Sie sind auf Seite 1von 22

CESIS

Electronic Working Paper Series

Paper No.68

Industry R&D Location1


– the role of accessibility to university R&D and
institutions of higher education

Martin Andersson, Urban Gråsjö & Charlie Karlsson

May 2006

1
martin.andersson@ihh.hj.se, urban.grasjo@hv.se, charlie.karlsson@ihh.hj.se
INDUSTRY R&D LOCATION

– the role of accessibility to university R&D


and institutions of higher education

By

Martin Andersson, Urban Gråsjö & Charlie Karlsson

martin.andersson@ihh.hj.se, urban.grasjo@hv.se, charlie.karlsson@ihh.hj.se

Abstract

The rapid globalization in recent years has created a radically new competitive situation for
the rich industrialized countries. Newly industrialized countries and not least China have be-
come more and more successful in penetrating the markets in the rich industrialized countries
with increasingly more advanced export products. This has generated a discussion in the rich
industrialized countries on how to meet this increased international competition. In some
countries demands for various protective measures have been raised while in others the dis-
cussion has mainly focused on how to develop a competitive strategy mainly concentrating on
making the own products more sophisticated by increasing their knowledge content. This is
by no means since the direct product development is controlled to a high extent by multina-
tional firms, which to an increasing degree are foreign owned. Governments mainly have to
rely on indirect measures, such as increasing the volume of higher education and public,
mainly university R&D. This raises the question: how responsive is private industry to these
kinds of indirect measures. Against this background, the purpose of this paper is to analyze to
what extent that the location and the extent of higher education and university R&D, respec-
tively, influence the location and the extent of industry R&D in Sweden using an accessibility
approach. After an extensive literature survey, we develop a simple theoretical model for the
location of R&D from the perspective of a multinational enterprise. From this theoretical
model, we then deduce our empirical model, which we then estimate in the form of a Tobit
model using data from Swedish labour market regions and municipalities. We show that the
location of industry R&D in Sweden can be partly explained by the intra-municipal accessi-
bility to students in higher education, while the accessibility to university R&D turned out to
be insignificant.

Key-words: industry R&D, university R&D, higher education, region, municipality,


location, accessibility, Tobit model, Sweden

JEL-Codes: O300, O380, O520, R110, R120, R320

1
1. Introduction

The rapid globalization in recent years has created a radically new competitive situa-
tion for the rich industrialized countries. Not least due to the rapid industrial growth in
China, they have experienced increased penetration of their domestic markets by
products produced in China and other newly industrialized countries2. This increased
penetration of imported goods has not been limited to “simple” products such as tex-
tile, cloths and shoes. To an increasing degree, the rich industrialized countries have
been able to observe an increasing penetration also of more advanced industry prod-
ucts such as computers, cars and mobile phones.
The increased import penetration has generated different reactions in different
countries. In some countries such as the US, voices have been raised for introducing
various protectionist measures. The same has been true within the European Union
(EU), which has introduced quotas for China’s export of cloths to EU. Another reac-
tion heard, for example, in Sweden is that the rich industrialized countries must in-
crease the knowledge content and the degree of sophistication of their products to re-
tain their comparative advantages in their export markets and to find new export mar-
kets.
How this shall be achieved in practical terms is much more of an open question.
Of course, there has been a strong argument for increasing the share of young people
going to university as well as for increasing the public R&D investments. However,
higher education by itself does not make old products more knowledge intensive or
generate new products or processes, nor does public R&D investments to any major
extent. Public R&D investments are mainly directed towards basic research.
The upgrading of old products, the generation of new products and the develop-
ment and upgrading of processes is the object of industry research mainly controlled
by private industry. The possibilities for governments to directly control private R&D
is limited in market economies and the options to subsidize private R&D are also lim-
ited within e.g. the EU, since such subsidies distort competition. There are, however,
indirect measures, such as investments in higher education and public R&D, to influ-
ence industry R&D. The question is: how responsive is private industry to these kinds
of indirect measures?
The answer to that question is by no means simple. To take Sweden as an exam-
ple, we can observe that about 90 percent of all private R&D is controlled by multi-
national enterprises (MNEs) and about 40 percent of that is performed by foreign-
owned MNEs. Swedish MNEs on the other hand perform almost half of their R&D
abroad (Lööf, 2005). Given that a very limited number of MNEs, of which a high
share is foreign-owned, control so much of the industry R&D it is an open question to
what extent national and regional policies can influence industry R&D in a country or
region. MNEs, for instance, optimize their operations at a global scale.
Nevertheless, a possible way in which national and regional policies can affect in-
dustry R&D is to make regions attractive as locations for R&D by private firms. In an
earlier paper, two of the authors (Karlsson & Andersson, 2005) of this paper studied
among other things how the location of industry R&D is influenced by the location of
public, i.e. university, R&D. The empirical results pointed in the direction of a posi-

2
China’s share of the EU-market (imports from China as a share of total imports) has, for instance,
grown from about 2 % 1990 to 9 % 2003. During the same time period, Chinas share of the US market
(defined analogously) grown from 3.2 % to 12.5 %, (see Prasad (ed), 2004, IMF).

2
tive influence. However, that paper did not consider the possible influence of higher
education in terms of students and graduates. A recent study by Faggian & McCann
(2006), for instance, shows that migration effects of embodied human capital in stu-
dents and graduates is of greater importance than (informal) university-industry spill-
overs. This suggests that the effect of students and graduates at institutions of higher
education on the location of industry R&D needs to be considered. In view of this, the
purpose of this paper is to analyze to what extent that the location and extent of public
R&D and higher education, in terms of potential recruitment of graduates, influence
the location and the extent of industry R&D in Sweden.
The paper is organized as follows: In Section 2 we discuss some general charac-
teristics of innovation processes and their dependence upon knowledge flows, and
give an overview of the general spatial conditions for innovation processes, which is
followed by an elaboration over the factors determining the location of company
R&D in general and its dependence on closeness to university R&D and higher edu-
cation, in particular. The data, the models and the econometric techniques used in the
empirical analysis is presented in Section 3. Our empirical analysis can be found in
Section 4 and our conclusions in Section 5.

2. Innovation Processes, Agglomeration and the Lo-


cation of Industry R&D

2.1 Innovation Processes and Knowledge Flows

Knowledge and information are critical inputs in innovation processes. However,


there is an important distinction. Knowledge is a critical input in innovation proc-
esses, which is used to generate new or improved products and/or new production
techniques. This knowledge input may come from different sources: (i) scientific
knowledge in the form of basic scientific principles, (ii) technological knowledge in
the form of technical solution and blueprints, and/or (iii) entrepreneurial knowledge,
i.e. knowledge about customer preferences and willingness to pay, market conditions,
business concepts and business methods, etc (Karlsson & Johansson, 2006). These
types of knowledge can be developed in R&D processes over time and can be ac-
cessed through various types of knowledge networks. This explains why firms are ac-
tive in many different knowledge networks with many economic actors possessing
different types of knowledge (Batten, Kobayashi & Andersson, 1989).
Except for knowledge networks internal to firms, they derive information and
knowledge from their participation in external knowledge networks, which in the lit-
erature are described as innovation networks or innovation systems. Each firm will
normally simultaneously participate in a range of such networks involving customers,
suppliers, other firms in the industry, universities, R&D institutes, etc. Sometimes a
distinction is made between horizontal and vertical networks (Cox, Mowatt &
Prevezer, 2003). Firms can be embedded in horizontal knowledge networks with
similar firms and in vertical knowledge networks with supplier and customer firms.
For innovative firms, interaction with the scientific community via specialized
knowledge networks is generally considered as crucial. Innovative firms are in par-
ticular assumed to be highly dependent upon knowledge generated in nearby research
universities. In this paper we are in particular interested in studying the involvement

3
of innovative firms in knowledge networks involving research universities and insti-
tutions of higher education.

2.2 The Spatial Conditions for Innovation Processes

It is a common observation that innovations tend to be agglomerated, i.e. to be clus-


tered and in particular to clusters in large urban regions. Large urban regions offer
proximity advantages, which facilitate information and knowledge flows (Artle, 1959;
Vernon, 1962; Glaeser, 1999; Feldman & Audretsch, 1999) and create a proximity-
based communication externality (Fujita & Thisse, 2002).
Why do innovations tend to be clustered in large urban regions? What are the
proximity and accessibility benefits these regions offer? Already Marshall (1920)
identified the exchange of information as an externality leading to the agglomeration
of economic actors. In more recent years, Henderson (1974) has used information ex-
change in the form of technology spillovers as an explanation for the agglomeration of
economic agents across space. Proximity is seen as critical for all the different types
and forms of knowledge flows essential in innovation processes (Karlsson & Johans-
son, 2006).
Within large functional urban regions3, firms have normally high accessibility to
pertinent actors, such as customers, suppliers, research universities and other institu-
tions of higher education, R&D institutes, etc. These actors are all important sources
for intellectual capital and innovation-relevant information and knowledge. Large
functional urban regions also offer greater opportunities for labor mobility, which is
an important channel for knowledge transfers and for the maintenance and growth of
knowledge capital.4
There has been a steady progression of theoretical frameworks and methods to in-
vestigate the influence of spatial factors on innovation processes. These range from
general knowledge production functions that embody broad forms of distance-sensi-
tive knowledge flows, including tacit as well as formal knowledge inputs, to more
precisely specified models of knowledge flows and spillovers including so called lo-
calized knowledge spillovers through patents, patent citations and product innovations
(Varga, 2002). Studies of localized knowledge spillovers occasionally, although not
always, distinguish clearly between pecuniary and technological spillovers, their pub-
lic and club good features, and various forms of private intellectual property.
The size of a functional region is critical also to its ability to attract, support and
maintain innovative firms. Large functional urban regions offer special advantages to
firms by offer many clusters of specific industries as well as a broad range of indus-
tries. They combine the specialization advantages of the Marshall-Arrow-Romer type
with the diversity advantages advocated by Jacobs (1969). Hence, large functional
urban regions offer innovative firms advantages in the form of both network and ag-
glomeration externalities, which stimulate knowledge transfers.
Large functional urban regions are also important since they represent an arena at
which different geographical scales meet. They represent a nexus between local, re-
gional, national and international networks of different kinds including knowledge
networks (Lagendijk, 2001).

3
Functional urban regions are delimited by labor and housing market perimeters.
4
One hour’s travel time by car from a given location seems to set the limit for the positive proximity
externalities associated with agglomerations (Johansson, Klaesson & Olsson, 2002).

4
2.3 The Location of Industry R&D

There are plenty of evidences in the literature that industry R&D is substantially more
concentrated spatially than industry production.5 For example, Kelly & Hageman
(1999) show that innovation exhibits strong geographical clustering, independently of
the distribution of employment. Sectors locate their R&D not where they are produc-
ing but near to where other sectors do their R&D. However, Audretsch & Feldman
(1996) found that there are substantial differences across sectors in spatial clustering
with some industries, like computers and pharmaceuticals, displaying a higher degree
of concentration compared to all manufacturing. Similar conclusions were drawn by
Breschi (1999) after an examination of patent data for the period 1978-1991 from the
European Patent Office (EPO).
Theoretical arguments concerning localized knowledge flows suggests that
knowledge production and innovative activities within a company will tend to be
more efficient in agglomerations containing research universities and other R&D per-
forming companies, since the access to knowledge flows and potential knowledge
externalities is greater. The knowledge production and the innovative activities will be
more productive in such agglomerations because there is a high probability that com-
panies can access potentially useful external knowledge at a cost that is lower than
producing this knowledge internally or of trying to acquire it externally from a geo-
graphic distance (Harhoff, 2000). The cost of transferring such knowledge is a func-
tion of geographic time distance. This is one of the arguments why R&D agglomera-
tions are likely to give rise to localized knowledge externalities (Siegel, Westhead &
Wright, 2003). Thus, given the character of knowledge flows, it seems natural to as-
sume that the spatial dimension is a key factor explaining the location of R&D activi-
ties of companies. The location of R&D activities of companies is influenced by the
potential knowledge externalities from knowledge flows from university R&D and
R&D in other companies.
There is a rich literature regarding various aspects of the relationship between
university R&D and industry R&D and innovation and to a certain extent also about
the relationship between higher education and industry R&D and innovation. Some
studies focus on the ability of companies to utilize knowledge flows from universities
(Cohen & Levinthal, 1989 & 1990; Cockburn & Henderson,1998; Ziedonis, 1999;
Lim, 2000). Another strand of literature studies the characteristics of universities that
generate knowledge flows of interest for industry R&D and innovation (Henderson,
Jaffe & Trajtenberg, 1998; Thursby & Thursby, 2002; Feldman, et al., 2002; Jensen &
Thursby, 1998; Di Gregorio & Shane, 2000). A third set of studies analyze the chan-
nels through which knowledge flow from universities to industry (Cohen, et al., 1998;
Cohen, Nelson & Walsh, 2002; Agrawal & Henderson, 2002; Colyvas, et al., 2002;
Shane, 2002). These channels include:

• Personal networks of academic and industry researchers (Liebeskind, et al.,


1996; MacPherson, 1998)

5
However, there are authors that claim that R&D-intensive and high-tech industries do not necessarily
agglomerate (Devereux, Griffith & Simpson, 1999; Shaver & Flyer (2000), Kalnins & Chung, 2001,
Barrios, et al., 2003; Alecke, et al., 2003). In her study of Japanese investments in Europe Mariani
(2002) found that R&D tends to locate close to production activities.

5
• University researchers consulting to industry or serving on company boards
• University researchers leaving university to work for industry
• Technological spillovers of newly created knowledge from universities to
industry.
• Purchases by industry of newly created university knowledge or intellectual
property
• Spin-offs of new firms from universities, i.e. academic entrepreneurship
(Slaughter & Lesley, 1997; Stuart & Shane, 2002)
• Universities creating incubators, enterprise centers and science parks to im-
prove interaction with industry, and to facilitate university knowledge trans-
fers.
• Participation in conferences, seminars and presentations
• Flows of fresh graduates at the master and PhD level to industry (Varga,
2000).

However, there seems to be fewer studies that explicitly study the influences of uni-
versity R&D on companies in general and on company R&D, in particular. The spe-
cific and relative role played by each of these different links for the development of
industry is not well understood (Karlsson & Manduchi, 2001). Moreover, the actual
links between universities and industry in many cases have proved difficult to detect.
However, recent studies have shown strong evidence of knowledge transfers and
spillover flows, as demonstrated by the joint distributions of university capacity and
high technology sectors (Varga, 1997 & 2002).
At a general level research universities have been identified as a location factor of
growing importance (Henderson, Jaffe & Trajtenberg, 1995; Zucker & Darby, 1998;
Adams, 2002; Hall, Link & Scott, 2003; Zucker & Darby, 2005). It has been sug-
gested that regions with strong research universities have better opportunities to at-
tract and support innovative firms than regions without such universities. Regionally
based science parks can be seen as an institutional set-up to integrate the resources of
research universities and innovative firms (Luger & Goldstein, 1991). Also, network
type interactions among innovative firms and private and public research institutions
seem to be of growing importance (Lundvall, 1992, Ed., Nelson, 1993, Ed., Etzkowitz
& Leyersdorff, 2000; Charles, 2003).
Zucker, Darby and Brewer (1998) examine the location decisions of companies
relative too the location of star university scientists. Mariani (2002) in a study of
Japanese investments in Europe showed that geographical proximity to the local sci-
ence base is an important factor for locating only R&D laboratories compared to R&D
and production and production only. Agrawal & Cockburn (2002) use data on scien-
tific publications and patents as indicators of university R&D and industry R&D and
find strong evidences of geographic concentration in both activities at the level of
metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) in the US. They also find strong evidences of
co-location of upstream and downstream R&D activities. Agrawal & Cockburn
(2003) report that high levels of university publishing in metropolitan areas in the
United States and Canada tend to be matched by high levels of company patenting in
the same technology field and metropolitan area, suggesting co-location of research
activities. Other empirical studies suggest a strong correlation between the specializa-
tion of the regional R&D infrastructure and the innovative activities conducted by in-
dustry (Feldman, 1994 a; Felder, Fier & Nerlingar 1997 a & b; Harhoff, 1997; Nerlin-
ger, 1998). These results can be interpreted as indicating that knowledge externalities
from the R&D infrastructure can be best used in innovation activities in companies in

6
the same or closely related scientific and technological field(s). The correlation tends
to increase with the complexity of the R&D and innovation activities and the more
specific the demand for technological know-how (Feldman, 1994 a; Feldman & Flor-
ida, 1994). Results presented by Bade & Nerlinger (2000) indicate strong correlations
between the occurrence of new technology-based firms and the proximity to R&D-
facilities comprising universities, technical colleges and non-university R&D-insti-
tutes as well as private R&D.
Griliches’ ‘knowledge production function approach’ (Griliches, 1979) did not ac-
knowledge that knowledgeable persons and knowledge production activities are
spread out in geography and at the same time to a high degree concentrated to ag-
glomerations. However, the original ‘knowledge production function approach’ has
later been modified to also accommodate the spatial dimension (Jaffe, 1989;
Audretsch & Feldman, 1994 & 1996; Feldman, 1994a & 1994b). The inputs and out-
puts considered in these studies vary from study to study and so does the geographic
unit of analysis. With a few exceptions (Henderson, Jaffe & Trajtenberg, 1994; Beise
& Stahl, 1999), empirical research suggests that knowledge flows from public science
to companies decline with geographical distance.
The input ‘federal research funding’ is related to the output ‘new patents issued’ at
the state level in the US study by Jaffe (1989). Acs, Audretsch & Feldman (1992) cor-
relate the input ‘university research spending’ with the output ‘new product an-
nouncements’. Jaffe, Trajtenberg & Henderson (1993) use the input ‘original patents’
to explain the output ‘patents that cite the original patents’ at the city level in the US.
They as well as several other studies (Narin, Hamilton & Olivastro, 1997; Verspagen,
1999; Malo & Geuna, 2000) find that academic papers and university patents are
more frequently cited than their equivalents from private companies suggesting that
public science outputs are an important knowledge source for inventions in compa-
nies. However, this method is not entirely accurate because the cited papers and pat-
ents may not have contributed to the invention, since the citation may be included
only to build the patent claim. This method also underestimates the value of public
R&D since many inventions are not patented (Arundel & Kabla, 1998). Audretsch &
Feldman (1996) connect the input ‘local university research funding’ in the US to the
output ‘local industry value-added’ at the state level. The input ‘number of local re-
search stars’ is associated to the output ‘number of new local biotech firms’ at the
level of the economic region in the US by Zucker, Darby & Armstrong (1998). Bran-
stetter (2000) links the input ‘scientific publications from the University of California’
to the output ‘patents that cite those papers’ at the state level. The input ‘hours of in-
teraction with the MIT professor associated with a particular patented invention’ is
used by Agrawal (2002) to estimate the effect on the ‘likelihood or degree of success
of commercializing that invention’ and he also evaluates the impact of distance on this
effect. Mowery & Ziedonis (2001) find knowledge flows from universities through
market transactions to be more geographically localized than those operating through
non-market “spillovers”. This indicates that high contact intensity is especially im-
portant when knowledge must be specified as a commodity for which property rights
are clearly defined. Irrespectively of whether these studies use the production function
approach or patent citations they find that knowledge flows from academic research to
private companies are highly localized at the regional or state level in the US.
In summary, the abovementioned theoretical arguments and empirical results
point in the direction that the location of industry R&D is attracted to locations with
high accessibility to universities R&D and students and graduates at institutions of
higher education.

7
2.4 Accessibility and Industry R&D Location across Re-
gions

The preceding sections suggest that investments in industry R&D are attracted to lo-
cations with high accessibility to university R&D and students and graduates at insti-
tutions of higher education. This section illustrates how this kind of accessibility po-
tentially affects firms’ evaluation of alternative locations for their R&D investments.
Given the discussion in the introduction about the dominating role of multinational
national enterprises (MNEs) in industry R&D, it seems natural to take a MNE as an
example.
Consider a MNE that is about to choose a location for their R&D investments.
Since such a firm operates at a global level, we may conjecture that the MNE’s first
decision is which part of the world it should choose. This can be choice among, e.g.
Western Europe, Asia or North America, and is likely to depend on which part of the
world constitutes the main (or home) market for the MNE. Given the choice of conti-
nent, the question is then which country to choose6. Conditional on the choice of
Europe, for instance, this involves a choice between Germany, France, Sweden or
U.K, etc. Once a country has been chosen, the question is which region to locate in.
An MNE certainly evaluates the alternative regions in an economic territory (such as a
country) based on a set of pertinent attributes of the regions. A main conjecture here is
that accessibility to university R&D and institutions of higher education are two such
pertinent attributes of regions.
Against the background above we now consider a MNE that has decided to locate
its R&D investments in a country which hosts N ={1,…,n} regions. How is a region’s
accessibility to university R&D and institutions of higher education related to the at-
tractiveness of the region as regards location of an R&D unit? Here, we employ the
basic set-up in Johansson, Klaesson & Olsson (2002) and relate accessibility to the
preference structure in random choice theory, which starts from a stochastic specifi-
cation of the preference value associated with different alternatives. We start with in-
stitutions of higher education in terms of student and graduates.
A R&D unit r located in region i ∈ N by an MNE faces the set of N alternatives
as regards recruitment of graduates from institutions of higher education. The set N
denotes the set of regions in the national economy considered. Thus, each alternative
pertains to student and graduates at institutions of higher education in a specific re-
gion. We might now ask: what determines the preference value of R&D unit r as re-
gards potential recruitment of (and collaboration with) graduates in region j ∈ N ?
This preference value, denoted by U ij ,r is specified as consisting of two parts:

U ij ,r = u ij ,r + ε ij (2.1)

where uij ,r denotes the deterministically known part and ε ij denotes random influence
from non-observed factors. uij ,r is in turn assumed to be a function of (i) the size of
the institution of higher education (in terms of graduates), Hj, (ii) the quality differen-
tial of the graduates between region i and j, qj, (iii) the wage differential of graduates

6
It should here be recognized that ample evidence suggests that MNE particularly likely to locate their
R&D activities to their home country compared to other activities, (Patel & Pavitt, 1995).

8
(cost differential) in region j and i, (pj – pi), (iv) interaction costs between i and j, cij,
and (v) travel time between region i and j, tij. uij ,r is specified in Equation (2.2):

u ij ,r = ln H j + δ (q j − qi ) − α ( p j − pi ) − β cij − γt ij (2.2)

where δ, α, β and γ are parameters. In Equation (2.2) the size of the institution of
higher education in region j can be interpreted as the attraction factor in region j.
Assuming that the ε ij are i.i.d. and extreme value distributed, the probability that a
R&D unit r will hire (or collaborate with) graduates in region j, given that the R&D
unit is located in region i, Pij ,r , is given by7:

{u }
e ij , r

Pij ,r = {u } (2.3)
∑ j∈N e ij , r

Equation (2.3) is the general expression for the choice probabilities in the multinomial
logit (MNL) model, (see e.g. Anderson, de Palma & Thisse, 1992). In Equation (2.3),
the numerator is the preference value for graduates from institutions of higher educa-
tion in municipality j whereas the denominator is the sum of such preference values.
Now consider the denominator in (2.3) and assume that (i) the quality of the
graduates and the wages are equal in all regions and (ii) the monetary travel costs are
proportional to the time distance such that cij = γtij . Using these assumptions, the de-
nominator in (2.3) can be expressed as:
{− λtij }
Ti H = ∑ j∈N H j e (2.4)

where λ = ( βγ + γ ) . The expression in (2.4) gives the sum of the preference values,
conditional on a location in region i. Observe that the set of N alternatives is the same
in any region in the set N ={1,…,n}. Thus, an R&D unit located in region s ∈ N faces
the same set of alternatives, i.e. alternative regions, as a R&D unit located in i ∈ N ,
but the sum of the preference values from that location is different8. Hence, locations
where the sum of such preference values is high can thus be interpreted as location
with high attractiveness9. Ti H in Equation (2.3) is also a standard measure of
accessibility with exponential distance decay. This type of accessibility measure be-
longs to the family of accessibility measures that satisfies criteria of consistency and
meaningfulness, as has been shown in Weibull (1976). Both the size of the attractor
and time distances in (2.4) are arguments in the preference function in (2.2).
An analogous reasoning can be applied to university R&D. Region i’s accessibil-
ity to university R&D is thus be expressed as:
{−λtij }
TiU = ∑ j∈M U Rj & D e (2.5)

7
This condition is derived in several texts, see inter alia Train (1993), Anderson, de Palma & Thisse
(1992).
8
i.e. tsj ≠ tij.
9
Compare Ben-Akiva & Lerman (1979).

9
where U Rj & D denotes the size of the investments in university R&D in region j.
A national economy can be divided into functional regions that consist of one or
several localities. Such localities are here labeled municipalities. Functional regions
are connected to other functional regions by means of economic, knowledge and in-
frastructure networks. The same prevails for the different municipalities within a
functional region. Moreover, each municipality can also be looked upon as a number
of nodes connected by the same type of networks. With reference to such a structure,
it is possible to separate between (i) intra-municipal accessibility, (ii) intra-regional
accessibility10. Letting R denote the set of municipalities belonging to functional re-
gion R, such that R ⊂ N , the different accessibilities can be expressed as (accessibility
to H is here taken as an example):
{− λtii }
• Intra-municipal => TiMH = H i e
{−λtij }
• Intra-regional => TiRH = ∑ j∈R ,i ≠ j
H je

The advantage of this separation is that the effect of each type of accessibility can be
estimated directly. The subsequent sections of the paper analyses the relationship
between the location of industry R&D and accessibility to university R&D and acces-
sibility to students and graduates at institutions of higher education using data at the
municipality-level in Sweden.

3. Empirical Model, Variables and Data

The empirical model used to assess the relationship between the location of industry
R&D and accessibility to university R&D and student enrolment at institutions of
higher education, respectively, is presented in Equation (3.1) below, where t refers to
2001 and t − τ to 1995.

I iR,t& D = α + β1I iR,t&−τD + β 2 MPi ,t + β 3TiMH ,t + β 4TiRH,t + ...


(3.1)
... + β T U
5 iM ,t +β T U
6 iR ,t + β7 Dair
i ,t + ε i ,t

The variables in the model are explained in Table 3.1. Industry R&D in municipality i
in 2001 is thus explained by: (i) industry R&D in 1995, (ii) market potential of mu-
nicipality i in 2001, (iii) intra-municipal and intra-regional accessibility to students
enrolled at institutions of higher education in 2001, (iv) intra-municipal and intra-re-
gional accessibility to university R&D 2001 and (v) a dummy which takes the value 1
if municipality i belongs to a functional region hosting an international airport. The
industry R&D in previous periods is a natural control variable to include. Moreover,
the market potential of a municipality can be seen as a ‘catch-all’ variable and is in-
deed related to the theoretical discussion in previous sections on the advantages of
10
It is possible to also define a third type of accessibility extra-regional accessibility, (see e.g. Johans-
son, Klaesson & Olsson, 2002). However, this accessibility is not considered in the present paper.
There is now a set of papers using municipalities as the observational unit, which have used all three
types of accessibility. These papers have shown that extra-regional accessibility is insignificant in a
large number of alternative settings, (see e.g. Gråsjö, 2005 a & b; Karlsson & Andersson, 2006;
Andersson & Gråsjö, 2005)

10
large regions as locations for R&D. Researchers are in general mobile and are ex-
pected, but also required, to participate in various conferences around the world. Be-
cause of this, we include a dummy for international airports as an additional control
variable.
Table 3.1. Description of variables in Equation (3.1).
Variable Description Source
Industry R&D in terms of man-years in
I iR,t& D Statistics Sweden (SCB)
municipality i 2001.

Industry R&D in terms of man-years in


I iR,t&−τD Statistics Sweden (SCB)
municipality i 1995.
Market potential of municipality i in
MPi t 2001. Measured as the municipality’s Statistics Sweden (SCB)
accessibility to population.

Student enrolment at institutions of


H Statistics Sweden (SCB)
higher education in 2001.

University R&D in terms of man-years


U Statistics Sweden (SCB)
in 2001.
Intra-municipal accessibility to variable Statistics Sweden (SCB)
TiMX ,t X in municipality i 2001, based on and the Swedish Road
travel time distances by car*. Administration (SRA)
Intra-regional accessibility to variable X Statistics Sweden (SCB)
TiRX,t in municipality i 2001, based on travel and the Swedish Road
time distances by car*. Administration (SRA)

A dummy which is 1 of municipality i


Diair
,t belongs to a functional region hosting Statistics Sweden (SCB)
an international airport, 0 otherwise.
*) X indicates the variable to which accessibility is calculated and is either H or U.

The data used in the paper are constructed based on secondary material from Statistics
Sweden (SCB). The R&D data originates from SCB and are collected by SCB via
questionnaires that are sent out to firms and universities. The R&D data is measured
in man-years. One man-year is the amount of work a full-time employee performs
during a year. This means that a full-time employee who only spends 50 % of her
work on R&D counts as 0.5 man-years. The data on students and graduates at institu-
tions of higher education also comes from SCB. These data report the number of stu-
dents enrolled at institutions of higher education (i.e. university students and gradu-
ates) in different regions in different municipalities in Sweden.
Accessibility is calculated for university R&D and student enrolment at institu-
tions of higher education. These calculations are based on a Swedish travel time-dis-
tance matrix, which reports the minimum travel time by car: (i) between zones within
municipalities and (ii) between municipalities. This matrix is provided by the Swedish
Road Administration (SRA). The time distance sensitivity parameter was set to 0.017
in these calculations. This is the sensitivity parameter found by Hugosson & Johans-
son (2001) in a study of the spatial extent of business trips across Swedish regions.
In order to provide the reader with a feel for the data of main interest in the paper,
descriptive statistics for industry and university R&D and student enrolment at insti-
tutions of higher education are presented in Table 3.2. As can be seen from the differ-
ence between the mean and median, the data are highly skewed to the right.

11
Table 3.2. Descriptive statistics for industry and university R&D and student enrolment at institutions
of higher education across Swedish municipalities in 2001.

University
Industry R&D Student enrolment*
R&D

Min 0 0 0

Max 11 912.35 3 452.03 44 578

Mean 171.87 68.94 1 006.89

Median 7.92 0 6

Std. deviation 894.58 380.57 4 135.90

10.45 7.08 7.04


Skewness**
(0.14) (0.14) (0.14)

123.27 52.31 59.56


Kurtosis**
(0.29) (0.29) (0.28)

No. obs. 286 286 286

Data source: Statistics Sweden (SCB)


*) Refers to student enrolment at institutions of higher education.
**) Standard errors presented within brackets.

Figure 3.1 compares the spatial concentration of industry and university R&D and
student enrolment at institutions of higher education with population in 2001. Munici-
palities where ranked in ascending order according to their share of the total popula-
tion. Then, the cumulative percentage of population, industry R&D and
university R&D where calculated.

As is evident from the figure, industry and university R&D as well as student enrol-
ment at institutions of higher education are more concentrated than population. More-
over, university R&D and student enrolment show a similar concentration pattern
whereas industry R&D is relatively less concentrated in space.

4. The Location of Industry R&D – An Empirical


Analysis

Parameter estimated of the variables in Equation (3.1) are presented in Table 3.3.
Three models are tested; one including accessibility to both university R&D and stu-
dents and graduates and two with each accessibility variable separately. This is so be-
cause TiMH ,t and TiMU ,t as well as TiRH,t and TiRU,t are correlated. Such a correlation might
distort the parameter estimates. The standard errors reported in the Table 3.1 are boot-
strapped using 1000 replications, which reduces biases from potential heteroscedas-
ticity.

12
Cumulative share (%)

100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
0 50 100 150 200 250 Municipalities
ranked in ascending
Population University R&D order according to
population share
Industry R&D Student enrolment

Figure 3.1. The spatial concentration of industry and university R&D and student enrolment at institu-
tions of higher education relative to population.

Since the dependent variable is bottom-censored, i.e. cannot be below zero, and
several municipalities have zero R&D man-years in the industry, the parameters are
estimated using a Tobit model after Tobin (1958). The Tobit model assumes a latent
dependent variable, Yi*, that is not directly observed. Yi is however observed and is
defined as:

Yi = Yi* iff Yi * > c


(3.1)
Yi = c iff Yi ≤ c*

where c denotes the lower bound below which Yi* is censored. Yi* is assumed to be
generated by the canonical linear regression model such that:

Yi * = β ' X i + ε i (3.2)

where denotes Xi a vector of regressors and β a corresponding vector of parameters.


The error terms are assumed to be i.i.d, εi ∼N(0,σ2). In our case, the lower bound is
zero, c = 0. Neglecting such a lower bound can lead to biased and inconsistent pa-
rameter estimates.

The estimates reported in the table shows that industry R&D in previous time periods
is a good predictor of the R&D in present time periods. The parameter estimate is sig-
nificant and positive in all specifications. Likewise, the parameter estimate of the
market potential variable comes out as significant and positive. Thus, consistent with
previous literature and theory industry R&D seems to be attracted to larger regions.
Interestingly, the intra-municipal accessibility to students and graduates at institutes of
higher education comes out as positive and significant in the specifications were it is

13
included. Intra-regional accessibility is insignificant. None of the parameter estimates
for accessibility to university R&D is significant. This indicates that the main attractor
for industry R&D on average is not the university R&D as such, but rather the human
capital embodied in students and graduates at institutions of higher education. This
cannot, however, be interpreted as that university R&D is unimportant. The supply of
students and graduates are certainly large in regions where University R&D is large.
Rather, as aforementioned, the results suggest that the main attractor is the supply of
students and graduates. Thus, consistent with other recent studies (c.f. Faggian &
McCann, 2006), the results indicate that university R&D is mainly accessed indirectly
via labor-market transactions.

Table 3.3. Tobit estimates of the parameters in Equation (3.1), bootstrapped standard errors (1000 rep-
lications).
Estimates Estimates Estimates (To-
Variable
(Tobit model) (Tobit model) bit model)
-86.39 -91.24 -84.92
Intercept
(-4.77) (-5.21) (-4.59)

1.06 1.06 1.10


I iR,t&−τD
(0.06) (0.05) (0.06)

0.0001 0.0001 0.0001


MPi t
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00)

0.02 0.03
TiMH ,t -
(0.01) (0.01)

TiRH,t n.s. n.s. -

TiMU ,t n.s. - n.s.

TiRU,t n.s. - n.s.

Diair
,t n.s. n.s. n.s.

Pseudo R2 0.27 0.27 0.26


# censored obs. 106 106 106
# obs. 286 286 286
*) only parameter estimates significant at the 0.05 level are shown in the table, (n.s denotes insignifi-
cance at the 0-05 level).
**) bootstrapped standard errors presented within brackets.

5. Conclusions

The endeavor in this paper has been to analyze how the location of industry R&D is
related to accessibility to students and graduates at institutions of higher education
and university R&D. Two types of accessibilities were considered in the paper: (i)
intra-municipal accessibility and intra-regional accessibility.
By relating the location of industry R&D across Swedish municipalities to a set of
municipal characteristics, including intra-municipal and intra-regional accessibility to

14
university R&D and students and graduates at institutions of higher education, it is
shown that the location of industry R&D can be related to accessibility to students and
graduates at institutions of higher education. However, we find no significance as re-
gards accessibility to university R&D. This indicates that the main attractor for indus-
try R&D on average is not the university R&D as such, but rather the human capital
embodied in students and graduates at institutions of higher education. However, this
is not interpreted as that university R&D is unimportant. The supply of students and
graduates are certainly large in regions where University R&D is large. Rather, as
aforementioned, the results suggest that the main attractor is the supply of students
and graduates. Thus, consistent with other recent studies (c.f. Faggian & McCann,
2006), the results indicate that university R&D is mainly accessed indirectly via labor-
market transactions.
The methodology applied in the paper, however, does admittedly not allow for
causative interpretations. An avenue for further research is therefore to use method-
ologies that allow for causative interpretations. Moreover, the paper has used aggre-
gate R&D data across industries. Controlling for heterogeneity across industries re-
quires disaggregate R&D data and is a further topic for additional research.

15
References

Acs, Z.J., D.B. Audretsch & M.P. Feldman (1992), Real Effects of Academic Re-
search, American Economic Review 82, 363-367
Adams, J.D. (2002), Comparative Localization of Academic and Industrial Spillovers,
Journal of Economic Geography 2, 253-278
Agrawal, A. (2002), Technology Acquisition Strategy for Early-Stage Innovations:
Measuring the Importance of Engaging the Inventor, Queen’s University
(mimeo)
Agrawal, A & I.M. Cockburn (2002), University Research, Industrial R&D and the
Anchor Tenant Hypothesis, NBER Working paper 9212, Cambridge, MA
Agrawal, A & I.M. Cockburn (2003), The Anchor Tenant Hypothesis: Exploring the
Role of Large, Local, R&D Intensive Firms in Regional Innovation Systems,
International Journal of Industrial Organisation 21, 1227-1253
Agrawal, A & R. Henderson (2002), Putting Patents in Context: Exploring Knowl-
edge Transfer from MIT, Management Science 48, 44-60
Alecke, B., et al. (2003), New Empirical Evidence on the Geographic Concentration
of German Industries: Do High-Tech Clusters Really Matter?, The Annals of
Regional Science (forthcoming)
Anderson, S.P, A. de Palma & J-F. Thisse (1992), Discrete Choice Theory of Product
Differentiation, The MIT Press, Cambridge
Andersson, M. & U. Gråsjö (2005), On the Specification of Regression Models with
Spatial Dependence – An Application of the Accessibility Concept, CESIS
Working Paper 51, Centre for Science and Innovation Studies, KTH/JIBS,
Stockholm/Jönköping
Andersson, M. & C. Karlsson (2004), The Role of Accessibility for Regional Innova-
tion Systems, in Karlsson, Flensburg & Hörte (2004) (Eds.), 283-310
Andersson, Å.E., D.F. Batten and C. Karlsson (1989) (Eds.), Knowledge and Indus-
trial Organisation, Berlin; Springer-Verlag
Archibugi, D. & B.-Å. Lundvall (2001) (Eds.), The Globalising Learning Economy,
Oxford; Oxford University Press
Artle, R. (1959), The Structure of the Stockholm Economy – Toward a Framework for
Projecting Metropolitan Community Development, Stockholm; Stockholm
School of Economics
Arundel. A. & I. Kabla (1998), What Percentage of Innovations are Patented? Empiri-
cal Estimates for European Firms, Research Policy 27, 127-141
Audretsch, D.B, & M. Feldman (1994), Knowledge Spillovers and the Geography of
Innovation and Production, Discussion Paper 953, Centre for Economic Policy
Research, London
Audretsch, D.B, & M. Feldman (1996), R&D Spillovers and the Geography of Inno-
vation and Production, The American Economic Review 86, 630-640
Bade, F.-J. & E.A. Nerlinger (2000), The Spatial Distribution of New Technology-
Based Firms: Empirical Results for West-Germany, Papers of Regional Science
79, 155-176
Barrios, S., et al. (2003), Agglomeration Economies and the Location of Industries: A
Comparison of Three Small European Countries, CORE Discussion paper,
2003-67

16
Batten, D.F., J. Casti & R. Thord (1995) (Eds.), Networks in Action. Communication,
Economics and Human Knowledge, Berlin; Springer-Verlag
Batten, D.F., K. Kobayashi & Å.E. Andersson (1989), Knowledge, Nodes and Net-
works: An Analytical Perspective, in Andersson, Batten & Karlsson (1989)
(Eds.), 31-46
Beise, M. & H. Stahl (1999), Public Research and Industrial Innovation in Germany,
Research Policy 28, 397-422
Ben-Akiva, M & S. Lerman (1979), “Disaggregate Travel and Mobility Choice Mod-
els and Measures of Accessibility”, in Henscher, D.A & P.R Stopher (Eds.), Be-
havioral Travel Modelling, Croon Helm, London: pp. 654-679
Bingham, R. & R. Mier (1997) (Eds.), Dilemmas of Urban Economic Development.
Issues in Theory and Practice, Sage Publications, London
Branstetter, L. (2000), Measuring the Link Between Academic Science and industrial
Innovation: The Case of California’s Research Universities, Paper presented at
the NBER Summer Institute
Breschi, S. (1999), Spatial Patterns of Innovation: Evidence from Patent Data, in
Gambardella & Malerba (1999) (Eds.), 71-102
Chandler, A., P. Hagström & Ö. Sölvell (1998) (Eds.), The Dynamic Firm, New York,
Oxford University Press
Charles, D. (2003), Universities and Territorial Development: Reshaping the Regional
Role of UK Universities, Local Economy 18, 7-20
Cockburn, I. & R. Henderson (1998), Absorptive Capacity, Coauthoring Behaviour
and the Organisation of Research in Drug Discovery, Journal of Industrial Eco-
nomics XLVI, 157-182
Cohen, D.W., et al. (1998), Industry and the Academy: Uneasy Partners in the Cause
of Technological Advance, in Noll R.G., (1998) (Eds.) Challenges to Research
Universities, Washington D.C.: Brookings Institution Press: pp.171-199
Cohen, D.W. & D.A. Levinthal (1989), Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of
R&D, The Economic Journal 99, 569-596
Cohen, D.W. & D.A. Levinthal (1990), Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on
Learning and Innovation, Administrative Science Quarterly 35, 128-152
Cohen, D.W., R.R. Nelson & J. Walsh (2002), Links and Impacts: The Influence of
Public Research on Industrial R&D, Management Science 48, 1-23
Colyvas, J., e al., (2002), How Do University Inventions Go Into Practice?, Manage-
ment Science 48, 61-72
Cox, H., S. Mowatt & M. Prevezar (2003), New Product Development and Product
Supply within a Network Setting: The Chilled Ready-Meal Industry in the UK,
Industry and Innovation 10, 197-217
Devereux, M.P., R. Griffith & H. Simpson (1999), The Geographic Distribution of
Production Activity in the UK, IFS Working Paper W99/26, Institute for Fiscal
Studies
Di Gregorio & S. Shane (2000), Why Do Some Universities Generate More Spill-
overs than Others?. University of Maryland (mimeo)
Etzkowitz, H. & L. Leyersdorff (2000), The Dynamics of Innovation: From National
Systems and “Mode 2” to a Triple Helix of University-industry-government
Relations, Research Policy 29, 109-123
Faggian, A & McCann P. (2006) Human Capital and Regional Knowledge Assets: a
Simultaneous Equation Model, Oxford Economic Papers (forthcoming)

17
Felder, J., A. Fier & E. Nerlinger (1997 a), High Tech in den neuen Ländern: Unter-
nehmensgründungen und Standorte, Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsgeographie 41, 1-
17
Felder, J., A. Fier & E. Nerlinger (1997 b), Im Osten nichts Neues? Unternehmens-
gründungen in High-Tech Industrien, in Harhoff, (1997) (Hrsg) 73-100
Feldman, M. (1994a), The Geography of Innovation, Kluwer, Dordrecht
Feldman, M. (1994b), Knowledge Complementarity and Innovation, Small Business
Economics 6, 363-372
Feldman, M., et al. (2002), Equity and the Technology Transfer Strategies of Ameri-
can Research Universities, Management Science 48, 105-121
Feldman, M. & D. Audretsch (1999), Innovation in Cities: Science-Based Diversity,
Specialisation and Localised Competition, European Economic Review 43, 409-
429
Feldman, M.P. & R. Florida (1994), The Geographic Sources of Innovation: Techno-
logical Infrastructure and Product Innovation in the United States, Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 84, 210-229
Fischer, M.M. & J. Fröhlich (2001) (Eds.), Knowledge, Complexity and Innovation
Systems, Berlin; Springer-Verlag
Fujita, M. & J.-F., Thisse (2002), Economics of Agglomeration – Cities, Industrial
Location and Regional Growth, Cambridge; Cambridge University Press
Gambardella, A. & F. Malerba (1999) (Eds.), The Organisation of Innovative Activity
in Europe, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press
Glaeser, E. (1999), Learning in Cities, Journal of Urban Economics 46, 254-277
Gordon, I.R. & P. McCann (2000), Industrial Clusters: Complexes, Agglomeration
and/or Social Networks, Urban Studies 37, 513-532
Griliches, Z. (1979), Issues in Assessing the Contribution of Research and Develop-
ment to Productivity Growth, Bell Journal of Economics 10, 92-116
Gråsjö, U. (2005a),Accessibility to R&D and Patent Production, An Application of
the Accessibility Concept, CESIS Working Paper 37, Centre for Science and In-
novation Studies, KTH/JIBS, Stockholm/Jönköping
Gråsjö, U. (2005b), Human Capital, R&D, and Regional Export Performance, An Ap-
plication of the Accessibility Concept, CESIS Working Paper 50, Centre for
Science and Innovation Studies, KTH/JIBS, Stockholm/Jönköping
Hall, B.H., A.N., Link & J.T. Scott (2000), Universities as Research Partners, NBER
Working Paper 7643
Harhoff, D. (1997), Innovation in German Manufacturing Enterprises: Empirical
Studies on Productivity, Externalities, Corporate Finance, and Tax Policy, Ha-
bilitationsschrift, Universität Mannheim
Harhoff, D. (1997) (Hrsg), Unternehmensgründungen – Empirische Analysen für die
alten and neuen Bundesländer, Vol. 7, Baden-Baden
Harhoff, D. (2000), R&D Spillovers, Technological Proximity, and Productivity
Growth – Evidence from German Panel Data, Schmalenbach Business Review
52, 238-260
Henderson, J.V. (1974), The Size and Type of Cities, American Economic Review 89,
650-656
Henderson, R.M., A. Jaffe & M. Trajtenberg (1994), Numbers Up, Quality Down?
Trends in University Patenting 1965-1992, Presentation to CEPR/AAAS Con-
ference University Goals, Institutional Mechanisms and the Industrial Transfer-
ability of Research, Stanford University, March 18-20

18
Henderson, R.M., A. Jaffe & M. Trajtenberg (1995), Universities as a Source of
Commercial Technology: A Detailed Analysis of Univeristy Patenting 1965-
1988, NBER WP 5068
Henderson, R.M., A. Jaffe & M. Trajtenberg (1998), Universities as a Source of
Commercial Technology: A Detailed Analysis of University Patenting, 1965-
1988, Review of Economic sand Statistics 80, 119-127
Hugosson, P. (2001) Interregional business travel and the economics of business in-
teraction, JIBS Dissertation Series No. 009, Jönköping
Hugosson, P. & B. Johansson (2001), “Business trips between functional regions”, in
Hugosson, P. (2001)
Jacobs, J. (1969), The Economy of Cities, New York; Vintage
Jaffe, A.B. (1989), Real Effects of Academic Research, American Economic Review
79, 957-970
Jaffe, A.B., M. Trajtenberg & R. Henderson (1993), Geographic Localisation of
Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent Citations, Quarterly Journal of
Economics 108, 577-598
Jensen, R. & M. Thursby (1998), Proofs and Prototypes for Sale: The Tale of Univer-
sity Licensing, NBER Working Paper No. 6698, Cambridge, MA
Johansson, B., C. Karlsson & L. Westin (1994) (Eds.), Patterns of a Network Econ-
omy, Berlin; Springer-Verlag
Johansson, B., J. Klaesson & M. Olsson (2002), Time Distances and Labor Market
Integration, Papers in Regional Science 81, 305-327
Kalnins, A. & W. Chung (2001), Firm Heterogeneity, Market Heterogeneity and Ag-
glomeration, Strategic Management Journal (forthcoming)
Karlsson, C. & Andersson, M. (2005, The Location of University R&D and the Loca-
tion of Company R&D – How Are They Related? CESIS Working Paper 38,
Centre for Science and Innovation Studies, KTH/JIBS, Stockholm/Jönköping
Karlsson, C., P. Flensburg & S.-Å. Hörte (2004) (Eds.), Knowledge Spillovers and
Knowledge Management, Cheltenham; Edward Elgar
Karlsson, C. & B. Johansson (2006) Towards a Dynamic Theory for the Spatial
Knowledge Economy, in Johansson, B., C. Karlsson & R.R. Stough (2006) (Eds.),
Entrepreneurship and Dynamics in the Knowledge Economy, Routledge, London
& New York (Forthcoming)
Karlsson, C. & A. Manduchi (2001), Knowledge Spillovers in a Spatial Context – A
Critical Review and Assessment, in Fischer & Fröhlich (2001) (Eds.), 101-123
Kelly, M. & A. Hageman (1999), Marshallian Externalities in Innovation, Journal of
Economic Growth 4, 39-54
Lagendijk, A. (2001), Scaling Knowledge Production: How Significant is the Re-
gion?, in Fischer & Frölich (2001) (Eds.), 79-100
Landau, R. (1986) (Ed.), The Positive Sum Strategy, Washington, D.C., National
Academic Press
Liebeskind, J., et al. (1996), Social Networks, Learning and Flexibility: Sourcing Sci-
entific Knowledge in new Biotechnology Firms, Organizational Science 7, 428-
443
Lim, K. (2000), The Many Faces of Absorptive Capacity: Spillovers of Copper Inter-
connect Technology for Semiconductor Chips, MIT (mimeo)
Luger, M. & H. Goldstein (1991), Technology in the Garden: Research Parks and
Regional Development, Chapel Hill; University of North Carolina Press
Luger, M. & H. Goldstein (1997), What is the Role of Public Universities in Regional
Economic Development? In Bingham & Mier (1997) (Eds.),104-134

19
Lundvall, B.-Å. (1992) (Ed.), National Systems of Innovation, London, Pinter
Lööf, H. (2005), Den växande utlandskontrollen av ekonomierna i Norden. Effekter
på FoU, innovation och produktivitet, ITPS A 2005:005
MacPherson, A.D. (1998), Academic-industry Linkages and Small Firm Innovation:
Evidence from the Scientific Instruments Sector, Entrepreneurship and Re-
gional Development 10, 261-276
Malo, S. & A. Geuna (2000), Science-Technology Linkages in an Emerging Research
Plattform: The Case of Combinatorial Chemistry and Biology, Scientometrics
47, 303-321
Mariani, M. (2002), Next to Production or to Technological Clusters? The Economics
and Management of R&D Location, Journal of Management and Governance 6,
131-152
Marshall, A. (1920), Principles of Economics, 8th edition, London; Macmillan
Mowery, D.C. & A.A. Ziedonis (2001), The Geographic Reach of Market and Non-
Market Channels of Technology Transfer: Comparing Citations and Licences of
University Patents, NBER Working Paper No. 8568
Narin, F., K.S. Hamilton & D. Olivastro (1997), The Increasing Linkage between U.S.
Technology and Public Science, Research Policy 26, 317-320
Nelson, R.R. (1986), Institutions Supporting Technical Advance in Industry, Ameri-
can Economic Review 76, 186-189
Nelson, R.R. (1993) (Ed.), National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Study, New
York, Oxford University Press
Nelson R.R. & Winter S.G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change,
Cambridge Mass., Harvard University Press
Nerlinger, E. (1998), Standorte und Entwicklung junger innovativer Unternehmen:
Empirische Ergebnisse für West-Deutschland, ZEW-Schriftenreihe 27, Baden-
Baden
Noll, R. (1998), Challenges to the Research University, Brookings Institution, Wash-
ington, D.C.
Patel, P. & Pavitt, K. (1995), “Patterns of Technological Activity: Their Measurement
and Interpretation,” in Paul Stoneman (ed), Handbook of the Economics of Inno-
vation and Technological Change, Oxford: Blackwell.
Prasad, E. (ed) (2004), China’s growth and integration into the world economy: pros-
pects and challenges, IMF Occasional Paper No 232, Washington DC
Shane, S. (2002), Selling University Technology: Patterns from MIT, Management
Science 48, 122-137
Shaver, J.M. & F. Flyer (2000), Agglomeration Economies, Firm Heterogeneity, and
Foreign Direct Investments in the United States, Strategic Management Journal
21, 1175-1193
Siegel, D.S., P. Westhead & M. Wright (2003), Assessing the Impact of University
Science Parks on Research Productivity: Exploratory Firm-Level Evidence from
the United Kingdom, International Journal of Industrial Organisation 21, 1357-
1369
Slaughter & Leslie (1997)
Stuart, T.E. & S. Shane (2002), Organisational Endowments and the Performance of
University Start-ups, Management Science 48, 151-170
Sörensen, C. (1997) (Ed.), Empirical Evidence of Regional Growth: The Centre-Pe-
riphery Discussion, The Expert Committee of the Danish Ministry of the Inte-
rior, Copenhagen

20
Thursby, J. & M. Thursby (2002), Who Is Selling the Ivory Tower? Sources of
Growth in University Licensing, Management Science 48, 90-104
Tobin, J. (1958), “Estimations of Relationships for Limited Dependent Variables”,
Econometrica, 26, 24-36
Train, K. (1993), Qualitative Choice Analysis – theory, econometrics and an applica-
tion to automobile demand, MIT Press, Massachusetts
Varga, A. (1997), University Research and Regional Innovation: A Spatial Economet-
ric Analysis of Technology Transfers, Boston; Kluwer Academic Publishers
Varga, A. (2000), Local Academic Knowledge Transfers and the Concentration of
Economic Activity, Journal of Regional Science 40, 289-309
Varga, A. (2002), Knowledge Transfers from Universities and the Regional Economy:
A Review of the Literature, in Varga & Szerb (2002) (eds.), 147-171
Varga, A. & Szerb (2002) (eds.),
Vernon, R. (1962), Metropolis 1985, Cambridge, MA; Harvard University Press
Verspagen, B. (1999), Large Firms and Knowledge Flows in the Dutch R&D System:
A Case Study of Philips Electronics, Technology Analysis & Strategic Manage-
ment 11, 211-233
Weibull, J. (1976), An Axiomatic Approach to the Measurement of Accessibility, Re-
gional Science and Urban Economics 6, 357-379
Ziedonis, A. (1999), Inward Technology Transfer by Firms: The Case of University
Technology Licences, University of California, Berkeley (mimeo)
Zucker, L.G. & M.R. Darby (1998), Capturing Technological Opportunity via Japan’s
Star Scientists: Evidence from Japanese Firm’s Biotech Patents and Products,
NBER Working Paper 6360
Zucker, L.G. & M.R. Darby (2005), Socio-eonomic Impact of Nanoscale Science:
Initial Results and NanoBank, NBER Working Paper 11181
Zucker, L., M. Darby & J. Armstrong (1998), Intellectual Capital and the Birth of
U.S. Biotechnology Enterprises, American Economic Review 88, 290-306

21

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen