remains
and patent litigants likely will continue to A rule-of-reason analysis is used
use reverse payment settlements to resolve when a per se analysis is inappropriate.
certain patent litigations. This paper Under a rule-of-reason analysis, a court
explores recent developments regarding determines whether the restraint on trade
merely regulates and promotes
competition or whether it suppresses or
77
Drug Price Competition and Patent Term even destroys competition.88 A reverse
Restoration Act of 1984, Pub. L. No. 98-417, 98 Stat. payment situation complicates the antitrust
1585
(1984) (codified at 21 U.S.C. §§ 355, 360(cc) (2000),
35 U.S.C. §§ 156, 271, 282 (2000)), as amended 84
A more detailed analysis of the Hatch-Waxman
by the Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, framework and earlier cases involving reverse
and Modernization Act of 2003, Pub. L. No. 108- payment settlements can be found in the article by
173, 117 Stat. 2066 (2003) (―MMA‖). Robert G. Pluta titled “Promoting the Progress” or
78
Teva Pharms. USA, Inc. v. Novartis Pharms. Paying for Delay: Balancing Patent and Antitrust
Corp., 482 F.3d 1330, 1344 (Fed. Cir. 2007) (quoting Law in the Age of Health Care Reform, 11 Engage 86
149 Cong. Rec. S15885 (Nov. 25, 2003). (Mar. 2010). See also Robert G. Pluta and Jeremy S.
Snodgrass, "Reverse Payment" Patent Settlements:
79
See generally Bigelow & Willig, “Reverse Recent Cases and Legislation, The AIPLA Antitrust
Payments” in Settlements of Patent Litigation: News—May 2011, 9-15.
85
Schering-Plough, K-Dur, and the FTC, in THE 15 U.S.C. § 2; State Oil Co. v. Khan, 522 U.S. 3,
ANTITRUST REVOLUTION 248 (Kwoka, Jr. & White 10 (1997) (noting Supreme Court ―has long
eds., 2005). recognized that Congress intended to outlaw only
80
Brief of Petitioner at 5–6, La. Wholesale Drug Co. unreasonable restraints‖ on trade).
86
v. Bayer AG, No. 10-762. State Oil, 522 U.S. at 10.
81 87
La. Wholesale Drug Co. v. Bayer, No. 10-762. Id.
82 88
See S. 27. Fed. Trade Comm’n v. Ind. Fed’n of Dentists, 476
83
See, e.g., S. 369. U.S. 447 (1986).

16
analysis because courts must consider that settlements to be per se illegal restraints
patent law grants an innovator ―the right to on trade.94
exclude others from making, using,
offering for sale, or selling the invention Denial of Certiorari in Louisiana
throughout the United States or importing Wholesale Drug
the invention into the United States.‖89
To date, the FTC and antitrust
To date, courts have struggled with plaintiffs have been unable to convince the
the reverse payment issue, but generally Supreme Court to grant certiorari to
agree such payments are not per se illegal. review the validity of reverse payment
The D.C. Circuit holds that such settlements. The most recent setback for
agreements must be analyzed under opponents of reverse payment settlements
antitrust analysis to determine whether occurred in early 2011, when the Court
they are unreasonable restraints on trade.90 denied certiorari in Louisiana Wholesale
The other circuit courts to consider the Drug Co. v. Bayer AG.95 The petitioners
issue—the Second, Eleventh, and Federal in Louisiana Wholesale were the plaintiff-
Circuits—hold that the antitrust per se appellants from the Second Circuit
analysis and the rule of reason analysis are decision Arkansas Carpenters Health &
inappropriate because patents are Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG, 604 F.3d 98
exclusionary by their very nature.91 (2d Cir. 2010).
Instead, courts must consider whether
reverse payment settlement agreements In Arkansas Carpenters, the
exceed the exclusionary power of plaintiffs, direct and indirect purchasers of
patents.92 None of these courts have held ciprofloxacin hydrochloride, averred that
reverse payments to be invalid, concluding the reverse payment settlement agreement
that reverse settlement payments violate entered into by Bayer AG with generic
antitrust law only where there is evidence pharmaceutical company Barr
of fraud on the Patent & Trademark Office Laboratories, Inc. violated antitrust law.96
(―PTO‖) or the litigation is a sham.93 To Specifically, Bayer agreed to pay Barr
date, only one circuit court, the Sixth $49.1 million immediately and between
Circuit, has found reverse payment $12.5 and $17.125 million quarterly for
the duration of the relevant patent; in
return, Barr conceded the patent‘s validity
89
and agreed not to market a generic
90
35 U.S.C. § 154(1)(1) & (2). ciprofloxacin prior to the patent‘s
See, e.g., Andrx Pharms., Inc. v. Biovail Corp.
Int’l, 256 F.3d 799, 810 (D.C. Cir. 2001). expiration.97 The district court granted
91
See, e.g., In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride summary judgment for Bayer and Barr and
Antitrust Litig., 544 F.3d 1323, 1335–36 (Fed. Cir. the Second Circuit affirmed, finding the
2008); In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litig., 466 case indistinguishable from its
F.3d 187 (2d. Cir. 2006); Schering-Plough Corp. v.
Fed. Trade Comm’n, 402 F.3d 1056 (11th Cir. 2005).
92 94
Id. In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig., 332 F.3d 896
93
Id. Moreover, a court need not consider the (6th Cir. 2003).
95
validity of a patent when analyzing the validity of a __S. Ct.__, No. 10-762, 2011 WL 727622 (Mar. 7,
reverse payment settlement agreement unless there is 2011).
96
evidence of fraud before the PTO or sham litigation. Id. at 100–02.
97
Id. Id. at 102.

17
precedential decision in In re Tamoxifen, the ―technology involved with litigated
which ―rejected antitrust challenges to patents is almost without exception
reverse payments as a matter of law.‖98 extremely valuable.‖ Therefore, the
foundation contends that mistakes
The Court rejected the petition for involving the validity of litigated patents
certiorari on March 7, 2011.99 In fact, the can cause severe harm to the marketplace,
Court has consistently refused to hear and the public needs would-be competitors
reverse payment settlement cases, as the to challenge those patents instead of
Louisiana Wholesale petitioners noted.100 colluding with patent owners to reap the
Because the majority of circuit courts rewards of invalid patents.103
believe reverse payment settlements are
valid, and because the Supreme Court In a similar vein, the National
refuses to hear these cases, it seems Association of Chain Drug Stores, Inc.
unlikely that the judicial system will do contends that the appropriate analysis for
anything to disrupt the use of reverse reverse payment settlements must consider
payment settlement agreements. the possibility that the patent being
enforced is invalid.104 The association
By denying certiorari, the Court argues there is no absolute right to exclude
also rejected some unique arguments set afforded by the patent laws, as a patent is
forth in the amicus briefs. For example, simply the conclusion of a legal analysis
The Public Patent Foundation argues that conducted by the Patent and Trademark
the quality of U.S. patents is poor Office (―PTO‖).105 Moreover, the
compared to patents issued in Europe and presumption of validity is a procedural
Japan, and therefore consumers are device, not substantive law, and the public
harmed when patent owners are able to has an interest in judicial determination of
avoid invalidation of their weak patents by patent validity due to the monopolistic
paying would-be competitors to settle.101 nature of patents.106 For those reasons, the
According to the foundation, a study of association argues that in order to maintain
70,000 issued U.S. patents found that the proper balance between competition
foreign counterpart patents issued only and patent protection, the validity of the
72.5% of the time in Europe and only underlying patent must be analyzed when
44.5% of the time in Japan.102 considering the legality of reverse
Compounding this problem is the fact that payment settlements. Nonetheless, the
Supreme Court did not find the arguments
98 of the amici curiae important enough to
Id. at 103, 106, 110.
99
La. Wholesale Drug Co. v. Bayer, No. 10-762. warrant judicial review.
Justices Sotomayor and Kagan took no part in the
consideration or decision.
100
Brief of Petitioner at 33, La. Wholesale Drug Co.
v. Bayer AG, No. 10-762. See also, for example, the
103
Court‘s denial of certiorari in Joblove v. Barr Id. at 6.
104
Laboratories, Inc., No. 06-830 (June 25, 2007). See generally Brief of Amicus Curiae National
101
See generally Brief of the Public Patent Association of Chain Drug Stores, Inc. in Support of
Foundation as Amicus Curiae in Support of Petitioners, La. Wholesale Drug Co. v. Bayer AG,
Petitioners, La. Wholesale Drug Co. v. Bayer AG, No. 10-762.
105
No. 10-762. Id. at 4.
102 106
Id. at 8. Id. at 5–6.

18
Congress Continues To Fight Reverse (i) An ANDA filer
Payment Settlements—To No Avail receives anything
of value; and
Due to the reluctance of federal
courts to find fault with reverse payment (ii) The ANDA filer
settlements, members of Congress have agrees to limit or
taken up the cause against these forego research,
agreements—with little success. For development,
example, Senator Herb Kohl (D-Wis.), manufacturing,
along with Senators Sherrod Brown (D- marketing, or
Ohio), Susan Collins (R-Me.), Richard sales of the
Durbin (D-Ill.), Al Franken (D-Minn.), ANDA product
Chuck Grassley (R-Iowa), Amy Klobuchar for any period of
(D-Minn.), and Bernard Sanders (I-Vt.) time.110
introduced the Preserve Access to
Affordable Generics Act (―Preserve It has been suggested that the
Access Act‖) in February of this year.107 proscription against a generic company
The act marks the third straight Congress receiving ―anything of value‖ is so vague
in which Senator Kohl has submitted as to be meaningless.111 To perhaps
legislation intended to outlaw reverse address this criticism, the Preserve Access
payment settlements.108 Act clarifies that it does not ―prohibit a
resolution or settlement of a patent
The Preserve Access Act states in infringement claim in which the
the Congressional Findings section that consideration‖ received includes ―only one
reverse payment settlements ―have unduly or more‖ of the following:
delayed the marketing of low-cost generic
drugs contrary to free competition, the (1) The right to market
interests of consumers, and the principles the ANDA product in the United
of underlying antitrust law.‖109 In order to States prior to the expiration of—
combat such agreements, the act declares:
(A) Any patent
An agreement shall be that is the basis for the
presumed to have an patent infringement claim;
anticompetitive effect and or
be unlawful if:
(B) Any patent
right or other statutory
exclusivity that would
prevent the marketing of
107
S. 27. such drug.
108
Donald Zuhn, Sen. Kohl Introduces Bill to
110
Prohibit Reverse Payments, Patent Docs (Feb. 2, Id. at 4.
111
2011, 11:59 PM), http://www. See, e.g., Robert G. Pluta, “Promoting the
patentdocs.org/2011/02/sen-kohl-introduces-bill-to- Progress” or Paying for Delay: Balancing Patent
prohibit-reverse-payments.html. and Antitrust Law in the Age of Health Care Reform,
109
S. 27 at 3. 11 Engage 86, 88 (Mar. 2010).

19
(2) A payment Conclusion
for reasonable litigation expenses
not to exceed $7,500,000. Proponents of reverse payment
settlement agreements argue that the
(3) A covenant not to agreements are valid because they fall
sue on any claim that the ANDA within the right of the patent owner to
product infringes a United States exclude others from making and selling
patent.112 infringing products. Critics argue that the
right to exclude under the patent laws must
Thus, the act seeks to permit settlement of be balanced with the need to avoid
Hatch-Waxman lawsuits so long as the monopolistic restraints on trade. The
ANDA filer does not do one of the White House, the FTC, and Congress have
following: (1) agree to refrain from taken up the fight against the agreements,
entering the market until expiration of the but the federal courts have routinely found
asserted patent, (2) receive more than $7.5 them to be valid. And because the
million from the brand drug manufacturer, Supreme Court is reluctant to review the
or (3) stipulate to the validity and/or validity of reverse payment settlement
infringement of the asserted patent. agreements, the status quo will remain for
the foreseeable future.
The act is still vague, however,
because the act appears to prohibit any
settlement agreement that contains a
clause other than the three explicitly set
forth. Moreover, the act prevents certain EDITOR’S NOTES: PRIVACY
settlement agreements used by second- RIGHTS, ATHLETE IMAGES AND
filers that have no anti-competitive effects. TEXT MESSAGES
For example, it is not uncommon for a
second-filer to stipulate to the David G. Swenson
infringement and validity of a patent, and Baylor University School of Law
Waco, Texas
in return receive the right to launch a
david_swenson@baylor.edu
generic product prior to patent expiration
should another ANDA filer be successful
in challenging the patent. This type of A number of developments involving
agreement permits the second-filer to Antitrust Law have occurred since the time
avoid litigation expenses and also has no of the last newsletter. As mentioned above,
anticompetitive effect as the second-filer the issue of reverse payments is still very
has no market exclusivity right that would much alive. In fact, the FTC announced on
prevent other generic companies from May 3, 2011, that the number of reverse
launching their products. Based on this payment agreements entered into by
reason and the past failures of Senator pharmaceutical companies during 2010 had
Kohl‘s bills, it seems unlikely that increased by more than 60% to an all time
Congress will approve this act as currently high of 31. The staff reported that a total of
drafted. 22 brand name pharmaceuticals with sales
nearing $10 Billion were involved in these
112
S. 27 at 6–7 (emphasis added). arrangements. The staff report indicated a

20
particular concern that 26 of the 31 complaint to be filed. The complaint as
settlement agreements involved producers of amended was sufficient in the court‘s view
generic drugs that would have been the first to support a conclusion that CLC may have
party to market the generic version of the been agreeing to facilitate an effort by the
branded drug. The FTC clearly is NCAA to reduce competition in the
continuing its long expressed concern with collegiate licensing market.
both the desirability and legality of these
reverse payment agreements. Finally, the Supreme Court decided
to allow a 7th Circuit decision regarding
In another development, the FTC alleged price fixing to stand in Cellco
announced that it had reached a settlement Partnership v. Morris.115 The defendants
with Google as an outgrowth of last year‘s were four companies that together were
launch of the ―Buzz‖ social network. The responsible for 90% of the text messaging
settlement, In re Google, Inc,.113 was services sold in the United States. The 7th
unusual in that the consent decree calls for Circuit had concluded that plaintiff‘s
implementation by Google of a allegations were sufficient to meet the
comprehensive program to ensure user pleading requirements of Bell Atlantic Corp.
privacy rights are respected along with third v. Twombly.116 Petitioner‘s attempts to paint
party audits to ensure that privacy concerns the issue as inferring a conspiracy only
are satisfied for the next 20 years. because the defendants are members of the
same trade association who exist in a
Although most of the antitrust concentrated industry and adopt similar
interest in the sports world seems to be pricing practices was unsuccessful, so the
focused right now on the ongoing dispute case will proceed.
between the NFL and NFL Players
Association, that is not the only antitrust
case affecting the sports world. A class
action on behalf of former college student
athletes challenging the use of their names
and likenesses in video games has survived
a motion to dismiss, In re NCAA Student
Athlete Name and Likeness Litigation.114
Although the first complaint was dismissed,
the district court just held that the second
amended complaint states plausible claims
for relief under the antitrust laws. At least
that was the conclusion in terms of the
potential liability of the NCAA and the
Collegiate Licensing Company (CLC). The
video game producer Electronic Arts, Inc.
was successful on their claim to dismiss but
leave was granted for a further amended

113
FTC File Number 102 3136, 3/30/11
114 115
Number 4:09-CV-01967-CW, ND Cal. No. 10-1172, cert. denied, US 4/25/11
116
5211 550 U.S. 544 (2007).
21

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen