Sie sind auf Seite 1von 19

Functions in Innovation System Approaches

Anna Johnson Department of Industrial Dynamics Chalmers University of Technology SE-412 96 Gteborg Sweden Phone: +46-(0)31-772 12 22 Fax: +46-(0)31-772 12 37 E-mail: anjo@mot.chalmers.se

Abstract In the last twenty years, a large number of innovation system approaches have emerged. Even though there are similarities between different approaches, they emphasise different aspects of innovation systems. Moreover, within each approach the system models differ in terms of the concepts used and the actors identified and emphasised. It might, therefore, be useful to see if there is any agreement between the approaches with respect to what they claim happens in an innovation system, i.e. what functions are served in the system. The purpose of this paper is twofold: (1) to find out if existing innovation system approaches share an understanding of the functions that are served in an innovation system and (2) to elaborate on the usefulness of the concept of function in innovation system studies. In summary, there seems to be quite a widely spread correspondence between different innovation system approaches with respect to the functions they mention so that a number of common, basic functions can be identified. The concept of function has several benefits. It provides a tool for setting system borders and may be used as a tool to diagnose the present state of a system or to create an easily grasped picture of innovation system dynamics. It makes it possible to assess system performance and may be useful in comparative studies since actors may be uncoupled from what happens in the system.

1. Introduction
An increasing number of researchers in fields such as industrial dynamics, technology policy and firm strategy claim that technological development cannot be viewed as an isolated phenomenon but has to be studied as a part of a larger system, an innovation system.1 A number of system approaches have emerged, including the national systems of innovation approach (e.g. Edquist and Johnson (1997), Lundvall (1992) and Nelson (1992)), the technological systems approaches (e.g. Hughes (1983) and Carlsson and Stankiewicz (1995)), the sociotechnical systems approach (e.g. Bijker (1995)) and the network approach (e.g. Hkansson (1990)).

Even though there are similarities between these approaches, they emphasise different aspects of innovation systems, mostly due to underlying differences in the fields of research. For example, the industrial network approach focus on how a companys relationships to other actors influence its capability to become a successful innovator, whereas advocates of the sociotechnical systems approach are interested in the social processes influencing the way we perceive technological artefacts.

Moreover, within each approach authors often focus on describing the characteristics of innovation systems on the basis of case studies, resulting in quite case-specific system models that differ in terms of the concepts used and the actors identified and emphasised.

The differences between and within approaches make it difficult to compare, or indeed combine, the findings of different system approaches. It might, therefore, be useful to look beneath their surface to see if there is any agreement between the approaches with respect to what the claim happens in an innovation system.

For this purpose, the concept of function may be of use. Inherent in a systems view is a notion that all system components contribute to the goal of the system or they would

For reasons of simplicity, all system concepts are here labelled innovation systems.

not be considered part of that system.2 The contribution of a component or a set of components to the goal is what is here called a function.3 The question is, thus, whether the different innovation system approaches agree on the functions that are served by components in an innovation system or if there are differences between them also in this respect.

The purpose of this paper is twofold: (1) to find out if existing innovation system approaches share an understanding of the functions that are served in an innovation system and (2) to elaborate on the usefulness of the concept of function in innovation system studies.

The paper is structured as follows. In section two, some different innovation system approaches and some of the authors representing them will be described with a focus on the functions they identify. In section three, the approaches views of the functions served in innovation systems will be compared. In section four, the analytical usefulness of the concept of function will be discussed and section five concludes the paper.

2. Functions in Innovation System Approaches


In this section some innovation system approaches will be described with respect to the functions they identify.4 The intention has not been to make a complete scrutiny of the literature, but rather to study some representatives of the major approaches. Three major approaches have been identified: the national systems of innovation approach, the technological systems approach and the network/development block approach. The classification of authors into these approaches has been made on basis of a perception of affinity between authors with regards to level or unit of analysis.5 The three approaches will be described in sections 2.2-2.4. However, since functions have been defined as contributions to the systems goal, the goal of an innovation system must first be discussed.
In an analytical sense. This does not imply that the system in reality is directed by some overriding principle (see also below). To some extent, this view of the concept of function resembles the ones used in political science, although Almond and Powell (1967) include both system capabilities, i.e. what the system does, and the mechanisms by which the capabilities are achieved in their description of the functioning of a political system. It is also similar to Talcott Parsonss notion of functions as contributions of elements in social system to the continuing operation of the whole (Cuff et al, 1998). 4 The description, thus, includes some analysis; since the authors themselves have not used the concept of function, describing them in those terms makes it necessary to reformulate their writings somewhat.
3 2

2.1 The Goal of an Innov ation System


The goal of an innovation system may be said to be to develop, diffuse and utilise innovations.6

This is, evidently, an analytically constructed goal. Few (if any) innovation systems have been consciously created with an explicit goal to develop, diffuse and utilise innovations (even though systems may be modified in such a direction by policy or strategy). Moreover, actors in the system may very well be driven by individual goals that do not correspond with each other or with the systems goal (as here defined), e.g. profits or social welfare.

Nevertheless, for the purpose of identifying functions in innovation system approaches it is analytically useful to perceive them as contributions to the development, diffusion and utilisation of innovations.7

2.2 The National Systems of Innovation Approach


Even though all national system of innovation agree that the nation or country is an appropriate level of analysis, there are many different opinions of how the system should be defined more exactly. The definitions range from narrow (including only organisations performing R&D) to broad (including basically anything that affects learning). The reader should keep this in mind since the definition, of course, affects what functions the authors identify.

Porter (1990) discusses the importance of national characteristics for the competitive advantage of individual companies. The basic idea is that in addition to the function served by companies in terms of acts of innovation (for example through R&D or small advances based on existing knowledge) several functions are served by components in a larger system of which the companies form a part.
It should be noted that the authors in some cases have referred to and built on each other's work even though they are presented here as separate from each other. 6 This definition is inspired by Carlsson and Stankiewicz (1995) and Galli and Teubal (1997). 7 The concept of function has been used before in the IS literature in slightly different ways than in this paper. For example, Galli and Teubal (1997) use the concept of function as a synonym to role (e.g. R&D and policy-making). McKelvey (1997) use the concept of function as synonymous to three principles of change that should exist in an innovation system: retention and transmission of information, generation of novelty and selection.
5

One of these functions is guiding innovative activity, i.e. influencing the direction in which companies deploy their resources and skills. For example, home demand might influence companies perceptions of opportunities, and standards and security regulations help (or force) companies to choose specific development paths.

The role of the government is, among other things, to stimulate markets, provide infrastructure and education and give companies incentives to invest in innovation. The latter two are of vital importance since the supply of resources, both in terms of (venture) capital and competence, is necessary to achieve competitive advantage.

In contrast to Porter, Lundvall is not primarily interested in industrial competitiveness, but in the production, diffusion and use of new, and economically useful, knowledge in general. The paper referred to here (Lundvall, 1992) is, however, largely focused on the role of learning in the production of new knowledge.

According to this paper, there are several sources of new knowledge. Whereas some of the inputs to the knowledge production process originate from search and exploration efforts in R&D, other arise from learning in connection to everyday activities. Often, the identification of bottlenecks in technology affects the direction of problem definition and the search for solutions. The rate and direction of innovation are also influenced by regulations and standards. Furthermore, providing the resources and competencies needed is an important task of the system of innovation.

As is the case with Lundvall, Edquist and Johnson (1997) see innovations as results of interactive learning, where knowledge is combined in new ways or new knowledge is created, either in connection with R&D or in relation to everyday activities such as production and marketing.

The actors (organisations) play an important role, as they search for new knowledge, absorb knowledge created elsewhere and utilise the expected and unexpected results.

They also contribute to the distribution of knowledge, knowledge regulation (e.g. standard setting) and the development of the institutional set-up. The primary concern of Edquist and Johnson is, however, the institutional set-up,8 which serves four basic functions with respect to innovation. First, institutions (e.g. patent laws, norms for repayment periods etc.) may reduce uncertainty, either by providing information about the behaviour of other people or by reducing the amount of information needed. Second, institutions manage conflicts and co-operation between individuals and groups. For example, practices of co-operation may work as bridges between different departments in a company. Another example is social security and labour market arrangements that influence conflicts between old products and new, thereby counteracting resistance to change. Third, institutions provide incentives to engage in learning and to participate in innovation processes. The incentives can be of various kinds, e.g. income taxes, property rights, perceived competitive advantage and status norms. Finally, institutions such as tax rules, government subsidies and allocation of resources to universities channel resources to innovation activities and also help to re-channel resources from ailing activities to new ones.

Whereas the papers described so far are largely theoretical in nature, the work of Nelson (1992) is based on a comparative study of the national innovation systems of 15 countries. Among the functions served by different actors in the countries studied, the investment in and implementation of R&D are given most attention.

In this context, the direction of innovative work is said to be an important function, one that often is served by customers. Moreover, economic incentives to innovate have to be provided and the innovative work has to be funded by internal financing of R&D and/or the supply of venture capital. Other necessary resources, e.g. competence (knowledge and skills), also have to be made available.

New knowledge may also come from other sources than R&D, e.g. from learning-bydoing, learning-by-using or imitation. For learning to occur, it is, however, necessary to
8

Institutions are defined as sets of common habits, routines, established practices, rules, or laws that regulate the relations and interactions between individuals and groups (Edquist and Johnson, 1997, pp. 46).

co-ordinate departments within companies, to spread knowledge about new developments, and to promote co-operation between companies.

Finally, it might also be necessary to support (or even create) markets. This may involve providing companies with incentives to export.

2.3 The Technological Sy stems Approach


As in the national systems of innovation approach, the authors that are here considered to be part of the technological systems approach define their systems in different ways. Moreover, some use other names for their system concepts. However, they all have chosen a technology (or product) level of analysis. The issue of interest for these authors is, thus, how different actors etc influence the development, diffusion and use of a particular technology or product.

The concept of technological system is said to have been first introduced by Thomas Hughes in the book Networks of Power.9 According to Hughes (1983, 1990) 10, technological systems solve problems identified or constructed by the system. The identification of a problem usually involves identifying a demand and the available resources that might fill it. Inventions are sometimes based on the identification of reverse salients, i.e. components in the system that have fallen behind or are out of phase with the others (Hughes, 1983; Hughes, 1990), but they can also be based on experiences from using existing technology (Hughes, 1983) or on earlier inventions that failed to develop into innovations (Hughes, 1990).

In addition to invention and development of new technology, there is a need to provide financial support (Hughes, 1990) and competence (Hughes, 1983) and to raise

However, authors Edward Wenk Jr and Thomas J. Kuehn used the concept already in 1977 as synonymous to their concept of "technological delivery system" (Wenk and Kuehn, 1977). 10 The concept of technological system is not well defined in the 1983 book, but in the 1990 paper some system components are mentioned: physical and legislative artefacts, organisations, natural resources, books, articles, university teaching and research, inventors, industrial scientists, engineers, managers, financiers and workers.

complementary resources (Hughes, 1983). Other important functions are technology transfer and adaptation.

Hughes (1990) also stresses the importance of institutional factors, e.g. values in the society and legislation, in the selection of technical, organisational and social solutions. For a new technology (or a new technological system) to develop it may be necessary to clear political and legislative ground (Hughes, 1983), stimulate enthusiasm for the new technology (Hughes, 1983), and through the destruction of alternative systems force unity from diversity (Hughes, 1990). It may also be important to reduce uncertainty by taking control of the environment (Hughes, 1990).

In the early 1990s, Carlsson and Stankiewicz developed a notion of a technological system largely independent from the one of Hughes, which is described in, e.g., Carlsson and Stankiewiz (1995).11

They describe innovation in terms of search and experimentation (i.e. learning), which makes exchange of information essential. Moreover, for a technological area to grow, someone has to perceive the possibility of the technology and identify the potential for growth, the resources needed (in terms of funding, competence etc) have to be secured and the different activities in the process co-ordinated. Furthermore, the institutional framework has an important role to play. Institutions12 promote stable pattern of social interactions and transactions, reduce social uncertainty and prevent or mitigate conflicts. They may also absorb and diffuse some part of the risk of individual actors, e.g. by stimulating markets or providing information, and may work for the creation of efficient selection mechanisms, both at company and market level.

In addition to the authors that explicitly speak of technological systems, there are others using very similar concepts, e.g. Anders Lundgren, Gunnar Eliasson and Wiebe Bijker.
11

They define a technological system as a network of agents interacting in a specific economic/industrial area under a particular institutional infrastructure or set of infrastructures and involved in the generation, diffusion, and utilization of technology (Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995, pp. 49). This concept is very similar to the one developed by Wenk and Kuehn (1977), although no reference is made to their work.

Lundgren (1993) uses the concept of industrial networks,13 defined as technical systems14 and networks of relationships between actors. Within industrial networks, innovation is often driven by the identification of imbalances or bottlenecks in the technological system or the relationships between actors. However, since problems are defined differently by different actors, due to the fact that their historical background influence the way they perceive the situation at hand, the resulting research and product development will follow different routes.

For networks of relationships to emerge, it is necessary that some actor identifies the technical system, i.e. perceives the complementarities of different products and technologies, and spreads this notion to other actors. At this stage, the role of networks of relationships is to co-ordinate specialisation and division of labour between actors, develop routine transactions and distribute the economic surplus. The actors also have to attract resources and work to legitimise the activities of the network to the environment. Later on, the technical system has to be adapted to other systems through complementary investments in other fields. New problems may be identified through a process of learning-by-using and standards are developed.

Another related concept is the competence bloc, developed by Gunnar Eliasson and described in, e.g., Eliasson (1997).15 The first requirement of a competence bloc is the presence of innovators who integrate different new and old technologies in an innovative, i.e. unexpected. Knowledge is transferred by, e.g., movement of people and imitation. Second, entrepreneurship is needed to identify and select the commercially viable innovations and move them to the market.

During the innovation process, it is important that venture capitalists recognise and finance commercially viable opportunities. It is also crucial that there are incentives for
Defined as both organisations and regimes. This concept has been developed based on a study of the emergence of digital image technology in Sweden. 14 In the paper referred to, Lundgren uses the concept of technological system for complementary products of different technologies and pieces of knowledge (Lundgren, 1993, pp. 147), which obviously is not the same as the technological systems concept of Hughes and Carlsson and Stankiewicz (described above). In fact, Lundgren (19??) in Swedish uses a concept which is more correctly translated to technical system, a translation that will be used here in order to avoid misunderstandings.
13 12

actors to involve themselves in the process, i.e. that actors who succeed are rewarded by getting reasonable or better returns on their investments. Moreover, the selection process demands competent actors who have the capability of recognising and evaluating opportunities. Therefore, organisations supplying educated people have to be present.

Finally, since technological development results in reallocation of factors of production over markets, there is also an acceptance (social) problem to be solved. It is therefore important to have institutions making the necessary social adjustments (e.g. in social insurance and labour market policy), so that the society is prepared to accept the change accompanying economic growth.

The last related concept described here is the sociotechnical system concept used by Bijker (1995).16 According to Bijker, the process of innovation consists of variation and selection in three layers. First, relevant social groups identify a variety of problems, based on perceived functional failures or presumptive anomalies17, of which some are selected for further attention. Second, a variety of solutions are generated and some of these solutions yield new artefacts. Third, one of the artefacts becomes dominant over all relevant social groups, partly as a result of one relevant social groups ability to convince the other groups about the superiority of its problem definition and resulting artefact.

Different mechanisms might provide the necessary input to innovation in different situations. In the case of the social construction of Bakelite, Bijker describes how research and development activities were guided in a specific direction by monetary incentives and how learning-by-doing and learning-by-using gave important inputs to

According to Eliasson (1997), the main differences between this concept and that of Carlsson and Stankiewicz (1995) are that it is not input determined but defined in terms of its end results functionally related products in the market and that it is concerned with the selection of successful innovations. These differences are, however, not easily noticed in the work of the different authors. 16 Bijker stresses the need to view every artefact as a sociotechnical ensemble, since it is impossible to separate the technical from the social, economical or political. The resulting notion of a sociotechnical system, consisting of different artefacts and actors, strongly resembles the technological system concepts described above. However, in contrast to the other authors Bijker makes a strong point of not assuming a fixed artefact after the invention artefacts are gradually constructed in the social interactions between and within so called relevant social groups and the point of interest is the process by which artefacts attain or fail to attain a stable interpretation. 17 Assumptions that under some future conditions the system will fail or function badly or that a radically different system will do a much better job.

15

10

the innovation process. Moreover, the patent system provided both efficient conflictsolving and supplied incentives for innovation.

2.4 The Network Approac h and the Development Block Approach


Whereas the authors described above are concerned with analysing entire innovation systems, other authors have chosen other units of analysis. Since these approaches are focused on smaller parts of the total system, the functions identified are fewer (but maybe better understood).

Hkansson (1990) focuses on the relationships between actors, especially on the importance and functions of relationships with different counterparts in the development process. He identifies three reasons why relationships ought to be important: (1) interactions with companies that have knowledge in other areas can generate technical questions and new knowledge to solve them, (2) the evaluation and acceptance of a new technology or product is dependent on support from several actors and (3) companies often have to supplement their resources with those of others.

The unit of analysis of Dahmn (1987) is the development block which refers to a sequence of complementarities which by way of a series of structural tensions, i.e. disequilibria, may result in a balanced situation. Economic success in a development process might require the realisation of one or more specific complementary stage, and in situations where stages are missing, the development potential will be released as soon as the missing stages have come in place.

The primary function of actors is to identify the development block in advance and to fill the gaps within it by active search, both for new technical solutions and for actors that can invest in complementary stages, for example market identification or creation.

3. Comparison and Identification of Basic Functions


It is already evident that the different approaches are similar with respect to the functions they identify, but the questions of how similar and in what ways still remain.

11

In this section, the approaches will be compared more systematically. The comparison will be built around some basic functions that most authors seem to agree on.

One group of functions, described by all authors, consists of the functions directly related to the innovation process. The first of these is the function identify problem (Bijker, 1995; Dahmn, 1987; Hughes, 1983 and 1990; Hkansson, 1990; Lundgren, 1993)18. Almost all of these authors recognise the importance of identifying bottlenecks in the system, or in the words of the authors themselves functional failures (Bijker, 1995), missing complementary stages (Dahmn, 1987), reverse salients (Hughes, 1983 and 1990), imbalances or bottlenecks (Lundgren, 1993) and bottlenecks in technology (Lundvall, 1992). Most considered only bottlenecks of a technical nature, but they might according to Dahmn (1987) and Lundgren (1993) also appear in other parts of the innovation system (e.g. in the relationships between actors).

For most authors, the next step in the innovation process is to develop a solution to the identified problem,19 often a new technology or product, i.e. to create new knowledge.20 Although some of the authors (Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Eliasson, 1997; Hughes, 19XX; Porter, 1990), recognise the possibility to create new knowledge by combining old and new knowledge in an innovative way, most of them speak primarily of the production of entirely new knowledge. They also very much agree on the possible sources of new knowledge: R&D (Bijker, 1995; Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Hughes, 19XX; Lundgren, 1993; Nelson, 1992; Porter, 1990), search and experimentation (Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995; Lundvall, 1993),21 learning in connection to everyday activities, i.e. learning-by-doing and learning-by-using (Bijker, 1995; Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Hughes, 19XX; Lundgren, 1993; Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1992) and imitation22 (Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Eliasson, 1997; Nelson, 1992).

In this section, references indicate that the identified function is mentioned by the authors in question. It should be noted that although the authors describe the innovation process in stages, several of them emphasise the feedback loops in the process. It is, thus, possible for sub-functions creating new knowledge to contribute to the problem identification function and vice versa. 20 According to Bijker and Hughes, however, there is an intermediary function: to develop a solution idea. They both argue that the search for solutions is not unconstrained, but is determined by the actors perceptions of viable solutions. 21 Search and experimentation is of course a much more general concept than the others, but in the papers it is used much in the same way as R&D, i.e. as a deliberate way of producing new knowledge. 22 Imitation may create knowledge that is new to an individual actor although it might not be new to the innovation system as a whole. Moreover, even though the authors do not mention the possibility, imitation might give important inputs to the creation of knowledge that is new to the system as well.
19

18

12

In addition to the functions directly concerned with the innovation process, the authors identify several functions that support the innovation process indirectly. Since the support might vary between innovations, these functions might also work to promote specific innovations.

The first support function is to supply incentives for companies to engage in innovative work (Porter, 1990; Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Nelson, 1992; Eliasson, 1997, Bijker, 1995); companies have to feel that they get reasonable returns on their investments in R&D etc.

The second support function is to supply resources. The most mentioned resources are indubitably funding (Porter, 1990; Nelson, 1992, Hughes, 1990, Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995, Eliasson, 1997, Dahmn, 1987) and competence (Porter, 1990; Lundvall, 1990; Nelson, 1992; Hughes, 1983; Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995; Eliasson, 1997). However, some authors also leave the door open for other resources to be considered (Lundvall, 1990; Nelson, 1992; Hughes, 1983; Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995) or do not specify what resources they have in mind (Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Hkansson, 1990; Lundgren, 1993).

The third support function is to guide the direction of search, i.e. influence the direction in which actors deploy their resources. Several authors (Porter, 1990; Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1992; Hughes, 1983; Lundgren, 1993; Bijker, 1995) mention this function, although in different ways. Some authors (Bijker, 1995; Hughes, 1983; Lundgren, 1993) recognise the guidance inherent in problem identification and identification of solution idea. Other authors (Porter, 1990, Lundvall, 1992; Nelson, 1992) perceive the guidance of innovative activity as a function not necessarily served by the companies themselves. For example, Lundvall (1992) and Porter (1990) mention the role of standards and regulations. Both groups of authors seem to refer primarily to guidance in a technical sense, i.e. in terms of choice of product design or specific technology within a product or technology area, but the possibility to also include guidance towards new technological areas or perhaps different markets should not be neglected. These latter

13

types of guidance are very much related to the function provide incentives for // innovative work and to the fourth support function.

The fourth, support function is to recognise the potential for growth of the innovation, which is necessary for it to attract resources and be brought to the market. This may come in terms of identifying technological possibility (Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995), commercial viability (Eliasson, 1997) and/or complementary resources (Lundgren, 1993; Dahmn, 1987).

The fifth support function is to facilitate the exchange of information and knowledge (Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995; Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Nelson, 1992; Lundgren, 1993).23 This may be important both for providing feedback between system performance and goals (Hughes, 1990) and for diffusion of technology and products on the market. This function is related to co-ordination of different departments within companies (Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Nelson, 1992, Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995), to promotion of co-operation between actors (Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Nelson, 1992, Bijker, 1995; Hkansson, 1990) and to division of labour between actors once cooperation is established (Lundgren, 1993).

The sixth support function is to stimulate/create markets (Porter, 1990; Nelson, 1992; Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995; Dahmn, 1987) since markets do not necessarily develop spontaneously.24 As already mentioned, diffusion is also connected to the facilitation of information exchange and the transfer of knowledge/technology.

The seventh support function is to reduce social uncertainty, i.e. uncertainty about how others will act and react (Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Hughes, 1990; Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995). Related to this function is also the function to prevent or solve conflicts between companies or individuals (Edquist and Johnson, 1997; Carlsson and Stankiewicz, 1995; Bijker, 1995), since conflicts often arise when actors do not understand each other. According to Edquist and Johnson (1997) social uncertainty can

Some of these authors use the word transfer instead of exchange and/or technology instead of knowledge. In this context, it is interesting to note that few authors seem to consider market introduction and diffusion as direct parts of the innovation process; these steps are only dealt with in terms of supporting functions such as this one.
24

23

14

be reduced either by providing information about the behaviour of other people or by reducing the amount of information needed (e.g. through patent laws). The latter function is similar to one mentioned by Carlsson and Stankiewicz (1995), i.e. the promotion of stable patterns of interaction and transactions, the purpose of which can be said to reduce the need for information.

The eighth and final support function is to counteract the resistance to change that may arise in society when an innovation is introduced or, in other words, to provide legitimacy for the innovation (and the activities of the system surrounding it) in the eyes of the outside world (Lundgren, 1993). Resistance may arise because of conflicts between new and old products (Edquist and Johnson, 1997) or because of the effects the new product may have on employment etc (Eliasson, 1997). Some possible means to counteract the resistance are to stimulate the enthusiasm for the new technology (Hughes, 1983), to clear political and legislative ground in favour of the new technology (Hughes, 1983; Eliasson, 199725). Moreover, stimulating relationships between actors may be needed in order to create support for a new technology or product (Hkansson, 1990; Bijker, 1995)

Obviously, all these functions are very much related to each other. In fact, much of the system dynamics is created by the interaction of functions (see, e.g., Johnson and Jacobsson (2000)). For example, the interaction makes it possible for cumulative and circular causation to appear. A system in which one function is not served (or served in a way which is not good for the system) may, therefore, be expected to malfunction also in other ways. On the other hand, virtuous circles may appear as well if the functions strengthen each other through feedback loops.

To conclude, there seems to be quite a widely spread correspondence between different innovation system approaches with respect to the functions they identify. The basic functions described above cover the ones identified in the different approaches to a very large extent and most functions are mentioned by a majority of the authors. Thus, the first purpose of the paper has been fulfilled. In the next section, the other purpose of the
25 Eliasson (1997) focus on the possibility to make adjustments in, for example, the social welfare system and labour market regulations, so that society is prepared to accept new technology even though it might entail unemployment.

15

paper, to discuss the possible benefits of using the concept of function in innovation system studies, will be covered.

4. Benefits of the Concept of Function in Innovation System Studies


Even though it apparently is possible to identify basic functions that, according to many authors in the field, are (or should be) served in an innovation system, the benefits of doing so may be less obvious at a first glance. The concept of function may, however, contribute to innovation system studies in a number of ways.

First, it provides a tool for setting system borders, which is a problem in many existing innovation system approaches. The innovation system would then include all components that influence one or more of the identified functions for the object of study (e.g. a product or technology).26 This means that the borders are not set a priori to nation, region or technology and that different levels of analysis may be combined.

This type of definition could be especially useful in cases such as wind power technology, which is influenced by factors on the technological level (e.g. technologyspecific knowledge and subsidies), the sectoral level (e.g. energy sector incumbents, substitutes and energy taxes) and the national level (e.g. norms and values in society).

Second, the concept of function may be used as a tool to describe the present state of a system. The mechanisms that in a particular situation induce or block the functions may be identified and possibly stimulated and removed respectively (by policy and/or strategy).

Third, it may be useful when studying innovation system dynamics. Mapping the functional pattern, i.e. how functions have been served, over time gives an easily grasped picture of the way in which the system has emerged. Thereby, the concept may provide some structure to a process which is often difficult to describe and may, thus, possibly contribute to the understanding of how innovation systems emerge and change.
26 This type of extended technological system was used in a study of the Swedish innovation system for renewable energy technology (Johnson and Jacobsson, 1999) and in a study of the German, Dutch and Swedish wind turbine industries (Johnson and Jacobsson, 2000).

16

Fourth, the concept of function allows us to assess the performance of an innovation system, for example in terms of how it has supported the development of a new industry. This may be done by analysing the functionality of the system, i.e. how well the functions have been served, which, of course, demands a definition of what well served means in the particular case of interest. 27

Finally, by focussing on functions actors may be uncoupled from what happens in an innovation system. This may be useful in comparative studies since it reduces the risk of comparing system structure instead of system functionality; two systems may function equally well even though their structure is totally different (i.e. functions may be served in many different ways). Of course, the purpose of a study may be to compare structure instead of, or in combination with, functionality. In such cases, the concept of function may still be of use, for example in an analysis of the relationship between how and how well functions are (or have been) served.

5. Concluding remarks
The existing innovation system approaches seem to have a shared understanding of a number of basic functions that are (or should be) served in innovation systems. The differences between approaches thus seem to be less profound than the confusion in terms of levels of analysis and concepts used indicates.

There also seem to be a number of benefits of using the concept of functions in innovation system studies. So far, the concept has, however, only been used in a couple of very similar studies. The usefulness for other types of studies is, thus, still to be demonstrated.

27 This type of analysis may be found in Johnson and Jacobsson (2000), where the difference in success between the Swedish, German and Dutch wind turbine industries is argued to be due mostly to differences in how the functions were served in the three innovation systems in different industry life-cycle phases.

17

6. References
Almond, G. A. and Powell, G. B. (1967): Comparative Politics: A Developmental Approach. Little, Brown and Company, Boston. Bijker, W. E. (1995): Of Bicycles, Bakelites, and Bulbs: Toward a Theory of Sociotechnical Change. The MIT Press. Cambridge, Massachusetts. Carlsson, B. and Stankiewicz, R. (1995): On the nature, function and composition of technological systems. In: Carlsson, B. (ed.): Technological Systems and Economic Performance: The Case of Factory Automation. Kluwer Academic Publishers. Dordrecht, pp. 21-56. Cuff, E. C., Sharrock, W. W. and Francis, D. W. (1998): Perspectives in Sociology (4th ed.). Routledge, London. Dahmn, E. (1987): Development Blocks in Industrial Economics. Scandinavian Economic History Review. Edquist, C. and Johnson, B. (1997): Institutions and Organizations in Systems of Innovation. In: Edquist, C. (ed): Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organizations. Pinter Publishers. London, pp. 41-63. Eliasson, G. (1997): Competence Blocs and Industrial Policy in the Knowledge Based Economy. TRITA-IEO R 1997-04. Department of Industrial Economics and Management. Stockholm. Galli, R. and Teubal, M. (1997): Paradigmatic Shifts in National Innovation Systems. In: Edquist, C. (ed): Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organizations. Pinter Publishers. London, pp. 342-370. Hughes, T. P. (1983): Networks of Power: Electrification in Western Society, 18801930. The Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore. Hughes, T. P. (1990): The Evolution of Large Technological Systems. In: Bijker, W. E. (ed.); Hughes, T. P. (ed.) & Pinch, T. J. (ed.): The Social construction of Technological Systems: New Directions in the Sociology and History of Technology. The MIT Press. Cambridge, Massachusetts. Hkansson, H. (1990): Technological Collaboration in Industrial Networks. EMJ, vol.3, pp. 371-379. Johnson, A. and Jacobsson, S. (1999): Inducement and Blocking Mechanisms in the Development of a New Industry. To appear in: Coombs, R., Green, K., Walsh, V. and Richards, A. (eds): Technology and the Market: Demand, Users and Innovation. Edward Elgar. Cheltenham and Northhampton, Massachusetts.

18

Johnson, A. and Jacobsson, S. (2000): The Emergence of a Growth Industry: A Comparative Analysis of the German, Dutch and Swedish Wind Turbine Industries. Mimeo. The department of Industrial Dynamics, Chalmers University of Technology, Sweden. (To be published in the Schumpeter Conference 2000 proceedings.) McKelvey, M. (1997): Using Evolutionary Theory to Define Systems of Innovation. In: Edquist, C. (ed): Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organizations. Pinter Publishers. London, pp. 200-222. Lundgren, A. (19XX): Ett ntverks frdelse Utvecklingen av digital bildteknik i Sverige. In: Hkansson, H., Laage-Hellman, J., Lundgren, A. and Waluszewski, A.: Teknikutveckling i fretaget: Ett ntverksperspektiv. Studentlitteratur. (In Swedish). Lundgren, A. (1993): Technological innovation and the emergence and evolution of industrial networks: the case of digital image technology in Sweden. Advances in International Marketing, vol. 5, pp. 145-170. Lundvall, B.-. (1992): Introduction. In: Lundvall, B.-. (ed.): National Systems of Innovation toward a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning. Pinter Publishers. London, pp. 1-19. Nelson, R. R. (1992): National Innovation Systems: A Retrospective on a Study. Industrial and Corporate Change, no. 2, pp.347-374. Porter, M. (1990): The Competitive Advantage of Nations. Harvard Business Review. March-April. Wenk, E. and Kuehn, T. J. (1977): Interinstitutional Networks in Technological Delivery Systems. In: Haberer, J. (ed): Science and Technology Policy. Lexington Books, Lexington, Massachusetts, pp. 153-175.

19

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen