Sie sind auf Seite 1von 25

J. of Modern African Studies, 46, 2 (2008), pp. 191214. f 2008 Cambridge University Press doi:10.

1017/S0022278X08003194 Printed in the United Kingdom

Diamonds or development ? A structural assessment of Botswanas forty years of success


ELLEN HILLBOM*

Department of Economic History, Lund University, P.O. Box 7083, S-220 07 Lund, Sweden
Email : ellen.hillbom@ekh.lu.se

ABSTRACT

Due to its four decades of high long-term economic growth and democratic system, Botswana has been depicted as an exceptional success story in a region full of economic and political failures. In this article, a structural analysis is applied, and it is argued that Botswanas success should be understood as one of pre-modern growth without development. It is claimed that although the country may be a growth miracle, it has not yet experienced modern economic growth , characterised by structural change in patterns of production as well as in social and political institutions. Such analysis also oers an explanation for the duality of Botswanas economy and society, since pre-modern growth, as opposed to development, allows for signicant poverty rates and extremely unequal resource and income distribution to prevail in the midst of plenty.

INTRODUCTION

At Independence in 1966, Botswana was a poor, undeveloped and seldom heard of part of the world. Forty years later, it is regarded as a growth miracle (Samatar 1999), a sign of hope for sub-Saharan Africa, and as an exemplar of prosperity and success. The country experienced a staggering GDP per capita increase of 13% per annum in the years 198089 (Mpabanga 1997), and a long-run growth over the last four decades that even surpasses the performance of the Pacic Asian tigers (Leith 2005: 4,
* The research for this article was conducted within the research project The Role of Equity in Development , funded by the Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency, Department for Research Cooperation (Sida/SAREC). The author wishes to acknowledge the valuable comments given by her colleagues Christer Gunnarsson, Martin Andersson and Erik Green, and by two anonymous referees.

192

ELLEN HILLBOM

Table 1.1). Simultaneously, the government has managed to establish one of the longest running multiparty democracies on the continent. The question is frequently posed how a country that used to be among the poorest, situated in the most underdeveloped and conict-ridden continent in the world, could achieve outstanding growth paired with political stability. The explanation for the success story is found mainly in limited colonial inuence, good political institutions, wise leaders and prudent economic policy (see e.g. Acemoglu et al. 2003 ; Beaulier & Subrick 2006; Harvey & Lewis 1990; Iimi 2006 ; Leith 2005; Mpabanga 1997 ; Owusu & Samatar 1997; Samatar 1999). In this article Botswanas economic performance is, however, analysed not from the viewpoint of stability and growth, but from that of structural change and development. The position is taken that while commendable advances have been achieved during the last four decades, these need to be complemented with technological innovations, signicant productivity increase, change in economic and political structures, a signicant rise in living standards for the poor, and a more equal distribution of resources, incomes and opportunities, for there to be long-run sustainable opulence with substance. It is necessary to distinguish between growth and development. Botswanas signicant economic and political advances make up a clear case of growth without development, as long as such change has not taken place. The diamond-led economic growth record of Botswana is truly impressive, and the country is presently classied as an upper-middle-income country with an estimated GNI per capita of US$5,900 in 2006 (World Bank 2008a). Although average GDP growth rates have been levelling o and falling below 4% per annum (World Bank 2008b), no immediate end to further economic expansion is in sight. The most serious socioeconomic threat is the estimated 24% prevalence of HIV/AIDS in the productive population aged 1549 (World Bank 2008a), resulting in a 35-year life expectancy, and infant and under-ve mortality rates at 87 and 120 respectively (ibid.). This gives the country the unique and deplorable combination of impressive growth with diving social indicators. As part and parcel of the successful growth, Botswana is also associated with political progress. Independence was peaceful, and compared with other African leaders, the Botswana political elite has shown an ability to govern both peacefully and prudently (see e.g. Acemoglu et al. 2003 ; Beaulier & Subrick 2006; Hill 1991; Leith 2005). The country has a high regulatory quality, and is considered by many not only to be the least corrupt country in Africa, but as on par in this regard with Western Europe (Robinson & Parsons 2006: 10710). This view is, however, being

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

193

contested as increasing mismanagement and corruption on the part of the power elite has been documented (Makgala 2006). In the midst of this peaceful growth miracle, there thus exist serious deciencies. Apart from a degree of elite capture, these include concerns over high and unchanging inequalities, poor and neglected rural areas, high unemployment rates, failure in limiting the AIDS epidemic, discrimination against minority groups such as the San and a weak civil society (see e.g. Allen & Heald 2004; Good 1993, 1994; Gulbrandsen 1996; Heald 2006; Lekoko & van der Merwe 2006 ; Makgala 2006 ; Nthomang 2004; Phaladze & Tlou 2006; Wikan 2004). Dual development and contradictory indicators are typical of a country experiencing pre-modern growth without structural change and development. A holistic structural analysis that recognises Botswanas socio-economic institutional structure as partly pre-modern underscores the ambiguity in the growth process, and is necessary for drawing up strategies for turning growth into development.
GROWTH OR DEVELOPMENT

Kuznets (1973) argued that in our time the end goal for any society is to reach modern economic growth (MEG), thereby leaving the pre-modern growth process behind. This modernisation, which is the equivalent of development, is characterised by technological advances, high rates of growth, a rise in productivity, and structural transformation of the economy, society and ideology. Depending on its causes and characteristics, growth may be more or less likely to promote such processes of structural change, and societies can experience growth while staying pre-modern. Botswana is an example of a small country possessing exceptionally valuable resources, allowing the state to provide its population with increasing rents. Such types are not representative in Kuznets original model of MEG, where they are treated as atypical cases. Building on Kuznets, using comparative history and comparative economic development, Adelman and Morris (1997 : 833) elaborate on the modernisation argument, taking the position that all processes of economic development are multifaceted and non-linear. Recognising variations in possible paths to modernisation and development does not, however, contradict stipulating a uniform end goal. In their categorisation, Botswana falls into a typology of agricultural, primary-export oriented, sharply dualistic and land-abundant countries. Within this group, the characteristics of existing natural resource endowments and degrees of government autonomy from tribal domestic elites and colonial powers determine patterns and sequence of structural change.

194

ELLEN HILLBOM

A theoretical approach to the potential development process of this category of economies is oered by a modied Lewis model. Lewis (1954, 1979) stipulates a closed economy, where population is large relative to capital and natural resources and, consequently, there is an unlimited supply of labour. As this labour leaves the subsistence sector where marginal productivity is negligible, zero or even negative, and moves into the capitalist sector with signicantly higher productivity, structural change and economic modernisation are realised. The industrialisation process is at the heart of the capitalist sector, but this also includes capitalist agriculture, and Lewis was highly concerned with raising agricultural productivity in order to prevent the creation of a dual economy. The original Lewis model must be restated for the analysis of economies of the Botswana type to an open-economy model, where export incomes from primary products are invested to achieve industrialisation and agricultural transformation (Adelman & Morris 1997 : 838). Such substitution for poor capital accumulation in other sectors, specically agriculture, is the primary opportunity for catching up oered to natural resource-dependent developing countries (Gerschenkron 1962). MEG marks a distinct economic epoch, and is separated from the premodern structure by six characteristics : (1) high rates of per capita and population growth; (2) high rate of rise in productivity; (3) high rate of structural transformation of the economy; (4) rapid change in social and ideological structures; (5) participation in a globalised economy; and (6) a signicant level of modern technology. At the same time as MEG represents a new structure, it also comprises the continuation of old trends, albeit in an accelerated form, and this makes the break between the premodern and the modern dicult to identify and analyse (Kuznets 1973: 2489). The conventional Botswana success story, resting on signicant growth rates due to high earnings from diamond exports, corresponds to only two of the above stated characteristics. However, the structural analysis provided in this article is concerned for all of the above presented characteristics of MEG, the presence of which would signify a break with the pre-modern growth process. Technological advance, productivity increase and structural change in patterns of production raise the income levels, while the distribution of resources and incomes via a modernised institutional structure leads to widespread improvements in human welfare. It is in the nature of development that all segments of society signicantly benet from economic gains. With such a demanding denition of development, there is only a very exclusive group of mostly Pacic Asian countries that have become developed since World War II. A lesson from the last 50 years is, however,

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

195

that economic development of developing countries is possible (Adelman 2003: 1718). The growth performance and improvements in infrastructure and human capital that are characteristics of Botswanas success are signicant, but they depend on export earnings from primary production, and the country has not reached development as dened above. The second issue to be investigated is then how pre-conditions for a transformation can be created, and whether there are any implications from the Botswana case for other natural resource-abundant countries striving for development. There is a clear connection between theories on MEG on the one hand, and development on the other. Although Kuznets only used the term development explicitly in the sense of self-sustained growth, together with structural change in production and technological advance, the redistribution of resources is implicit in the model. Kuznets (1955) hypothesised that societies prior to MEG are characterised by fairly equally distributed low levels of income and a high incidence of poverty. During the process of structural change, inequality temporarily increases, but in the modern economy the higher levels of income will be distributed to all levels of society, leading to signicantly improved living conditions. Equity, dened as equal opportunities for all members of society and an avoidance of deprivation in outcomes (World Bank 2006: xi), is both a means of reaching development and the goal of development itself. In the case of Botswana, the point of departure involved high poverty rates, combined with high degrees of inequality and growth. Adelman and Morris (1997) claim that the individual starting point is decisive for the development process, and for Botswana a conscious strategy of fairness, improvements of living standards and inclusion would then be imperative for reaching equity in development.
ECONOMIC STRUCTURAL CHANGE

Hirschman (1958) argued that in a small country with an economy dominated by a valuable natural resource, growth usually has few linkages to other aspects of the economy and society, unless there is active government involvement to substitute for stagnating sectors. Technological advance and innovation need to be paired with a exible and encouraging institutional structure, in order to produce a signicant increase in productivity. The general technological level of industry in Botswana has, however, stayed low, and productivity has not experienced any signicant increase with the exception of the mining sector. In fact, the increase in Total Factor Productivity is brought about mainly by increase in factor

196

ELLEN HILLBOM

input of capital and skilled and unskilled labour, and less than 10% of the growth in output in the 1980s and 1990s was due to increases in productivity (Leith 1997a : 2930). Unfortunately, mining employs only 4% of the labour force, is not complemented by other forms of industry, and has not encouraged or contributed to technological advance, via either imported technology or domestic innovations (Gaolathe 1997: 41213; Mpabanga 1997: 373; RoB 2004a: 12, Fig. 2.4). It mainly has spin-o eects on the public sector via government employment (Good 1993) and spending. The service sector has at present expanded to 45% of GDP (World Bank 2008a), becoming the largest sector as increased incomes allow for increased demand from government and the public for certain services and goods. Most consumption goods are imported from the Southern African Customs Union (SACU) (RoB 2003 : 114), which lowers market incentives for domestic producers. In 1968 agriculture dominated the economy, representing over 40% of GDP, only to decline to less than 2% in 2006; it continues to hold a very modest position. Mining instead expanded from 8% of GDP in 1974/75 to 53% in 1988/89, only to shrink again to roughly 35% in 2002 (Leith 1997a : 24 ; 2005: 5, Table 1.1; Siwawa-Ndai 1997 : 343, Table 2 ; World Bank 2008a). These changes represent, however, a shift in balance in the economy, rather than a rise of new sectors, export goods or modes of production. The industrial sector has grown signicantly in relative terms, but this is mainly due to the expansion of the mining sector, while manufacturing persists at roughly 4% of GDP, with gures falling over the last two decades (Mpabanga 1997: 371 ; RoB 2003: 28, Table 3.1 ; Siwawa-Ndai 1997: 347). Botswanas contemporary economy is thus not substantially more diversied than was the case at Independence (Leith 2005 : 100; Siwawa-Ndai 1997). The governments eorts to diversify have failed, and left the economy vulnerable in the long term. In 1966, government policy established that the role of the state would be one of providing infrastructure and education, while it was up to the private sector to develop manufacturing. The Botswana Meat Commission (BMC) abattoir completely dominated the manufacturing sector at Independence, accounting for over 90% of output and employment. Starting from the mid-1970s there has, however, been an intrasectoral diversication and signicant overall growth in value added, but not in relative terms in percentage of GDP ; much of the growth can be attributed to the very low starting point (Harvey & Lewis 1990: 15969 ; Owusu & Samatar 1997: 275). The government did appreciate the need to expand beyond mining and agriculture into high productivity industry, and a number of assistance schemes have been launched over the years.

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

197

TABLE 1 Shares of GDP by sector


Sector Agriculture Mining & Quarrying Manufacturing Water and Electricity Construction Trade, Hotels and Restaurants Transport Banks, Insurance & Business Services General Government Social and Personal Services Source: Adapted from RoB 2003: Table 3.1. 1966 % of GDP 42.7 5.7 0.6 7.8 9.0 4.3 20.1 9.8 1975/76 % of GDP 20.75 17.5 7.6 2.3 12.8 8.6 1.1 4.7 14.6 2.8 1985/86 % of GDP 5.6 48.9 3.9 2.0 4.6 6.3 2.5 6.4 12.8 2.5 2000/2001 % of GDP 2.6 36.5 4.1 2.4 5.8 10.3 3.8 10.9 16.0 4.0

Unfortunately these became subject to increasing abuse and subsequently failed (Leith 2005: 99100). When it came to expanding beyond the traditional and well-established sectors, Botswana exposed itself as resembling other corrupt African countries from which it is generally set apart. The inference must be that industry has not experienced signicant technological advance or innovation, achieved much increase in productivity or undergone structural change, and therefore cannot be considered as part of a transformation to MEG. Low levels of technology and productivity unfortunately also characterise the agricultural sector, which is further restrained by a hostile environment (RoB 2003 : 17882; Silitshena & McLeod 1998, chs. 910). Only 4% of the countrys area is suitable for agriculture (Parson 1984: 4), and absolute agricultural production could never be expected to become high in a country that is as climatically challenged as Botswana, with roughly two-thirds of the country comprising the Kalahari Desert. In the 1930s, Batswana farmers grew 90% of the countrys cereals consumption, but production decreased and in the 1980s the gure was 50%. Consequently, in 1991 the Botswana government abandoned its previous goal of self-suciency in food production, and instead adopted a policy of food security (Silitshena & McLeod 1998 : 889). The country is today totally dependent on SACU for imports, while elds and animals yield even below the requirements for subsistence, and many households depend on complementary o-farm incomes (Gulbrandsen 1996: 23). The advancement of cattle rearing has been the most prominent government venture in the agricultural sector, in colonial times and

198

ELLEN HILLBOM

after Independence. Already in the late 1920s and 1930s, the colonial administration started borehole drilling schemes, as beef exports were conceived as the only comparative advantage of the Bechuanaland Protectorate (see e.g. Carlsson 2003: 1537;1 Lawry 1983: 2; Parsons & Crowder 1988; Peters 1994, ch. 3). This assumption turned out to be valid, in the sense that until the present the countrys only signicant agricultural export has been beef, and it will continue to be so in the foreseeable future. At Independence, beef represented 85% of Bechuanalands total export earnings, a gure that had dropped to 2% in 2006 (Colcough & McCarthy 1980 : 32; Harvey & Lewis 1990: 7882; Leith 1997b : 530 ; RoB 2007). In 1975 the Botswana government negotiated favourable conditions from the Beef and Veal Protocol of the Lome Convention, which guaranteed exports to Europe with high prots due to signicant reductions in taris (Harvey & Lewis 1990: 7882; Siwawa-Ndai 1997: 363). The independence government has continued in the footsteps of its colonial predecessors : constructing water sources, subsidising veterinary services, distributing vaccines, building veterinary fences, and setting up the BMC as a monopsony buyer of cattle and exporter of meat (Acemoglu et al. 2003 : 101; Lawry 1983 : 14). The livestock sector presently contributes 80% to agricultural GDP, but ranching in Botswana is a low technology sector, and not much has happened in terms of technological advance since the introduction of modern boreholes and the establishment of the Lobatse abattoir in 1954. Despite its decreasing relative contribution to the economy and low productivity, the cattle sector is continuously expanding as the numbers of animals increase, although there have been severe setbacks in drought years. At the same time there is a polarisation in cattle ownership, with increasing numbers of small-scale farmers without cattle at the one end, and large holders at the other (Gulbrandsen 1996 : 3 ; Peters 1994 : Silitshena & McLeod 1998, ch. 11). The continued striving by the large cattle-holders to amass more animals can be explained by the high social status that is still associated with cattle, and by the export prots channelled to individual cattle holders by the BMC. From a national economic and environmental sustainability point of view, this expansion of the cattle sector is unwarranted, as natural resources such as water and land are being heavily exploited while returns are modest. In the general model for MEG, productivity increase in subsistence agriculture resulting in agricultural transformation should generate capital and free labour that can move over to industry and other capitalist sectors, thereby becoming a starting point for structural change (see e.g. Lewis 1954 ; Mellor 1986). However, in the case of Botswana it would not be realistic to expect the agricultural sector to initiate MEG. In order to avoid

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

199

creating a dual economy with a disadvantaged countryside, it is still important for there to be an agricultural transformation including an adoption of new farming methods, which could increase productivity and raise standards of living. When the agricultural sector is failing to ll its role as the engine of MEG, other more successful sectors in the case of Botswana the mining industry could substitute for its shortcomings in forming capital, thereby becoming the engine of development (Gerschenkron 1962). Botswana has been urbanising quickly for the last four decades, and has moved from 4% living in urban settlements at Independence (Gulbrandsen 1996: 19) to 58% at present (Leith 2005: 13, Table 1.2 ; World Bank 2008b). This could be viewed as a sign of structural change, but although urbanisation entails a profound reorganisation of the population and has implications for various aspects of human development, it is not equivalent to growth in the industrial or capitalist sectors in which high productivity is found. Lewis original model is often misunderstood, and quoted as an argument for economic development centred on a process of labour moving from agriculture to industry, and urbanisation equalling industrialisation. Both industry and agriculture are part of the capitalist sector, and although the subsistence sector is primarily associated with premodern agriculture, it is common in developing countries for subsistence sectors to expand also in urban areas, the most evident case being informal self-employment. Botswanas prime engine of growth, the diamond sector, is neither located in the urban areas, nor does it have signicant links to other sectors of industry. The urban settlements are instead attracting labour that nds employment within the government administration, service sector, household employment, trade, and so on, some of it in the formal and some in the informal sector. Labour is thus mainly moving from subsistence agriculture to non-capitalist urban sectors, and provides yet another indicator that structural change and MEG are not present. Since the early 1990s, a serious unemployment problem has been registered, with 18% unemployment in 2005/06 (RoB 2006: 2), and as long as the industrial sector is not expanding, the gure will probably not improve signicantly. With high urban unemployment rates, as in the case of Botswana, individuals motives for migrating to the urban areas can be questioned, but also explained in a satisfactory fashion. Urbanisation becomes rational behaviour at the individual level, as economic models shift focus from full employment equilibrium to expected rather than actual contemporary and future urban wages (Todaro 1969) and relative deprivation (Stark 1991). Instead of being a sign of modernisation, urbanisation should in the Botswana case be perceived as a symptom of a dual economy with a poor and neglected rural sector.

200

ELLEN HILLBOM

Lipton (1977) points out that the most important class conict in developing countries today is that between the rural poor, and urban groups experiencing improvements in living standards and human capital. There is an urban bias favouring the larger cities and industry at the expense of the countryside and agriculture, which drives a process creating dual economies. It is damaging because it is counter-productive to both an eciency norm, implying an allocation of resources to maximise long-run output, and an equity norm, distributing income so as to maximise welfare. As long as most of the poor are located in the rural areas, and agricultural production is characterised by low levels of technology and productivity compared with the urban sector, the highest returns will be on investments made in the rural sector. Urban bias thus slows down both growth and development. In Botswana most agricultural production has been in the private sector, and the government has merely provided a framework of infrastructure, administration, education and utilities. While government spending on agriculture has been small compared with that in urban areas (Harvey & Lewis 1990: 2523), private investments have not succeeded in compensating for the lack of government involvement. Rapid urbanisation can also be explained by historical migration patterns, revealing that the Batswana have a long tradition of moving in order to farm, to nd pasture, and for wage employment. In the rural areas, each household may have as many as three dwellings in the village, at the arable elds and by the cattle post and household members move between them depending on season and assignments. With the colonial era came the demand for payment of taxes, and new labour migration patterns were established as the men left in large numbers to nd employment in the mines of neighbouring South Africa (Schapera & Comaro 1991: 24). This had severe negative impacts on agricultural production, and caused social unrest and disrupted family units (Colcough & McCarthy 1980, ch. 7). These patterns of temporary movement within the rural areas and between the rural and urban are still in place. As in the case of urbanisation, however, neither can be associated with labour moving from subsistence to national capitalist sectors, nor do they promote structural change.
MANAGING NATURAL RESOURCES

The economic history of Botswana is to a large extent the story of natural resource management, generous gifts and limiting scarcity, which thus have an inescapable place in a structural analysis. It is most unlikely that the Botswana growth miracle could have occurred unless diamonds had been found at Independence, and the government had nationalised all

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

201

sub-soil mineral resources in 1967, thereby gaining control over future revenues. Historical circumstances provided a combination of a perfect resource that is valuable, storable and cheap to transport, and perfect timing, assuring uncontested incomes to the newly established government. Without diamonds, the country could very well have had a functioning institutional structure oering economical and political stability, but it is hard to imagine any other way of achieving comparable consistent growth. Parallel with its diamond deposits, the country has severe constraints to economic expansion. It is landlocked, resulting in high transport costs, it has no internationally competitive wage advantage, the climate is unfriendly to agricultural expansion and intensication, and there are no other comparatively valuable natural resources. Until the 1970s, economists in general had a favourable view of abundant natural resources. Many developing countries that became independent in the decades after World War II possessed great wealth in primary products, and this was understood as almost a guarantee for future growth. The actual outcome, however, was other than expected, as the following decades saw the economic growth and development of the Newly Industrialising Economies in East Asia, stagnation in Latin America and economic and political failure in sub-Saharan Africa. The empirical evidence from most resource-abundant countries has for the last 3040 years included corrupt leaders selling o natural assets and pocketing the prots, individuals and international companies becoming wealthy while governments stayed poor, and nancial policies unable to control exchange rates and ination. Meanwhile, low wages have become a stronger comparative advantage than resource wealth. In theory, abundant natural resources are still believed to promote growth by allowing for investments in infrastructure and human capital (see e.g. Sachs & Warner 1999), but from the 1990s onwards there has also been a lively debate focusing on negative aspects such as the natural resource curse (see e.g. Leite & Weidman 1999; Sachs & Warner 1995), and Dutch disease (see e.g. Corden & Neary 1982; Hill 1991). Sachs and Warner (1995) have shown that there is generally a negative correlation between natural resource endowments and economic growth. This is a paradox, since incomes from natural resources raises wealth and purchasing power over imports and, hence, should also raise investment levels and growth rates. The explanations given for the failure of many resource-abundant countries vary, and include higher prevalence of indolence, rent seeking, conict between stakeholders, corruption, and predation, compared with economies relying on other comparative advantages. While being the eighteenth largest resource exporter in the

202

ELLEN HILLBOM

world (Iimi 2006: 6), Botswana has managed to avoid both the resource curse and Dutch disease, by creating a long-term plan for the extraction of natural resources and good policy for continued growth (Hill 1991; Iimi 2006). This achievement makes it a member of a very exclusive group of developing countries, including only a few others such as Mauritius and Malaysia (Sachs & Warner 1995). The standard explanation for Botswanas successful management of incomes from its diamonds has some compulsory elements. The government has extracted diamonds wisely and negotiated a 5050% deal with the South African mining company De Beers, thus ensuring signicant revenues for the country. As a result, diamonds account for roughly 30% of GDP, 70% of export revenues and 50% of government revenue (RoB 2003 : 28, Table 3.1, 205, Table 11.1, 206, Table 11.3). By comparison with other African states, Botswanas leaders have mostly been honest, and elite corruption was rare until the 1990s. The government has shown great prudence in the management of diamond incomes, keeping expenses consistent in boom years and building up foreign exchange reserves, thereby being able to compensate for bust years. This strategy, combined with proper management of the exchange rate, has also meant that real exchange rate appreciation has been under control, which has been positive for the export sector. Through scal policy the government has avoided external debt problems, and has maintained a stable growth rate over time (Hill 1991). There is a general consensus on the shrewdness of government scal policies, both in building international reserves, but also in investing in key sectors such as infrastructure, education and health care. Government actions have been in line with IMF recommendations and have certainly assured growth. Much praise is given to the government for this achievement, but the relevance of the Dutch disease debate for the structural analysis is questionable. It is agreed that Botswana does not suer from Dutch disease, although all the typical pre-conditions are present. The country has a dominating and lucrative tradable natural resource sector that supports a growing non-tradable service sector, while the tradable manufacturing sector is relatively weak. The greater the income from natural resource exports the higher the demands for the nontradable sector, and consequently the less capital and labour is available for the manufacturing sector (Corden & Neary 1982; Iimi 2006: 5). What sets Botswana apart from the typical Dutch disease syndrome is the fact that at Independence Botswana had an insignicant manufacturing sector, which consequently could not be ruined by the allocation of capital and labour to other sectors. It would, however, be fair to claim that the country is caught in a natural resource trap. As long as diamonds dominate

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

203

government revenues, there is an indirect discrimination against a diversication of the economy, there are few incentives for industrialisation and productivity increase, and consequently the process of structural change is hindered. Absurd as it may seem, HIV/AIDS may well not lead to economic collapse in Botswana, because the mining sector may not be too severely aected, as it needs a workforce of only 8,000 paid employees (RoB 2004a: 24, Table 2.1). Growth could then continue in the midst of human tragedy and social collapse. Of course, although the mining sector may be unaected, the epidemic makes it even less likely that MEG will appear in the near future, due to the immense stress on society at large and on the economy outside the mining industry. Long before diamonds were discovered, the Botswana economy was centred on cattle. Access to land and water resources was thus the key for creating wealth, guaranteeing future incomes and setting up patronclient relationships. The Tswana had a unique settlement pattern, with the population concentrated in larger villages surrounded by arable elds, with the grazing ranges situated further away. Natural resources used to be communally owned, and each household was allocated land and water resources by the chiefs according to its needs. Individuals were given private user rights to arable elds and water sources, while cattle were grazed on communal ranges, and each household privately owned and controlled its own production (see e.g. Carlsson 2003: ch. 5 ; Colough & McCarthy 1980: ch.1; Peters 1994). Communal ownership of natural resources, combined with private user rights to resource units and private ownership of production, is a property rights system common to rural communities in sub-Saharan Africa (see e.g. Berry 1994 ; Carlsson 2003: ch. 5; Ensminger 1997; Perrings 1992). While the property rights institutions in rural Botswana have not experienced signicant structural change, individuals have struggled with one another within the institutional frameworks, conducting negotiations and taking advantage of positions of power (Carlsson 2003). These power struggles have concentrated resources in the hands of the wealthier segments of society, while at the same time upholding a minimal basic needs level for the poor that is guaranteed by traditional property rights (see e.g. Carlsson 2003; Peters 1994). In customary Tswana land tenure, resources belonged to the tribe and were kept in trust by the chief, who was also in charge of land policy. In 1968 the implementation of the Tribal Land Act meant that the tribal land remained as communal property, but the allocation responsibilities were removed from the chief and assigned to newly established Land Boards

204

ELLEN HILLBOM

which were to follow traditional allocation principles (Gulbrandsen 1984 : 79). In the 1970s, the government became increasingly concerned with the issue of overgrazing, and in 1975 the Tribal Grazing Land Policy was launched, dividing all land into three categories : communal, private and wildlife reserves. It was argued that the move of larger herds to fenced-o private farms would reduce the pressure on the communal grazing range. With these two land tenure reforms, the government took over responsibility for land distribution from the tribal authorities and allocated private land to the largest cattle holders, while not doing much to promote grazing management among smallholders on communal land (Lawry 1983 : 1925). In a dry country such as Botswana, water is a scarce key resource for all economic activities, both agricultural and industrial. In the densely populated south-eastern parts of the country, there is likely to be a shortage in water by the year 2020 if demand continues to increase at the present rate (Silitshena & McLeod 1998 : ch. 5). Still, little is being done to promote conservation and hinder pollution in rural and urban areas, although progressive water fees have been introduced primarily in the urban settlements. There may be several reasons for the political unwillingness to be more forceful in using pricing and command and control measurements in order to reduce water use. One is a dread of losing political support ; another is a principle of securing the poor the rights to free clean water for drinking purposes. Instead of reducing demand and preventing pollution, the government has relied on increasing supply through various water development projects, but it can be questioned whether current policy either represents a sustainable strategy or promotes a more ecient use of water resources (Carlsson 2003; Rahm et al. 2006). Traditionally, wealth was measured in cattle and, by controlling cattle and lending them to kin and other tribe members, chiefs bought political loyalty and access to labour resources (Lawry 1983: 3). Access to and income from cattle are still central to both the urban elite and rural dwellers. Due to the economic elites interest in investing in cattle, the national herd has increased to a point threatening both grazing and water resources. Colcough and McCarthy (1980: 22) estimate that the national herd grew tenfold from the beginning of the twentieth century, reaching 3 million head by 1978. The numbers then decreased during the 1980s due to droughts, and reached 2 million in the early 1990s (Silitshena & McLeod 1998 : 122,, Table 11.1), only to increase again to 3 million at present (Rahm et al. 2006 : 159). The solution to overgrazing has been to extend further into the Kalahari desert, and to extend private tenure (Lawry 1983: 11). As the large cattle holders and the

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

205

political elite are the same, there is modest political will to protect natural resources and to inict eciency demands on the cattle sector. The number of animals is increasing and so is production, but productivity has not been improved to any signicant degree and structural change is absent.
INEQUALITY AND DEVELOPMENT

Growth is valued not because it further enriches the already well-o, but because it gives an opportunity to signicantly and lastingly improve standards of living for the majority, including the poor. For a country to achieve the characteristics of development, poverty must be alleviated, income levels be considerably improved, and resources and opportunities be distributed by a modern state in order for all segments of society to benet (Adelman 2003: 1718). Traditional unequal distribution of resources and incomes, and a dual economy with discriminated sectors and groups within society, dene a society as prior to MEG. The systematic relationship between economic growth and income inequalities has been discussed theoretically and investigated empirically ever since Kuznets (1955) presented his inverted U-curve, and there is today a consensus that no straightforward relation can be established (World Bank 2006: 44, Box 2.6). There is, however, an inseparable link between equity, dened as equal opportunities for all, and avoidance of absolute deprivation (ibid.: 1819). Equity likewise plays an important role in promoting development, as it frees people from the poverty trap and strengthens the political institutional structure. By ensuring higher overall levels of income and the support of a modern state, the rural poor can aord to turn away from being risk minimisers and instead become utility optimisers, contributing to the economy through their human capital capacities and raised productivity, and bringing considerably increased supply and demand to the domestic market (Lipton 1968). All members of society represent assets in human and social capital, and in order to create sustainable prosperity these resources should be made use of to the fullest. Equitable institutions include all individuals in the development process, oering them equal opportunities by protecting their property rights and giving them equal treatment before the law. Causation, however, runs both ways, and the increased capabilities of individuals result in higher demands on a well-functioning modern institutional structure in both economic and political terms (World Bank 2006: ch. 6).

206

ELLEN HILLBOM

Developing countries with signicant mineral resources and abundant land tend to be less equal in resource distribution than others (Bourguignon & Morrisson 1990 : 11278), and Botswana ts this characterisation. By international standards, income divides are high in Botswana. They have been so in historical perspective, and have probably increased during the decades of exceptional growth. Today Botswana has one of the highest levels of income inequality in the world, together with some Latin American and sub-Sahara African nations (Good 1993: 203 ; Jeeris 1997: 4936). The current national GINI coecient as assessed by UNDP (2006) is 0.6. Despite substantial growth, 47% of the population lives below the national poverty line (UNDP 2006), and there are reports of prevailing and even increasing rural poverty, at least in certain regions (see e.g. Gulbrandsen 1996; Wikan 2004). The fact that the divide between the richest and the poorest groups in society is widening may not in itself be a severe reason for concern. What is disturbing is that the divergence is combined with high unemployment, continued high poverty rates and discrimination against certain groups, specically the San (see e.g. Curry 1987 ; Good 1993). Together, this reects an institutional inequality where government policies tend to favour elites in various ways, while denying the majority of the population equal opportunities (Engerman & Sokolo 2002 ; World Bank 2006: 1078). Even worse, contemporary inequalities appear to be inherent in the socio-economic structure going back in history (see e.g. Good 1994: 205 ; Peters 1994; Wylie 1990), and there is no structural change. Unemployment rates are important for equity, since a prominent way of eradicating poverty is through growth, resulting in formal employment and increasing real wages (Quibria 2002). Much of the explanation for the Pacic Asia miracle rests on equal opportunities and distribution of resources. The unemployed in Botswana are primarily youths and individuals with little or no education, possibly with a higher proportion of women. A fundamental requirement for making demand meet supply appears to be to increase the level of education, specically university degrees, in the workforce (Siphambe 2003). There has been both a trickle down from the wealthier segments of society, and a political consciousness of the need to ght high poverty rates. As a result, poverty in terms of income levels has improved from 59% of individuals being poor in 1985 (Jeeris 1997: 484, Table 2) to 47% in 2005 (UNDP 2006). These gures may stand out in a regional context, but have not been achieved through structural change. It is important to keep in mind that attitudes towards inequality and poverty are rooted in

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

207

TABLE 2 GINI Coecients


Disposable Cash Income Region Cities/Towns Urban Villages Rural National 1993/94 0.548 0.552 0.599 0.638 2002/03 0.513 0.552 0.622 0.626 Disposable Income 1993/94 0.539 0.451 0.414 0.537 2002/03 0.503 0.523 0.515 0.573

Source: RoB 2004b. Higher numbers indicate greater inequality.

normative values, and that distribution of resources and incomes are subject to conscious government policies. Government policy on distribution of wealth in Botswana has mainly been the equivalent of a basic needs system, giving support to the poor via food-for-work programmes that have been running during droughts since 1965 (Colcough & McCarthy 1980: 133), as well as providing health care and education free of charge until recently. During the colonial era, the British spent little in excess of administrative costs in the Bechuanaland Protectorate. The independence government has, however, spent about 40% of GDP primarily on infrastructure and human capital, a gure that is one of the highest in Africa and comparable with Norway (Acemoglu et al. 2003: 85; Leith 2005: 85, Fig. 3.9). In 1966, there were only 12 kilometres of paved roads (Acemoglu et al. 2003 : 80), while today this gure is almost 9,000 kilometres. There are 85 airports, over a million telephone subscribers out of a population of 1.7 million, 60,000 internet users (CIA 2008), and 95% of the population has access to improved water sources (World Bank 2008b). The British considered education to be a tribal responsibility, and at Independence there were fewer than two dozen Batswana who had received university education and 100 who had completed secondary school (Acemoglu et al. 2003: 803 ; Colough & McCarthy 1980: 28). Today adult literacy rates are 81%, and more than 5% of the population has completed tertiary education (World Bank 2008a, 2008b). Contemporary health indicators are severely negatively aected by the rampant HIV/AIDS epidemic, which makes them dicult to evaluate. It is, however, relevant to point out that although they were good they were never exceptional, and that less has been spent on health improvement than on education (Leith 2005: 86, Fig. 3.10). In the early 1990s, before the impact of HIV/AIDS, the best gures recorded for life expectancy and infant mortality were 65 years

208

ELLEN HILLBOM

and 45 out of 1,000 births respectively (Leith 1997a : 23, Fig. 2 ; 2005: 13, Table 1.2). Government policy has given better results than can be detected simply from levels of income poverty, as it has improved human capital and the capabilities of the poor. In a broader based approach the concept of capability poverty can be used, in which case Botswana scores much more favourably, with 30% suering from capability poverty in 1996 according to UNDP, as opposed to 46% being income poor in the same year (Jeeris 1997 : 4923). The actions of the Botswana government in improving capabilities have thus been commendable, but they have not automatically generated dynamic processes of increasing productivity and are not equivalent to equity. Indeed, the reliance on government welfare programmes has made many rural destitutes passive, and cemented existing structures (see e.g. Nthomang 2004 ; Wikan 2004). In the agricultural sector, poverty is a matter more of access to resources than of income levels, and since smallholders are mainly subsistence farmers, their standards of living are dicult to estimate. A minimal access to resources is generally guaranteed within the traditional property rights systems, where key resources such as water and land have a strong public goods dimension (Carlsson 2003: 1017). Batswana farmers are vulnerable and prone to poverty due to limiting climatic and soil conditions and recurring droughts. This weakness of the agricultural sector has implications for poverty reduction on a national level, as traditional agriculture is only estimated to be able to support 1520% of the labour force, thereby augmenting the pressure on other sectors for oering employment (Jeeris 1997 : 478). Distribution of wealth is to a high degree associated with distribution of cattle, which has a long history of being very unequal, with the traditional chiefs and their relatives being the largest cattle holders (Colcough & McCarthy 1980: 22 ; Lawry 1983: 6). Cattle continue to be amassed by a minority of large holders, while the number of cattleless smallholders is increasing. In the 1940s only 10% of households had no cattle, while in 1993/94 that gure was 57%. In 1990 33% of cattle holders had on average six beasts each, while 35 commercial farms, representing 0.6% of cattle holders, held above 4,000 head on average, and 19 farms held more than 10,000 (Good 1993: 2234; Silitshena & McLeod 1998 : 127). After Independence, the traditional economic elite moved into the new state, establishing a strong connection between large cattle holders and government. In the early years of Independence, two-thirds of the members of the National Assembly were large or medium sized cattle owners (Samatar 1999 : 6970).

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

209

There is a well-documented and uncontested history of the economic and political elite being one and the same in Botswana (see e.g. Acemoglu et al. 2003 ; Good 1993 ; Peters 1994 ; Wylie 1990). Very few Europeans ever settled in the Bechuanaland Protectorate as they saw little future in either agriculture or mining, and only 3% of farm land came under European control (Colcough & McCarthy 1980: 7). This marginal colonial inuence allowed the Tswana political and economical institutional structure to stay strong, and to guarantee a continuity in the social structure of the precolonial, colonial, and post-colonial era (Acemoglu et al. 2003; Colcough & McCarthy 1980: ch. 1). That the political and economic elite are identical is presented by some researchers as a decisive factor explaining Botswanas economic success (see e.g. Acemoglu et al. 2003 : 104). Maintaining the status quo has, however, allowed this elite to protect its own interests, and there is no reason to assume that it would act according to anything other than its own selfinterest (Kaufmann & Kraay 2002 : 204). The political elite is further connected to the leading bureaucrats, who share common economic interests in cattle and commerce (Good 1994: 499). This overlap between the wealthy, the political leaders and the bureaucracy explains the lack of interest in equity in resource and income redistribution. The theory of MEG, however, implies that growth has to lead to shifts in the economic position of various groups attached to particular production sectors. Hence, old economic elites have to be challenged and transformed or replaced, in order for new production sectors to appear, together signifying a break with old economic and social structures (Kuznets 1973: 252). Such change may not be welcome in the eyes of the elite. While pre-modern growth is in their best interest, it is questionable whether they are motivated to promote development, as this requires structural change and not the continuity of existing political institutions. If the elite is interested in maintaining the status quo, the demand for change and equity may come instead from the grass-roots level, but this does not appear to be the case in Botswana, as there are no sizeable social movements or contesting political parties (Good 1994 : 518). Political stability, consensus building and economic growth appear to have dampened the opposition. Diamonds have kept all content and happy, as there has been some for all, and a lot for a few.
ANALYSIS AND IMPLICATIONS

As sub-Saharan African countries became independent in the mid-1950s through to the beginning of the 1970s, there was a great optimism for the

210

ELLEN HILLBOM

future. Income levels were higher than in many Asian regions and on par with Latin America, the continent held great riches in natural resources and Africans were nally free to form their own destiny. Unfortunately, the continent soon became troubled by ethnic and racial conict, political unrest, violent crime, ravaging poverty, economic failure and resignation, predatory leaders and rampant corruption. Political and economic stagnation, decline, and chaos have been widespread experiences since the 1970s, and the overall economic crisis triggered the introduction of the Structural Adjustment Programmes in the 1980s. Since then, the continents aspirations have been lowered. Stability and growth have been viewed not just as acceptable or sucient achievements, but even as the best imaginable result, while development has been reduced to an almost forgotten utopia. It is in this context that Botswana has qualied to be depicted as an exceptional success story. What the country has experienced for the last 40 years is export-led growth combined with political stability. It is not enough, however, to rest content with describing only the Botswana growth miracle, without discussing its fundamental socio-economic structure and possible future improvements. The key issue is MEG, development and structural change. Despite impressive growth, political stability, improved infrastructure, prudent nancial management, material modernisation and investments in human capital, Botswana is at present also experiencing a decline in population, there is no signicant increase in productivity, little economic, social or ideological transformation, and only sporadic introduction of high levels of modern technology. Hence, four out of six characteristics of MEG are missing, and the inference must be that Botswana is a case of pre-modern growth and not development, while the socio-economic structure is being cemented and hailed as stability. Although continuity is an active process and may contain dynamic institutional change, it does not amount to a break with earlier structures, and the lack of structural change is the reason behind faltering development indicators. The advances that have been made are indeed very promising, but they are only pre-conditions for turning growth into development, while there are few signs that structural change is promoted either by agriculture or industry, by the elite or the grass-roots level. Neither is equity part of Botswanas strategy, although it is a necessary ingredient in development. Botswana has experienced a profound change in factor relative price, due to a massive increase in capital primarily from diamond exports, and the success of the mining sector has the potential of becoming a window of

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

211

opportunity for development. This sector could substitute for missing capital formation in the low producing agriculture, and help transform agriculture as well as diversify industry. In order for this to be realised, however, the government has to step up and take on the challenge to become a developmental state. The success of Pacic Asia provides several important lessons concerning economic development. It shows that development is possible, and that a developmental state can create the institutional structure necessary for subsequent development. Through intentional policy choices, countries such as Botswana can shift from a trade-led, natural resource intensive, limited industrialisation with narrow based growth, to a broader development strategy. Further, although development is a process that entails a discontinuous break with earlier structures, it is also pathdependent in that each country has a unique economic, political, and social history, and an existing institutional setting. All development strategies must take this into account. The economic and political institutional structures are of equal importance in this process of development, and are closely linked to one another (Adelman 2003: 1721). Botswana oers lessons for other natural resource dependent developing countries, in the importance of prudent management in avoiding the natural resource curse and Dutch disease, as well as the blessing of leaders who have been relatively modest in their rent seeking. It can thereby be a model for how to achieve important pre-conditions for development, but it cannot be a model for actual development, since there has been no transformation into modernisation. The progress of Botswana is truly commendable, but the goal for any society must be development through MEG, and the next step is to leave the safe haven of stability and growth to venture into structural change and development. With a developmental state promoting equity and bringing prosperity to all segments of society, Botswana could use its diamond wealth to diversify industry, transform agriculture, and become a modern society. This is necessary for long-run economic sustainability because it is development and not diamonds that lasts forever.
NOTES

1. Published under the maiden name of the present author.

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson & J. Robinson. 2003. An African success story: Botswana, in D. Rodrik, ed. In Search of Prosperity: analytic narratives on economic growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 80119.

212

ELLEN HILLBOM

Adelman, I. 2003. Global institutions and economic development what have we learned?, in M. Andersson & C. Gunnarsson, eds. Development and Structural Change in Asia-Pacic: globalising miracles or end of a model? London: Routledge, 1747. Adelman, I. & C. T. Morris. 1997. Editorial: development history and its implications for development theory, World Development 25, 6: 83140. Allen, T. & S. Heald. 2004. HIV/AIDS policy in Africa: what has worked in Uganda and what has failed in Botswana? , Journal of International Development 16: 114154. Beaulier, S. & R. Subrick. 2006. The political foundations of development: the case of Botswana, Constitutional Political Economy 17, 2: 10315. Berry, S. 1994. No Condition is Permanent: the social dynamics of agrarian change in sub-Saharan Africa. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press. Bourguignon, F. & C. Morrisson. 1990. Income distribution, development and foreign trade: a crosssectional analysis, European Economic Review 34, 6 : 111332. Carlsson, E. 2003. To Have and to Hold: continuity and change in property rights institutions governing water resources among the Meru of Tanzania and the BaKgtala in Botswana, 19252000. Lund Studies in Economic History, 28. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell International. Central Intelligence Agency (CIA). 2006. The World Factbook: Botswana. <https://www.cia.gov/cia/ publications/factbook/geos/bc.html> accessed 15.12.2006. Colcough, C. & S. McCarthy. 1980. The Political Economy of Botswana: a study of growth and distribution. Oxford University Press. Corden, W. & J. Neary. 1982. Booming sector and de-industrialisation in a small open economy, Economic Journal 92: 82548. Curry, R. L. Jr. 1987. Poverty and mass unemployment in mineral-rich Botswana, American Journal of Economics and Sociology 46, 1: 7187. Engerman, S. & K. Sokolo. 2002. Factor endowments, inequality, and paths of development among New World economies, Economia 3, 1: 41108. Ensminger, J. 1997. Changing property rights: reconciling formal and informal rights to land in Africa, in J. Drobak & J. Nye, eds. The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics. San Diego, CA: Academic Press. Gaolathe, B. 1997. Development of Botswanas mineral sector, in Salkin et al., eds. Aspects of the Botswana Economy, 40131. Gerschenkron, A. 1962. Economic backwardness in historical perspective, in A. Gerschenkron, ed. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press, 530. Good, K. 1993. At the ends of the ladder: radical inequalities in Botswana, Journal of Modern African Studies 31, 2: 20330. Good, K. 1994. Corruption and mismanagement in Botswana : a best case example?, Journal of Modern African Studies 32, 3 : 499521. Gulbrandsen, O. 1984. When land becomes scarce, Bergen Studies in Social Anthropology 33. Bergen: Norse Publications. Gulbrandsen, O. 1996. Poverty in the midst of plenty, Bergen Studies in Social Anthropology 45. Bergen: Norse Publications. Harvey, C. & S. R. Lewis, Jr. 1990. Policy Choice and Development Performance in Botswana. London: Macmillan in association with the OECD Development Centre. Heald, S. 2006. Abstain or die : the development of HIV/AIDS policy in Botswana, Journal of Biosocial Science 38, 1: 113. Hill, C. 1991. Managing commodity booms in Botswana, World Development 19, 9: 118596. Hirschman, A. 1958. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven, CT : Yale University Press. Iimi, A. 2006. Did Botswana escape from the resource curse?, IMF Working Paper 06/138, Washington, DC : IMF. Jeeris, K. 1997. Poverty in Botswana, in Salkin et al., eds. Aspects of the Botswana Economy, 46999. Kaufmann, D. & A. Kraay. 2002. Growth without governance, Economica 3, 1: 169229. Kuznets, S. 1955. Economic growth and income inequality, American Economic Review 65, 1: 128. Kuznets, S. 1973. Modern economic growth: ndings and reections, American Economic Review 63, 3: 24758. Lawry, S. 1983. Land tenure, land policy, and small livestock in Botswana, Research paper No. 78, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin, Madison, WI. Leite, C. & J. Weidmann. 1999. Does Mother Nature corrupt? Natural resources, corruption, and economic growth, IMF Working Paper 99/85, Washington, DC: IMF.

DIAMONDS OR DEVELOPMENT IN BOTSWANA

213

Leith, C. 1997a. Growth and structural transformation in Botswana, in Salkin et al., eds. Aspects of the Botswana Economy, 2135. Leith, C. 1997b. Botswanas International Trade Policies, in Salkin et al., eds. Aspects of the Botswana Economy, 52948. Leith, C. 2005. Why Botswana Prospered. Montreal & Kingston: McGill-Queens University Press. Lekoko, R. N. & M. van der Merwe. 2006. Beyond the rhetoric of empowerment: speak the language, live the experience of the rural poor, Review of Education 52: 32332. Lewis, A. 1954. Economic development with unlimited supply of labour, The Manchester School 2, 2: 13991. Lewis, A. 1979. Dual economy revisited, The Manchester School, 47, 3: 2219. Lipton, M. 1968. Theory on the optimising peasant , Journal of Development Studies 4, 3: 32751. Lipton, M. 1977. Why Poor People Stay Poor: a study of urban bias in world development. London: Maurice Temple Smith. Makgala, C. J. 2006. Elite Conict in Botswana: a history. Pretoria: African Institute of South Africa. Mellor, J. 1986. Agriculture on the road to industrialisation, in J. P. Lewis & V. Kallab, eds. Development Strategies Reconsidered. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books, for The Overseas Development Council, Washington, DC. Mpabanga, D. 1997. Constraints to industrial development , in Salkin et al., eds. Aspects of the Botswana Economy, 36987. Nthomang, K. 2004. Relentless colonialism: the case of the Remote Area Development Programme (RADP) and the Basarwa in Botswana, Journal of Modern African Studies 42, 3: 42535. Owusu, F. & A. I. Samatar. 1997. Industrial strategy and the African state : the Botswana experience , Canadian Journal of African Studies 31, 2: 26899. Parson, J. 1984. Botswana: liberal democracy and labor reserve in Southern Africa. Boulder, CO: Westview. Parsons, N. & M. Crowder, eds. 1988. Monarch of All I Survey: Bechuanaland Diaries 192937. Gaborone : The Botswana Society. Perrings, C. 1992. Sustainable development of the human and natural resources of sub-Saharan Africa: the case of Botswana, report prepared for the Technology and Employment Branch, International Labour Oce, Riverside. Peters, P. 1994. Dividing the Commons: politics, policy, and culture in Botswana. Charlottesville, VA : University Press of Virginia. Phaladze, N. & S. Tlou. 2006. Gender and HIV/AIDS in Botswana: a focus on inequalities and discrimination, Gender and Development 14, 1: 2335. Quibria, M. G. 2002. Growth and poverty: lessons from the East Asian miracle revisited, ADB Institute Research Paper Series, No. 33, Asian Development Bank, ADB Institute, Tokyo. Rahm, D., L. Swatuk & E. Matheny. 2006. Water resource management in Botswana: balancing sustainability and economic development , Environment, Development, and Sustainability 8: 15783. Republic of Botswana (RoB). 2003. National Development Plan 9. Gaborone: Ministry of Finance & Development Planning. RoB. 2004a. Labour Statistics 2002. Gaborone : Government Printer. RoB. 2004b. 2002/03 Household Income and Expenditure Survey: Botswana. Gaborone: Central Statistics Oce. <http://www.cso.gov.bw/> accessed 28.09.2007. RoB. 2006. Preliminary 2005/2006 Labour Force Survey Results. Gaborone : Central Statistics Oce, <http://www.cso.gov.bw/> accessed 25.9.2007. RoB. 2007. Table 3A: Export by Principal Commodities , in Trade Statistics. Gaborone: Central Statistics Oce, <http://www.cso.gov.bw/> accessed 28.9.2007. Robinson, J. A. & N. Parsons. 2006. State formation and governance in Botswana, Journal of African Economies 15 (AERC Supplement 1): 10040. Sachs, J. & A. Warner. 1995. Natural resource abundance and economic growth, Development Discussion Paper No. 517a, Harvard Institute for International Development, Harvard University. Sachs, J. & A. Warner 1999. The big push, natural resource booms and growth, Journal of Development Economics 59: 4376. Salkin, J. S., D. Mpabanga, D. Cowan, J. Selwe & M. Wright, eds. 1997. Aspects of the Botswana Economy. Gaborone: Lentswe La Lesedi. Samatar, A. I. 1999. An African Miracle: state and class leadership and colonial legacy in Botswana development. Portsmouth, NH: Heinemann. Schapera, I & J. Comaro. 1991. The Tswana. London: Kegan Paul International, revised edition. Sen, A. 1999. Development as Freedom. Oxford University Press.

214

ELLEN HILLBOM

Silitshena, R. M. K. & G. McLeod. 1998. Botswana : a physical, social and economic geography. Gaborone: Longman Botswana, 2nd edition. Siphambe, H. K. 2003. Understanding unemployment in Botswana, South African Journal of Economics 71, 3 : 48095. Siwawa-Ndai, P. 1997. Industrialisation in Botswana: evolution, performance and prospects, in Salkin et al., eds. Aspects of the Botswana Economy, 33567. Stark, O. 1991. The Migration of Labor. Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell. Todaro, M. 1969. A model of labor migration and urban unemployment in less developed countries, American Economic Review 59, 1: 13848. UNDP. 2006. UNPD Botswana: Poverty reduction. <http://www.unbotswana.org.bw/undp/poverty. html> accessed 4.1.2008. Wikan, G. 2004. The level of living in rural Botswana re-studied, Norwegian Journal of Geography 58: 110. World Bank. 2006. World Development Report 2006: equity and development. Washington, DC : World Bank. World Bank. 2008a. The World Bank Group: Botswana Data Prole. <http://devdata.worldbank.org/ external/CPProle.asp?SelectedCountry=BWA&CCODE=BWA&CNAME=Botswana&PTYPE= CP> accessed 4.1.2008. World Bank. 2008b. Botswana-at-a-glance. <http://devdata.worldbank.org/AAG/bwa_aag.pdf> accessed 4.1.2008. Wylie, D. 1990. A Little God: the twilight of patriarchy in a Southern African chiefdom. Hanover, NH: Wesleyan University Press.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen