Sie sind auf Seite 1von 44

The Dual Tracking Puzzle: When IPO Plans Turn into Mergers

Qin Lian* University of Alabama Department of Economics, Finance & Legal Studies Tuscaloosa, AL 35487-0224 Phone: 218-341-0217 E-mail: qlian@cba.ua.edu Qiming Wang FMIS Department, SBE 150 Labovitz School of Business & Economics University of Minnesota Duluth 412 Library Drive Duluth, MN 55812 Phone: 218-726-7083 Fax: 218-726-7517 E-mail: qwang@d.umn.edu

Current Version, March, 2007 First Draft, January, 2005


Keywords: Dual Tracking, IPO Withdrawal, Acquisition Discount, CARs JEL Classification: G14, G34, G39

*Corresponding author. The authors thank Anup Agrawal, James Ligon, Harris Schlesinger, and participants at the 2005 Financial Management Association International (FMA) meeting and the 2006 European Finance Association (EFA) meeting for their helpful comments.

Electronic copy of this paper is available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=899983

The Dual Tracking Puzzle: When IPO Plans Turn into Mergers

ABSTRACT

We examine a sample of 132 dual tracking targets private firms entertaining acquisition offers at the same time as preparing for initial public offerings (IPOs) and eventually withdrawing their IPOs to be acquired after spending considerable time, money, and effort preparing for IPOs. We find that dual tracking private targets sell at a 58 percent acquisition premium relative to comparable private targets that never file IPO registrations, while their acquirers still earn a substantial average abnormal announcement return of 2.6 percent. Controlling for endogeneity effects does not change our results. The significant acquisition premium is due to neither dual tracking targets improved bargaining power in negotiations nor higher potential synergistic benefits for bidders. The premium is more consistent with the explanation that dual tracking private targets can signal their valuation to bidders and reduce valuation uncertainty by filing IPO registrations.

1
Electronic copy of this paper is available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=899983

Investors in a private firm can cash out by either selling shares to investors in the initial public offering (IPO) market or selling the firm to a public firm in the merger and acquisition (M&A) market. By investigating whether an IPO or a takeover is eventually used by a private firm to turn public, Brau, Francis, and Kohers (2003) and Poulsen and Stegemoller (2007) suggest that private firms choose the IPO market instead of the M&A market as the pathway to access the public equity market when they 1) have higher growth opportunities and more capital constraint, 2) are easier to value, and 3) are in a relatively hot IPO market. However, by focusing only on which route is chosen eventually by a private firm, this literature overlooks possible connections between IPO and M&A markets for private firms planning to sell their assets in public equity markets. While most private firms do decide whether an IPO or a takeover is the appropriate pathway to public ownership from the get-go and pursue the strategy from the beginning, a subgroup of private firms, namely dual tracking firms, seems to pursue transactions in both IPO and M&A markets simultaneously.1 A dual tracking private firm files an IPO registration while also exploring opportunities to be acquired. The firm either successfully completes its IPO or withdraws from the IPO registration to be acquired. However, the firm rarely declares its intention to dual track both IPO and M&A markets. Due to limited disclosure, we cannot identify a dual tracking firm that succeeds in its IPO instead of being acquired or a dual tracking firm that is acquired by a private firm. Therefore, in this paper, we focus on dual tracking target firms withdrawn-IPO firms that are acquired by a public firm after

Zingales (1995) and Pagano, Pannetta, Zingales (1998) posit that an IPO is the initial step for

entrepreneurs to eventually sell their assets in takeovers.

withdrawing IPO registrations to study how IPO registrations affect their acquisition valuations. The choice to pursue dual tracking is puzzling. The IPO registration process is costly. Lee, Lochhead, Ritter, and Zhao (1996) document direct expenses (registration fee and printing; legal and auditing costs) of IPO registration at 3.69 percent of expected proceeds for IPOs from 1990 to 1994. Given that the median dual tracking private firm in our sample plans to raise $44 million in their IPO filings, the IPO registration cost is estimated to be $1.6 million. When a dual tracking private firm withdraws its IPO to be acquired, it essentially forfeits all the time, money, and effort spent on the registration process. So the ultimate question is, if a private firm sells itself to a public firm via a takeover, why does it file for an IPO and endure the additional costs of the IPO registration process in the first place? As the first attempt to shed light on the dual tracking puzzle, this paper investigates targets acquisition valuations and acquirers announcement returns for a sample of 132 dual tracking private firms between 1984 and 2004. First, we examine the effects of filing and withdrawing IPO registrations on private targets valuations in the M&A market. We compare the valuations of dual tracking private targets to those of three control samples: 1) pure private targets, 2) newly public targets, and 3) established public targets. Consistent with previous studies, we find that private targets sell at an acquisition discount of 10-20 percent relative to similar public targets. However, our results suggest that the acquisition discount of private targets mainly reflects the discount of pure private targets relative to both newly public and established public targets. We find that dual

tracking private targets receive valuation multiples comparable to those received by newly public targets. They also receive significantly higher valuation multiples than those received by the matched sample of established public targets. Most importantly, we find that, compared to pure private targets, dual tracking private targets sell at a significant acquisition valuation premium of 58 percent even after controlling for several valuation-related firm attributes. This result remains, after accounting for private firms self selection of the dual tracking path over a straight sale. Our results suggest that dual tracking private targets are willing to endure the additional costs of IPO registration because they will likely receive higher acquisition valuations than they otherwise would in takeovers. Then, the next question is how investors react in situations when buyers are willing to pay significant acquisition premiums relative to prices paid to acquire similar pure private targets. To answer this question, we compare average announcement period cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) for public firms that acquire dual tracking private targets to acquirers announcement returns for acquisitions of pure private targets. Recent studies show that acquirers experience positive average CARs when acquiring private targets and zero or negative average CARs when acquiring public targets. 2 Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) posit and Officer, Pouslen and Stegemoller (2006) show that the lower acquisition prices in acquisitions of private targets explain bidders superior CARs when acquiring private targets. Given that dual tracking private targets receive significant acquisition premiums relative to pure private targets and are sold at a price as if they were

See Chang (1998), Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002), Faccio, McConnell and Stolin (2006), Officer,

Poulsen and Stegemoller (2006), and others.

public, we would expect that acquirers CARs would be significantly lower when acquiring dual tracking private targets than when acquiring pure private targets. However, we find that acquirers still earn a significantly positive average CAR of 2.6 percent around the announcement of acquisitions of dual tracking private targets and a significantly positive average CAR of 2.65 percent around announcement of acquisitions of pure private targets. This difference in CARs is statistically insignificant, even after controlling for the size of the acquirer, the acquisition valuation ratio, the method of payment, and the relative size of the target. This finding suggests that other market participants agree with acquirers assessment of the valuations of dual tracking private targets and deem the average 58 percent acquisition premium paid for such targets to be justified. Finally, we explore three explanations for the higher acquisition premiums received by dual tracking private targets relative to pure private targets. We find no evidence to support the bargaining power hypothesis that dual tracking targets use the IPO filing, thus increasing their visibility and generating an outside option, to improve their bargaining power to negotiate higher prices. The median (mean) numbers of bidders for dual tracking and pure private targets are same. Acquisition premiums relative to pure private targets for dual-tracking targets are not different between dual-tracking firms that withdraw IPOs before acquisition announcements and those withdrawing IPOs after announcements. We also find little evidence to support the argument that dual tracking targets receive higher acquisition premiums due to higher synergistic benefits for potential bidders. Information disseminated via the IPO process might lead to acquirers that have greater potential synergies from acquisitions. Therefore, acquirers are willing to

pay premiums for withdrawn-IPO firms. The post-acquisition long-run stock performances for acquirers of dual tracking targets are no better than those for acquirers of pure private targets. Another potential explanation for the higher premium is the lower valuation uncertainty hypothesis. Fulfilling the SEC registration requirement reduces valuation uncertainty surrounding those private targets through more and better information disclosure. And the book-building process generates information on investors demand and on valuations for those targets. This argument implies that private firms that are difficult to value, such as firms with high growth potentials, are more likely to take the dual tracking route. Consistent with this implication, we find that private firms with higher growth rates, higher R&D costs, and lower profits are more likely to dual track both IPO and M&A markets. In other words, private targets with higher valuation uncertainty are more likely to use IPO filings, though costly, to reduce their valuation uncertainty and subsequently increase their acquisition prices relative to comparable pure private targets. Our results on acquisition valuation of various private and public targets contribute to the previous studies on acquisition discount received by private targets. Koeplin, Sarin, and Shapiro (1996) and Officer (2007) document that private targets are acquired at an average 15-30 percent discount relative to similar public targets. Our paper extends the previous studies by not only considering the impact of targets listing status, private or public, on their acquisition valuations, but also finding that by dual tracking both IPO and M&A markets, private targets that withdraw their IPOs command similar valuation ratios

as public targets and significantly higher acquisition valuation ratios than other comparable pure private targets do. Our paper also contributes to the IPO withdrawal literature. Busaba (2006) and Busaba, Benveniste, and Guo (2001) argue that IPO withdrawals can be a valuable option for issuers to solicit the true information from investors in the book-building process. Dunbar and Foerster (2007) and Lian (2007) find that 9% of withdrawn IPOs are able to return to the IPO market successfully. This paper adds to the IPO withdrawals literature by examining dual tracking firms that are acquired after IPO withdrawals, an alternative of withdrawn IPOs, and provides evidence that withdrawals are valuable options for issuers by showing that 9% of withdrawn IPOs are acquired in M&A market shortly after withdrawals and at a significant premium to other pure private targets. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section I describes our data and presents sample descriptive statistics. Section II examines the acquisition valuation ratios, and Section III investigates acquirers returns around the announcement period. Section IV addresses concerns on selection bias, and Section V examines three explanations for the higher acquisition premium for dual tracking private targets. Section VI concludes.

I. Sample Selection and Data Description A. Sample and Data Sources Our primary data sources are the Global New Issues Database and the Merger and Acquisition Database from the Securities Data Corporation (SDC). Our sample includes acquisitions over the period January 1, 1984 July 25, 2004.3

We use 1984 as the beginning point because SDC started IPO withdrawal coverage that year.

We first extract a list of IPO withdrawals, firms that file an IPO registration but later withdraw, from the Global New Issues Database. From the Merger and Acquisition Database, we construct a takeover sample that contains completed deals involving 100 percent acquisitions of U.S. private firms by U.S. publicly traded acquirers. Using 6-digit CUSIPs to match the withdrawn-IPO list and the takeover list, we identify a sample of dual tracking private targets. After verifying the accuracy of matching, using SEC filings from the SEC Edgar database and the Lexis-Nexis Academic database, we obtain a sample of 150 dual tracking private targets that announce their acquisitions within three years of their initial filing dates. Following a similar procedure, we also construct a sample of 507 newly public targets that have completed their IPOs and announce their acquisitions within three years of their IPO dates. [INSERT TABLE I] Panel A of Table I reports IPO completion and withdrawal activities, as well as subsequent takeover activities for withdrawn IPOs and newly public firms by year. During the sample period, 1,652 firms (around 20 percent of all IPO filings) withdraw their IPOs. Of those IPO withdrawals, 150 (9 percent) are acquired by public bidders within three years of their IPO registrations. About two-thirds of our sample of acquisitions of dual tracking firms occurs during the late 1990s. Of the successful IPOs, 507 (8 percent) are acquired within three years of their IPO dates. Panel B of Table I summarizes IPO and takeover activities by industry. We follow the industry classifications used in Busaba, Benveniste, and Guos (2001) study of IPO withdrawal

options. 4 Dual tracking targets and newly public targets are widely distributed across industries the service sector has the most dual tracking targets and newly public targets. [INSERT FIGURE 1] Figure 1 shows the distribution of the number of days between IPO filing and announcement of acquisition for dual tracking private targets and the number of days between IPO date and announcement of acquisition for newly public targets. In the dual tracking private target sample, the average (median) number of days from the IPO registration filing date to the takeover announcement date is 376 (294) days. However, the average (median) number of days for the newly public target sample is 611 (625) days after its IPO date. Sixty-four firms announce their acquisition before they formally file an IPO withdrawal form with the SEC.5 Approximately 25 percent of the targets that withdraw their IPOs are acquired within 115 days of their IPO registrations, but merely 5 percent of newly public firms are acquired within 115 days of their IPO date. Dual tracking firms shorter average time from IPO registration to takeover suggests that a potential acquisition drives some of these firms to withdraw their scheduled offerings. Three control samples are constructed as following. For each dual tracking private target we find an acquisition of a comparable pure private target, newly public target, and established public target (a firm that has been public for more than three years).

We add the financial industry (two-digit primary SIC codes: 60-69), which is excluded in Busaba,

Benveniste, and Guo (2001).


5

These 64 firms that are acquired before their formal IPO withdrawals truly dual track IPO and M&A

markets simultaneously

Comparable targets are in the same two-digit primary SIC code industry6, have the same acquisition payment method (stock or cash or combination of stock and cash), are announced within a 90 calendar-day window around the announcement of the acquisition of the dual tracking private target, and have the closest deal value among acquisitions that meet the first three conditions. We collect financial data for newly public targets and established targets from COMPUSTAT if available and from the SDC database otherwise. For dual tracking private targets, we try to obtain financial data from SEC filings by their acquirers7 if available and from the SDC database otherwise. We use the SDC database to obtain financials for pure private targets. In the final sample, we include only those dual tracking private targets with available deal values and financial information for the fiscal year preceding the takeover, and those acquirers that are covered by CRSP over the event period. Our final sample includes 132 dual tracking private targets, a matched sample of pure private targets, a matched sample of newly public targets, and a matched sample of established public targets. [INSERT TABLE II]

Like Officer (2007), we use this comparable industry transaction method to compare acquisition

valuation differences between private targets and public targets, as suggested by Kaplan and Ruback (1995)
7

Securities regulations require that public acquirers disclose financials of targets of takeovers that have

material impact (acquisitions in which that deal value is more than 10% of the acquirers total assets) in their SEC filings, including S4, 8K, Proxy, or S1 filings. We obtain the financials of private targets acquired through the SEC Edgar, 10K Wizard, and LexisNexis databases. See Fuller, Netter and Stegemoller (2002) for details and we thank Mike Stegemoller for point out this data sources for private targets.

10

B. Sample Characteristics Table II reports attributes for acquisitions of dual tracking private targets, pure private targets, newly public targets, and established public targets. Panel A presents the characteristics of takeover deals and acquirers. The first three rows show that: 1) deal value, acquirers size (measured as the market value of equity one month prior to the acquisition announcement), and target-to-acquirer relative size (measured as deal value divided by the acquirers size) for acquisitions of private targets are significantly lower than those for acquisitions of public targets; 2) and acquisitions of dual tracking private targets, on average, have a higher deal value and larger acquirer, but with lower relative target-to-acquirer size, than acquisitions of pure private targets do. The last two rows show that: 1) acquirers, on average, use more stock and less cash as acquisition currencies when purchasing public targets than when purchasing private targets; 2) and only in acquisitions of pure private targets, cash is the dominant payment method with fraction of cash payment at mean (median) of 50% (53%) and fraction of stock payment at mean (median) of 41% (20%); 3) and with fraction of cash payment at mean (median) of 33% (5%) and fraction of stock payment at mean (median) of 56% (76%), payment methods in acquisitions of dual tracking private targets seems more like that in acquisitions of newly public targets and established public targets. Panel B describes targets sales, sales growth over the takeover year, OPA (defined as EBITDA divided by total assets), OPS (defined as EBITDA divided by sales), leverage (defined as the total debt divided by total assets), and R&D (defined as research and development expenses divided by total assets). As shown in Panel B, dual tracking private targets are smaller, as measured by sales, than newly public and established

11

public targets, but larger than pure private targets. Dual tracking private targets, on average, have significantly higher sales growth, use more financial leverage, and spend more on research and development (R&D) than all other comparable targets do. However, on average, dual tracking targets have poorer operating performance, as measured by OPA and OPS.8

II. Acquisition Valuations of Dual Tracking Private Targets In this section, we examine the acquisition valuation difference between dual tracking private targets and other targets, including pure private targets, newly public targets, and established public targets. Section A deals with results of univariate analyses and Section B discusses results of multivariate tests where other determinants of valuations are controlled for. [INSERT TABLE III] A. Univariate Comparisons of Acquisition Multiples Following Officer (2007), we use three different acquisition multiples: deal value to sales, deal value to book value of equity, and deal value to EBITDA to compare acquisition valuations of different types of targets.9 Table III reports mean and median acquisition valuation multiples for dual tracking private targets and three samples of
8

We also compare firm attributes of dual tracking private targets and newly public targets at the time of

their initial IPO filings. The unreported results are similar to those presented in Panel B of Table 2.
9

Officer (2007) uses the average of percentage differences in four acquisition valuation multiples of private

targets relative to public targets as the acquisition discount/premium for private targets. We do not use price to earnings, the fourth acquisition multiple used by Officer (2007) to derive average acquisition discount, because including price to earnings reduces size of dual tracking private targets by more than 70%.

12

comparable targets. The mean and median values of the three acquisition multiples show similar patterns. Because of extreme outliers in the right-hand tail for all the multiples, we focus on the median values in the following discussions. As shown in Table III, two of the three valuation multiples in acquisitions of dual tracking private targets are significantly higher than those in acquisitions of pure private targets. Acquirers typically pay $2.99 for each dollar in sales for dual tracking private targets. This amount is 63 percent higher than the $1.8410 per dollar in sales paid for pure private targets. Acquirers, on average, pay $14.07 per dollar in book value for dual tracking private targets, and this figure is 58 percent higher than the $8.88 per dollar in book value paid for pure private targets. The deal value to EBITDA in acquisitions of dual tracking targets is 12.86, which is similar to the 12.79 multiple in acquisitions of pure private targets. Averaging the difference in these acquisition multiples, we find that dual tracking private targets sell at a significant 41 percent premium relative to comparable pure private targets in takeovers by public acquirers. As also shown in Table III, on average, dual tracking private targets generally receive similar valuation multiples compared to newly public targets, but they receive higher valuation multiples compared to established public targets. However, pure private targets sell at lower acquisition multiples compared to both newly public targets and established public targets. This pattern suggests that the private target acquisition discount documented in Koeplin, Sarin, and Shapiro (1996) and Officer (2007) is driven by lower acquisition valuations of pure private targets. Using deal value/sales, which is not

10

This number is similar to Officers (2007) results that stand-alone unlisted target firms, including all

private targets, have a typical 1.85 deal valuation ratio on sales.

13

truncated, unlike deal value/book value and deal value/EBITDA, we find that, compared to matched public targets, dual tracking private targets sell at an insignificant 9 percent premium and pure private targets sell at a significant 32% discount. Following Officer (2007), after discarding all observations with the percentage difference in valuation multiples between the private target and the matched public target that is higher than +1 to adjust for extreme outliers, we find, based on average of three valuation multiples, compared to similar public targets, dual tracking private targets sell at insignificant 3 percent premium and pure private targets sell at significant 21 percent discount. B. Multivariate Analyses Our univariate analyses show that, by filing for IPOs and then withdrawing to be acquired, dual tracking private targets sell at a 41 percent premium relative to pure private targets in takeovers by public acquirers. We next perform multivariate analyses to determine whether the premium persists when we control for a panel of valuation-related independent variables. B.1 Regression Setup The dependent variable in our regression is the natural logarithm of acquisition valuation multiple.11 As for independent variables, we include a dummy for whether the target is a pure private /newly public/established public firm (1) or a dual tracking private target (0), a dummy for whether payment is made in stock (1) or not (0), and a dummy for whether payment is a combination of stock and cash (1) or not (0).

11

Due to skewness of valuation rations, we use natural logarithm transformation of valuation multiples in

all regressions. Our results still hold if we winsorize valuation multiples at top and bottom using 1% and 2% thresholds.

14

Bhojraj and Lee (2002) develop a systematic approach for pricing private firms on the basis of profitability, growth, and risk characteristics. They show that their valuation method accommodates both the general universe of firms as well as a sub-population of new-economy firms.12 Therefore, we also include as control variables factors Bhojraj and Lee (2002) find to be related to firms valuations. We include as control variables: INDVS (industry enterprise value to sales), the harmonic mean of the enterprise value-to-sales multiple for all firms within the same two-digit SIC code at the transaction year13; and INDPB (industry enterprise value to book value), the harmonic mean of the industry price-to-book (PB) ratio; and INDVE (industry enterprise value to EBITDA), the harmonic mean of the industry price-toEBITDA ratio. valuation factors. Bhojraj and Lee (2002) show that: 1) the more profitable a firm is relative to its industry, the higher the valuation, and 2) valuations are less responsive to negative earnings the negative valuation impact of the dollar loss per dollar of total assets is smaller than the positive valuation impact of the dollar profit per dollar of total assets. Therefore, using profit margin (OPA), defined as EBITDA divided by total assets, as our proxy for profitability, we include as independent variables the Industry-adjusted OPA,
12

We choose INDVS, INDPB, and INDVE to account for industry

New economy firms refer to those loss firms especially among the tech, biotech, and telecommunication

industries. These firms always report negative earnings.


13

The harmonic mean is the inverse of the average of the inversed valuation multiples. Baker and Ruback

(1999) have suggested that the harmonic mean leads to the minimum variance estimates for an industry valuation multiple. Enterprise value is defined as the sum of market capitalization of equity and book value of debt.

15

defined as the difference between a targets OPA and the median of the OPA of the firms within the same two-digit SIC code, and Loss*industry-adjusted OPA, where Loss is a dummy for whether OPA is negative (1) or positive (0). Finally, we also use LEV, the financial leverage proxy defined as total debt divided by total assets;14 R&D, the fraction of R&D expenses in total assets; and Growth, the sale growth for the takeover year, as additional control variables. [INSERT TABLE IV] B.2 Regression Results Table IV reports OLS estimates of regression models of three acquisition valuation multiples: deal value/sales, deal value/book value, and deal value/EBITDA. Regressions in columns 1, 4, and 7 of Table IV are estimated for dual tracking private targets and matched pure private targets. In column 1, the natural logarithm of deal value/sales is the dependent variable. The coefficients of INDVS and Industry-adjusted OPA are significantly positive, while the coefficient of Loss*industry-adjusted OPA is significantly negative. Consistent with the results of Bhojraj and Lee (2002), target firms from industries with higher valuation receive higher prices in acquisition. Target firms acquisition valuations are also less responsive to negative earnings than to positive earnings. Consistent with the notion that high growth should be positively correlated with firm value; the coefficient of Growth is positive and significant. Most importantly, for the purpose of this study, consistent with our univariate test, dual tracking private targets are acquired at significantly higher valuations than matched

14

Officer (2007) argues that leverage is a proxy for liquidity constraint and documents that leverage ratio is

positively correlated with private target acquisition discount relative to similar public targets.

16

pure private targets even after controlling for other determinants of valuations. The coefficient of pure private target dummy is negative and statistically significant at -0.46. The magnitude implies that dual tracking private targets sell at a 58 percent15 premium, measured by deal value to sales, relative to comparable pure private targets in acquisitions, after controlling for other determinants of valuations. Given that dual tracking private targets have sales of $34 million (median) and are valued at deal value/sales of 2.99 (median), they would receive $37 million ($34*2.99 - $34*2.99/1.58) less if they were not dual tracking and therefore were valued as pure private targets in acquisitions. The increases in acquisition valuations from filing IPO registrations are more than enough to compensate for approximate $1.6 million direct expenses related to IPO filing (Lee et al. (1996) document that direct expenses of IPO registration is 4% of expected proceeds for IPO. The median dual tracking target firm in our sample plans to raise $44 million in their IPO filings. This number is not reported in the table). The regressions in columns 4 and 7 are similar to those in column 1 except that the natural logarithm of deal value/book value (deal value/EBITDA) is the dependent variable in column 4 (7) and INDPB (INDVE) instead of INDVS is used as the independent variable in column 4 (7) to control for industry valuation. Results on other control variables are similar to those reported in column 1. Most importantly, the pure private target dummy is negative though insignificant in both columns 4 and 7. The regressions in columns 2, 5, and 8 of Table IV are estimated for dual tracking private targets and newly public targets, and the regressions in columns 3, 6, and 9 are

15

From the coefficient estimates of -0.46, reversing the log transformation on deal value/sales, we find deal

value/sales for dual tracking private targets are 58% (e0.46 - 1) higher than that for pure private targets.

17

estimated for dual tracking private targets and established public targets. In column 5, we find dual tracking targets receive a significantly higher acquisition multiple in deal value to book value of equity than matching publicly-traded targets, which is consistent with Officers (2007) finding that price to book value of equity shows higher average premiums for unlisted targets than publicly-traded targets. This may simply reflect that public firms tend to have more equity financing than private firms. In general, our multivariate results are consistent with univariate tests. Dual tracking private targets sell at valuation multiples comparable to newly public targets and at higher valuation multiples than established targets; however, pure private targets sell at a discount in acquisitions relative to both newly public targets and established public targets.

III. Acquirers Announcement Period Returns To investigate how other market participants respond to acquisitions of dual tracking private targets, in which acquirers clearly pay a significant premium relative to the price paid for similar pure private targets, we study stock price reactions of public acquirers when acquisitions are announced. We use the standard event study methodology by calculating CARs for the three-day period (-1, +1) around the announcement. We

estimate the abnormal return on stock i over day t using the market-adjusted model;
ARit = rit rmt ,

where rit and rmt are the returns for stock i and the market portfolio m

(CRSPs equal-weighted NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ index) on day t. The cumulative abnormal return for firm i over days (-1, +1) around the announcement date (day 0) is measured as CAR i1, +1 = ARit .
t = 1 +1

[INSERT TABLE V] 18

Table V tabulates acquirers mean and median 3-day CARs for dual tracking private targets, pure private targets, newly public targets, and established public targets, grouped by the method of payment. Largely consistent with prior studies findings that listing status determines announcement returns, the CARs of acquirers purchasing public targets are negative and significant, while the CARs of acquirers purchasing private target are positive and significant. Despite paying significantly higher price for dual tracking private targets, acquirers of dual tracking private targets still earn a significant average abnormal announcement return of 2.6 percent, which is not significantly different from 2.65 percent abnormal announcement return earned by acquirers of pure private targets. Further, regardless of the payment method, acquirers CARs in acquisitions of dual tracking private targets are positive and not significantly different from those in acquisitions of pure private targets. However, Table V shows that acquirers earn positive but insignificant announcement returns with stock payments when purchasing dual tracking private and pure private targets. The announcement returns with cash payments are significantly positive when purchasing pure private targets. These results are different from that reported by Chang (1998) and Fuller, Netter, and Stegemoller (2002), whose studies show that acquirers experience higher stock returns when buying private targets with stock than with cash. [INSERT TABLE VI] Table VI reports multivariate analyses for acquirers CARs to control for other factors. The dependent variable in our regressions is the cumulative abnormal return CAR over days (-1, +1) around the announcement. We include as independent variables factors found to explain acquirers announcement returns in prior studies. Regressions in Models

19

1, 2, and 3 of Table VI are estimated with dual tracking private and pure private targets, dual tracking private and newly public targets, and dual tracking private and established public targets, respectively. Bradley, Desai, and Kim (1983); Jarrell and Poulsen (1989); Servaes (1991); and others document that the target size relative to the acquirer size is positively correlated with the acquirers CAR. To control for this factor, we include relative size, measured as deal value divided by the market value of the acquirer one month before deal announcement. Fuller, Netter, Stegemoller (2002) find that a private (public) targets size relative to acquirers size is positively (negatively) correlated with the acquirers return at the takeover announcement. To control for the different effects of the relative size on the acquirers announcement return in acquisitions of different types of targets, we also include three interaction terms between the relative size and the dummy variable indicating a targets type. Consistent with other studies, the coefficients of relative size are positive and significant in our three regression models. We also find the positive (negative) relationship between the relative size of acquisition and acquirers announcement return for acquisitions of private firms (public firms). Following Fuller, Netter, and Stegemoller (2002) and Faccio, McConnell, and Stolin (2006), to control for the impact of the method of payment on acquirers CARs, we also include a dummy for whether the payment is stock (1) or not (0), and a dummy variable for whether payment is a mix of stock and cash (1) or not (0). The coefficients of stock payment dummy and mixed payment dummy are not significant in our three regression models. This result differs from other studies, which document that acquirers earn

20

significantly higher announcement returns when buying private targets with stock rather than with cash. Maquiera, Megginson, and Nail (1998) report that acquirers announcement returns are higher in within-industry acquisitions. We also include a dummy for whether the target and the acquirer have the same two-digit SIC code (1) or not (0). Neither of the coefficients of the same industry dummy is significant in our regressions; this result is similar to Faccio, McConnell, and Stolin (2006). Officer, Poulsen, and Stegemoller (2006) document that the acquisition discount is positively correlated to bidders CARs when acquiring private targets. We include one of the acquisition multiples, deal value/sales16, to control for this factor. The coefficients of deal value/sales are negative but not significant at 5% in our three regressions. Most importantly, the coefficient of the pure private dummy in Model 1 is not significant. This finding suggests that acquirers of dual tracking private targets earn the similar abnormal announcement returns as those earned by acquirers of pure private targets even after controlling for other factors such as higher prices paid for dual tracking private targets.

IV. Selection Bias Adjustments It is necessary to account for the fact that the firm decision to file an IPO registration before its acquisition is endogenous, and is dependent on firm characteristics. Failure to adjust for this potential endogeniety might result in inconsistent and biased estimates of

16

Using deal value/book value or deal value/EBITDA reduces our sample size by more than half and

produces qualitatively similar results.

21

the effect of dual tracking on acquisition valuation ratios in Section II. To address this selection bias concern, we use the two-step estimation procedure (see Heckman (1979) and Lee, Maddala, and Trost (1980)). The first-step Probit model estimates the probability of choosing the dual tracking strategy conditional on a set of private firm characteristics. In the second-step linear regression on acquisition valuation ratios, we add Lambda, the inverse Mills ratio, from the first-step Probit model estimation as a control variable, with the control variables used in Section II. [INSERT TABLE VII] The Model 1 of Table VII reports the coefficient estimates along with marginal effects calculated at the mean of each control variable for the first-step Probit model with the dependent variable, Dual Tracking (which equals one for dual tracking private targets and zero for pure private targets). We base this Probit model on prior work on a private firms choice of going public through IPO markets or M&A markets. Specifically, Brau, Francis, and Kohers (2003) and Poulsen and Stegemoller (2007) show that private firms choose the IPO market instead of the M&A market when they have higher growth opportunities and more capital constraint. Therefore, our Probit model includes Growth, LEV, R&D, and Industry-adjusted OPA as control variables to analyze determinants of a private firms decision of dual tracking. The Model 1 of Table VII shows that private firms with high sales growth and R&D costs are more likely to dual track. Private firms that are more profitable than their industry peers are less likely to file for IPOs before being acquired and leverage does not affect the dual tracking decision. This result suggests that private firms with high growth potential and less profitability, which are

22

inherently difficult to be valued accurately, are more likely to use IPO processes to release information to potential bidders. For the second-step model on acquisition valuation ratios, the inverse Mills ratios from the first-step Probit estimation are insignificant except for in Model 2. The estimates in Models 2, 3, and 4 of Table VII are very similar to those reported in Table IV. In summary, our results that dual tracking private targets receive higher acquisition valuations relative to pure private targets still hold after controlling for private firms choices of filing for IPOs.

V. Why Does IPO Filing Improve Dual Tracking Targets Acquisition Valuations In this section we investigate three possible explanations for dual tracking targets acquisition premium relative to pure private targets. The bargaining power hypothesis postulates that dual tracking firms use the IPO filing to improve their bargaining power in negotiation with acquirers to receive better valuations. The synergy benefits hypothesis argue that a private firm, seeking capital to expand, may initiate an IPO and then be approached by an acquirer offering a higher valuation owing to potential synergies. The lower valuation uncertainty posits that IPO filing can reduce valuation uncertainty. Therefore, bidders are willing to pay higher prices for dual tracking targets than for pure private targets. A. Bargaining Power IPO filing may improve a dual tracking targets bargaining power in two ways. First, filing IPO can improve a private firms visibility and therefore increase the number of potential bidders. Inconsistent with this argument, the median (mean) number of bidders

23

for 127 dual tracking targets with information available is one and it is no different from that of their matched pure private targets. [INSERT TABLE VIII] Second, investors in the IPO market can be viewed as another bidder; therefore, IPO filing generates an outside option for a dual tracking target. This argument implies that dual tracking firms that announce their acquisitions after they have withdrawn IPO registrations would have acquisition valuations similar to pure private targets since the IPO market is no longer an implicit bidder for those dual tracking firms. To test this implication, we separate dual tracking private target firms into two groups: 1) acquisitions announced before IPO withdrawals, referred as strong dual tracking, and 2) acquisitions announced after IPO withdrawals, as weak dual tracking. Table VIII reports acquisition multiple comparisons for both groups. The results are similar to those reported in Table III for both strong dual tracking and weak dual tracking firms. That is, dual tracking private targets are acquired at a significant acquisition premium to other pure private targets, regardless of timing of acquisitions. However, the magnitudes of acquisition multiples for the strong dual trakcing firms are larger than those for the weak dual tracking firms in Table VIII. We repeat regression analyses in Tables IV and VII with the dummy variable Strong Dual Tracking indicating the timing of acquisitions. The coefficients for Strong Dual Tracking are not significant (results not reported, available at request). Overall, we do not find supporting evidence for the bargaining power hypothesis.

24

B. Synergistic Benefits The thick registration statement gives a potential buyer the information to do initial due diligence on the target firm. This information disseminated via the IPO process might lead to acquirers that have greater synergies from acquisitions. Hence, acquirers are willing to pay higher prices for dual tracking targets. Then we would expect acquirers of dual tracking firms to have better long-run performance after acquisitions than acquirers of comparable pure private firms. To test this implication, we compare the average abnormal return (AR) for acquirers of dual tracking targets and that for acquirers of pure private targets up to three years after acquisitions. For each acquirer, over the month t relative to the month of acquisition announcement, we compute AR as the intercept of a time-series of regression of its monthly stock returns on Fama and French three factors and momentum factors (See Fama and French (1993) and Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) for details). [INSERT TABLE IX] Table IX presents the mean and median of ARs for the acquirers of dual tracking targets and the acquirers of pure private targets. None of the difference in ARs between acquirers of dual tracking and of pure private targets is significantly different from zero up to three years after deals. Therefore, there is little evidence of the synergy benefits hypothesis. C. Lower Valuation Uncertainty The information asymmetry problem between an acquirer and a private target is more severe than the problem between an acquirer and a public target because private firms generally have less information available and lower information disclosure

25

standards. By fulfilling the SEC registration requirement, a dual tracking private target releases more information and sends signals to potential bidders. Furthermore, book building process generates information on investors demand and valuation for the target share. Hence, dual tracking firms receive a better acquisition price by reducing valuation uncertainty and information asymmetry. One implication of the lower valuation uncertainty hypothesis is that private targets that are more difficult to value thus with higher valuation uncertainty are more likely to choose filing for IPO before being acquired. We find that, consistent with this implication, 1) Panel B of Table II shows that, compared to pure private targets, dual tracking targets tend to have higher valuation uncertainty due to higher growth rate, higher R&D costs, and lower profitability before acquisitions; 2) Estimations of the first-step Probit model from Table VII show that private targets with higher growth rates in sales, higher R&D expenses, and lower profits are more likely to take dual tracking route.

VI. Concluding Remarks This study examines the dual tracking puzzle by investigating a sample of 132 private firms that withdraw their IPOs to be acquired by public bidders between 1984 and 2004. We find that such dual tracking private targets sell at a 58 percent acquisition premium relative to comparable pure private targets that never file IPO registrations. This finding suggests that acquirers are willing to value these almost public targets as similar to public targets and to pay more for such dual tracking private targets than for similar pure private targets.

26

The significant acquisition premium is not due to dual tracking targets improved bargaining power in negotiations nor higher potential synergistic benefits for bidders. The acquisition premium is more consistent with the explanation that IPO filing can reduce valuation uncertainty of those dual tracking private targets. We also document that, despite paying significantly higher prices for dual tracking private targets, acquirers of such targets still earn a significant average abnormal announcement return of about 2.6 percent, which is not significantly different from the 2.7 percent abnormal announcement return earned by acquirers of pure private targets. This finding suggests that investors agree with acquirers valuation assessments for dual tracking private targets and deem the 58 percent acquisition premium paid for private targets that file for an IPO relative to the prices paid for pure private targets that never file for IPO to be justified.

27

REFERENCES Baker, Malcolm, and Richard S. Ruback, 1999, Estimating industry multiples, Harvard University . Working Paper. Bradley, Michael, Anand Desai, and E. Han Kim, 1983, The rationale behind interfirm tender offers: Information or synergy? Journal of Financial Economics 11, 183-206. Bhojraj, Sanjeev and Charles M. C. Lee, 2002, Who is my peer? A valuation-based approach to the selection of comparable firms, Journal of Accounting Research 40, 407-439. Brau, James C, Bill Francis, and Ninon Kohers, 2003, The choice of IPO versus takeover: Empirical evidence, Journal of Business 76, 583-612. Busaba, Walid Y., 2006, Bookbuilding, the option to withdrawn, and the timing of IPOs, Journal of Corporate Finance 12, 159-186. Busaba, Walid Y., Lawrence M. Benveniste, and Re-jin Guo, 2001, The option to withdraw IPOs during the premarket: Empirical analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 60, 73-102. Chang, Saeyoung, 1998, Takeovers of privately held targets, methods of payment, and bidder returns, Journal of Finance 53, 773-784. Dunbar, C., and S. Foerster, 2007, Second Time Lucky? Withdrawn IPOs that Return to the Market, Journal of Financial Economics (Forthcoming). Faccio, Mara, John J. McConnell, and David Stolin, 2006, Returns to acquirers of listed and unlisted targets, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41, 197-220. Fama, E. F. and K. R. French., 1993, Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56.

28

Fuller, Kathleen, Jeffry Netter, and Mike Stegemoller, 2002, What do returns to acquiring firms tell us? Evidence from firms make many acquisitions, Journal of Finance 57, 1763-1793. Heckman, James J., 1979, Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error, Econometrica 47, 153-161. Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman, 1993, Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency, Journal of Finance 48, 65-91. Jarrell, Gregg A., and Annette B. Poulsen, 1989, The return to acquiring firms in tender offers: Evidence from three decades, Financial Management 18, 12-19. Koeplin, John, Atulya Sarin, and Alan C. Shapiro, 1996, The private company discount, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 12, 94-101. Lian, Qin, 2007, Does the Market Incorporate Previous IPO Withdrawals When Pricing Second-time IPOs? University of Alabama.Working Paper. Lee, Inmoo, Scott Lochhead, Jay R. Ritter, and Quanshui Zhao, 1996, The costs of raising capital, Journal of Financial Research 19, 59-74. Lee, Lung-Fei, G.S. Maddala, and R.P. Trost, 1980, Asymptotic Covariance Matrices of Two-stage Probit and Two-stage Tobit Methods for Simultaneous Equation Models with Selectivity, Econometrica 48, 491-503. Maquieira, Carlos P., William L. Megginson, and Lance Nail, 1998, Wealth creation versus wealth redistributions in pure stock-for-stock mergers, Journal of Financial Economics 48, 3-33. Officer, Micah S., 2007, The price of corporate liquidity: acquisition discounts for unlisted targets, Journal of Financial Economics (Forthcoming).

29

Officer, Micah S., Annette B. Poulsen, and Mike Stegemoller, 2006, Information asymmetry and acquirer returns, University of Southern California. Working Paper. Pagano, M., F. Pannetta, and L. Zingales, 1998, Why do Companies Go Public? An Empirical Analysis, Journal of Finance 53, 27-64. Poulsen, Annette and Mike Stegemoller, 2007, Moving from private to public ownership: Selling out to public firms vs. initial public offerings, Financial Management (Forthcoming). Servaes, Henri, 1991, Tobins Q and the gains from takeovers, Journal of Finance 46, 409-419. Zingales, Luigi, 1995, Insider ownership and the decision to go public, Review of Economics Studies 62, 425-448.

30

Table I Frequency Distribution of IPO Filings and Subsequent Takeovers


This table reports the annual incidence and industry representation of firms filing IPOs and their subsequent takeovers. The sample comes from the SDC New Issues Database and the M&A Database from 01/01/1984 to 7/25/2004. The IPO sample excludes ADRs, unit offerings, closed end funds, and REITs; while the takeover sample excludes leverage buyouts, tender offers, spin-offs, recapitalizations, self-tenders, repurchases, privatizations, and reverse takeovers. Year refers to the year of filing IPO registration. We count only withdrawn-IPOs that are acquired within three years of their IPO registrations. Newly public target firms are the successful IPOs that are acquired within three years of their initial public offerings. The percentage of withdrawn-IPOs is the number of withdrawn-IPOs over the sum of withdrawn-IPOs and successful IPOs in a given year or an industry. The percent of withdrawn-IPO firms that are acquired (newly public firms that are acquired) refers to the number of withdrawn-IPO firms that are acquired (newly public firms that are acquired) over the number of withdrawn-IPOs (successful IPOs) for a year or an industry.

Panel A. Distribution by Year


Number of WithdrawnIPOs Successful IPOs WithdrawnIPO firms that are acquired 0 1 4 1 0 0 4 2 5 6 5 5 14 15 10 29 33 6 7 0 3 150 Newly public firms that are acquired 12 14 24 13 8 5 8 11 21 31 33 66 85 45 27 64 29 5 5 1 0 507 Withdrawn -IPOs Percent of WithdrawnIPO firms that are acquired 0% 3% 5% 1% 0% 0% 13% 6% 5% 8% 5% 9% 12% 14% 8% 27% 10% 17% 15% 0% 7% 9% Newly public firms that are acquired 6% 5% 4% 4% 5% 4% 6% 3% 5% 6% 9% 13% 12% 10% 10% 13% 10% 8% 8% 1% 0% 8%

Year

1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Total

86 32 87 89 34 11 32 36 102 78 104 53 120 105 129 106 318 35 46 8 41 1652

204 260 567 333 150 138 138 359 396 542 383 504 694 453 277 489 283 60 64 91 60 6445

30% 11% 13% 21% 18% 7% 19% 9% 20% 13% 21% 10% 15% 19% 32% 18% 53% 37% 42% 8% 41% 20%

31

Table I (Cont.) Panel B. Distribution by industry classification


Number of Industry Two-digit SIC codes WithdrawnIPOs Successful IPOs WithdrawnIPO firms that are acquired 3 3 8 6 7 9 9 11 5 9 10 59 11 150 Newly public firms that are acquired 15 1 29 14 15 35 35 48 12 30 62 196 15 507 WithdrawnIPOs Percent of WithdrawnIPO firms that are acquired 7% 17% 5% 5% 13% 9% 9% 7% 7% 8% 5% 13% 14% 9% Newly public firms that are acquired 13% 2% 4% 4% 5% 7% 9% 10% 5% 6% 7% 12% 6% 8%

Crops, natural resource extraction Construction Other manufacturing Chemicals and allied products Industrial machinery Electronic and electric equipment Instruments and related products Transportation Wholesale Retail Financial Services Unclassified Total

01-05,10-14 15-17 20-27, 29-34, 37, 39 28 35 36 38 40-49 50, 51 52-59 60-69 70-80 other

43 18 160 110 52 96 95 151 76 112 198 463 78 1652

120 63 685 395 321 504 372 503 252 523 841 1616 250 6445

26% 22% 19% 22% 14% 16% 20% 23% 23% 18% 19% 22% 24% 20%

32

Table II Characteristics of Acquisitions of Dual Tracking Private Targets and Matching Targets
This table compares characteristics of dual tracking private targets and matching target firms. Panel A presents the deal and acquirer's characteristics. Panel B contains targets characteristics. For each dual tracking private target, we identify an acquisition of a pure private firm, a newly-public firm, and an established public firm, respectively, which is closest in size (measured as deal value) within the same industry (same first 2-digit primary SIC code) purchased during the same time period and paid for with the same payment method. Deal value equals the total value of consideration paid by the acquirer, excluding fees and expenses. The size of the acquirer is measured as the market value of acquirer equity one month before the acquisition announcement. Relative size of acquisition is the deal value over the market value of acquirer equity. Growth is the sales growth rate prior to the takeover year. OPA and OPS are the EBITDA divided by total assets and sales respectively. LEV is the leverage defined as the total debt divided by the total assets. R&D is the research and development expense as a percent of the total assets. Comparisons are conducted by using matching-pair t-tests for differences in means and Wilcoxon signed-rank tests for differences in medians. Medians are reported in parentheses below the mean values. N is the number of matching pairs.
Dual tracking private targets (1) Deal value ($ million) (Median) Size of acquirer ($ million) (Median) Relative size of acquisition (Median) Cash in payment (%) (Median) Stock in payment (%) (Median) Sales (Median) Growth (Median) OPA (Median) OPS (Median) LEV (Median) R&D (Median)
17

Pure private targets (2) 88 (40) 993 (222) 0.31 (0.20) 50 (53) 41 (20) 53.68 (23.91) 0.5617 (0.24) 0.32 (0.19) 0.18 (0.11) 0.37 (0.15) 0.00 (0.00)

Matching Newly public targets (3) 958 (234) 12,695 (1,257) 0.44 (0.24) 18 (0) 76 (100) 237.80 (68.34) 0.76 (0.43) 0.13 (0.12) 0.18 (0.15) 0.23 (0.09) 0.06 (0.00)

Established public targets (4) 560 (148) 6,493 (1,031) 0.69 (0.16) 30 (0) 64 (81) 285.11 (91.69) 0.25 (0.11) 0.11 (0.10) 0.17 (0.12) 0.19 (0.09) 0.05 (0.00)

P-value for the difference (1) - (2) 0.01 (0.00) 0.02 (0.00) 0.49 (0.04) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.05 (0.10) 0.03 (0.01) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.88 (0.08) 0.00 (0.00) (1) - (3) 0.00 (0.00) 0.36 (0.07) 0.06 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.01 (0.00) 0.01 (0.02) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) (1) - (4) 0.06 (0.07) 0.60 (0.62) 0.24 (0.07) 0.43 (0.38) 0.08 (0.07) 0.01 (0.00) 0.01 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00)

Panel A: Deal and Acquirer Characteristics


252 (112) 8,416 (947) 0.27 (0.11) 33 (5) 56 (76) 97.39 (33.89) 4.71 (0.61) -0.38 (0.02) -1.92 (0.03) 0.35 (0.23) 0.20 (0.01) 132

121

121

130

130

Panel B: Target Characteristics


110

96

105

104

107

107

The sample size for this group is 66.

33

Table III Valuation Ratios of Dual Tracking Private Targets and Matching Targets
This table presents univariate comparisons of valuation ratios of dual tracking private targets and their matching pure private, newly-public, and established public targets. For each dual tracking private target, we identify an acquisition of a pure private firm, a newly-public firm, and an established public firm, respectively, which is closest in size (measured as deal value) within the same industry (same first 2-digit primary SIC code) purchased during the same time period and paid for with the same payment method. In Panel B (C), only firms with positive book value of equity (EBITDA) are included. Comparisons are conducted by using matching-pair t-tests for differences in means and Wilcoxon signed-rank tests for differences in medians. N is the number of matching pairs.
N Mean 156.31 3.20 7.99 2.93 0.26 0.28 0.26 Median 2.99 1.84 3.20 2.25 0.00 0.58 0.00

Panel A: Deal value to sales


(1) Dual tracking private targets (2) Pure private targets (3) Newly public targets (4) Established public targets p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4) 108 108 108 108

Panel B: Deal value to book value of equity


(1) Dual tracking private targets (2) Pure private targets (3) Newly public targets (4) Established public targets p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4) 60 60 60 60 41.89 23.48 12.59 7.11 0.16 0.02 0.01 14.07 8.88 4.98 3.47 0.02 0.00 0.00

Panel C: Deal value to EBITDA


(1) Dual tracking private targets (2) Pure private targets (3) Newly public targets (4) Established public targets p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4) 55 55 55 55 24.65 30.07 63.65 31.13 0.53 0.08 0.48 12.86 12.79 17.15 12.51 0.75 0.11 0.62

34

Table IV Regressions of Valuation Ratios for Dual Tracking Private Targets and Matching Targets
The valuation ratio is deal value divided by sales, book value, and EBITDA, respectively. Regressions shown in Models 2 and 3 only include observations with positive book values or EBITDA, respectively. The dependent variables are the log (valuation ratio). INDVS is the industry harmonic mean of enterprise-value-tosales based on the two-digit SIC code for the year of acquisition. INDPB is the industry harmonic mean of market-value-to-book-value based on two-digit SIC code for the year of acquisition. INDVE is the industry harmonic mean of enterprise-value-to-EBITDA based on the two-digit SIC code for the year of acquisition. Growth is the sales growth rate prior to the takeover year. LEV is the leverage defined as the total debt divided by the total assets. R&D is the research and development expense as a percent of total assets. Industry-adjusted OPA is the difference between a target firm's OPA and the median value of the same 2-digit SIC industry OPAs. The OPA is defined as the EBITDA divided by total assets. Loss*Industry-adjusted OPA is the interaction term of Loss and Industry-adjusted OPA, while the Loss equals 1 if the industry-adjusted OPA is less than or equal to zero, otherwise it takes the value of zero. Absolute values of t-statistics are reported in parentheses. T-statistics are calculated using robust standard errors. * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%.
Model 1 Deal value/sales (1) (2) (3) Pure private Newly public Established public INDVS INDPB INDVE Growth LEV R&D Industryadjusted OPA Loss*Industryadjusted OPA Mixed payment Stock payment Constant Number of Observations Adjusted R2 0.04** (4.32) 0.07 (0.88) 0.28 (0.46) 0.61** (3.91) -1.00** (3.15) -0.33 (1.36) 0.84** (3.15) 0.22 (0.78) 164 0.33 0.04** (4.42) -0.68 (1.95) 0.44 (0.79) 0.30 (0.38) -0.59 (0.69) -0.36 (1.39) 0.46 (1.69) 0.68 (1.91) 198 0.21 0.04** (4.48) -0.66 (1.79) 0.36 (0.65) 0.73 (1.11) -1.05 (1.44) -0.17 (0.73) 0.73** (3.13) 0.31 (0.95) 198 0.32 0.00 (0.25) 0.13** (4.44) 1.21 (1.42) 0.29 (1.31) -0.64 (1.65) 0.40 (1.06) 0.88** (2.65) 1.96** (5.66) 94 0.10 0.01 (0.58) 0.64 (1.34) 1.56* (2.17) 1.50 (1.61) -1.94 (1.71) 0.27 (0.72) 0.70* (2.10) 1.74** (3.57) 114 0.24 0.01 (0.89) 0.57 (1.27) 1.26 (1.74) 1.54 (1.83) -2.07* (2.01) 0.24 (0.67) 0.61 (1.96) 1.75** (3.98) 114 0.37 0.31* (2.53) 0.31* (2.34) -0.46* (2.28) 0.09 (0.42) -0.59** (2.74) 0.44** (4.04) 20.01 (0.73) -33.62 (0.32) Model 2 Deal value/book value (4) (5) (6) -0.45 (1.55) -0.86** (3.37) -1.27** (4.86) Model 3 Deal value/EBITDA (7) (8) (9) -0.04 (0.16) 0.29 (1.24) -0.06 (0.26)

77.00 (0.66) 0.21** (3.40) 0.04 (1.87) 0.10* (2.30) -0.32 (0.32) 0.10* (2.14) 0.06 (1.40) -0.33 (1.19) -0.01 (0.01) 0.06 (1.28) 0.03 (1.12) -0.59 (1.66) 1.00 (1.04)

0.02 (0.08) 0.28 (1.02) 0.47 (0.76) 88 0.15

0.02 (0.09) 0.27 (1.04) 1.65** (3.05) 105 0.06

0.06 (0.21) 0.23 (0.90) 2.11** (4.26) 104 0.04

35

Table V Acquirers' Announcement Period CARs over Days (-1, +1)


This sample represents acquisitions of dual tracking private targets and their matched targets. For each dual tracking private target, we identify an acquisition of a pure private firm, a newly-public firm, and an established public firm, respectively, which is closest in size (measured as deal value) within the same industry (same first 2-digit primary SIC code) purchased during the same time period and paid for with the same payment method. Abnormal returns are calculated using a modified market model, the return on an acquirer minus the equal-weighted market index return. The three day announcement period abnormal returns are measured from day -1 through day 1. Day 0 is the announcement date. Comparisons are conducted by using matched-pair t-tests for differences in means and Wilcoxon signed-rank tests for difference in medians. The alternative hypothesis for the paired t-test is that the mean of IPO-withdrawn target valuation ratios is not equal to that of matching samples. P-value of t-test and Wilcoxcon test is reported in parentheses. ** and * represent significance at 1% level and 5% level for testing whether CARs are different from zero. N is the number of matching pairs. Mean CAR (p-value) Matching Newly Pure private public targets targets 4.18%** -2.75%** (0.13) (0.05) 2.39% (0.30) 1.65% (0.98) 2.65%** (0.92) -0.57% (0.02) -3.05% (0.13) -1.98%* (0.00) Median CAR (p-value) Matching Newly Pure private public targets targets 2.28%** -1.63%* (0.42) (0.06) 1.92% (0.20) 0.27% (0.82) 0.89%** (0.72) -0.29% (0.01) -1.19% (0.23) -0.91%** (0.00)

Dual tracking private targets Cash Offers Hybrid Stock Offers All 0.94%

Established public targets -1.09% (0.24) -2.69%** (0.00) -3.11% (0.18) -2.38%** (0.00)

Dual tracking private targets 0.84%

N Established public targets -0.49% (0.16) -3.48%** (0.00) -0.61% (0.29) -1.50%** (0.00)

34

4.46%**

1.78%**

48

1.76%

0.28%

39

2.6%*

0.96%*

121

36

Table VI Regressions for Acquirers' CARs for Acquisitions of Dual Tracking and Matching Private Targets
The dependant variable is the acquirers three-day (-1, +1) CARs around the acquisition announcement. Relative size of acquisition is the deal value over the market value of acquirer equity one month before acquisition announcement. Interaction terms are measured as firm types interact with log (relative size of acquisition). The Within industry dummy takes a value of one when acquirers are in the same industry as targets if they share the same 2-digit primary SIC code. Absolute values of t-statistics are reported in parentheses. T-statistics are calculated using the robust standard errors. * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%. Model 1 -0.02 (0.67) -0.09** (3.00) -0.14** (4.89) 0.02* (2.16) Model 2 Model 3

Pure private Newly public Established public Log(relative size) Pure private * Log(relative size) Newly public * Log(relative size) Established public * Log(relative size) Within industry Mix payment dummy Stock payment dummy Log(deal value/sales ) Intercept Number of Observations Adjusted R-squared

0.02* (2.19) -0.01 (0.48)

0.02* (2.27)

-0.03** (2.95) -0.04** (3.98) 0.01 (0.45) 0.01 (0.79) 0.00 (0.20) -0.01 (1.42) 0.07* (2.31) 206 0.03 -0.02 (1.23) 0.02 (1.15) -0.02 (1.00) -0.01 (1.30) 0.08** (2.81) 206 0.10 0.01 (0.56) 0.01 (0.62) 0.00 (0.02) -0.01 (1.87) 0.07* (2.44) 206 0.13

37

Table VII Selection Bias Adjustments: Valuation Ratios of Dual Track and Pure Private Targets
This table presents estimates of the effect of filing IPO on dual tracking private targets subsequent acquisition valuation, after controlling for selection bias. We include the dual tracking target sample and matched pure private target sample in this analysis. We use the following two-step estimation procedure. In the first-step Probit regression (Model 1), the dependent variable, Dual Tracking, is one for dual tracking firms and zero for pure private targets. The second-step estimation uses ordinary least squares (OLS), where the dependent variable is the natural logarithm of acquisition valuation rations (Deal value/sales, Deal value/book value, and Deal value/EBITDA, in Models 2, 3, and 4, respectively). Lambda is the inverse Mills ratio from the first-step. As for other control variables, INDVS is the industry harmonic mean of enterprise-value-to-sales based on two-digit SIC code for the year of acquisition. INDPB is the industry harmonic mean of market-value-to-book-value based on two-digit SIC code for the year of acquisition. INDVE is the industry harmonic mean of enterprise-value-toEBITDA based on two-digit SIC code for the year of acquisition. Growth is the sales growth rate prior to the takeover year. LEV is the leverage defined as the total debt and short-term divided by the total assets. R&D is the research and development expense as a percent of total assets. Industry-adjusted OPA is the difference between a target firm's OPA and the median value of the same 2-digit SIC industry OPAs. The OPA is defined as the EBITDA divided by total assets. Loss*Industry-adjusted OPA is the interaction term of Loss and Iindustry-adjusted OPA, while Loss equals to 1 if Industry-adjusted OPA is less or equals to zero, otherwise it takes the value of zero. Absolute values of Z-statistics are reported in parentheses. Z-statistics are calculated using the robust standard errors. * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%.

38

Table VII (Cont.)


First-Step Probit Estimate Model 1 Marginal Coefficient effect Dual Tracking Dummy INDVS INDPB INDVE
Growth LEV R&D Industryadjusted OPA Loss*Industryadjusted OPA Mixed payment Stock payment

Second-Step OLS Estimates Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Deal Deal value/book Deal value/sales value value/EBITDA 1.35** (2.87) 0.30** (2.83) 0.86 (1.10) 1.73 (1.71)

17.95 (0.51) 0.21** (4.43) -0.02 (0.30) 0.12 (1.24) -2.47 (1.42)

0.34** (2.65) 0.04 (0.44) 6.34** (3.27) -1.33** (3.97)

0.04** 0.00 0.76** -0.16**

Lambda Constant Number of Observations P-value for Wald-test -0.37* -2.38 164 0.00

0.03** (3.94) 0.07 (0.80) -0.26 (0.46) 0.88** (2.87) -1.23** (3.28) -0.37 (1.57) 0.81** (3.33) -0.68 (2.18)* -0.65 (1.89) 164 0.00

0.00 (0.01) 0.14 (1.45) 0.97 (1.21) 0.40 (1.02) -0.67 (1.21) 0.40 (1.08) 0.87* (2.45) -0.29 (0.57) 1.29* (2.44) 94 0.00

-0.05 (0.19) 0.28 (1.09) -1.11 (1.78) -0.37 (0.53) 88 0.00

39

Table VIII Valuation Ratios of Dual Tracking Private and Matching Targets by Timing of Acquisitions
This table presents univariate comparisons of acquisition valuation ratios of dual tracking private targets and their matching pure private, newly-public, and established public targets. For each dual tracking private target, we identify an acquisition of a pure private firm, a newly-public firm, and an established public firm, respectively, which is closest in size (measured as deal value) within the same industry (same first 2-digit primary SIC code) purchased during the same time period and paid for with the same payment method. Sub-panel A (B) analyze withdrawn-IPOs announce to be acquired before (after) withdrawing their IPO filings. Comparisons are conducted by using matching-pair t-tests for differences in means and Wilcoxon signed-rank tests for differences in medians. N is the number of matching pairs.

Panel 1: Deal value to sales

N Panel 1.A: Acquisitions announced before IPO withdrawals (1) Dual tracking private targets 48 (2) Pure private targets 48 (3) Newly public targets 48 (4) Established public targets 48 p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4) Panel 1.B: Acquisitions announced after IPO withdrawals (1) Dual tracking private targets 60 (2) Pure private targets 60 (3) Newly public targets 60 (4) Established public targets 60 p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4)

Mean 325.83 3.13 10.09 2.83 0.30 0.31 0.30

Median 3.08 1.70 4.01 2.55 0.00 0.63 0.00

20.69 3.25 6.32 3.01 0.07 0.14 0.07

2.41 1.84 2.75 1.54 0.01 0.63 0.00

Panel 2: Deal value to book value of equity


Panel 2.A: Acquisitions announced before IPO withdrawals (1) Dual tracking private targets 29 (2) Pure private targets 29 (3) Newly public targets 29 (4) Established public targets 29 p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4) Panel 2.B: Acquisitions announced after IPO withdrawals (1) Dual tracking private targets 31 (2) Pure private targets 31 (3) Newly public targets 31 (4) Established public targets 31 p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4) 33.21 26.27 16.31 9.96 0.52 0.13 0.00 14.29 10.20 4.92 3.78 0.13 0.00 0.00

50.02 20.86 9.11 4.45 0.21 0.07 0.05

13.12 7.31 5.04 3.23 0.12 0.00 0.00

40

Table VIII (Cont.)


N Panel 3.A: Acquisitions announced before IPO withdrawals (1) Dual tracking private targets 24 (2) Pure private targets 24 (3) Newly public targets 24 (4) Established public targets 24 p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4) Panel 3.B: Acquisitions announced after IPO withdrawals (1) Dual tracking private targets 31 (2) Pure private targets 31 (3) Newly public targets 31 (4) Established public targets 31 p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (2) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (3) p-value of t-test / Wilcoxon test: (1) - (4)

Panel 3: Deal value to EBITDA

Mean 23.66 30.15 89.37 28.60 0.55 0.09 0.67

Median 14.21 12.79 19.54 10.87 0.72 0.16 0.76

25.93 29.96 28.63 34.40 0.78 0.84 0.59

11.86 12.90 16.41 12.85 0.33 0.42 0.31

41

Table IX Acquirers Long-run Post-acquisition Stock Performance (AR)


This table presents acquirers average abnormal return (AR) up to three years after acquisitions. For each acquirer over months +1 to +t following the deal-announcement month, we compute AR as the intercept of a time-series of regression of monthly stock returns on Fama and French three factors and momentum factor. The symbols **, * denote significance at the 1% and 5% level (two-sided), respectively, for testing whether mean or median of ARs are different from zero. P-value of t-test and Wilcoxcon test is reported in parentheses for testing the difference between acquirers of dual tracking targets and acquirers of pure private targets. N is the number of matching pairs. Acquirers of dual tracking firms -1.10% -0.11% -0.92% 0.22% -0.79% 0.39% Acquirers of pure private firms -0.22% 0.18% -0.21% -0.05% -0.18% 0.00%

Month 1 - 12

Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median

p-value 0.48 0.16 0.46 0.39 0.51 0.71

N 123

Month 1 - 24

123

Month 1 - 36

123

42

Figure 1.Length of Time from IPO to Takeover

For withdrawn-IPO firms, the number of days is the length of time between the IPO registration and takeover announcement. The average (median) number of days is 376 (294) days for withdrawn-IPO firms. For newly public firms, the number of days is the length of time from IPO date to takeover announcement. The average (median) number of days is 615 (629) days for newly public firms.

30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 120 240 360 480 600 720 840 960 1080 1200 Number of days Withdrawn-IPO firms Newly public firms

43

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen