Sie sind auf Seite 1von 23

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev

World Development Vol. xx, No. x, pp. xxxxxx, 2004 2004 Published by Elsevier Ltd. Printed in Great Britain 0305-750X/$ - see front matter

doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2003.10.007

2 3

ROBERT HUNTER WADE * London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK

Summary. Over the past 20 years or so India, China, and the rest of East Asia, experienced fast economic growth and falls in the poverty rate, Latin America stagnated, the former Soviet Union, Central and Eastern Europe, and sub-Saharan Africa regressed. But what are the net trends? The neoliberal argument says that world poverty and income inequality fell over the past two decades for the rst time in more than a century and a half, thanks to the rising density of economic integration across national borders. The evidence therefore conrms that globalization in the context of the world economic regime in place since the end of Bretton Woods generates more mutual benet than conicting interests. This paper questions the empirical basis of the neoliberal argument. 2004 Published by Elsevier Ltd. Key words globalization, poverty, inequality, neoliberalism, political economy of statistics, World bank

The best evidence available shows . . . the current wave of globalization, which started around 1980, has actually promoted economic equality and reduced poverty (Dollar & Kraay, 2002; emphasis added).

[G]lobalization has dramatically increased inequality between and within nations (Jay Mazur, US union leader, 2000).

38

39 1. INTRODUCTION 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50
The neoliberal argument says that the distribution of income between all the worlds people has become more equal over the past two decades and the number of people living in extreme poverty has fallen, for the rst time in more than a century and a half. It says that these progressive trends are due in large part to the rising density of economic integration between countries, which has made for rising eciency of resource use worldwide as countries and regions specialize in line with their
1

UN

CO

RR

Evidence suggests the 1980s and 1990s were decades of declining global inequality and reductions in the proportion of the worlds population in extreme poverty (Martin Wolf, The Financial Times, 2002).

EC

Over the past 20 years the number of people living on less than $1 a day has fallen by 200 million, after rising steadily for 200 years (James Wolfensohn, president of the World Bank, World Bank, 2002b).

TE
*I

19

PR

OO
51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75

comparative advantage. Hence the combination of the dollar-Wall Street economic regime 1 in place since the breakdown of the Bretton Woods regime in the early 1970s, and the globalizing direction of change in the world economy since then, serves the great majority of the worlds people well. The core solution for lagging regions, Africa above all, is freer domestic and international trade and more open nancial markets, leading to deeper integration into the world economy. Evidence from the current long wave of globalization thus conrms neoliberal economic theorymore open economies are more prosperous, economies that liberalize more experience a faster rate of progress, and people who resist further economic liberalization must be acting out of vested or rent-seeking interests. The world economy is an open system in the sense that country mobility up the income/wealth hierarchy is unconstrained by the structure. The hierarchy is in the process of being attened, the NorthSouth, core-periphery, rich country-poor country divide is being eroded away as globalization proceeds. The

thank without implicating Sanjay Reddy, Michael Ward, Branko Milanovic, Ron Dore, David Ellerman, Martin Wolf, 2002a, Timothy Besley, and James Galbraith; and the Institute for Advanced Study, Berlin, and the Crisis States Program, DESTIN, LSE, for nancial support. Final revision accepted: 30 October 2003.

Is Globalization Reducing Poverty and Inequality?

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 2

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

125 The growth rate of world GDP, measured in 126 US dollars and at current exchange rates, fell 127 sharply from around 5.5% in 197080 to 2.3% 128 in 198090 to 1.1% in 19902000. 4 This is bad

UN

76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 111 112 113 114 115 116 117 118 119 120 121 122 123

same evidence also validates the rationale of the World Trade Organization (WTO), the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and other multilateral economic organizations as agents for creating a global level playing eld undistorted by state-imposed restrictions on markets. This line of argument is championed by the more powerful of the centers of thinking for the world that inuence international policy making, including the intergovernmental organizations such as the World Bank, the IMF and the WTO, also the US and UK Treasuries, and opinion-shaping media such as The Financial Times and The Economist. The standard Left assumption, in contrast, is that the rich and powerful countries and classes have little interest in greater equity. Consistent with this view, the anti-globalization (more accurately, anti-neoliberal) argument asserts that world poverty and inequality have been rising, not falling, due to forces unleashed by the same globalization (for example, union leader Jay Mazurs quote above). 2 The line of solution is some degree of tightening of public policy limits on the operation of market forces; though the anti-neoliberal camp embraces a much wider range of solutions than the liberal camp. The debate tends to be conducted by each side as if its case was overwhelming, and only an intellectually decient or dishonest person could see merit in others case. For example, Martin Wolf of The Financial Times claims that the anti-globalization argument is the big lie. 3 If translated into public policy it would cause more poverty and inequality while pretending to do the opposite. This paper questions the empirical basis of the neoliberal argument. In addition, it goes beyond the questions to suggest dierent conclusions about levels and trends, stated in terms not of certainties but stronger or weaker probabilities. Finally it explains why we should be concerned about probably-rising world inequality, and how we might think about the neglected subject of the political economy of statistics.

Table 1. GNP per capita for region as % of cores GNP per capitaa Region Sub-Saharan Africa Latin America West Asia and North Africa South Asia East Asia (w/o China and Japan) China South North America Western Europe Southern Europe Australia and NZ Japan North ( core) 1960 5 20 9 2 6 1980 4 1999 2

OO
1 8 1 5 124 111 52 95 79 100 1 4 100 104 60 75 134 100

Source: Arrighi, Silver, and Brewer (2003). a Based on World Bank data. GNP at current exchange rates.

TE

PR

F
18 9 12 7 2 13 3 5 101 98 60 73 145 100

124 2. THE REGIONAL COLLAGE

news, environmental considerations aside. But it still grew a little faster than world population over the past two decades; and the (populationweighted) GDP of developing countries as a group grew a little faster than that of the highincome countries. On the other hand, regional variation within the global South is large. Table 1 shows the trends of regional per capita GNP to the per capita GNP of the core regions (with incomes converted to US$ at current exchange rates as a measure of international purchasing power). During 196099 the per capita incomes of sub-Saharan Africa, Latin America, and West Asia and North Africa fell as a fraction of the cores; South Asias remained more or less constant; East Asias (minus China) rose sharply; Chinas also rose sharply but from a very low base. The most striking feature is not the trends but the size of the gaps, testimony to the failure of catchup. Even success-story East Asia has an average income only about 13% of the cores. 5 It is a safe bet that most development experts in 1960 would have predicted much higher percentages by 2000. The variation can also be shown in terms of the distribution of world income by regions and income percentiles. Figure 1 shows the regional distribution of people at each income percentile for two years, 1990 and 1999. Here incomes are expressed in purchasing power parity dollars

129 130 131 132 133 134 135 136 137 138 139 140 141 142 143 144 145 146 147 148 149 150 151 152 153 154 155 156 157 158 159

CO

RR

EC

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

160 161 162 163 164 165

UN

Figure 1. World income distribution, by region, at each percentile of global income distribution: (A) 1990 and (B) 1999 (population at any particular income 100) (Source: Dikhanov & Ward, 2003).

(PPP$), 6 in order to measure, notionally at least, domestic purchasing power. One sees the African collapse in the increased share of the African population in the bottom quintile; also the falling back of the Eastern and Central European populations from the second to the

CO

RR

EC

TE
third quintile; and the rising share of the East Asian population in the second quintile. Figure 2 shows, in the top half, the worlds population plotted against the log of PPP$ income, taking account of both between-country and within-country income distribution;

D
166 167 168 169 170 171

PR

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 4

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

172 173 174 175 176 177

UN

Figure 2. World income distribution, by region: top half, distribution of world population against income; bottom half, distribution of world income against income, 1999 (Source: Dikhanov & Ward, 2003).

CO

RR

EC

TE
and the breakdown by region. The bottom half shows the worlds income plotted against income level, hence the share of income accruing to people at dierent income levels and in dierent regions. Residents of South Asia and East Asia predominate at income levels below the median, and residents of the OECD countries predominate at the top. Finally, Figure 3 shows the movement in the bimodal shape of the overall PPP$ income-topopulation distribution during 197099. The 1999 distribution has shifted forward compared

D
178 179 180 181 182 183

PR

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

Figure 3. World income distribution, 1970, 1980, 1990, 1999 (Source: Dikhanov & Ward, 2003).

193 3. POVERTY 194 195 196 197 198 199 200 201 202 203 204 205 206 207 208 209 210 211 212

Figure 2 shows the two standard international poverty lines, $1 per day and $2 per day; and also the line corresponding to an income of 50% of the worlds median income. Notice that even the higher $2 per day absolute poverty line is below the conventional minimum relative poverty line of half of the median. Notice too how small a share of world income goes to those on less than $1 per day, and how small a share of the income of the richest earners would be needed to double the income of the poorest. Figures 13 are based on a data set on income inequality compiled by the United Nations World Institute for Development Economics Research (WIDER). 7 But the standard poverty numbersthe ones normally used in discussions about the state of the worldcome from the World Banks data set. This is the source of the claims that, in the

UN

CO

RR

EC

184 185 186 187 188 189 190 191 192

TE

PR
to the 1970 one, especially the lower of the two income humps, reecting the arrival of large numbers of South and East Asians into the middle deciles of the world income distribution. How does the collagepositive world per capita growth and wide divergence of economic performance between developing regionsnet out in terms of global trends in poverty and inequality? words of President James Wolfensohn, Over the past 20 years the number of people living on less than $1 a day has fallen by 200 million, after rising steadily for 200 years 8 and the proportion of people worldwide living in absolute poverty has dropped steadily in recent decades, from 29% in 1990 to a record low of 23% in 1998. 9 The opening sentence of the Banks World Development Indicators 2001 says, Of the worlds 6 billion people 1.2 billion live on less than $1 a day, the same number in 1987 and 1998. 10 No ifs or buts. I now show that the Banks gures contain a large margin of error, and the errors probably atter the result in one direction. 11 To get the world extreme poverty headcount the Bank rst denes an international poverty line for a given base year by using purchasing power parity conversion factors (PPPs) to convert the purchasing power of an average of the ocial national poverty lines of a set of low-income countries into the US dollar amount needed to have the same notional purchasing power in the United States in the same year. In its rst global poverty estimation this procedure yielded a conveniently understandable US$1 per day for the base year of 1985. 12 Then the Bank uses PPP conversion factors to estimate the amount of local currency, country by country, needed to have the same purchasing power in the same year as in

OO
213 214 215 216 217 218 219 220 221 222 223 224 225 226 227 228 229 230 231 232 233 234 235 236 237 238 239 240 241 242 243 244

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 6

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

(a) Large margin of error

261 262 263 264 265 266 267 268 269 270 271 272 273 274 275 276 277 278 279 280 281 282 283 284 285 286 287 288 289 290 291 292 293 294 295 296 297 298

There are several reasons to expect a large margin of error, regardless of direction. First, the poverty headcount is very sensitive to the precise level of the international poverty lines. This is because the shape of income distribution near the poverty line is such that, in most developing countries, a given percentage change in the line brings a similar or larger percentage change in the number of people below it. Recent research on China suggests that a 10% increase in the line brings a roughly 20% increase in the poverty headcount. Second, the poverty headcount is very sensitive to the reliability of household surveys of income and expenditure. The available surveys are of widely varying quality, and many do not follow a standard template. Some sources of error are well known, such as the exclusion of most of the benets that people receive from publicly provided goods and services. Others are less well known, such as the sensitivity of the poverty headcount to the survey design. For example, the length of the recall period makes a big dierence to the rate of reported expenditurethe shorter the recall period the higher the expenditure. A recent study in India suggests that a switch from the standard 30-day reporting period to a seven-day reporting period lifts 175 million people from poverty, a nearly 50% drop. This is using the Indian ocial poverty line. Using the higher $1/day international line the would be even greater. 13 The point here is not that household surveys are less reliable than other possible sources (for example, national income accounts); simply that they do contain large amounts of error. Third, China and India, the two most important countries for the overall trend, have

UN

CO

RR

EC

TE

PR

245 246 247 248 249 250 251 252 253 254 255 256 257 258 259

the US base case. This gives an international extreme poverty line equivalent to US$1 per day, expressed in domestic currency. By way of illustration, Rs. 10 may have the same purchasing power in India in 1985 as US$1 in the United States in the same year, in which case Indias international extreme poverty line is Rs. 10 per day. From household surveys the Bank then estimates the number of people in the country living on less than this gure. It sums the country totals to get the world total. It uses national consumer price indices to keep real purchasing power constant across time, and adjusts the international poverty line for each country upwards with ination.

PPP-adjusted income gures that contain an even bigger component of guess work than for most other signicant countries. The main sources of PPP income gures (the Penn World Tables and the International Comparison Project) are based on two large-scale international price benchmarking exercises for calculating purchasing power parity exchange rates, one in 1985 in 60 countries, the other in 1993 in 110 countries. The government of China declined to participate in both. The purchasing power parity exchange rate for China is based on guestimates from small, ad hoc price surveys in a few cities, adjusted by rules of thumb to take account of the huge price dierences between urban and rural areas and between eastern and western regions. The government of India declined to participate in the 1993 exercise. The price comparisons for India are extrapolations from 1985 qualied by later ad hoc price surveys. The lack of reliable price comparisons for China and Indiahence the lack of reliable evidence on the purchasing power of incomes across their distributionscompromises any statement about levels and trends in world poverty. 14 Fourth, the often-cited comparison between 1980 and 19981.4 billion in extreme poverty in 1980, 1.2 billion in 1998is not valid. The Bank introduced a new methodology in the late 1990s which makes the gures noncomparable. The Bank has recalculated the poverty numbers with the new method only back to 1987. 15 The change of method amounts to: (i) a change in the way the international poverty line was calculated from the ocial poverty lines of a sample of low- and middle-income countries (and a change in the sample countries), which resulted in, (ii) a change in the international poverty line from $PPP 1 per day to $PPP 1.08 per day, and (iii) a change in the procedure for aggregating, country by country, the relative price changes over 198593 for a standard bundle of goods and services. We do not know what the 1980 gure would be with the new method. We do know however that the new method caused a huge change in the poverty count even for the same country in the same year using the same survey data. 16 Table 2 shows the method-induced changes by regions for 1993. Angus Deaton, an expert on these statistics, comments that Changes of this size risk swamping real changes. . . it seems impossible to make statements about changes in world poverty when the ground underneath ones feet is changing in this way. 17

299 300 301 302 303 304 305 306 307 308 309 310 311 312 313 314 315 316 317 318 319 320 321 322 323 324 325 326 327 328 329 330 331 332 333 334 335 336 337 338 339 340 341 342 343 344 345 346 347 348 349 350 351 352 353 354

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY? Table 2. 1993 poverty rate, using old and new World Bank methodologya Old poverty rate (%) Subsaharan Africa Latin America Middle East/N Africa 39.1 23.5 4.1 New poverty rate (%) 49.7 15.3 1.9

Source: Deaton (2001). a The poverty rate is the proportion of the population living on less than $1 a day.

(b) Downward bias

356 357 358 359 360 361 362 363 364 365 366 367 368 369 370 371 372 373 374 375 376 377 378 379 380 381 382 383 384 385 386 387 388 389 390 391 392 393 394 395

Further sources of error bias the results downward, making the number of people in poverty seem lower than it really is; and the bias probably increases over time, making the trend look rosier than it is. There are at least three reasons. First, the Banks international poverty line underestimates the income or expenditure needed for an individual (or household) to avoid periods of food-clothing-shelter consumption too low to maintain health and wellbeing. (Moreover, it avoids altogether the problem that basic needs include unpriced public goods such as clean water and access to basic healthcare.) The Banks line refers to an average consumption bundle, not to a basket of goods and services that makes sense for measuring poverty (though $1 per day does have intuitive appeal to a Western audience being asked to support aid). Suppose it costs Rs. 30 to buy an equivalent bundle of food in India (dened in terms of calories and micronutrients) as can be bought in the United States with $1; and that it costs Rs. 3 to buy an equivalent bundle of services (haircuts, massages) as $1 in the United States, such services being relatively very cheap in developing countries. 18 Current methods of calculating purchasing power parity, based on an average consumption bundle of food, services and other things, may yield a PPP exchange rate of $PPP 1 Rs. 10, meaning that Rs. 10 in India buys the equivalent average consumption bundle as $1 in the United States. But this is misleading because the poor person, spending most income on food, can buy with Rs. 10 only one-third of the food purchasable with $1 in the United States. To take the international poverty line for India as Rs. 10 therefore biases the number of poor downward.

We have no way of knowing what proportion of food-clothing-shelter needs the Banks international poverty line captures. But we can be fairly sure that if the Bank used a basic needs poverty line rather than its present articial one the number of absolute poor would rise, because the national poverty lines equivalent to a global basic needs poverty line would probably rise (perhaps by 3040%). 19 A 3040% increase in a basic-needs-based international poverty line would increase the world total of people in extreme poverty by at least 3040%. Indeed a recent study for Latin America shows that national extreme poverty rates, using poverty lines based on caloric and demographic characteristics, may be more than twice as high as those based on the World Banks $1/ day line. For example, the World Bank estimates Brazils extreme poverty rate (using its international poverty line) at 5%, while the Economic Commission for Latin America, using a calories-and-demography poverty line, estimates the rate at 14%. 20 In short, we can be reasonably condent that switching from the Banks rather arbitrarily derived international extreme poverty line to one reecting the purchasing power necessary to achieve elementary human capabilities would substantially raise the number of people in extreme poverty. The second reason is that the Banks new international poverty line of $1.08/day probably increases the downward bias, leading the Bank to exaggerate the decline in the poverty headcount between the years covered by the old methodology and those covered by the new one. The new international poverty line of $PPP 1.08 lowers the equivalent national poverty lines in most countries compared to the earlier $PPP 1 line. It lowers them in 77% of the 94 countries for which data are available, containing 82% of their population. It lowers the old international poverty line for China by 14%, for India, by 9%, for the whole sample by an average of 13%. 21 As noted, even a small downward shift in the poverty line removes a large number of people out of poverty. Third, future updating of the international poverty line will continue articially to lower the true numbers, because average consumption patterns (on which the international poverty line is based) are shifting toward services whose prices relative to food and shelter are lower in poor than in rich countries, giving the false impression that the cost of the basic con-

396 397 398 399 400 401 402 403 404 405 406 407 408 409 410 411 412 413 414 415 416 417 418 419 420 421 422 423 424 425 426 427 428 429 430 431 432 433 434 435 436 437 438 439 440 441 442 443 444 445 446 447 448 449 450

UN

CO

RR

EC

TE

PR

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 8

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

451 452 453 454 455 456 457 458 459 460 461 462 463 464 465 466 467 468 469 470 471 472 473 474 475 476 477 478 479 480 481 482 483 484 485 486 487 488 489 490 491 492 493 494 495 496 497 498 499 500 501 502 503 504

sumption goods required by the poor is falling. 22 All these problems have to be resolved in one way or another in any estimate of world poverty, whoever makes it. But the fact that the World Bank is the near-monopoly provider introduces a further complication. The number of poor people is politically sensitive. The Banks many critics like to use the poverty numbers as one of many pointers to the conclusion that it has accomplished precious little, in the words of US Treasury Secretary ONeill; which then provides a rationale for tighter US control of the Bank, as in the statement by the head of the US Agency for International Development, Whether the US way of doing things drives some multilateral institutions, I think it should, because, frankly, a lot of the multilateral institutions dont have a good track record. 23 A comparison of two recent Bank publications suggests how the Banks statements about poverty are aected by its tactics and the ideological predispositions of those in the ideas-controlling positions. The World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty says that the number of people living on less than $1 a day increased by 20 million from 1.18 billion in 1987 to 1.20 billion in 1998. When it was being written in the late 1990s the key ideas-controlling positions in the Bank were held by Joe Stiglitz and Ravi Kanbur (respectively, chief economist and director of the World Development Report 2000/2001), not noted champions of neoliberal economics. 24 At that time the Bank was trying to mobilize support for making the Comprehensive Development Framework the new template for all its work, for which purpose lack of progress in development helped. Then came the majority report of the Meltzer Commission, for the US Congress, which said the Bank was failing at its central task of poverty reduction and therefore should be sharply cut backas shown by the fact that the number of people in absolute poverty remained constant at 1.2 billion during 198798. 25 Now the Bank needed to emphasize progress. The next major Bank publication, Globalization, Growth, and Poverty: Building an Inclusive World Economy, claimed that the number of people living in poverty decreased by 200 million in the 18 years over 198098. 26 By this time Stiglitz and Kanbur were gone and David Dollar, a prominent Bank economist,

was ascendant. He was chief author of Global- 505 ization, Growth and Poverty. 27 506

(c) Conclusions about poverty

UN

We can be fairly sure that the Banks poverty headcount has a large margin of error in all years, in the sense that it may be signicantly dierent from the headcount that would result from the use of PPP conversion factors based more closely on the real costs of living of the poor (dened in terms of income needed to buy enough calories, micronutrients and other necessities in order not to be poor). By the same token we should question the Banks condence that the trend is downward. We do not know for sure how the late 1990s revision of the method and the PPP numbers alter the poverty headcount in any one year and the trend. But it is likely that the Banks numbers substantially underestimate the true numbers of the worlds population living in extreme poverty, and make the trend look brighter. On the other hand, it is quite plausible that the proportion of the worlds population living in extreme poverty has fallen over the past 20 years or so. For all the problems with Chinese and Indian income gures we know enough about trends in other variablesincluding life expectancy, heights, and other nonincome measuresto be condent that their poverty headcounts have indeed dropped dramatically over the past 20 years. If it is the case (as some experts claim) that household surveys are more likely to miss the rich than the poor, their results may overstate the proportion of the population in poverty. The magnitude of world population increase over the past 20 years is so large that the Banks poverty numbers would have to be huge underestimates for the world poverty rate not to have fallen. Any more precise statement about the absolute number of the worlds people living in extreme poverty and the change over time currently rests on quicksand.

508 509 510 511 512 513 514 515 516 517 518 519 520 521 522 523 524 525 526 527 528 529 530 531 532 533 534 535 536 537 538 539 540 541 542 543 544 545 546 547

CO

RR

EC

TE

PR

4. INEQUALITY World poverty headcount could move in one direction while the world in equality moved in the other. The neoliberal argument says that they have both dropped. 28 But in the past several years world income distribution has

OO

549 550 551 552 553

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

588 589 590 591 592 593 594 595 596 597 598 599 600 601 602 603 604 605 606

Proposition 1. World income distribution has become rapidly more unequal, when incomes are measured at market exchange rates and expressed in US dollars. No one disputes this. The dispute is about what the gures mean. Most economists say that exchange-rate-based income measures are irrelevant, and hence would dismiss the data in Table 1. GDP incomes should always be adjusted by PPP exchange rates to take account of dierences in purchasing power, they say. 30 This makes a big dierence to the size of the gap between rich and poor. As noted, the PPP adjustment is made by computing the relative prices for an average bundle of goods and services in dierent countries. The PPP adjustment substantially raises the relative income of poor countries. Indias PPP GDP, for example, is about four times its market exchange rate

UN

CO

RR

554 555 556 557 558 559 560 561 562 563 564 565 566 567 568 569 570 571 572 573 574 575 576 577 578 579 580 581 582 583 584 585 586 587

become a hot topic of debate in international economics and in sociology (much hotter than trends in world poverty). Disagreements about the overall inequality trend should not be surprising given the variation in regional economic performancedierent ways of measuring emphasize dierent parts of the collage. The only valid short answer to the question, What is the trend of world income distribution? is, It depends on which combination out of many plausible combinations of measures and countries we choose. 29 Whereas we could get better data on the poor to the extent that the poverty headcount would command general agreement, there is no single best measure of world income inequality. The choices include: alternative measures of income (GDP per capita converted to US dollars using market exchange rates or GDP per capita adjusted for dierences in purchasing power across countries); alternative weightings of countries (each country weighted as one unit or by population); alternative measures of distribution (including the Gini or some other average coecient, or ratios of the income of the richer deciles of world population to that of poorer deciles, or average income of a set of developing countries to that of a set of developed countries); alternatives sources of data on incomes (national income accounts or household surveys); alternative samples of countries and time periods. We can be reasonably condent of the following six propositions.

GDP. The PPP adjustment thus makes world income distribution look much more equal than the distribution of market-exchange-rate incomes. Market-exchange-rate-based income comparisons do suer from all the ways in which ocial exchange rates do not reect the real economy: from distortions in the ocial rates, exclusion of goods and services that are not traded, and sudden changes in the ocial exchange rate driven more by capital than by trade movements. Nevertheless, we should reject the argument that incomes converted via PPP exchange rates should always be used in preference to incomes converted at market exchange rates. The practical reasons concern the weaknesses of the PPP numbers. Plausibly constructed PPP numbers for China dier by a factor of two. Estimates for countries of the former Soviet Union before the 1990s also dier by a wide margin; and Indias dier too. So if incomes converted via market exchange rates do not give an accurate measure of relative purchasing power, neither do the PPP numbers for countries that carry heavy weight in world trends. Condence in world PPP income distribution should be correspondingly limited. Practical problems aside, PPP-adjustment is in principle preferable when one is interested in domestic purchasing power or, more generally, material well-being. We may however, be interested in income not only as a measure of material well-being. We may also be interested in income as a proxy for the purchasing power of residents of dierent countries over goods and services produced in other countriesfor example, the purchasing power of residents of developing countries over advanced country products compared to the purchasing power of residents of advanced countries over developing country products. If we are interested in any of the questions about the economic and geopolitical impact of one country (or region) on the rest of the worldincluding the cost to developing countries of repaying their debts, importing capital goods, and participating in international organizationswe should use market exchange rates. The reason why many poor small countries are hardly represented in negotiations that concern them directly is that they cannot aord the cost of hotels, oces, and salaries in places like Washington DC and Geneva, which must be paid not in PPP dollars but in hard currency bought with their own currency at market

607 608 609 610 611 612 613 614 615 616 617 618 619 620 621 622 623 624 625 626 627 628 629 630 631 632 633 634 635 636 637 638 639 640 641 642 643 644 645 646 647 648 649 650 651 652 653 654 655 656 657 658 659 660 661 662

EC

TE

PR

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 10

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

696 Proposition 2. World PPP-income polarization 697 has increased, with polarization measured as 698 richest to poorest decile. 699 700 701 702 703 704 705 706 707 708 709 710 711 712 713 714 715
The broad result is hardly surprising: the top 10% is comprised almost entirely of people living in the core countries of North America, western Europe, and Japan, where incomes have grown over the past 2030 years, while a large chunk of the bottom 10% is comprised of African countries where incomes have stagnated or fallen. According to one study, the trend of richest to poorest decile goes like this: 197092, 1980109, 1990104, 1999 104. 31 Another study nds a jump in the ratio of 25% over 198893. 32 The change is made up of the top decile pulling sharply up from the median and the bottom decile falling away from the median. The polarizing trend would be much sharper with the top 1% rather than the top decile.

RR

EC

663 664 665 666 667 668 669 670 671 672 673 674 675 676 677 678 679 680 681 682 683 684 685 686 687 688 689 690 691 692 693 694 695

exchange rates. In addition, the reason they cannot aord to pay the foreign exchange costs of living up to many of their international commitmentshiring foreign experts to help them exercise control over their banking sectors so that they can implement their part of the anti-money-laundering regime, for example likewise reects their low market-exchange-rate incomes. On the other hand, international lenders have not been lining up to accept repayment of developing country debts in PPP dollars, which would reduce their debt repayments by 75% or more in many cases. These same foreign impacts feed back to domestic state capacity. For example, we should use market exchange rates to pick up the key point that the long-run deterioration in the exchange rates of most developing countries is putting those countries under increasing internal stress. When a rising amount of real domestic resources has to go into acquiring a given quantity of importssay, of capital goodsother domestic uses of those resources are squeezed, including measures to reduce poverty, to nance civil services and schools and the like. This backwash eect is occluded in PPP calculations. Hence we do need to pay attention to what is happening to market-exchange-rate world income distribution. It is widening fast. The next four propositions refer to inequality of PPP-adjusted incomes, as an approximation to domestic purchasing power.

Proposition 3. Between-country world PPPincome inequality has increased since at least 1980, using per capita GDPs, equal country weights (China Uganda), and a coefficient like the Gini for the whole distribution.

716 717 718 719 720 721 722 723 724 725 726 727 728 729 730 731 732 733 734 735 736 737 738 739 740 741 742 743 744 745 746 747 748 749 750 751 752 753 754 755 756 757 758 759 760 761 762 763 764 765 766 767

Of course, we would not weight countries equally if we were interested simply in relative well-being. But we would weight them equallytreat each country as a unit of observation, analogous to a laboratory test observationif we were interested in growth theory and the growth impacts of public policies, resource endowments, and the like. We might, for example, arrange (unweighted) countries by the openness of their trade regime and see whether more open countries have better economic performance. The same inequality-widening trend is obtained using a somewhat dierent measure of inequalitythe dispersion of per capita GDPs across the worlds (equally weighted) countries. Dispersion increased over the long period, 195098, and especially fast over the 1990s. Moreover, the dispersion of per capita GDP growth rates has also risen over time, suggesting wider variation in performance among countries at each income level. A study by the Economic Commission for Latin America using these dispersion measures concludes that there is no doubt as to the existence of a denite trend toward distributive inequality worldwide, both across and within countries. 33 Proposition 4. Between-country world PPPincome inequality has been constant or falling since around 1980, with countries weighted by population.

CO

UN

TE

This is the result that the neoliberal argument celebrates. There are just two problems. First, exclude China and even this measure shows a widening since 1980; also exclude India and the widening is pronounced. Therefore, falling income inequality is not a general feature of the world economy, even using the most favorable combination of measures. 34 Second, this measurethe average income of each country weighted by populationis interesting only as an approximation to what we are really interested in, which is income distribution among all the worlds people or households regardless of which country they reside in. We would not be interested in mea-

PR

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

11

UN

Table 3. World income distribution by households (1988 and 1993) 1988 0.63 7.28 0.31 1993 0.67 8.98 0.28 % Change +6 +23 )10

CO

777 778 779 780 781 782 783 784 785 786 787 788 789 790 791 792 793 794 795 796 797 798 799 800 801 802 803 804 805 806 807 808 809 810

Studies which attempt to measure income distribution among all the worlds people show widely varying results, depending on things like the precise measure of inequality, the sample of countries, the time period, and the sources of income data. But several studies, which use a variety of data sources and methods, point to widening inequality. Steve Dowrick and Muhammad Akmal make an approximation to the distribution of income among all the worlds people by combining (population-weighted) between-country inequality in PPP-adjusted average incomes with within-country inequality. They nd that world inequality widened over 198093 using all of four common measures of inequality over the whole distribution. 35 Branko Milanovic uses the most comprehensive set of data drawn only from household income and expenditure surveys (it does not mix data from these surveys with data from national income accounts). He nds a sharp rise in world inequality over as short a time as 198893, using both the Gini coecient and ratio (or polarization) measures. 36 Some of his ndings are shown in Table 3. Preliminary analysis of 1998 data suggests a slight drop in inequality in 199398, leaving a large rise over 198898. We have to be cautious about Milanovics results partly because household surveys have the kind of weaknesses described above (though these weaknesses do not make them worse than the alternative, national income

OO

772 773 774 775 776

Proposition 5. Several serious studies find that world PPP-income inequality has increased over a period within the past two to three decades, taking account of both between- and withincountry distributions.

768 769 770 771

suring income inequality within the United States by calculating the average income for each state weighted by population if we had data for all US households.

accounts, which have their own problems), and partly because even a 10-year interval, let alone a ve-year interval, is very short, suggesting that some of the increase may be noise. Yuri Dikhanov and Michael Ward combine micro-level household survey data with national income accounts, using the WIDER data set, a dierent statistical technique to the earlier authors, and a longer time period, 1970 99. They nd that the Gini coecient increased over this period from 0.668 to 0.683. 37 Proposition 6. Pay inequality within countries was stable or declining from the early 1960s to 19801982, then sharply and continuously increased to the present. 198082 is a turning point toward greater inequality in manufacturing pay worldwide. 38

811 812 813 814 815 816 817 818 819 820 821 822 823 824 825 826 827 828 829 830 831 832 833 834 835 836 837 838 839 840 841 842 843 844 845 846 847 848 849 850 851 852 853 854 855 856

Pay data have the great advantage over income data that pay data are a much less ambiguous variable, have been collected systematically by the United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO) since the early 1960s, and give many more observation points for each country than any data set on incomes. (The standard data set for world poverty and inequality, the World Banks Deininger-Squire set, has few observation points for most of Africa, West Asia and Latin America during the 1980s and 1990s, requiring the analyst to guess the intervening years.) The disadvantage of pay data, of course, is that they treat only a small part of the economy of many developing countries, and provide only a proxy for incomes and expenditure. They are of limited use if our interest is only in relative wellbeing (though of more use if our interest is in the eects of trade, manufacturing innovation, etc.). But not as limited as may seem at rst sight, because what is happening to pay rates in formal-sector manufacturing reects larger trends, including income dierences between countries and income dierences within countries (since the pay of unskilled, entry-port jobs in manufacturing is closely related to the opportunity cost of time in the informal or agricultural sectors). 39

RR

EC

TE

Gini Richest decile/median Poorest decile/median Source: Milanovic (2002a).

PR

(a) China and India With 38% of the worlds population, China and India shape world trends in poverty and inequality. They have grown very fast over the past decade (India) or two (China), if the g-

858 859 860 861

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 12

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

Table 4. Chinas GNPPC and growth rate (199799)a

UN

CO

862 863 864 865 866 867 868 869 870 871 872 873 874 875 876 877 878 879 880 881 882 883 884 885 886 887 888 889 890 891 892 893 894 895 896 897 898 899 900 901

ures are taken at face value. Chinas average purchasing power parity income rose from 0.3 of the world average in 1990 to 0.45 in 1998, or 15 percentage points in only eight years. We can be sure that world poverty and inequality are less than they would be had Chinas and India grown more slowly. About any stronger conclusion we have to be cautious. First, recall that Chinas and Indias purchasing power parity numbers are even more questionable than those for the average developing country, because of their nonparticipation in the international price comparisons on which the PPP calculations rest. Second, Chinas growth in the 1990s is probably overstated. Many analysts have recently been revising Chinas growth statistics downward. Whereas government gures show annual real GDP growth of 78% in 1998 and 1999 one authority on Chinese statistics estimates that the economy may not have grown at all. 40 Even the Chinese government says that the World Bank has been overstating Chinas average income, and the Bank has recently revised its numbers down. Table 4 shows the Banks estimates for Chinas average GNP in US$ for 199799 and the corresponding growth rates. The level of average (exchange rate-converted) income fell sharply during 199798, while the corresponding growth rate over 1997 98 was +6.4%. The Bank reduced Chinas per capita income partly because it believed that Chinas fast growth campaign begun in 1998 had unleashed a torrent of statistical falsication. In addition, the Chinese government armtwisted the World Bank (especially after the allegedly accidental US bombing of the Chinese embassy in Belgrade in May 1999) to lower average income below the threshold of eligibility for concessional IDA lending from the

RR

EC

Banknot for cheap IDA loans but for the privilege extended to companies of IDA-eligible countries to add a 7.5% uplift on bids for World Bank projects. 41 Over the 1990s Chinas annual growth rate is more likely to have been around 68% than the 810% of the ocial statistics. This one change lowers the probability that world interpersonal distribution has become more equal. 42 We have to be cautious about going from Chinas fast growth to falls in world income inequality not only because Chinas growth rates and income level may be overstated but also because the rise in inequality within both China and India partly osets the reduction in world income inequality that comes from their relatively fast growth of average income though careful calculations of the relative strength of the two contrary eects have yet to be made. 43 Chinas surging inequality is now greater than before the Communists won the civil war in 1949, and inequality between regions is probably higher than in any other sizable country. The ratio of the average income of the richest to poorest province (Guangdong to Guizhou) rose from around 3.2 in 1991 (current yuan) to 4.8 in 1993, and remained at 4.8 in 19982001. 44 The corresponding gure for India in the late 1990s was 4.2, the United States, 1.9.

902 903 904 905 906 907 908 909 910 911 912 913 914 915 916 917 918 919 920 921 922 923 924 925 926 927 928 929 930 931

TE
1999 3,550 780 6.1

(b) The United States and other Anglo political economies Canada excepted, all the countries of English settlement, led by the United States, have experienced big increases in income inequality over the past 2030 years. In the United States, the top 1% of families enjoyed a growth of after-tax income of almost 160% over 197997, while families in the middle of the distribution had a 10% increase. 45 Within the top 1% most of the gains have been concentrated in the top 0.1%. This is not a matter of reward to education. Inequality has expanded hugely among the college-educated. Whatever the causes, the fact is that the United States is now back to the same level of inequality of income as in the decades before 1929, the era of the robber barons and the Great Gatsby. Income distribution in the United Kingdom grew more unequal more quickly than even in the United States during the 1980s, and is now the most unequal of the big European countries.

PR

OO

1997 3,070 860 7.4

1998 3,050 750 6.4

GNPPC/PPP (US$) GNPPC (US$) Annual growth rate of GNPPC (%)

Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators (19992001). a Note that each volume gives gures for only one year, so that the discrepancy can be seen only by compiling ones own table.

934 935 936 937 938 939 940 941 942 943 944 945 946 947 948 949 950 951 952 953

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

13

(c) Country mobility

RR

955 956 957 958 959 960 961 962 963 964 965 966 967 968 969 970 971 972 973 974 975 976 977 978 979 980 981 982 983 984 985 986 987 988

How much do countries move in the income hierarchy? One study uses real GNP per capita data (GNP deated in local currency to a common base year, then converted to dollars at the exchange rate for that base year), and nds a robustly trimodal distribution of world population against the log of GNP per capita during 196099. 46 The three income zones might be taken as empirical correlates of the conceptual zones of core, semi-periphery, and periphery. For the 100 countries in the sample, 72 remained in the same income zone over the whole period sampled at ve yearly intervals (e.g., Australia remained in zone 1, Brazil in zone 2, Bolivia in zone 3). The remaining 28 countries moved at least once from one zone to another (e.g., Argentina from 1 to 2). No country moved more than one zone. (South Korea, Hong Kong and Singapore in 1960 were already in the middle, not low zone.) There are about as many cases of upward movement as downwards. Compared to the rate of potential mobility (each country moving one zone at each measurement date) the rate of actual mobility was 3%. Of the 28 out of 100 countries that moved at least once between zones, about half had stable moves in the sense that their position in 1990 and 1999 was one zone above or below their position in 1960 and 1965. Greece moved stably up from 2 to 1, Argentina moved stably down from 1 to 2, El Salvador moved stably down from 2 to 3. As many countries moved stably up as down. (d) The absolute income gap

(e) Conclusions about inequality

OO

Wards gures show that, overall, the absolute gap between the average income of the top decile of world population and the bottom decile increased from $PPP 18,690 in 1970 to $PPP 28,902 in 1999. 47 We can be sure thata seventh propositionabsolute gaps between people and countries are widening fast and will continue to widen for at least two generations.

1007 1008 1009 1010 1011 1012 1013 1014

EC

The evidence does support the liberal argument when inequality is measured with population-weighted countries per capita PPPadjusted incomes, plus a measure of average inequality, taking Chinas income statistics at face value. On the other hand, polarization has clearly increased. Moreover, several studies that measure inequality over the whole distribution and use either cross-sectional household survey data or measures of combined inequality between countries and within countries show widening inequality since around 1980. The conclusion is that world inequality measured in plausible ways is probably rising, despite Chinas and Indias fast growth. The conclusion is reinforced by evidence of a quite dierent kind. Dispersion in pay rates within manufacturing has become steadily wider since the early 1980s, having remained roughly constant from 1960 to the early 1980s. Meanwhile, absolute income gaps are widening fast.

1016 1017 1018 1019 1020 1021 1022 1023 1024 1025 1026 1027 1028 1029 1030 1031 1032 1033 1034 1035 1036

TE

PR

5. GLOBALIZATION I have raised doubts about the liberal arguments claim that (a) the number of people living in extreme poverty worldwide is currently about 1.2 billion, (b) it has fallen substantially since 1980, by about 200 million, and (c) that world income inequality has fallen over the same period, having risen for many decades before then. Let us consider the other end of the argumentthat the allegedly positive trends in poverty and inequality have been driven by rising integration of poorer countries into the world economy, as seen in rising trade/ GDP, foreign direct investment/GDP, and the like. Clearly the proposition is not well supported at the world level if we agree that globalization has been rising while poverty and income inequality have not been falling. Indeed, it is striking that the pronounced convergence of economic policy toward openness worldwide

990 991 992 993 994 995 996 997 998 999 1000 1001 1002 1003 1004 1005 1006

Our measures of inequality refer to relative incomes, not absolute incomes. Inequality between developing countries as a group and developed countries as a group remains constant if the ratio of developing country income to developed country income remains at 5%. But this, of course, implies a big rise in the absolute size of the gap. The absolute gap between a country with average income of $1,000 growing at 6% and a country with average income $30,000 growing at 1% continues to widen until after the 40th year! China and India are reducing the absolute gap with the faltering middle-income states such as Mexico, Brazil, Russia and Argentina, but not with the countries of North America, Western Europe and Japan. Dikhanov and

1038 1039 1040 1041 1042 1043 1044 1045 1046 1047 1048 1049 1050 1051 1052 1053 1054 1055 1056 1057

UN

CO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 14

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

UN

CO

1058 1059 1060 1061 1062 1063 1064 1065 1066 1067 1068 1069 1070 1071 1072 1073 1074 1075 1076 1077 1078 1079 1080 1081 1082 1083 1084 1085 1086 1087 1088 1089 1090 1091 1092 1093 1094 1095 1096 1097 1098

over the past 20 years has gone with divergence of economic performance. But it might still be possible to argue that globalization explains dierences between countries: that more open economies or ones that open faster have a better record than less open ones or ones than open more slowly. This is what World Bank studies claim. The best known, Globalization, Growth and Poverty, 48 distinguishes newly globalizing countries, also called more globalized countries, from nonglobalizing countries or less globalized countries. It measures globalizing by changes in the ratio of trade to GDP over 197797. Ranking developing countries by the amount of change, it calls the top third the more globalized countries, the bottom twothirds, the less globalized countries. It nds that the former have had faster economic growth, no increase in inequality, and faster reduction of poverty than the latter. Thus globalization clearly can be a force for poverty reduction, it concludes. The conclusion does not follow. First, using change in the trade/GDP ratio as the measure of globalization skews the results. 49 The globalizers then include China and India, as well as countries such as Nepal, C^te d Ivoire, o Rwanda, Haiti, and Argentina. It is quite possible that more globalized countries are less open than many less globalized countries, both in terms of trade/GDP and in terms of the magnitude of taris and nontari barriers. A country with high trade/GDP and very free trade policy would still be categorized as less globalized if its increase in trade/GDP over 197797 put it in the bottom two-thirds of the sample. Many of the globalizing countries initially had very low trade/GDP in 1977 and still had relatively low trade/GDP at the end of the period in 1997 (reecting more than just the

fact that larger economies tend to have lower ratios of trade/GDP). To call relatively closed economies more globalized or globalizers and to call countries with much higher ratios of trade/GDP and much freer trade regimes less globalized or even nonglobalizers is an audacious use of language. Excluding countries with high but not rising levels of trade to GDP from the category of more globalized eliminates many poor countries dependent on a few natural resource commodity exports, which have had poor economic performance. The structure of their economy and the low skill endowment of the population make them dependent on trade. If they were included as globalized their poor economic performance would question the proposition that the more globalized countries do better. On the other hand, including China and India as globalizersdespite relatively low trade/GDP and relatively protective trade regimesguarantees that the globalizers, weighted by population, show better performance than the nonglobalizers. Table 5 provides an illustration. The second problem is that the argument fudges almost to vanishing point the distinction between trade quantities and trade policy, and implies, wrongly, that rising trade quantities and the developmental benets thereofare the consequence of trade liberalization. Third, the argument assumes that fast trade growth is the major cause of good economic performance. It does not examine the reverse causation, from fast economic growth to fast trade growth. Nor does it consider that other variables correlated with trade growth may be important causes of economic performance: quality of government, for example. One reexamination of the Banks study nds that the globalizer countries do indeed have higher

1099 1100 1101 1102 1103 1104 1105 1106 1107 1108 1109 1110 1111 1112 1113 1114 1115 1116 1117 1118 1119 1120 1121 1122 1123 1124 1125 1126 1127 1128 1129 1130 1131 1132 1133 1134 1135 1136 1137 1138 1139

Table 5. Trade-dependent nonglobalizers and less-trade-dependent globalizers Exports/GDP 1990 36 26 7 6 1999 42 25 11 14 % Change 17 )0.04 57 133 )1.2 0.5 6.9 3.3 GNPRG 198899 (%)

Nonglobalizers Honduras Kenya

Globalizers India Bdesh

Source: World Bank, World Development Report 2000/01, Tables 1 and 13.

RR

EC

TE

PR

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

15

1140 1141 1142 1143 1144 1145 1146 1147 1148 1149 1150 1151 1152 1153 1154 1155 1156 1157 1158 1159 1160 1161 1162 1163 1164 1165 1166 1167 1168 1169 1170 1171 1172 1173 1174 1175 1176 1177 1178 1179 1180 1181 1182 1183 1184 1185 1186 1187 1188 1189 1190 1191 1192 1193 1194 1195

quality of government indicators than the nonglobalizer countries, on average. 50 Finally, trade does not capture important kinds of openness, including people ows and ideas ows. Imagine an economy with no foreign trade but high levels of inward and outward migration and a well-developed diaspora network. In a real sense this would be an open or globalized economy, though not classied as such. Certainly many countriesincluding China and Indiahave beneted from their more intensive engagement in international trade and investment over the past one or two decades. But this is not to say that their improved performance is largely due to their more intensive external integration. They began to open their own markets after building up industrial capacity and fast growth behind high barriers. 51 In addition, throughout their period of so-called openness they have maintained protection and other market restrictions that would earn them a bad report card from the World Bank and IMF were they not growing fast. China began its fast growth with a high degree of equality of assets and income, brought about in distinctly nonglobalized conditions and unlikely to have been achieved in an open economy and democratic polity. 52 Their experienceand that of Japan, South Korea and Taiwan earliershows that countries do not have to adopt liberal trade policies in order to reap large benets from trade. 53 They all experienced relatively fast growth behind protective barriers; a signicant part of their growth came from replacing imports of consumption goods with domestic production; and more and more of their rapidly growing imports consisted of capital goods and intermediate goods. As they became richer they tended to liberalize their tradeproviding the basis for the misunderstanding that trade liberalization drove their growth. For all the Bank studys qualications (such as We label the top third more globalized without in any sense implying that they adopted pro-trade policies. The rise in trade may have been due to other policies or even to pure chance), it concludes that trade liberalization has been the driving force of the increase in developing countries trade. The result of this trade liberalization in the developing world has been a large increase in both imports and exports, it says. On this shaky basis the Bank rests its case that developing countries must push hard toward nearfree trade as a core ingredient of their devel-

TE

opment strategy, the better to enhance competition in ecient, rent-free markets. Even when the Bank or other development agencies articulate the softer principletrade liberalization is the necessary direction of change but countries may do it at dierent speedsall the attention remains focused on the liberalization part, none on how to make protective regimes more eective. In short, the Banks argument about the benign eects of globalization on growth, poverty and income distribution does not survive scrutiny at either end. And a recent crosscountry study of the relationship between openness and income distribution strikes another blow. It nds that among the subset of countries with low and middle levels of average income (below $5,000 per capita in PPP terms, that of Chile and the Czech Republic), higher levels of trade openness are associated with more inequality, while among higher-income countries more openness goes with less inequality. 54

1196 1197 1198 1199 1200 1201 1202 1203 1204 1205 1206 1207 1208 1209 1210 1211 1212 1213 1214 1215 1216 1217 1218

PR

6. CONCLUSION

OO

It is plausible, and important, that the proportion of the worlds population living in extreme poverty has probably fallen over the past two decades or so, having been rising for decades before then. Beyond this we cannot be condent, because the World Banks poverty numbers are subject to a large margin of error, are probably biased downward, and probably make the trend look rosier than it really is. On income distribution, several studies suggest that world income inequality has been rising during the past two to three decades, and a study of manufacturing pay dispersions buttresses the same conclusion from another angle. The trend is sharpest when incomes are measured at market-exchange-rate incomes. This is less relevant to relative well-being than PPP-adjusted incomes, in principle; but it is highly relevant to state capacity, interstate power, and the dynamics of capitalism. One combination of inequality measures does yield the conclusion that income inequality has been fallingPPPincome per capita weighted by population, measured by an averaging coecient such as the Gini. But take out China and even this measure shows widening inequality. Falling inequality is thus not a generalized feature of the world economy even by the most favorable measure. Finally, whatever we conclude about

1220 1221 1222 1223 1224 1225 1226 1227 1228 1229 1230 1231 1232 1233 1234 1235 1236 1237 1238 1239 1240 1241 1242 1243 1244 1245 1246 1247 1248

UN

CO

RR

EC

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 16

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

1300 The neoliberal argument says that inequality 1301 provides incentives for eort and risk-taking, 1302 and thereby raises eciency. As Margaret

UN

1249 1250 1251 1252 1253 1254 1255 1256 1257 1258 1259 1260 1261 1262 1263 1264 1265 1266 1267 1268 1269 1270 1271 1272 1273 1274 1275 1276 1277 1278 1279 1280 1281 1282 1283 1284 1285 1286 1287 1288 1289 1290 1291 1292 1293 1294 1295 1296 1297 1298

income inequality, absolute income gaps are widening and will continue to do so for decades. If the number of people in extreme poverty is not falling and if global inequality is widening, we cannot conclude that globalization in the context of the dollar-Wall Street regime is moving the world in the right direction, with Africas poverty as a special case in need of international attention. The balance of probability is thatlike global warmingthe world is moving in the wrong direction. The failure of the predicted eects aside, the studies that claim globalization as the driver are weakened by (a) the use of changes in the trade/ GDP ratio or FDI/GDP ratio as the index of globalization or openness, irrespective of level (though using the level on its own is also problematic, the level of trade/GDP being determined mainly by country size); (b) the assumption that trade liberalization drives increases in trade/GDP; and (c) the assumption that increases in trade/GDP drive improved economic performance. The problems come together in the case of China and India, whose treatment dominates the overall results. They are classed as globalizers, their relatively good economic performance is attributed mainly to their openness, and the deviation between their economic policiessubstantial trade protection and capital controls, for exampleand the core economic policy package of the World Bank and the other multilateral economic organizations is glossed. At the least, analysts have to separate out the eect of country size on trade/GDP levels from other factors determining trade/GDP, including trade policies, because the single best predictor of trade/GDP is country size (population and area). They must make a clear distinction between statements about (i) levels of trade, (ii) changes in levels, (iii) restrictiveness or openness of trade policy, (iv) changes in restrictiveness of policy, and (v) the content of trade whether a narrow range of commodity exports in return for a broad range of consumption imports, or a diverse range of exports (some of them replaced imports) in return for a diverse range of imports (some of them producer goods to assist further import replacement). (a) Should we worry about rising inequality?

Thatcher put it, It is our job to glory in inequality and see that talents and abilities are given vent and expression for the benet of us all. 55 We should worry about rising inequality only if it somehow makes the poor worse o than otherwise. The counterargument is that this productive incentive eect applies only at moderate, Scandinavian, levels of inequality. At higher levels, such as in the United States over the past 20 years, it is likely to be swamped by social costs. Aside from the moral case against it, inequality above a moderate level creates a kind of society that even crusty conservatives hate to live in, unsafe and unpleasant. Higher income inequality within countries goes with: (i) higher poverty (using World Bank data and the number of people below the Banks international poverty line); 56 (ii) slower economic growth, especially in large countries such as China, because it constrains the growth of mass demand; (iii) higher unemployment; and (iv) higher crime. 57 The link to higher crime comes through the inability of unskilled men in high inequality societies to play traditional male economic and social roles, including a plausible contribution to family income. But higher crime and violence is only the tip of a distribution of social relationships skewed toward the aggressive end of the spectrum, with low average levels of trust and social capital. In short, inequality at the national level should certainly be a target of public policy, even if just for the sake of the prosperous. The liberal argument is even less concerned about widening inequality between countries than it is about inequality within countries, because we cannot do much to lessen international inequality directly. But on the face of it, the more globalized the world becomes, the more that the reasons why we should be concerned about within-country inequalities also apply between countries. If globalization within the current framework actually increases inequality within and between countries, as some evidence suggests, increases in world inequality above moderate levels may cut world aggregate demand and thereby world economic growth, making a vicious circle of rising world inequality and slower world growth. Rising inequality between countries impacts directly the national political economy in the poorer states, as rich people who earlier compared themselves to others in their neighborhood now compare themselves to others in the United States or Western Europe, and feel

1303 1304 1305 1306 1307 1308 1309 1310 1311 1312 1313 1314 1315 1316 1317 1318 1319 1320 1321 1322 1323 1324 1325 1326 1327 1328 1329 1330 1331 1332 1333 1334 1335 1336 1337 1338 1339 1340 1341 1342 1343 1344 1345 1346 1347 1348 1349 1350 1351 1352 1353 1354 1355 1356 1357 1358

CO

RR

EC

TE

PR

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

17

1359 1360 1361 1362 1363 1364 1365 1366 1367 1368 1369 1370 1371 1372 1373 1374 1375 1376 1377 1378 1379 1380 1381 1382 1383 1384 1385 1386 1387 1388 1389 1390 1391 1392 1393 1394 1395 1396 1397 1398 1399 1400 1401 1402 1403 1404 1405 1406 1407 1408 1409 1410 1411 1412 1413

deprived and perhaps angry. Inequality above moderate levels may, for example, predispose the elites to become more corrupt as they compare themselves to elites in rich countries. They may squeeze their own populations in order to sustain a comparable living standard, enfeebling whatever norms of citizenship have emerged and preventing the transition from an oligarchic elite, concerned to maximize redistribution upward and contain protests by repression, to an establishment elite, concerned to protect its position by being seen to operate fairly. Likewise, rapidly widening between-country inequality in current exchange rate terms feeds back into stress in public services, as the increasing foreign exchange cost of imports, debt repayment and the like has to be oset by cuts in budgets for health, education, and industrial policy. Migration is a function of inequality, since the fastest way for a poor person to get richer is to move from a poor country to a rich country. Widening inequality may raise the incentive on the educated people of poor countries to migrate to the rich countries, and raise the incentive of unskilled people to seek illegal entry. Yet migration/refugees/asylum is the single most emotional, most atavistic issue in Western politics. Polls show that more than two-thirds of respondents agree that there should be fewer foreigners living in their countries. 58 Rising inequality may generate conict between states, andbecause the marketexchange-rate income gap is so bigmake it cheap for rich states to intervene to support one side or the other in civil strife. Rising inequality in market-exchange-rate termshelped by a high US dollar, a low (long-run) oil price, and the WTO agreements on intellectual property rights, investment, and trade in services allows the United States to nance the military sinews of its postimperial empire more cheaply. 59 The eects of inequality within and between countries depend on prevailing norms. Where power hierarchy and income inequality are thought to be the natural condition of man the negative eects can be expected to be lighter than where prevailing norms arm equality. Norms of equality and democracy are being energetically internationalized by the Atlantic states, at the same time as the lived experience in much of the rest of the world is from another planet.

EC

In the end, the interests of the rich and powerful should, objectively, line up in favor of greater equity in the world at large, because some of the eects of widening inequality may contaminate their lives and those of their children. This ts the neoliberal argument. But the route to greater equity goes not only through the dismantling of market rules rigged in favor of the richalso consistent with the neoliberal argumentbut through more political (nonmarket) inuence on resource allocation in order to counter the tendency of free markets to concentrate incomes and power. This requires international public policy well beyond the boundaries of neoliberalism. The need for deliberate international redistribution is underlined by the evidence that world poverty may be higher in absolute numbers than is generally thought, and quite possibly rising rather than falling; and that world income inequality is probably rising too. This evidence suggests that the income and prosperity gap between a small proportion of the worlds population living mainly in the North and a large proportion living entirely in the South is a structural divide, not just a matter of a lag in the Souths catch-up. Sustained preferences for the South may be necessary if the world is to move to a singlehumped and more narrowly dispersed distribution over the next century.

1414 1415 1416 1417 1418 1419 1420 1421 1422 1423 1424 1425 1426 1427 1428 1429 1430 1431 1432 1433 1434 1435 1436 1437 1438 1439 1440 1441 1442 1443 1444

RR

TE

(b) The political economy of statistics

PR

OO

Concerns about global warming gave rise to a coordinated worldwide project to get better climatological data; the same is needed to get better data on poverty and inequality. The World Bank is one of the key actors. It has moved from major to minor source of foreign nance for most developing countries outside of Africa. But it remains an important global organization because it wields a disproportionate inuence in setting the development agenda, in oering an imprimatur of sound nance that crowds in other resources, and in providing nance at times when other nance is not available. Its statistics and development research are crucial to its legitimacy. 60 Other regional development banks and aid agencies have largely given up on statistics and research, ceding the ground to the World Bank. Alternative views come only from a few urban guerrillas in pockets of academia and the UN system. 61 Keynes dictum on practical men and long-dead economists suggests that such intel-

1446 1447 1448 1449 1450 1451 1452 1453 1454 1455 1456 1457 1458 1459 1460 1461 1462 1463 1464 1465 1466 1467

UN

CO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 18

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

UN

1468 1469 1470 1471 1472 1473 1474 1475 1476 1477 1478 1479 1480 1481 1482 1483 1484 1485 1486 1487 1488 1489 1490 1491 1492 1493 1494 1495 1496 1497 1498 1499 1500 1501 1502 1503 1504 1505 1506 1507 1508 1509 1510 1511 1512 1513

lectual monopolization can have a hugely negative impact. Think of two models of a statistical organization that is part of a larger organization working on politically sensitive themes. The exogenous model says that the statistics are produced by professionals exercising their best judgment in the face of diculties that have no optimal solutions, who are managerially insulated from the overall tactical goals of the organization. The endogenous model says that the statistics are produced by sta who act as agents of the senior managers (the principals), the senior managers expect them to help advance the tactical goals of the organization just like other sta, and the statistics sta therefore have to massage the data beyond the limits of professional integrity, or quit. Certainly the simple endogenous model does not t the Bank; but nor does the other. The Bank is committed to an Ocial View of how countries should seek poverty reduction, rooted in the neoliberal agenda of trade opening, nancial opening, privatization, deregulation, with some good governance, civil society and environmental protection thrown in; it is exposed to arm-twisting by the G7 member states and international nongovernmental organizations (NGOs); it must secure their support and defend itself against criticism. 62 It seeks to advance its broad market opening agenda not through coercion but mainly by establishing a sense that the agenda is right and tting. Without this it would lose the support of the G7 states, Wall Street, and fractions of developing country elites. The units of the Bank that produce the statistics are partly insulated from the resulting pressures, especially by their membership in epistemic communities of professionals inside and outside the Bank; but not wholly insulated. To say otherwise is to deny that the Bank is subject to the Chinese proverb, Ocials make the gures, and the gures make the ocials; or to Goodharts law, which states that an indicators measurement will be distorted if it is used as a target.

CO

(Charles Goodhart was thinking of monetary policy, but the point also applies to variables used to make overall evaluations of the performance of multilateral economic organizations.) To say otherwise is equally to deny that the Bank is aected by the same pressures as the Fund, about which a former Fund ocial said, The managing director makes the big decisions, and the sta then puts together the numbers to justify them. 63 But little is known about the balance between autonomy and compliance in the two organizations, or the latitude of their statisticians to adjust the country numbers provided by colleagues elsewhere in the organization which they believe to be ddled (as in the China case, above). 64 Some of the Banks statistics are also provided by independent sources, which provide a check. Others, including the poverty numbers, are produced only by the Bank, and these are more subject to Goodharts law. The Bank should appoint an independent auditor to verify its main development statistics or cede the work to an independent agency, perhaps under UN auspices (but if done by, say, UNCTAD, the opposite bias might be introduced). And it would help if the Banks gures on poverty and inequality made clearer than they do the possible biases and the likely margins of error. All this, of course, only takes us to the starting point of an enquiry into the causes of the probable poverty and inequality trends, 65 their likely consequences, and public policy responses; but at least we are now ready to ask the right questions. Above all, we have to go back to a distinction that has all but dropped out of development studies, between increasing returns and decreasing returns or, more generally, between positive and negative feedback mechanisms. The central question is why, at the level of the whole, the increasing returns of the Matthew eectTo him who hath shall be givencontinues to dominate decreasing returns in the third wave of globalization.

1514 1515 1516 1517 1518 1519 1520 1521 1522 1523 1524 1525 1526 1527 1528 1529 1530 1531 1532 1533 1534 1535 1536 1537 1538 1539 1540 1541 1542 1543 1544 1545 1546 1547 1548 1549 1550 1551 1552 1553 1554 1555 1556 1557

RR

1560 1. Gowan (1999). 1561 2. Mazur (2000). 1562 3. Wolf (2000).

EC

TE
NOTES

PR

OO

4. International Monetary Fund (2003). The trend is, however, highly sensitive to the dollars strong depreciation in the 1970s and appreciation in the 1990s. When this is allowed for, the world growth rate may be closer to trendless.

1563 1564 1565 1566 1567

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

19

OO

1568 1569 1570 1571 1572 1573 1574 1575 1576 1577 1578 1579 1580 1581 1582 1583 1584

5. In more concrete terms the number of hours of work it took for an entry-level adult male employee of McDonalds to earn the equivalent of one BigMac around 2000 ranged from: Holland/Australia/NZ/UK/ US, 0.260.53 h; Hong Kong, 0.68 h; Malaysia/South Korea, 1.431.46 h; Philippines/Thailand, 2.322.2.66 h; China, 3.96 h; India, 8 h. 6. Purchasing power parity is a method of adjusting relative incomes in dierent countries to take account of the fact that market exchange rates do not accurately reect purchasing poweras in the common observation that poor Americans feel rich in India and rich Indians feel poor in the United States. 7. The WIDER data set marries consumption from household surveys with consumption from national income accounts, and makes an allowance for (nonpublic sector) nonpriced goods and services.

18. I take this example from Pogge and Reddy (2003). 19. The 2540% gure is Reddy and Pogges estimate, the range reecting calculations based on PPP conversion factors for 1985 and 1993, and for all-food and bread-and-cereals indices. 20. Also, Bolivias extreme poverty rate according to the World Bank line was 11%, according to the ECLA line, 23%; Chile, 4%, 8%; Colombia, 11%, 24%; Mexico, 18%, 21% (ECLA, 2001, p. 51).

1608 1609 1610 1611 1612 1613 1614 1615 1616 1617 1618 1619 1620 1621 1622 1623 1624 1625 1626 1627 1628 1629 1630 1631 1632 1633 1634 1635 1636 1637 1638 1639 1640 1641 1642 1643 1644 1645 1646 1647 1648 1649 1650 1651

21. Reddy and Pogge (2003a).

22. This eect is amplied by the widespread removal of price controls on necessities and the lowering of taris on luxuries. 23. Gopinath (2002). 24. See Wade (2002a). It uses Stiglitzs ring and Kanburs resignation to illuminate the US role in the Banks generation of knowledge. 25. Meltzer Commission (2000). Meltzer later described the drop in the proportion of the worlds population in poverty from 28% in 1987 to 24% in 1998 as a modest decline, the better to hammer the Bank (Meltzer, 2001). 26. World Bank (2002c). See Deaton (2002). 27. Dollar was ascendant not in terms of bureaucratic position but in terms of epistemic inuence, as seen in the Human Resource departments use of him as a metric for judging the stature of other economists. When reporters started contacting the Bank to ask why it was saying dierent things about the poverty numbersspecically why two papers on the Development Research Complexs web site gave dierent pictures of the trendsthe response was not, We are a research complex, we let 100 owers bloom, but rather an assertion of central control. Chief economist Nick Stern gave one manager special responsibility for making sure the Banks poverty numbers were all coherent (Stern to research managers, email, April 4, 2002). 28. Non-World Bank champions of the idea that globalization improves global income distribution include Martin Wolf of The Financial Times (Wolf, 2002b; source of the epigraph; Wolf, 2000, 2001a, 2001b); also Giddens, described by some as a leading social theorist of his generation (2002, p. 72), and Ian Castles, former Australian Statistician, who claims that

1585 8. World Bank (2002a) and World Bank (2002b, p. 30). 1586 9. Wolfensohn (2001).

1587 10. World Bank (2001b, p. 3). The $1 a day is 1588 measured in purchasing power parity. See also World 1589 Bank (2002c). 1590 1591 1592 1593 1594 1595
11. I am indebted to Sanjay Reddy for discussions about the Banks poverty numbers (Reddy & Pogge, 2003a). See also Ravallion (2003), and Reddy and Pogge (2003b). In this paper I do not consider the additional problems that arise when estimating the impact of economic growth on poverty. See Deaton (2003).

1596 12. The Bank also calculates a poverty headcount with 1597 $2/day, which suers from the same limitations as the $1/ 1598 day line. 1599 13. Reported in Deaton (2001).

1600 14. See Reddy and Pogge (2003a).

1605 16. The new results were published in World Devel1606 opment Report 2000/2001 (World Bank, 2001a). 1607 17. Deaton (2001, p. 128).

UN

1601 1602 1603 1604

15. Also [Since 1980] the most rapid growth has occurred in poor locations. Consequently the number of poor has declined by 200 million since 1980 (Dollar & Kraay, 2002, p. 125).

CO

RR

EC

TE

PR

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 20

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

OO

1656 1657 1658 1659 1660 1661 1662 1663 1664 1665 1666 1667 1668 1669 1670 1671 1672 1673 1674 1675 1676 1677 1678 1679 1680 1681 1682 1683

29. In addition to the studies referenced elsewhere I draw on: Firebaugh (1999), Jones (1997), Pritchett (1997), Quah (1997), UNDP (1999), Kanbur (2002), Korzeniewicz and Moran (1997, 2000). 30. A reviewer comments, The idea of using market exchange rates to calculate international inequality is unbelievably stupid, and it is amazing that it still makes an appearance here. The UN had a commission of enquiry on this, which concluded unambiguously that using market exchange rates was wrong. But, the World Bank continues to use market exchange rates, adjusted by the Atlas methodology, to calculate the per capita incomes that it then uses to rank countries by their degree of development; and hence as a criterion for its lending decisions. Member countries voting shares in the Bank are based largely on their Fund quotas, which in turn are based largely on relative GDP at market exchange rates. So the Banks practice does imply that it thinks that relative per capita incomes calculated through market exchange rates are meaningful proxies for well-being (and the practice has the benet of holding down the voting share of developing countries). Moreover, as the text explains, incomes converted at market exchange rates do give meaningful measures of international purchasing power. Businesses making exporting and FDI decisions (auto makers, for example) pay more attention to relative incomes at market exchange rates than to PPP incomes.

1652 1653 1654 1655

most studies suggest that the past 25 years have seen a reversal in the trend towards widening global inequalities which had been proceeding for two centuries (Castles, 2001).

income distribution would be Hamlet without the princ. (Wolf, 2002a). This misconstrues my argument. 35. Dowrick and Akmal (2001). They nd that world inequality increased over 198093 using Gini, Theil, coecient of variation, and the variance of log income.

1699 1700 1701 1702 1703 1704 1705 1706 1707 1708 1709 1710 1711 1712 1713 1714 1715 1716 1717 1718 1719 1720 1721 1722 1723 1724 1725 1726 1727 1728 1729 1730 1731 1732 1733 1734 1735 1736 1737 1738 1739 1740 1741 1742 1743

37. Dikhanov and Ward (2003).

38. See the work of James Galbraith and collaborators in the University of Texas Inequality Project, http:// utip.gov.utexas.edu. Also, Galbraith (2002). 39. This is the answer to a reviewers remark, The work of Galbraith and his collaborators at Texas is essentially worthless for the purposes currently being discussed. We are interested in peoples command over resources, not the earnings of people in work in the formal sector. The latter is transparently irrelevant in most of the poor countries of the world, including India and China. 40. See Kynge (2002) and Rawski (2002). As another example from Rawskis analysis, Chinese government gures show total real GDP growth of 25% during 1997 2000, whereas energy consumption gures show a drop of 13% (not all of which is likely to be due to replacement of inecient coal-red furnaces.) Rawski estimates the growth rate since 2000 has been about half the ocial rate. See further Waldron (2002). 41. World Bank sources who request anonymity. During negotiations for Chinas joining the WTO Chinese economists argued against the insistence of the United States and other rich countries that its average income be expressed in terms of purchasing power partyand hence that China should be under the same obligations as middle-income countries, tougher than those on low-income countries. This is another example of the politics of statistics. 42. In addition, taking account of even just the obviously big and roughly measurable environmental

1684 31. Dikhanov and Ward (2003). 1685 32. Milanovic (2002b). 1686 1687 1688 1689 1690 1691 1692 1693 1694 1695 1696 1697 1698

33. ECLA (2002, p. 85). The dispersion of per capita GDP/PPP is measured as the average logarithmic deviation, the dispersion of growth rates as the standard deviation. 34. In an earlier debate with Martin Wolf I wrongly said that the result depends on both China and India. Wolf commented, Here you argue that if we exclude China and India, there is no obvious trend in inequality. But why would one want to exclude two countries that contained about 60% of the worlds poorest people two decades ago and still contain almost 40% of the worlds population today? To fail to give these giants their due weight in a discussion of global poverty alleviation or

UN

CO

RR

EC

TE

PR

36. Milanovics (2002a) preliminary analysis of 1998 data and an associated reworking of 1988 and 1993 data has produced the following Gini coecients (and standard deviations): 1988: 61.9 (1.8), 1993: 65.2 (1.8), 1998: 64.2 (1.9). The trend for the Theil coecient is similar (personal communication, June 9, 2003). Sala-i-Martin (2002) nds a drop in both extreme poverty and inequality. His ndings have been rejected in Milanovic (2002c) and Nye and Reddy (2003).

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

21

1744 costs lowers Chinas ocial GDP by roughly 8%, 1745 Indias, by 5%. See Hommann and Brandon (1995). 1746 1747 1748 1749 1750 1751 1752 1753 1754 1755 1756 1757 1758 1759 1760
43. Evidence for rising inequality in India over the past two decades is set out in Jha (2000). Deaton agrees that inequality in India has been increasing in recent years, and that consumption by the poor did not rise as fast as average consumption (Deaton, 2002). 44. Some sources give ratios of 7:1 in the early 1990s to 11:1 in the late 1990s. But these gures take Shanghai as the richest province. With Shanghai province city as the numerator the ratio reects not only regional disparity but also rural-urban disparity, and more specically, the growth of a new Hong Kong within China (one whose average income is exaggerated because nonpermanent residents are not included in its population). For these points I thank Andrew Fischer, PhD candidate, Development Studies Institute, LSE.

52. Rodrik (1999). 53. Wade (2003a [1990]).

1775 1776

OO

54. Milanovic (2002b). Milanovic nds that in countries below the average income of about $PPP 5,000, higher levels of openness (imports plus exports/GDP) are associated with lower income shares of the bottom 80% of the population. 55. Quoted in George (1997).

1777 1778 1779 1780 1781 1782 1783 1784 1785 1786 1787 1788 1789 1790 1791 1792 1793 1794 1795 1796 1797 1798 1799 1800

56. Besley and Burgess (2003).

57. Lee and Bankston (1999), Hsieh and Pugh (1993), Fajnzylber, Lederman, and Loayza (1998) and Freeman (1996).

1761 45. Krugman (2002). 1762 46. Babones (2002). 1763 47. Dikhanov and Ward (2003). 1764 48. World Bank (2002c).

59. Wade (2003b, 2003c).

1765 49. In this Section 1 draw on the arguments of Rodrik 1766 (1999, 2001).

RR

1767 50. Besley (2002). Besley uses indicators such as press 1768 freedom, democratic accountability, corruption, civil 1769 rights. 1770 1771 1772 1773 1774

CO

51. Cf. As they reformed and integrated with the world market, the more globalized developing countries started to growth rapidly, accelerating steadily from 2.9% in the 1970s to 5% through the 1990s (World Bank, 2002c, p. 36, emphasis added).

1802 Arrighi, G., Silver, B., & Brewer, B. (2003). Industrial 1803 convergence, globalization and the persistence of the 1804 NorthSouth divide. Studies in Comparative Interna1805 tional Development, 38(1), 331. 1806 Babones, S. (2002). The structure of the world-economy, 1807 19601999. In 97th annual meeting of the American 1808 Sociological Association, Chicago. 1809 Besley, T. (2002). Globalization and the quality of 1810 government. Manuscript, Economics Department, 1811 London School of Economics, March.

UN

EC

1801 REFERENCES
Besley, T., & Burgess, R. (2003). Halving world poverty. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3), 322. Castles, I. (2001). Letter to The Economist, May 26. Deaton, A. (2001). Counting the worlds poor: problems and possible solutions. The World Bank Research Observer, 16(2), 125147. Deaton, A. (2002). Is world poverty falling? Finance and Development, 39(2), 34. Available: http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2002/06/deaton.htm. Deaton, A. (2003). Measuring poverty in a growing world (or measuring growth in a poor world). NBER

TE

60. Kapur (2002). 61. For a good example of a heterodox book from a corner of the UN system, see UNDP (2003). The WTO lobbied to prevent its publication. 62. Wade (2003d). 63. Gopinath (1999). 64. Key experts in the relevant statistical unit thought that colleagues had ddled the China income numbers reported in Table 4, but their boss ignored their objections. 65. For discussion of causes see Wade (2002b, in press).

58. Demeny (2003).

PR

1812 1813 1814 1815 1816 1817 1818 1819 1820 1821 1822

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used 22

ARTICLE IN PRESS
WORLD DEVELOPMENT

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

1823 1824 1825 1826 1827 1828 1829 1830 1831 1832 1833 1834 1835 1836 1837 1838 1839 1840 1841 1842 1843 1844 1845 1846 1847 1848 1849 1850 1851 1852 1853 1854 1855 1856 1857 1858 1859 1860 1861 1862 1863 1864 1865 1866 1867 1868 1869 1870 1871 1872 1873 1874 1875 1876 1877 1878 1879 1880 1881 1882 1883 1884

Working Paper 9822. http://d.repec.org/n?u RePEc:nbr:nberwo:9822&r dev. Demeny, P. (2003). Population policy dilemmas in Europe at the dawn of the twenty-rst century. Population and Development Review, 29(1), 128. Dikhanov, Y., & Ward, M. (2003). Evolution of the global distribution of income in 197099. In Proceedings of the Global Poverty Workshop, Initiative for Policy Dialogue, Columbia University. Available: http://www-1.gsb.Columbia.edu/ipd/povertywk.html. Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2002). Spreading the wealth. Foreign Aairs (January/February), 120133. Dowrick, S., & Akmal, M. (2001). Explaining contradictory trends in global income inequality: a tale of two biasses. Faculty of Economics and Commerce, Australia National University, March 29. Available: http://ecocomm.anu.edu.au/people/info. asp?Surname Dowrick&Firstname Steve. ECLA (2001). Panorama social de America Latina 2000 01, ECLA (CEPAL), Santiago. ECLA (2002). Globalization and development. ECLA, Santiago. Fajnzylber, P., Lederman, D., & Loayza, N. (1998). What causes violent crime? Typescript, Oce of the Chief Economist, Latin America and the Caribbean Region. World Bank, Washington, DC. Firebaugh, G. (1999). Empirics of world income inequality. American Journal of Sociology, 104(6), 15971630. Freeman, R. (1996). Why do so many young American men commit crimes and what might we do about it? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(1), 2542. Galbraith, J. K. (2002). A perfect crime: inequality in the age of globalization. Daedalus (Winter), 1125. George, S. (1997). How to win the war of ideas: lessons from the Gramscian right. Dissent, 44(3), 4753. Giddens, A. (2002). Where now for new labour. Cambridge: Polity Press. Gopinath, D. (1999). Slouching toward a new consensus. Institutional Investor, 1(September), 7987. Gopinath, D. (2002). Poor choices. Institutional Investor, September 1, 4150. Gowan, P. (1999). The global gamble. London: Verso. Hommann, K., & Brandon, C. (1995). The cost of inaction: valuing the economy-wide cost of environmental degradation in India. In Modelling global sustainability conference. United Nations University, Tokyo. Hsieh, C. C., & Pugh, M. (1993). Poverty, income inequality, and violent crime: a meta-analysis of recent aggregate data studies. Criminal Justice Review, 18, 182202. International Monetary Fund (2003). World economic outlook. Database IMF, Washington DC, April. Jha, R. (2000). Reducing poverty and inequality in India: has liberalization helped? Available: http:// www.wider.unu.edu/research/1998-1999-3.1.publications.htm. Jones, C. (1997). On the evolution of world income distribution. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3), 1936.

Kanbur, R. (2002). Conceptual challenges in poverty and inequality: one development economists perspective, WP2002-09, Dept. of Applied Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY. Kapur, D. (2002). The changing anatomy of governance of the World Bank. In J. Pincus & J. Winters (Eds.), Reinventing the World Bank (pp. 5475). Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Korzeniewicz, R., & Moran, T. (1997). World-economic trends in the distribution of income, 19651992. American Journal of Sociology, 102(4), 10001039. Korzeniewicz, R., & Moran, T. (2000). Measuring world income inequalities. American Journal of Sociology, 106(1), 209214. Krugman, P. (2002). For richer. New York Times, October 20. Kynge, J. (2002). Pyramid of power behind numbers game. Financial Times, February 27. Lee, M. R., & Bankston, W. (1999). Political structure, economic inequality, and homicide: a cross-sectional analysis. Deviant Behavior: an Interdisciplinary Journal, 19, 2755. Mazur, J. (2000). Labors new internationalism. Foreign Aairs, 79(January/February), 7993. Meltzer, A. (2001). The World Bank one year after the Commissions report to Congress. In Hearings before the Joint Economic Committee, US Congress, March 8. Meltzer Commission (United States Congressional Advisory Commission on International Financial Institutions) (2000). Report to the US Congress on the International Financial Institutions. Available: http://www.house/gov/jec/imf/iac. Milanovic, B. (2002a). True world income distribution, 1988 and 1993: rst calculations based on household surveys alone. Economic Journal, 112(476), 5192. Milanovic, B. (2002b). Can we discern the eect of globalization on income distribution? Evidence from household budget surveys. World Bank Policy Research Working Papers 2876. Available: http:// econ.worldbank.org. Milanovic, B. (2002c). The Ricardian vice: why Sala-iMartins calculations are wrong. Typescript, Development Research Group, World Bank. Available: www.ssrn.com. Nye, H., & Reddy, S. (2003). Weaknesses of recent global poverty estimates: Xavier Sala-i-Martin and Surjit Bhalla. Available: www.socialanalysis.org. Pogge, T., & Reddy, S. (2003). Unknown: the extent, distribution, and trend of global income poverty. Available: http://www.socialanalysis.org. Pritchett, L. (1997). Divergence: big time. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3), 317. Quah, D. (1997). Empirics for growth and distribution: stratication, polarization, and convergence clubs. Journal of Economic Growth, 2(1), 2757. Rawski, T. (2002). Measuring Chinas recent GDP growth: where do we stand? Available: http:// www.pitt.edu/~tgrawski. Reddy, S., & Pogge, T. (2003a). How not to count the poor. Available: http://www.socialanalysis.org. Reddy, S., & Pogge, T. (2003b). Reply to Ravallion. Available: http://www.socialanalysis.org.

1885 1886 1887 1888 1889 1890 1891 1892 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 1941 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947

UN

CO

RR

EC

TE

PR

OO

WD 1514 29 January 2004 Disk used

ARTICLE IN PRESS

No. of Pages 23, DTD = 4.3.1

IS GLOBALIZATION REDUCING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY?

23

UN

CO

RR

1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986

Ravallion, M. (2003). Reply to Reddy and Pogge. Available: http://www.socialanalysis.org. Rodrik, D. (1999). The new global economy and developing countries: making openness work. In Policy Essay 24, Overseas Development Council. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Rodrik, D. (2001). Trading in illusions. Foreign Policy, 123(March/April), 5562. Sala-i-Martin, X. (2002). The disturbing rise in global income inequality. NBER Working Paper 8904, April. Available: http://papers.nber.org/papers/ w8904. UNDP (1999). Human development report 1999. New York: United Nations. UNDP (2003). Making global trade work for people. London: Earthscan. Wade, R. H. (2002a). US hegemony and the World Bank: The ght over people and ideas. Review of International Political Economy, 9(2), 201229. Wade, R. H. (2002b). Globalisation, poverty and income distribution: does the liberal argument hold. In Globalisation, Living Standards and Inequality: Recent Progress and Continuing Challenges (pp. 3765). Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia. Wade, R. H. (2003a [1990]). Governing the market. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Wade, R. H. (2003b). The invisible hand of the American empire. Ethics and International Aairs, 17(2), 7788. Wade, R. H. (2003c). What strategies are viable for developing countries today. The WTO and the shrinking of development space. Review of International Political Economy, 10(4), 621644. Wade, R. H. (2003d). The World Bank and its critics: the dynamics of hypocrisy. Studies in Comparative International Development, in press. Wade, R. H. (in press). World poverty and inequality: why they are probably rising, and the NorthSouth divide persisting. New Political Economy.

EC

Waldron, A. (2002). Chinas disguised failure: statistics can no longer hide the need for Beijing to instigate painful structural reforms. Financial Times, July 4. Wolf, M. (2000). The big lie of global inequality. Financial Times, February 8. Wolf, M. (2001a). Growth makes the poor richer: reversing the eects of globalization might increase equality as the critics claim, but it would be an equality of destitution. Financial Times, January 24. Wolf, M. (2001b). A stepping stone from poverty. Financial Times, December 19. Wolf, M. (2002a). Are global poverty and inequality getting worse? Yes: Robert Wade, No: Martin Wolf. Prospect (March), 1621. Wolf, M. (2002b). Doing more harm than good. Financial Times, May 8. Wolfensohn, J. (2001). Responding to the challenges of globalization: Remarks to the G-20 nance ministers and central governors. Ottawa, November 17. World Bank (1999). World development indicators 1999. Washington, DC: The World Bank. World Bank (2000). World development indicators 2000. Washington, DC: The World Bank. World Bank (2001a). World development report 2000/ 2001, Attacking Poverty. New York: Oxford University Press. World Bank (2001b). World development indicators 2001. Washington, DC: The World Bank. World Bank (2002a). World development indicators 2002. Washington, DC. The World Bank. World Bank (2002b). Global economic prospects and the developing countries 2002: making trade work for the worlds poor. Washington DC: The World Bank. World Bank (2002c). Globalization, growth, and poverty: building an inclusive world economy. New York: Oxford University Press.

1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022

TE

PR

OO

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen