Sie sind auf Seite 1von 18

Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

Can creative destruction be destroyed? Military IR&D and


destruction along the value-added chain
Allen Kaufman a , Christopher L. Tucci b,∗ , Mark Brumer a
a Whittemore School of Business and Economics, University of New Hampshire, 15 College Road, Durham, NH 03824, USA
b NYU Stern School of Business, 44 W 4th Street, KMC 8-71, New York, NY 10012, USA

Received 14 November 2000; received in revised form 15 July 2002; accepted 30 October 2002

Abstract
We elaborate a supply chain innovation matrix that can be applied to both commercial and military supply chains. By shifting
the analysis from a focal firm to industry structure, we argue that the market structure of the entire supply chain functions as
a major moderating variable in determining both the timing and adoption of innovations, both for commercial and military
markets. We extend work on supply chain resource dependency by drawing a distinction between market-structure-induced
resource dependency and supplier over-reliance on a customer in a competitive market. This has policy implications for the
organization of military industrial research and development (IR&D). Joint service research and development (Jointness)
will certainly bring about innovation, but it will be incremental, reinforcing established military hierarchies. Policy makers
may need to add this probable consequence when comparing Jointness and inter-service rivalry. The cost savings inherent in
Jointness may unwittingly sustain a military force unready for fighting the next war.
© 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Creative destruction; Industrial research and development (IR&D); Value-added chain

1. Introduction elaborate a new supply chain innovation matrix that


can be applied to both commercial and military sup-
How has the military managed to promote inno- ply chains. By shifting the analysis from a focal firm
vation during and after the Cold War? To answer to industry structure, we argue that the market struc-
this question, we rely on management theories of ture of the entire supply chain functions as a major
innovation in the for-profit world. By adopting these moderating variable in determining both the timing
concepts, we argue that competition among the ser- and adoption of innovations, both for commercial and
vices promoted rather than hindered innovation. In military markets. We extend work on supply chain re-
deductively building an argument outlining the trade- source dependency by drawing a distinction between
off between efficiency and competition in military market-structure-induced resource dependency and
industrial research and development (IR&D)1 , we supplier over-reliance on a customer in a competitive
market.
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-212-998-0285.

E-mail addresses: allenkaufman@comcast.net (A. Kaufman), or targeted toward the military. Our IR&D includes but is not lim-
tucci@stern.nyu.edu (C.L. Tucci). ited to the Pentagon program (cost recovery category) of Indepen-
1 We use the term ‘IR&D’ in this article to refer generally to all dent Research and Development and specific military-sponsored
research and development conducted by industry and sponsored by research programs with the same acronym.

0048-7333/$ – see front matter © 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 0 4 8 - 7 3 3 3 ( 0 2 ) 0 0 1 3 9 - 7
1538 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

1.1. The context: Jointness To illustrate the Jointness doctrine, take the case
of the military’s best-advertised weapons IR&D pro-
Those who study military innovation note that mil- gram, the Joint Strike Fighter (JSF). Although the JSF
itary bureaucracies build interest groups resistant to differs in details to accommodate service needs, all
change, particularly during periods of relative peace planes are built from the same manufacturing plat-
(Posen, 1984; Rosen, 1994; Pierce, 2001). These theo- form. Jointness, so the argument goes, gives the mil-
rists use political science models of bureaucracy to ac- itary monopsony power. Firms compete first over de-
count for the military’s resistance to change, a model sign, and then in producing a prototype. Savings come
that scholars contrast to dynamic markets. The implicit primarily from consolidating costs of development and
comparison gives credence to those policy makers who from scale economies in producing and maintaining
would bring corporate cost-accounting practices to the one model (Jones, 1999). However, this application of
military industrial research and development (IR&D) Jointness actually restricts the ability of the defense
process. These reformers contend that business princi- industry to generate technologies that would upset the
ples demand joint service IR&D (“Jointness”), which Cold War military regime. The Defense Department
allegedly saves costs at the generic research and the explicitly states that the JSF must build from known
system development stages (Jones, 1999).2 technologies and by implication that it must perpetu-
However, this dominant paradigm ignores impor- ate the officer corps put in place during the Cold War.
tant distinctions made within the managerial literature In other words, the JSF offers the next generation of
both on industrial innovation and on supply chain aircraft that were originally designed to defeat Soviet
management. Jointness appears to run counter to fighters. As it is currently structured, Jointness has the
the literature on industrial innovation (e.g. Vonortas, potential to deliver cost-effective incremental techni-
1997; Fusfeld, 1994) that generic research works cal change that reproduces the Cold War’s military
best when organizations cooperate and that product hierarchies.
market development works best when organizations By using managerial concepts devised to understand
compete; likewise, the Jointness movement appears industrial innovation and to oversee supply chain man-
to be unaware of a growing literature (e.g. Afuah, agement, we present an alternative viewpoint on mili-
2002; Christensen and Bower, 1996) that views tary IR&D, one that takes much from empirical work
downstream relational power as a suppressant of rad- on the Cold War innovative system (e.g. Sapolsky,
ical upstream innovation. Instead, the Department 1972; MacKenzie, 1993; Flamm, 1988; Koppes, 1982;
of Defense (DOD) argument has as its basis corpo- Spinaldi, 1994). Defense policy wisdom portrays joint
rate cost-accounting methods that seek economies by service product development as a cost-effective means
eliminating duplication and by gaining scale. to foster innovation. In contrast, we argue that this
When viewed from the managerial literature on in- strategy creates, in effect, a “cartel”, which tends to
novation, Jointness leads to an unintended outcome. suppress radical innovation while encouraging incre-
Centralized control and reduction in duplication of ef- mental changes supportive of the Cold War officer
fort allow downstream users (the incumbent officer corps. Military IR&D works optimally when the ser-
corps) to form a buying “cartel” that has complete con- vices first cooperate on generic component part re-
trol over innovation’s disruptive consequences. And, search to reduce risks and enhance knowledge and
given the private defense industry’s customer focus, then, during the development phase, compete to bring
these firms typically become allies in efforts to halt the new weapon system to “market”. Service rivalry
radical innovation. provides an effective check against incumbent inter-
ests opposed to change (Hayes and Smith, 1994).3
2 The services differ in their understanding of Jointness. The 3 With the Cold War’s conclusion, Congress and the Department

Army and Air Force use the term to mean unification while of Defense (DOD) took steps to eliminate the competitive phase
the Navy and Marine Corps use it to mean integration (Owens, by labeling inter-service rivalry inefficient. These reforms were
1997, 1998). We adopt the Army and Air Force meaning for this hardly surprising since they can be found in a long list of blue
paper. Integration would amplify all the effects proposed in the ribbon commissions on improving DOD efficiency (Jones, 1999).
paper. On the matter of new weapon development, these reports advocated
A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554 1539

To make this argument, we propose that market duces. In Section 2.1, we define terms and review
structure along the supply chain is a critical deter- the literature in the management of innovation relat-
minant of the timing and effects of innovation. We ing to “radical” and “incremental” technology. Then
develop an IR&D supply chain matrix, absent in the (Section 2.2), we recount economic rationale for and
managerial literature, and apply it both to commer- obstacles to forming an industrial consortium. During
cial and military ventures. On the military side, we the generic phase of a radical IR&D project, a research
offer a theory of inter-service rivalry and innovation consortium offers substantial benefits. However, col-
derived from microeconomic concepts. Others have lective action problems associated with the forma-
made claims about inter-service rivalry’s benefits, but tion of a consortium regularly thwart the undertaking.
these have relied on institutional arguments outside The private sector’s inability to capitalize on IR&D
microeconomics (Sapolsky et al., 2000). consortia displays the military’s potential for orga-
nizing such consortia. Finally, we elaborate our own
1.2. Method and organization theory relating to the market structure of the supply
chain.
The literature on innovation and on regulatory pol- In Section 3, which includes the last three parts
icy provides the basic theoretical tools for our investi- of the argument, we apply the theory from Section 2
gation into IR&D supply chain management. Note that to the context of military IR&D. First (Section 3.1),
both share a microeconomic foundation in which mar- we review the military’s advantage in managing a
kets are assumed to be less than perfect (Williamson, research consortium. The military’s command and
1985; Stiglitz, 1997; Knight, 1921). Transaction cost control structures simply eliminate the collective
economics and property rights theory best elaborate action problems that market actors encounter. How-
a theory of the firm under the assumptions of imper- ever, command and control brings with it substan-
fect information and bounded rationality (Hart, 1996; tial problems, which, if not solved, render military
Williamson, 1985). Further, public choice theory has IR&D expenditures ineffectual. Once established, the
extended microeconomics into the public policy do- “inefficiencies” inherent in the military’s command
main (Riker, 1982; Buchanan and Tullock, 1962). structure (impacted information) and in the congres-
Our method for answering the question of how the sional budgetary process (rotating majorities) provide
military promoted innovation during and after the Cold an entanglement of interests that can sustain and
War proceeds deductively and synthetically. We em- expand IR&D investments.
ploy a deductive method by following the logic of mi- Section 3.2 reviews how coalitions form from the
croeconomic theory in assessing innovation, both in IR&D project officers’ oversight requirements. The
the commercial and military sectors. We build in each US political system provides incentives that bias the
section of the paper below a series of assumptions military to outsource many key services. Through
that, when combined, clarify the dynamics of techno- outsourcing, technical officers can hone an effec-
logical change and creative destruction. Further, our tive political lobby. Should these technologies prove
method is synthetic in that it links together transac- effective and threaten the incumbent officer corps,
tion cost and public choice theories of the private and a political battle will ensue between these officers
public sectors. Logical consistency is paramount. and reformers both inside and outside the military.
We divide the theoretical exposition into six parts. Finally, by constructing two hypothetical cases, we
Section 2 contains the first three parts and focuses on consider (Section 3.3) the dynamics by which a new
building the argument that cartels in a supply chain technology may advance and devalue an old one, as
change the kinds of innovations the supply chain pro- when missile technology lessened the importance of
long-range bombers. The first hypothetical assumes a
centralized administration, i.e. joint service projects. By placing “Joint” command structure while the latter presumes
IR&D weapon system research under a single authority, reformers a structure divided among services. This exercise
promised that the costly redundancies found in separate service
IR&D pursuits would be eliminated. At the same time, centralized
leads to interesting conclusions: (1) radical, new mil-
control would bring economies of scale during the project’s IR&D, itary technologies fall into two distinct stages, one in
manufacturing and maintenance phases. which the technology is developed and prototyped,
1540 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

and one in which the technology is deployed and are modified to produce a new product that opens new
brought to market; and (2) intra- and inter-service markets (Henderson and Clark, 1990).
rivalry provides the diversified portfolios required in In contrast, radical (or “competence-destroying”)
undertaking IR&D and the political dynamic for ad- innovations economically devalue existing technolo-
vancing these technologies, once they move into the gies (Anderson and Tushman, 1990, 1991; Utterback,
prototyping phase. 1994). These innovations typically depend on scien-
The final section (Section 4), offers implications tific understanding and technical know-how that does
for theory. We discuss how market power alone is not build on a firm’s current capabilities. The transis-
insufficient for understanding competence-destruction tor illustrates this sort of discontinuous change. The
along the supply chain. Instead, we propose that mar- transistor did not rest on the scientific knowledge or
ket structure of both customers’ and suppliers’ indus- make use of production skills accumulated by firms
tries affect the adoption and timing of innovation. We manufacturing vacuum tubes. Those who were unable
conclude Section 4 with policy recommendations. to transit into the new technological/manufacturing
system went out of business. To represent this,
Henderson and Clark (1990) proposed knowledge
2. Theory development destruction along two dimensions: core system and
component part knowledge. Note that only the de-
2.1. Incremental versus radical innovation struction of both fully undoes a product market’s
technological determinates.
2.1.1. Incremental and radical innovation
defined 2.1.2. Market resistance to radical innovation
Since at least the time of Schumpeter (1934), re- The possibility that a new, radical technology may
searchers have been interested in how innovation displace established firms accounts for their frequent
reshapes industries. Scholars speak of two kinds efforts to seek out and suppress new, threatening tech-
of innovation: incremental and radical (Utterback, nologies. This behavior regularly occurs when indus-
1994; Anderson and Tushman, 1990, 1991; Afuah trial markets have matured. Two literatures, one from
and Bahram, 1995). Incremental innovation improves economics and the other from management, have doc-
on a known product or the process for producing umented alternative ways that entrenched firms have
it, reinforcing existing engineering and manufac- resisted radical innovation.
turing know-how (thus, “competence-enhancing”). Economists and political scientists argue that es-
These innovations may be simply minor process tablished firms regularly organize to help establish or
improvements—such as introducing statistical pro- to capture state regulatory agencies. These provide
cess control—or incremental product quality im- an effective—some say the only effective—defense
provements, as when software firms introduce a new against price competition and radical innovation
edition of an existing software package. Such inno- (Stigler, 1971; Peltzman, 1976). These regulatory
vations allow firms temporarily to build upon their agencies have the power to set entry barriers, establish
former competitive advantage. price, and regulate technological change. Still, regula-
Incremental improvements may also be discon- tory agencies have the capabilities to promote change
tinuous. Take the striking case of turbo-jet engines. by using regulatory incentives and by promoting com-
Although the turbo-jet dramatically changed engine petition. The Cold War innovative system provides
performance, the innovation built from existing engi- the most cogent example (Mowery and Rosenberg,
neering and manufacturing know-how. In this sense, 1998; Nelson and Wright, 1992). Economists con-
the turbo-jet engine enhanced existing engine firm sider the defense industry a de facto regulatory sys-
capabilities. Discontinuous change may be subtle as tem, even though no independent regulatory agency
when a firm reconfigures known components to make controls entry and exit. The military effectively acts
a new product. The transformation of electric room as this agency because of its monopsony procurement
air fan into a ceiling fan offers a simple illustration. powers (Ferguson, 1994; Sandler and Harley, 1995;
Here, the components (blade, motor, control system) Scherer, 1964). Unlike their regulatory counterparts,
A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554 1541

like the now defunct Civilian Aeronautics Board, Cold Afuah (2000) offers an example of how this re-
War military technical and procurement officers use sistance to innovation works in a commercial supply
their resources to promote radical innovation. Even chain. When a supply chain member attempts to in-
critics of Cold War budgets concur on the military’s troduce a technology that would disrupt the chain,
excellence in conducting weapon system IR&D (Alic others band together to resist its introduction. These
et al., 1992). circumstances make it difficult for the innovative firm
Researchers who employ this concept of a Cold to quickly deploy the new technology. Christensen
War innovative system usually refer to (1) the ways and Bower (1996) offer a second example found
that DOD budgets spurred IR&D; and (2) how firms in the disk drive industry. They describe how disk
used this new technical know-how to spin-off commer- drive suppliers that are heavily dependent upon cus-
cial products beyond the military’s regulatory reach tomers failed to develop new technology that, while
(Mowery and Rosenberg, 1998). The Cold War, how- potentially competence-enhancing to the supplier,
ever, was a military campaign, not a commercial ven- were competence-destroying for existing customers
ture. The military evolved a regulatory framework that (which they labeled “disruptive”). In both cases, the
provoked radical innovation, remaking industries and firms that resisted the new technologies successfully
undoing military hierarchies. Here, economists have prevented their suppliers from adopting it. However,
done little work in accounting for how this innovative innovations eventually entered the market through
military system overcame vested bureaucratic interests alternative suppliers that sought out savvy customers.
to generate radical new technologies.
The managerial literature relating to supply chain 2.2. Private sector Industrial research and
management identifies the second way by which firms development
suppress economically threatening innovation. Trans-
action cost economics provides the logic of this pro- 2.2.1. The promise of industrial research consortia
cess. Firms (customers/suppliers) co-specialize their The literature on innovation makes it plain that
assets to gain efficiencies and establish collaborative, radical industrial research and development (IR&D)
long-term relationships to optimize on transaction is an uncertain business (Freeman and Soete, 1997;
costs (Williamson, 1985; Kay, 1997). These relation- Stiglitz and Wallsten, 1999; Utterback, 1994; von
ships allow for firms within the supply chain to engage Hippel, 1988; von Hippel, 1998). Results may be
in joint product design and concurrent engineering, long in coming, intangible, and inapplicable to devel-
to share personnel and equipment, and to leverage oping proprietary products. In fact, radical industrial
financial and marketing resources (Kaufman et al., research is so risky that typically only the most dar-
2000; Dyer and Singh, 1998). Thus, supply chains ing and well-financed firms engage in these activities.
that invest in complementary assets and collaborate to Nevertheless, uncertainty itself induces investments
improve their competitive positions have: (1) a joint because of the high returns that the few successes
interest in uncovering innovations that enhance their bring.
capabilities; and (2) a joint interest in suppressing in- When product development managers pursue inno-
novations that devalue these investments and relation- vation, they invariably define the product as a system
ships (Afuah, 2002). Should a downstream firm—say composed of subsystems or component parts. Some
the end supply chain customer (an original equipment components set the design parameters of others and
manufacturer)—gain monopoly power, it could use some are so fraught with practical problems that they
its monopsony position to enforce the supply chain constrain the system’s movement from design to de-
propensity to promote incremental innovations. Al- velopment to production (Vincenti, 1990). Product de-
ternatively, if a few downstream firms account for a velopment managers identify these troublesome spots
large portion of the market, technological threats to and put extra resources at the disposal of those re-
their investments may provide sufficient incentive for sponsible for developing the component. Solutions to
them to overcome their collective action problems a problem hindering a component may rearrange the
and act as an oligopoly to suppress value-destroying order of addressing design problems and the relation-
innovations. ships among components; hence the idea that critical
1542 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

components pose reverse salient problems (Hughes, 1999; Kaufman et al., 2000; Simonin, 1999; Dyer and
1989). Singh, 1998; Powell and Koput, 1996).
The distinction between generic and proprietary re- Once a consortium solves the generic technical
search opens the possibility for a research consor- problems, member firms proceed to integrate the
tium where competing managerial teams collaborate components into proprietary products until one de-
to solve generic, component part problems. Because sign holds sway over the market, either through con-
generic knowledge precedes proprietary applications, sumer choice or through regulatory fiat. At this point,
firms can share this information without divulging the managerial literature tells us product innovation
“trade” secrets. Obviously, if a firm uncovers answers moves into a third period. Firms begin to compete to
to these basic engineering problems and develops the improve incrementally the product and the processes
data for a “critical” component part solution before required for its production and distribution (Utterback,
others, it will have a competitive advantage in being 1994; Anderson and Tushman, 1990; Mowery, 1998).
first to market. However, the costs of going it alone are
extremely high given the various solution paths and 2.2.2. The hindrances in forming an IR&D
the multiple kinds of research and disciplinary train- consortium
ing required. Thus, firms have incentives to form con- The incentives for IR&D collaboration seem com-
sortia to share risks and costs and exclude others from pelling. However, IR&D managers know that market
their joint knowledge (Ouchi and Bolton, 1988). hindrances typically offset collaboration’s benefits.
An IR&D consortium reduces the associated costs Free riding is the most pervasive problem (Olson,
of basic research by enhancing information flows and 1965). A consortium attempts to resolve this problem
by distributing the risk among multiple participants. by functioning as a “selective” organization, in which
In a research consortium, member firms: (1) divide al- only its members share in the collaborative payoffs
ternative routes for developing non-proprietary com- (Hardin, 1982). But the problem persists. Each mem-
ponent parts; and (2) share information on the results ber firm hopes that others will delegate their best staff
of these vying solutions. This arrangement reduces and best resources to the project. When one firm con-
overall costs by allowing firms to share complemen- ducts research in its facilities or its team takes on a
tary technologies and know-how. Research regularly project in a joint facility, the firm has an incentive to
puts firms on paths that take them outside their expert less than fully disclose information. Personnel shar-
domains. A consortium brings together firms whose ing may mitigate this tendency, but effective research
combined technical inventory can handle many prob- teams take time to form, so that inter-firm collabora-
lems as they arise. Consequently, cost sharing reduces tion brings substantial costs. Consortium coordination
high IR&D overhead investments. poses another set of costly problems relating to setting
An IR&D consortium also reduces market risk. the agenda and defining a generic research program.
Since technical problems have competing solutions, Given the multiplicity of interests and the complexity
redundancy must be built into research and develop- of the consortium’s connections to outside parties,
ment projects. By dividing the multiple paths among consortia tend to leak information. These difficulties
members, the consortium reduces its members’ risks: typically lead firms to favor competition over collabo-
each firm holds a diversified research portfolio (Corey, ration, creating a less than socially “optimal” outcome.
1997; Stiglitz and Wallsten, 1999; Grindley et al.,
1994). 2.2.3. An IR&D supply chain taxonomy
A consortium reduces another sort or risk: informa- A consortium, then, functions as a supplier to the
tion asymmetry (cf. Williamson, 1985; Casson, 1998). industrial firms that design and develop the product. In
An IR&D consortium fashions a dense and an exten- fact, innovation, whether of a competence-destroying
sive information network, in which firms co-mingle (radical) or a competence-enhancing (incremental)
(Fransman, 1990). The formation of this intensive and sort, can work through a supply chain (Afuah and
extensive selective learning network provides mem- Bahram, 1995). The firm that designs and develops
bers with anticipated and unanticipated information the product or system functions as the customer while
to which non-members are denied access (Noteboom, the firm or research laboratory that performs com-
A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554 1543

Fig. 1. Market structure of supply chain and innovation.

ponent part research and development functions as lower right, “traditional”, is the cell in which com-
the supplier. Customers may compete or cooperate petition reigns along the supply chain. Those cells to
in managing their supply chain; and they may either the left, where customers cooperate and exert market
arrange their supply base either in a cooperative or power, typically requires cartel legislation or exemp-
competitive manner. Fig. 1 illustrates the industrial tions from anti-trust laws. The US government has
forms that this innovation supply chain can assume. not allowed for the cartel arrangement in the lower
In those cells in which customers (or suppliers) coop- left hand cell—except during the two world wars
erate, competence-enhancing innovation dominates. and a brief experiment during the Great Depression.
In these situations, customers have market power However, during 1970s and 1980s, when Japanese
and can use it to sustain capabilities rather than to firms captured market share in numerous markets,
“destroy” them. Congress relaxed antitrust laws when it passed the
In the cells to the right, customers have neither Cooperative Research and Development Act of 1984.
monopoly nor monopsony power. Market compe- This allowed firms to cooperate on industrial research
tition functions, making for uncertain outcomes. and development.
The possibility that a rival might undo the reigning Perhaps the best-known IR&D example, Semat-
paradigm compels each to pursue both incremental ech (see lower left cell: “cartel-induced innovation”),
and radical research. In the upper right, which we arose from 1987 Congressional legislation (Corey,
label “supplier-led innovation”, customers compete 1997). The DOD, fearing Japanese encroachments
with other firms in their own markets, while suppliers into the US semiconductor industry, lobbied for this
either cooperate or enjoy monopoly positions. The bill on national security grounds. The Act authorized
1544 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

DOD subsidies and exempted the companies from for developing the next generation of the existing
anti-trust constraints, claiming that they would be technology, and for amassing budgets to carry out
engaged in non-competitive basic research and devel- these IR&D projects. However, incumbent officers
opment. However, the industry failed to cooperate in have little inherent interest in introducing weapon
establishing a basic research agenda. Instead, Semat- systems that sabotage their commanding position,
ech became an association by which the industry’s and they have the power to delay or halt deployment.
primary players, Intel, IBM, Motorola, etc. organized This contrasts with private markets, in which radical
its supplier base. By setting standards and improve- technologies improve consumer wealth and enrich
ment milestones, Sematech has effectively promoted first-mover suppliers.
incremental innovation (Corey, 1997; Mowery, 1998). So why does an incumbent officer corps invest in
potentially radical IR&D? For two reasons: to increase
3. Application of the theory to military IR&D military budgets (Niskanen, 1971) and to develop tech-
nologies that enhance capabilities (Pierce, 2001). The
3.1. The officer corps, budgets and radical IR&D incumbent officer corps can garner additional funds
projects beyond those required to sustain and improve the given
force structure by embracing radical IR&D projects.
The pitfalls for firms in forming IR&D consortia Investments in IR&D programs have long time hori-
points to a general problem: that profit-maximizing zons and uncertain prospects. In fact, officers know
firms tend to under-invest in R&D. To correct this that most radical technologies fail. Because the incum-
market imperfection, government frequently invests in bent officer corps closely monitors program managers,
R&D and subsidizes private initiatives (Mowery et al., they must seek out senior officer alliances and dis-
1999; Stiglitz and Wallsten, 1999; Cohen and Noll, guise implications if radical technologies are to move
1991; Narin et al., 1997). However, national security forward (Davis, 1967; Pierce, 2001).
provides its own rationale for government-sponsored The second IR&D investment reason, to enhance
IR&D. current capabilities, affords radical change through
As government representatives, the military does unanticipated outcomes. To understand this point, re-
not encounter the collective action problems found call Henderson and Clark (1990), which Pierce (2001)
in the marketplace. This potentially allows the mil- adapts to military organizations. Unlike Henderson
itary to be a more effective agent for IR&D than and Clark, Pierce considers a third variable: doctrine
the market. However, advocates for a radical IR&D (cf. Rosen, 1994). By this, he refers to unified con-
weapon system consortium must overcome the in- cepts by which the military organizes its war-making
cumbent officers’ misgivings about investing in capabilities. In a logical—structure follows strategy—
competence-destroying technologies and create the sense, doctrine precedes weapon systems and its vari-
administrative means to coordinate the project. ous components. However, history rarely conforms to
logic. Doctrinal changes typically occur when an of-
3.1.1. The incumbent warrior officer corps’ ficer group discovers how incremental technological
resistance to radical change changes allow for a radically new way of making war
Modern militaries have developed two kinds of (Hayes and Smith, 1994). The blitzkrieg provides the
officers: the traditional warrior who plans and car- salient example, for it radically changed land warfare
ries out military campaigns and the technical offi- by combining known technologies—radio commu-
cer who reviews industrial and scientific advances nication and armored vehicles (Posen, 1984; Pierce,
that affect a military’s war-making capabilities (Van 2001). Here, radically different refers both to the
Creveld, 1991). Within the US military, warriors have military’s novel integration of proven technologies
dominated the officer corps. These officers’ careers into a new weapon systems and to the new career pos-
are generally tied to a particular weapon platform: sibilities that open to young officers when a doctrinal
bombers, aircraft carriers, etc. (Hundley, 1999). This shift occurs.
officer corps welcomes opportunities for incremen- Fig. 2 presents Pierce’s (2001) modification of
tally improving its weapon platform’s performance, Henderson and Clark. Notice that in Pierce’s matrix
A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554 1545

Fig. 2. Architectural innovation and military doctrine (Pierce, 2001).

two types of innovation—radical and architectural those who pursue technological advances and those
innovation—challenge established interests. Where who make use of technology to reinforce set authority
radical innovation does this by replacing one weapon patterns (Davis, 1967).
system (and so, one officer corps) with another Governmental “inefficiencies” sustain military in-
(competence-destroying), architectural threatens the vestments in radical IR&D. By “inefficiencies”, we
existing order by working directly with the old tech- are not referring to mismanagement or programs that
nologies to undermine the military’s career patterns. lack effective cost controls and oversight. Rather, we
Thus, military officers may invest in IR&D to enhance are speaking about the information asymmetries inher-
a given weapon system and only later find out that ent in large-scale government bureaucracies and the
these investments—contrary to expectations—caused “log rolling” tendencies of democratic governments.
a military upheaval. Though reformers generally rally against these allege-
dly wasteful consequences of democratic government,
3.1.2. The technical officer corps’ complex interest these practices play an important role in sustaining
in radical IR&D military innovation. They ensure the overlapping
Technical officers’ career paths depend less on the experimentation in which innovation thrives.
prevailing weapon system than combat officers. Al-
though military officers, they are also scientifically 3.2. Project IR&D coordination and outsourcing
trained professionals. These experts—whether as op-
erational technical officers or as staff officers—pursue All of this may give technical/procurement officers
technical objectives and provide advice on possi- space for developing radical technologies. However,
bilities. Here, scientific and engineering knowledge such research requires effective organization. For the
gauges actions, making for internal conflict between military to be successful in this endeavor, it must co-
1546 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

ordinate the IR&D project. To proceed, procurement rotating majorities that redistribute tax dollars to lo-
officers must decide on whether to invest in additional cal constituencies through public programs, including
research capacity or to purchase these services from military IR&D (Riker, 1982; Schattschneider, 1960).
university laboratories and private firms. In making Since budgets are fundamentally political, military of-
the decision on the “optimal” proportion of in- and ficers must consider how expenditures on in-house ca-
out-of-house research, military officers must consider pacity and on subcontracting will affect the military’s
such variables as the costs of building and adminis- political influence.
tering in-house capacity against the costs of writing, This structure ensures that the budgetary process
monitoring and enforcing contracts. This accounting will be anything but straightforward. The process’s
problem, however, becomes complicated when mili- multiple entry points allow interests ample opportuni-
tary officers consider the consequences of their de- ties to revise and counter-revise budgets. To participate
cision on the military’s internal power relations and effectively, interests must enter into coalitions. Though
on its abilities to build budgetary coalitions (Kaufman these coalitions are hardly stable, the constitutional
et al., 1993). structure does provide two general rules: align oneself
with (1) broad congressional-constituent interests;
3.2.1. The military’s propensity to outsource and (2) powerful private sector interests. In short, the
In general, the officer corps’ composition and the political process biases the military toward outsourc-
US political system provide incentives for outsourc- ing. Once procurement officers secure a budget and
ing. Since World War II (WWII), warriors have domi- once they have built a constituency, they may perpet-
nated the officer corps. They assure that the military’s uate their programs by exercising political influence
core competency revolves around winning wars rather (Cohen and Noll, 1991). These lobbying forces may
than managing weapon programs. Typically, warrior overcome incumbent officers’ self interest to weaken
officers prefer outsourcing to building in-house re- threatening programs, or they may overcome well
search capacity; an expansion of the latter may rework founded technological or balance of power objections.
the relative positions of warrior and technical officers.
Tradition, however, limits outsourcing. More impor- 3.2.2. Managing the IR&D complex
tantly, if the military outsourced all its technical ca- Given its predisposition to outsource, the military
pabilities, it would become information-dependent on must develop procurement skills to minimize transac-
outsiders, e.g. firms, research labs, consultants, etc. tion costs. First, long-term contracts offer one method
Technical officers who oversee IR&D projects have by which to reduce these costs. Procurement officers
a second compelling reason to build links with civil- require discretionary authority to grant these contracts
ians. IR&D works best when it occurs among various on a non-competitive basis. Research teams and re-
organizations and disciplines and when information search problems exist in well-defined communities in
flows among these “partner” and affiliate organiza- which peer review serves as a substitute for market
tions. Conceptually, the link between the applied competition. Still, contractors may shirk, falsify data,
sciences’ desire to dominate nature and the military’s and act in other opportunistic ways. The military has
desire to dominate adversaries strikes an intuitive two effective means for overcoming this problem: (1)
chord. Both have an interest in demonstrating their the military can establish a monitoring system by as-
prowess over nature. This fact—and not the lobbying signing procurement officers (or their civilian equiva-
benefits associated with it—persuaded the post-WWII lents) to research facilities and by assembling expert
military to enter into a cooperative relationship with review committees; and (2) the military can punish
the scientific and engineering communities (Kelves, non-performers by refusing to award them future con-
1975). tracts.
The military must consider another non-accounting The military may turn either to private firms, univer-
issue when considering its make/buy decision: the sity research centers, or to non-profit research organi-
budgetary process. As Buchanan and Tullock (1962) zations to conduct IR&D on a component part or in a
noted, democratic politics do not allocate resources to field that may contribute in finding technical solutions.
correct market failures. Instead, representatives form In general, the closer the project is toward prototyp-
A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554 1547

ing, the more likely the military will subcontract with Because the military tends to outsource and because
a production firm. For firms, IR&D contracts must the coordination requires such a diverse set of skills,
be sufficiently promising for production contracts or the military will favor a civilian coordinating team.
closely enough related to ongoing weapon system The military cannot easily delegate the task to a pri-
expertise to divert resources from profit generating vate firm or to a university research center. When a
activities. firm takes on this role, other companies will look sus-
When research tends toward generic knowledge, piciously at their rival’s decisions. University research
universities or private research institutes become likely centers are unwilling to manage a project that produces
contractors. For universities, the research must be con- a weapon system prototype. The military cannot use
sistent with the faculties’ perceptions of their knowl- a component part center for this undertaking because
edge generating activities and must be conducive to it does not have expertise in assessing the weapon
peer reviewed journal writing (Van der Meulen, 1998). as an integrated system. The coordination agencies
For those who publish first, research grant opportuni- may be ad hoc committees for the project’s duration
ties become plentiful, whether from public or private or sponsored organizations with system integration
research institutions. Successful researchers capitalize skills.
on their reputation by converting research grants into
laboratories and by garnering prestigious outside ad- 3.3. The dynamics of military: creative destruction
visory positions, including military advisee roles.
In-house military officers find their rewards through All of these factors prepare a fertile environ-
the normal promotion process, while civilian employ- ment for developing prototype radical technolo-
ees are civil servants who are subject to its established gies. However, incumbent officers usually resist
procedures. Neither of these reward systems is attrac- competence-destroying technologies when they enter
tive to research engineers. The first takes researchers into the prototyping phase. Because the officers work
outside civilian networks in which researchers distin- within well-defined bureaucratic regimes, they are
guish themselves. And, the second (civil service) puts more likely to suppress threatening technologies than
researchers in an organization that works like a union, private firms that operate in open markets. How, then,
securing benefits by years of service rather than by do radical new weapon platforms make it into the
merit (Johnson and Libecap, 1994). If the military is field when no clearly defined external threat exists?
to enlist academics into this effort, it must devise con- Rivalry, within—but especially among—the services
tracts that university officials will find beneficial and is the most salient force for change.
compatible with the institution’s knowledge creation
and dissemination purpose. If such a contract cannot 3.3.1. Military IR&D under a joint command
be written, procurement officers must create novel or- To illustrate how these two factors operate, con-
ganizations that can accommodate both the military’s sider a hypothetical situation in which no clear danger
and the researcher’s needs. Typically, these organiza- exists (as was the case before 11th September 2001)
tions (such as Rand, MITRE, the Applied Physics Lab- and the military operates through a “Joint” command.
oratory, and the Jet Propulsion Laboratory) become a Though this structure eliminates inter-service rivalry,
military–civilian hybrid: military sponsored and civil- it cannot fully repress intra-military rivalry. Also as-
ian controlled (Koppes, 1982; MacKenzie, 1993). sume that the military has competent technical staff
As component IR&D evolves into an ongoing and line units and that the incumbent officer corps
weapons program, the military must assemble a has secured budgets large enough to initiate IR&D
coordinating committee to rationalize efforts. To on several competence-destroying weapon systems.
“command” a consortium, the military must have However, the problems associated with the weapon
in-house know-how: (1) to divide up the various com- system’s development: (1) are so complex that they re-
ponent problems and their possible solutions; (2) to quire diverse, specialized disciplines; and (2) in some
assign them to the most capable research team; (3) instances, demand fundamental research. These prob-
to monitor progress and redress problems; and (4) to lems exceed the intra-military units’ in-house capabil-
ensure that (re)integration proceeds smoothly. ities.
1548 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

Although this hypothetical case assumes a joint compete for missions and budgets; and (3) no clear en-
command structure and a pre-operational radical tech- emy exists. This situation offers more opportunities for
nology, competition still plays a role. Because IR&D radical change than a joint military command. How-
requires diverse disciplines and because it serves ever, these opportunities come with increased costs.
different functional parts of the military, multiple tech- Each service has an incentive to pursue new tech-
nical units will evolve inside the joint command. Each nologies that diminish the others’ strategic importance
has constrained budgetary discretion. To pursue new and its budgetary share. The services pursue these new
technologies, the units attempt to loosen budgetary technologies through programs aimed at creating spe-
rules and to build budgetary accounts. In the battles cific weapon systems. In effect, each looks at the other
over budgets, each unit pursues a self-interested strat- as a “market” competitor. However, the services are
egy that makes for rotating coalitions, both in and more likely than market players to have accurate in-
outside the military. To strengthen its political stand- formation about the others’ strategic plans and its or-
ing, each unit hones civilian networks, allowing for ganizational capabilities. The budgetary process alone
alternative funding sources. forces information “disclosure” that can incite a lax
Markets can augment this process. Research scien- service to invest in radical R&D. Unless the services
tists and engineers can uncover market opportunities collude, which is a possibility given the small numbers
to manufacture either component parts or subsystems and the stakes involved, each service must engage in
for a new weapon system. Usually, the opportunity this inter-service competition or simply succumb.
appears when incumbent firms find little market Service rivalry has another effect. It promotes
prospect for the device’s growth potential, or they redundancy (functional divisions and IR&D units)
lack the skills for designing and manufacturing it greater than that found in a joint command. Thus,
(Nelson and Wright, 1992). Once researchers become service rivalry multiplies the avenues for IR&D fund-
entrepreneurs, they have a paramount interest in pro- ing, for start-up initiatives, and for firm technological
moting the new component and the weapon system to diversification. These redundancies make for a fertile
which it belongs (Howells, 1997), which may foster IR&D field.
intra-military rivalry both during the developmental As know-how about a technology grows and dis-
and deployment stages. seminates, service coordination offers opportunities
Established firms also have an interest in pursuing for lowering costs and improving development cycle
novel technologies. These firms compete for IR&D time. An organizational network may also arise by
dollars both as a revenue source and as a way to stay “design”. Take the case in which several services con-
technologically current. These firms need to hold a tract with a research center to work on a set of related
diverse technological portfolio, both to reduce risk topics. This research center acts as a hub where tech-
against radical change and to enhance in-house learn- nical personnel from the services and private firms
ing. Serendipitous discovery is the “raw material” out gather to learn about recent developments. Rival ser-
of which profits, or to be precise, new wealth, is made. vices may bring their contractor to learn about generic
Since defense firms serve an incumbent officer corps advances on a component part. These contractors can
with monopsony power, competence-destroying inno- take this information and rework it into proprietary
vation seems an unlikely option. However, profits can designs for a component to be included in a specific
be a subversive force. If an incumbent firm believes weapon system. Alternatively, the research center may
that it can be the first-mover in manufacturing a radical be a hub around which agencies that have existing in-
technology, it has a monetary, though risky, incentive formation connections rotate. Here, the hub functions
to promote the technology and build discord between more like a coordinator of efforts than as a new knowl-
officers divided by generation or function. edge creator and transfer mechanism among discrete
research entities.
3.3.2. Military IR&D under service commands Finally, if the new technology can benefit each
Here, let us assume that: (1) the military is divided service, they may join together to form a research
among services, though the line of command subordi- consortium. This effort typically requires DOD inter-
nates these rival services to a single authority; (2) they vention, for inter-service rivalry produces collective
A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554 1549

action problems like those found in private mar- Jointness constrains both product design and de-
kets. To take advantage of the promising technology, velopment competition. The Jointness cell captures
the DOD must command the services to cooper- current DOD military IR&D doctrine. Here, the ser-
ate. The coordination agency needs to identify the vices cooperate to enhance their buying power over
salient problems and parcel out solution paths to private defense contractors. Service arsenals/shipyards
each service. Recall that the problems themselves and non-profit research and development organiza-
pertain to individual component parts or the assem- tions mediate the relationship between the joint ser-
bly of these parts into a system. Thus, the services vice program officers and the private contractors. The
may search for answers by developing experimental officer corps’ concentrated buying power gives it in-
weapon systems. In these situations, the services will centives to, like a monopsonist, invest only in those
duplicate weapon systems, e.g. air-to-air missiles, innovations that augment its current capabilities.
surface-to surface missiles, surface-to-air missiles.
However, for efficiencies to be had, each service
must pursue unique solutions to component part de- 4. Implications and conclusions
velopment and to systems integration; further, each
service must have access to the other’s progress. Our theory on supply chain IR&D management
Again, the DOD plays the role of coordinator and has implications for both commercial and military
judge. managers. As discussed above, firms may not want
Once a radical technology approaches operational to develop or even adopt innovations if they are
status, the services will race to be first in bringing the competence-destroying to customers. If a supplier
“product to market” with the inherent advantages. Of pursues such a technology, the customer may switch
course, if the incumbent officer corps colludes, they to another supplier. If the innovative supplier de-
may halt the deployment of this radical technology. pends heavily on this customer, then, the technol-
This is much more likely to happen if the military ogy may be slow in coming to market. Because the
promotes Jointness than if it promotes rivalry. supplier–customer relationship runs along a supply
chain, the threatened customer need not be the final
3.3.3. A military IR&D supply chain matrix user.
The concepts that structure these two hypothetical Supply chain inflexibility is particularly unyielding
cases allow for a military IR&D supply chain ma- in the defense industry. In the military IR&D scenario
trix comparable to the one developed for the com- developed above, we found a paradox in which the
mercial sector, as shown in the lower portion of each customers (incumbent officers) encouraged innova-
cell in Fig. 1. Again, the industrial systems on the tion but prevented it from entering the marketplace.
left tend to foster competence-enhancing innovation When public policy restrains inter-service rivalry,
and those to the right both competence-enhancing and the officer corps may gain absolute market power
competence-destroying. Notice that the lower right along the value-added chain and wholly prevent
hand corner utilizes cooperation to form an industrial competence-destroying innovations from diffusing.
research consortium and product development compe- Unlike the Christensen and Bower (1996) example
tition to bring weapon systems into the field. In the discussed earlier, there is no competitor to enter and
case of the Service Arsenal/Shipyard System, it did offer new technology.
not have a central apparatus (DOD) to facilitate a mil- If the officer corps succeeds in stopping innovation,
itary consortium. In the US, this system operated until the innovating firm may not be hurt, as in the com-
WWII, when the Office of Scientific Development was mercial situation (cf. Afuah and Bahram, 1995). The
established to oversee research efforts. After the war, supplier need not worry about a new entrant convinc-
Congress established the DOD that, by subordinating ing risk neutral firms from adopting the new technol-
the services and their arsenals/shipyards to a central ogy. The military monopsony simply has no interest
authority, set the foundations for the Cold War inno- in change. Ironically, the military IR&D process has
vative system (Vander Meulen, 1991; Cooling, 1979; the potential to disable entrants and destroy “creative
Smith, 1985). destruction” itself.
1550 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

4.1. Implications for theory will focus exclusively on the most interesting cells:
the lower left versus lower right of Fig. 1 and the
There are several theoretical implications of the sce- lower right of Fig. 1 with high versus low resource
narios developed above. In particular, if we examine dependence.
the market structure of both suppliers and customers,
it may help us understand both military and commer- 4.1.2. Customer performance
cial patterns of entry timing and technological evo- Market structure interacts with customer firm per-
lution. In this section, we first examine how market formance in an interesting way. If we assume an inno-
structure might affect resource dependency; then how vation is competence-destroying to a customer firm,
technological changes that are radical to customers the firm will most likely reject the technology. But the
might affect suppliers’ performance; and finally, how ramifications of this rejection depend in a substantial
technological changes that are competence-destroying way on the competitiveness of the market in which the
to customers might affect suppliers’ entry timing. We customer competes. If there is absolutely no competi-
include testable propositions that result from these as- tion and no way that the technology could lead to an
sertions. entirely new value network, then the firm (customer)
will not be hurt by rejecting the technology. However,
4.1.1. Resource dependency as soon as we move away from this iron-clad pro-
Our study suggests that market structure may cause tectionist world, it is clear that the firm may be sub-
resource-dependent relationships. Thus, as market stantially damaged or in need of major restructuring.
structure varies, firm dependence varies. Resource This is due to the fact that if the customer’s market is
dependence theory has not explicitly examined the competitive, the technology will spread in any case to
relationship between market structure and firm depen- competing incumbent firms that have different capa-
dence. Christensen and Bower (1996), for example, bilities, or to new entrants. If the firm does not adopt
do not distinguish between resource dependence due the technology, it may be severely impaired. If the firm
to market structure and resource dependence due does adopt the new technology, it may find itself in
to over-reliance on a single customer in a competi- need of substantial restructuring. In this case, its own
tive market. Specifically, if one examines the lower suppliers will likely be harmed (Afuah and Bahram,
left corner of Fig. 1, market structure of suppliers 1995).
(competitive) versus customers (cooperative) ensures
that suppliers are dependent on customers. Likewise, 4.1.3. Supplier performance
the upper left dictates that there is a mutual depen- This leads to the next question. How do these sorts
dence between suppliers and customers. In the upper of contingent resource dependencies influence sup-
right, market structure dictates that customers will be plier performance when the innovation destroys cus-
resource-dependent upon suppliers. But in the lower tomer capabilities? We claim that resource dependency
right, suppliers may or may not be dependent upon that is not due to market structure (lower right corner
customers. If suppliers are dependent on customers in of Fig. 1) would hurt suppliers. The logic is as fol-
this quadrant, it is because they have over-invested in lows: if the innovation is competence-destroying, we
one customer when they had the option of maintaining can assume customers will tend to resist the change.
relations with more than one. However, as the customer is in a competitive market,
To use Afuah’s (2002) terminology, the customer either another incumbent with different capabilities or
may be “dominant” because of market structure rea- an entrant will accept the technology and the customer
sons (monopsonist or cartel), or the customer may be itself will be negatively affected, either severely weak-
dominant for other reasons (e.g. the customer hap- ened, destroyed, or restructured, thus directly hurting
pens to be important despite its position in a compet- the resource-dependent supplier. Afuah and Bahram
itive market). In a sense, we have overlain on top of (1995) make this argument by implicitly assuming a
our matrix another dimension: resource dependence; competitive customer market.
however, as resource dependence is partially deter- However, if we look at the lower left quadrant,
mined by market structure along the supply chain we we see the potential for the supplier, even though
A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554 1551

resource-dependent upon the customer, to be unaf- operating in a non-competitive market. These argu-
fected by the change. In this situation, the customer ments are consistent with Afuah’s (2002) findings on
rejects the technology as above. However, as the the development of supercomputer technology, even
customer itself is not in a competitive market, there though Afuah does not frame the argument explicitly
is little chance of the technology diffusing and the in terms of development versus adoption and again im-
customer being substantially hurt.4 This leads to our plicitly assumes a competitive customer base. These
first proposition. arguments are also consistent with King and Tucci’s
(2002) findings that incumbent suppliers of disk
Proposition 1a. Suppliers in a competitive market drives were quick to adopt new technology. Our
that are resource-dependent upon customers that oper- matrix suggests that most disk drive suppliers in
ate in a competitive market will be negatively affected the King and Tucci study had little resource depen-
by innovations that destroy customer capabilities. dency on customers (who were themselves in an
intensely competitive market). Thus, resource depen-
Proposition 1b. Suppliers in a competitive mar- dency in and of itself does not necessarily predict
ket that are resource-dependent upon tightly con- a firm’s innovative speed. However, once market
trolled cartelized or monopsonistic customers will structure is known, then resource dependence does
not be affected by innovations that destroy customer act as powerful predictor. In combination with mar-
capabilities. ket structure of both markets, it might be a better
predictor.
4.1.4. Supplier entry timing
In the previous section, we examined the incen- Proposition 2a. Suppliers that: (i) operate in a com-
tives for a supplier to adopt a competence-destroying petitive market; and (ii) are resource-dependent upon
innovation. Here, we examine how market structure customers operating in competitive markets will be
affects the speed of these innovations. Suppliers to slower to develop customer competence-destroying in-
market-dominant customers (cartel or monopsony, see novations than suppliers that: (i) operate in compet-
lower left corner of Fig. 1) know that the customer itive markets; and (ii) are not resource-dependent on
will not be harmed due to market competition. Con- a customer operating in competitive markets.
sequently, these suppliers, whether in competitive or
non-competitive markets, will develop new technol- Proposition 2b. Suppliers that: (i) operate in a
ogy as quickly as or quicker than suppliers providing competitive market; and (ii) are resource-dependent
goods to dominant customers in competitive markets. upon tightly-controlled cartelized or monopsonis-
If the dominant customer accepts the technology, the tic customers will be faster to develop customer
supplier can adopt the technology in a wholesale man- competence-destroying innovations than suppliers
ner, thus making a major commitment to it. In other that: (i) operate in a competitive market; and (ii)
words, the downside risk is limited. are resource-dependent on customers operating in
Contrast this situation to one in which the supplier competitive markets.
is dominated by a customer in a competitive market
(Fig. 1, lower right). In this case, development of rad-
4.2. Implications for military policy
ical technology has a negative downside risk that the
innovation may undo the supplier. Thus, the supplier
will be slower in both development and adoption of the When considering whether to promote inter-service
new technology than a supplier that serves a customer rivalry or Jointness, policy makers typically have ex-
amined the tradeoff between duplication costs and
flexibility. In making these calculations, policy mak-
4 Regarding the top row of the matrix in Fig. 1, in the upper
ers have relied on economies of scale, noting that
right corner suppliers are not dependent on customers. In the upper
left corner, where there is mutual dependence, it seems plausible
these follow business practices. However, policy mak-
that the innovation may not hurt the supplier based on the same ers have rarely asked whether Jointness promotes
logic as above. or squelches competence-destroying innovation. In
1552 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

attempting to answer this question, we too have made References


use of a market analogy, namely, creative destruction.
Our theory of supply chain market structure has Afuah, A., 2000. How much do your co-opetitors’ capabilities
categorized Jointness as a collusive activity dam- matter in the face of technological change? Strategic Mana-
gement Journal 21, 387–404.
aging to radical innovation. Jointness will certainly Afuah, A., 2002. Does a focal firm’s technology entry timing
bring about innovation, but it will be of an incremen- depend on the impact of the technology on co-opetitors?
tal sort, reinforcing established military hierarchies. Working Paper, University of Michigan Business School, MI.
In our estimation, policy makers need to add this Afuah, A.N., Bahram, K., 1995. The hypercube of innovation.
Research Policy 24, 51–76.
probable consequence when comparing Jointness and Alic, J.A., Branscomb, L.M., Brooks, H., Carter, A.B., Epstein,
inter-service rivalry. The cost savings inherent in G.L., 1992. Beyond Spinoff: Military and Commercial Techno-
Jointness may unwittingly sustain a military force un- logies in a Changing World. HBS Press, Boston.
ready for fighting the next war. This persistent status Anderson, P., Tushman, M.L., 1990. Technological discontinuities
and dominant designs: a cyclical model of technological change.
quo does not surprise military organization theorists
Administrative Science Quarterly 35, 604–633.
who contend that radical military innovation comes Anderson, P., Tushman, M.L., 1991. Managing through cycles of
infrequently and with great difficulty (Hundley, 1999). technological change. Research Management May/June, 26–31.
As in other bureaucratic regimes, these theorists iden- Buchanan, J.M., Tullock, G., 1962. The Calculus of Consent:
Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. The
tify elite decision-makers—in the military case, the
University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.
incumbent officer corps—as the principal obstruc- Casson, M., 1998. Information and Organization: A New Pers-
tion. They propose four factors that may undo this pective on the Theory of the Firm. Oxford University Press,
resistance: (1) a clear foreign threat that places the ex- New York.
Christensen, C.M., Bower, J., 1996. Customer power, strategic
isting military regime’s capabilities into question; (2)
investment, and the failure of leading firms. Strategic Mana-
intra-service rivalry in which a dormant officer corps gement Journal 17, 197–218.
aligns its future with a new weapon system that chal- Cohen, E., 2002. A tale of two secretaries. Foreign Affairs
lenges the established order; (3) civilian intervention 18 (May/June), 33–46.
Cohen, L., Noll, R., 1991. The Technology Pork Barrel. Brookings,
that overcomes incumbent officer corps interests; and
Washington, DC.
(4) inter-service rivalry over budgets during which Cooling, B.F., 1979. Gray Steel and Blue Navy Water: The
the services use new weapon systems to encroach on Formative Years of America’s Military–Industrial Complex
rival services’ missions and budgetary appropriations 1881–1917. Archon Books, Hamden.
Corey, E.R., 1997. Technology Fountainheads: The Management
(Posen, 1984; Rosen, 1994).
Challenge of R&D Consorita. Harvard Business School Press,
The first threat (a clear and present danger) has be- Boston.
come apparent since 11th September 2001, and it has Davis, V., 1967. The Politics of Innovation: Patterns in Navy
added to civilian calls for radical military innovation Cases. Monograph Series in World Affairs 4 (3), University of
(Rumsfeld, 2002; Cohen, 2002). As civilians act to Denver, Denver.
Dyer, J.H., Singh, H., 1998. The relational view: cooperative str-
overcome incumbent military interests, policy makers ategy and sources of inter-organizational competitive advantage.
must reevaluate whether the costs savings that Joint- Academy of Management Review 23, 660–679.
ness promises is worth the costs that it imposes on Ferguson, W., 1994. Economic incentives and the defense
those who wish to foster radical change. procurement process. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 8,
65–90.
Flamm, K., 1988. Creating the Computer: Government, Industry
and High Technology. Brookings, Washington, DC.
Acknowledgements Fransman, M., 1990. The Market and Beyond: Cooperation and
Competition in Information Technology in the Japanese System.
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
The authors thank Harvey Sapolsky and Engene Freeman, C., Soete, L., 1997. The Economics of Industrial
Gholz for many insights into military IR&D and thank Innovation. MIT Press, Cambridge.
the anonymous Research Policy referees for their help- Fusfeld, H., 1994. Industry’s Future. American Chemical Society,
ful suggestions. The authors acknowledge the support Washington, DC.
Grindley, P., Mowery, D.C., Silverman, B., 1994. ‘SEMATECH’
of the MIT Security Studies Program and the Berkley and collaborative research: lessons in the design of high-
Center for Entrepreneurial Studies at the NYU Stern technology consortia. Journal of Policy Analysis and Mana-
School of Business. gement 13, 723–758.
A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554 1553

Hardin, R., 1982. Collective Action. The Johns Hopkins University Mowery, D., Nelson, R.R., Sampat, B.N., Ziedonis, A.A.,
Press, Baltimore. 1999. The effects of the Bayh–Dole Act on US University
Hart, O., 1996. An economist’s perspective on the theory of the Research and Technology Transfer. In: Branscomb, L.M.,
firm. In: Buckley, B.J., Michie, J. (Eds.), Firms, Organizations Kodama, F., Florida, R. (Eds.), Industrializing Knowledge:
and Contracts: A Reader in Industrial Organization. Oxford University–Industry Links in Japan and the United States. MIT
University Press, Oxford, 1996, pp. 199–218. Press, Cambridge, MA, 1999.
Hayes, B., Smith, D. (Eds.), The Politics of Naval Innovation. Narin, F., Hamilton, K.S., Olivastro, D., 1997. The increasing
Research Report 4-94, Strategic Research Department, US linkage between US technology and public science. Research
Naval War College, US. Policy 26, 317–330.
Henderson, R.M., Clark, K.B., 1990. Architectural innovation: the Nelson, R.R., Wright, G., 1992. The rise and fall of Amer-
reconfiguration of existing product technologies and the failure ican technological leadership: the postwar era in historical
of established firms. Administrative Science Quarterly 35, 9–30. perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 30, 1931–1964.
Howells, J., 1997. Rethinking the market—technology relationship Niskanen, W.A., 1971. Bureaucracy & Representative Government.
for innovation. Research Policy 25, 1209–1219. Aldine-Atherton, Chicago.
Hughes, T., 1989. American Genesis: A Century of Innovation and Noteboom, B., 1999. Innovation and inter-firm linkages: new
Technological Enthusiasm 1870–1970. Penguin, New York. implications for policy. Research Policy 28, 793–805.
Hundley, R.O., 1999. Past Revolutions: Future Transformations. Olson, M., 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and
RAND, Santa Monica. the Theory of Groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge,
Johnson, R.N., Libecap, G.D., 1994. The Federal Civil Service MA.
System and the Problem of Bureaucracy: The Economics and Ouchi, W.G., Bolton, M., 1988. The logic of joint research and
Politics of Institutional Change. The University of Chicago development. California Management Review 30, 9–33.
Press, Chicago. Owens, M.T., 1997. The use and abuse of ‘Jointness’. Marine
Jones, W.D., 1999. Arming the Eagle: A History of US Weapons Corps Gazette November, 50–59.
Owens, M.T., 1998. Organizing: is the rush to ‘Jointness’ going
Acquisition Since 1775. Defense Systems Management College
off track? Armed Forces International June, 12–13.
Press, Fort Belvoir.
Peltzman, S., 1976. Toward a more general theory of regulation.
Kaufman, A., Englander, E.J., Marcus, A., 1993. Selecting an
Journal of Law and Economics 119, 211–240.
organizational structure for implementing issues management:
Pierce, T.C., 2001. Disguising Innovation. Unpublished disser-
a transaction costs and agency theory perspective. In: Mitnick,
tation, John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard
B.M. (Ed.), Corporate Political Agency: The Construction of
University, Harvard.
Competition in Public Affairs. Sage Publications, Newbury
Posen, B.R., 1984. The Sources of Military Doctrine: France,
Park, pp. 148–168.
Britain and Germany Between the Wars. Cornell University
Kaufman, A., Wood, C., Theyel, G., 2000. Collaboration and
Press, Ithaca.
technology linkages: a strategic supplier typology. Strategic
Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W., 1996. Interorganizational collaboration
Management Journal 21 (6), 649–663.
and the locus of innovation: networks of learning in
Kay, N.M., 1997. Pattern in Corporate Evolution. Oxford Univer-
biotechnology. Administrative Science Quarterly 41, 116–136.
sity Press, New York. Riker, W.H., 1982. Liberalism Against Populism: A Confrontation
Kelves, D.J., 1975. Scientists, the military, and the control of Between the Theory of Democracy and the Theory of Social
postwar defense research: the case of the research board for Choice. W.H. Freeman, San Francisco.
national security, 1944–1946. Technology & Culture 16 (1), Rosen, S.P., 1994. Winning the Next War: Innovation and the
20–47. Modern Military. Cornell University Press, Ithaca.
King, A., Tucci, C.L., 2002. Incumbent entry into new market Rumsfeld, D., 2002. Transforming the military. Foreign Affairs
niches: the role of experience and managerial choice in the 18 (May/June), 20–32.
creation of dynamic capabilities. Management Science 48 (2), Sandler, T., Harley, K., 1995. The Economics of Defense.
171–186. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Knight, F.H., 1921. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Houghton Mifflin, Sapolsky, H.M., 1972. The Polaris System Development:
Boston. Bureaucratic and Programmatic Success in Government.
Koppes, C.R., 1982. JPL and the American Space Program: A Harvard University Press, Cambridge.
History of the Jet Propulsion Laboratory. Yale University Press, Sapolsky, H.M., Gholz, E., Kaufman, A., 2000. Security lessons
New Haven. from the Cold War. Foreign Affairs 78, 77–89.
MacKenzie, D., 1993. Inventing Accuracy: A Historical Sociology Schattschneider, E.E., 1960. The Semisovereign People: A
of Nuclear Missile Guidance. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Realist’s View of Democracy in America. Holt, Rinehart and
Mowery, D., 1998. The changing structure of the US national Winston, New York.
innovation system: implications for international conflict and Scherer, F.M., 1964. The Weapons Acquisition Process: Economic
cooperation in R&D. Research Policy 27, 639–654. Incentives. Graduate School of Business Administration,
Mowery, D., Rosenberg, N., 1998. Paths of Innovation: Harvard University, Boston.
Technological Change in 20th Century America. Cambridge Schumpeter, J.A., 1934. The Theory of Economic Development.
University Press, Cambridge, UK. Harvard University Press, Cambridge.
1554 A. Kaufman et al. / Research Policy 32 (2003) 1537–1554

Simonin, B.L., 1999. Ambiguity and the process of knowledge Vander Meulen, J.A., 1991. The Politics of Aircraft: Building
transfer in strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal an American Military Industry. University of Kansas Press,
20, 595–624. Lawrence.
Smith, M.R., 1985. Military Enterprise and Technological Change: Van der Meulen, B., 1998. Science policies as principal–agent
Perspectives on the American System. MIT Press, Cambridge. games: institutionalization and path dependency in the relation
Spinaldi, G., 1994. From Polaris to Trident: The Development between government and science. Research Policy 27, 397–414.
of US Missile Fleet Technology. Cambridge University Press, Vincenti, W.G., 1990. What Engineers Know and How They
Cambridge. Know It: Analytic Studies from Aeronautical History. The Johns
Stigler, G.J., 1971. The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.
of Economics and Management Science 2, 3–21. von Hippel, E., 1988. The Sources of Innovation. Oxford
Stiglitz, J., 1997. Whither Socialism? MIT Press, Cambridge. University Press, New York.
Stiglitz, J.E., Wallsten, S.J., 1999. Public private technology von Hippel, E., 1998. Economics of product development by users:
partnerships. American Behavioral Scientist 43 (1), 52–73. the impact of “sticky” local information. Management Science
Utterback, J.M., 1994. Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation. 44, 629–644.
Harvard Business School Press, Boston. Vonortas, N.S., 1997. Cooperation in Research and Development.
Van Creveld, M., 1991. Technology and War: From 2000 b.c. to Kluwer, Boston.
the Present, A Revised and Expanded Edition. The Free Press, Williamson, O.E., 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism.
New York. The Free Press, New York.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen