Sie sind auf Seite 1von 6

Fiscal multipliers: another caveat

James Hamilton reminds us of what all Econ 101 students learn (or are supposed to learn) about the peculiarities of national income and product accounting and the caveats that need to be kept in mind when equating the measured GDP to true economic activity. The lesson is hammered home by Yoshiyasu Ono in this paper The Keynesian Multiplier Effect Reconsidered published earlier this year. Here is Hamilton's nice summary of the paper: According to traditional Keynesian models, even for the case of a completely useless government project, if we were to raise private-sector taxes by just the amount needed to pay the salaries of the hole-diggers, GDP would increase, with a balanced-budget multiplier of one. Yet, Professor Ono asks, how could paying the crew a salary to dig a useless hole possibly lead to an improvement in welfare relative to simply handing them a direct transfer and allowing them to spend more time safely and comfortably at home with the family? And, to make things very simple, if the source of funds for paying the workers was in fact a tax levied on those same individuals, how could we possibly conclude that the enterprise has increased total national income? The answer is, we include government spending, even on useless projects, in the definition of GDP, and assume that the value of what is produced is the dollar sum that the government paid for it. The reason even useless government spending has a balancedbudget multiplier of one is that we now have a filled-in hole that we didn't have before. So we have more goods and services (in the form of a newly filled-in hole) than we used to, and impute the value of this new extra stuff as added income for the nation as a whole. To understand what underlies this phenomenon, we have to revisit the definition of GDP. The Gross Domestic Product is defined as the market-value of all final goods and services produced by domestic factors of production over some specified time period. It is also useful to keep the following in mind. All production is, by definition, sold (inventory accumulation is treated as a capital expenditure). Therefore, total output equals total expenditure. Moreover, as any expenditure on one side of a transaction constitutes income on the other side, it follows that total expenditure equals total income. To summarize: Output (GDP) is equivalent to Expenditure is equivalent to Income

Just to be clear, this is not a theory. It is an accounting identity (something that is true by definition). Now let me work through a series of examples. First, suppose that a firm pays a worker $1 to produce an object that has a market value of $2. What is the contribution to GDP? The answer is $2. There are two ways to see this. First, the market-value of what has been produced/sold is $2. Second, total income has increased by $2. (Labor income has increased by $1 and profit income has increased by $1). Now, suppose that a firm pays a worker $1 to produce an object that has a market value of $0. What is the contribution to GDP? The answer is zero. Again, there are two ways to see this. First, the marketvalue of what has been produced is zero. Second, while it is true that the income of the worker has increased by $1, this income gain is offset exactly by a $1 income loss for the firm. All that has happened in this example is a transfer of purchasing power from the firm to the worker. This is redistribution, not production. Next, suppose that the government pays a worker $1 to produce an object that has a market value of $0. What is the contribution to GDP? The true contribution is zero. But that's not how the contribution will be measured in the NIPA. The NIPA assumes that the market value of the object produced by (or on behalf of) the government is $1. All that has happened in this example is a transfer of purchasing power from the taxpayer to the worker. This is redistribution, not production. But it will nevertheless be measured as production. Why does this happen? Is someone trying to pull the wool over our eyes? No. As it turns out, many of the government services produced by government workers are provided for "free" and are hard to value at market prices (national defense is a classic example). When this is the case, it does not seem unreasonable to impute the market-value of a non-priced service by the cost of production. Having said this, the lesson here is that one should nevertheless use caution in interpreting the estimated multiplier effects of fiscal stimulus programs using historical data as indicators of the likely impact of contemporaneous spending measures on true (as opposed to measured) GDP. The estimates are surely biased upward, although by how much likely depends on the exact nature of the expenditure. What I have just described is a caveat for those who are inclined to perform cost-benefit exercises using "Keynesian" multiplier analysis. This type of analysis emerged out of a static model (the Keynesian Cross), where the benefit of a $1 expenditure by the government had to exist contemporaneously (there is no explicit future in a static model), which explains why the existence of multipliers greater than unity are so important in this way of thinking about things. There is a better way of evaluating the net benefit of a government stimulus program. This involves estimating the expected net present value of the program (easier said than done, of course). With the real return on U.S. Treasuries so low (see my previous post), with U.S. infrastructure reportedly in a sorry state, and with so many unemployed construction workers, I would be surprised to learn that there are few positive NPV infrastructure projects currently available. Unfortunately, political shenanigans (from all sides) sometimes make a mockery out the attempt to estimate NPV in a systematic and unbiased manner. We appear to be living in such times.

http://andolfatto.blogspot.com/2011/11/fiscal-multipliers-another-caveat.html High quality global journalism requires investment. Please share this article with others using the link below, do not cut & paste the article. See our Ts&Cs and Copyright Policy for more detail. Email ftsales.support@ft.com to buy additional rights. http://blogs.ft.com/moneysupply/2011/09/26/the-fiscal-multiplier-revisited/#ixzz1qyezzlaV

The fiscal multiplier revisited


September 26, 2011 9:42 pm by Robin Harding

Although it seems like a world away, the main economic policy argument in the early summer of 2010 was about the effectiveness of fiscal stimulus, in the wake of the Obama administrations $787bn American Recovery and Reinvestment Act. Now that the administration is asking for a new $447bn stimulus that question should be back at the top of the agenda and thanks to two excellent new NBER papers it is going to be a lot harder for people to distort the economic argument. Most of the new evidence suggests that in todays specific circumstances where the zero lower limit means that monetary policy is not as loose as the Fed would like then fiscal stimulus could be very effective indeed. The ARRA argument The summer of 2010 was marked by wildly different estimates of how much extra activity you get for every dollar of stimulus the fiscal multiplier which basically determines whether it is worthwhile. Those ranged from short-run impacts of -0.26 (output falls because of stimulus); plenty between 0 and 1 (stimulus increases activity but by less than the value of the stimulus); to well above 1 (so total activity might increase by $1,000bn for a $787bn stimulus). The basic problem is that there was no counterfactual you never know what would have happened without a stimulus so the answer depended entirely on a researchers model. Once economists started arguing about models policymakers started ignoring them; they could pick a fiscal multiplier estimate to suit their political position on stimulus. Comparing models In their NBER paper, Eric Leeper, Nora Traum and Todd Walker use some cunning Bayesian statistics to test different models and demonstrate that the model pretty much does decide the multiplier even before you plug data into it.

This chart really spells out how arguments about fiscal multipliers are all about models.

Solid lines These are for a model with real frictions only, e.g. there are adjustment costs for investment because you cannot build a factory a little bit at a time. The outer lines are 90 per cent confidence intervals. Dotted lines A model with nominal frictions as well. Prices and wages dont immediately adjust to shocks to the economy. Dotted-dashed lines Includes some people who consume all of their income, i.e. they do not save any stimulus money in expectation of future tax cuts to pay for it.

The results show pretty clearly that a high multiplier is all but impossible unless you assume at least some nominal rigidity. Monetary and fiscal policy The other thing that Leeper et al do is test their most general model under the assumptions that monetary policy is active and passive.

Thick lines are with a passive central bank, which does not raise interest rates as government borrowing grabs available investment funds, and dotted lines are with an active central bank which does. At the moment, with rates stuck at zero and the Fed trying all it can to ease policy further, the US central bank is passive. It makes a huge difference: if monetary policy is passive then it is hard to get a multiplier below 1. Theoretical work by Lawrence Christiano and colleagues and Michael Woodford gets similar results. The bottom line is this: if you think that people are unlikely to accept wage cuts because of a weak economy, and that the Fed is unlikely to have to put up interest rates because of a stimulus, then you should expect a multiplier of 1 or above on a new fiscal stimulus. Getting rid of the models The other NBER paper, by Alan Auerbach and Yuriy Gorodnichenko of UCLA-Berkeley, is a direct statistical analysis that relies less on models. As in their previous work, they come out with numbers that suggest a multiplier of 0 during expansions but about 1.5-2 during recessions.

Conclusion The lesson I draw from these papers is that people should not be allowed to get away with saying models differ in debates about fiscal stimulus. In particular, people claiming low multipliers need to explain and justify what frictions they do and do not assume, and what assumptions they make about monetary policy.
http://blogs.ft.com/money-supply/2011/09/26/the-fiscal-multiplier-revisited/#axzz1qyetrXfH

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen