Sie sind auf Seite 1von 34

PPS603 Microeconomics of International Development Policy

3. HOUSEHOLD AND INTRAHOUSEHOLD MODELS

Agricultural Households as Consumption and Production Units

Standard microeconomic theory relies on two fundamental, separate agents the consumer and the producer. But households in developing countries are often consumers and producers of specific goods. This is especially true for staples (e.g., rice, maize, wheat). We focus on the agricultural household, which is both a production and a consumption unit. Well talk of agricultural household models (AHMs).

Refresher: Consumer Theory Good 2 Direction of Increasing Utility

* x2

IC1 IC0

p1 / p2

* x1

Good 1

Refresher: Production Theory


Output

w/ p

F ( L* , E A )

L*

Labor

Basic Agricultural Household Model


Two individuals: i {1,2} Each individual has a level of consumption ci and a level of leisure i The price of the consumption good is p and the price of labor (and thus leisure) is w The household produces some of the consumption good according to the production function F(L,A), where L denotes labor used on the farm and A denotes the amount of cultivable land Endowments of time and land are EiL and E A Price of one unit of land is r

Basic Agricultural Household Model


The households maximization problem is thus max U (c1 , c2 , 1 , 2 ) subject to
c1 ,c2 ,1 , 2

m p(c1 c2 ) wLh rA h pF ( L, A) w( L1 Lm ) rA m 2

Expenditures
f L L1f L2 Lh A A f Ah E A A f Am EiL Lif Lm i i ci , i , Lif , Lm , A f , Am 0 i

Income

Resource Constraints

Basic Agricultural Household Model

The problem of the household is to maximize its utility subject to a budget constraint (expenditures cannot exceed income) and several resource constraints.

The above problem can be reduced by substituting the resource constraints into the budget constraint: this yields the following version of the households maximization problem.

Basic Agricultural Household Model


The households maximization problem is then max U (c , c , , ) subject to
c1 ,c2 ,1 , 2 1 2 1 2

p(c1 c2 ) w( 1 2 ) w( E1L E2L ) rE A


New Budget Constraint pF ( L, A) wL rA Farm Profit

ci , i , L, A 0
The new budget constraint is called the full-income constraint, and the next equation represents farm profits.

Basic Agricultural Household Model

The new problem is recursive: if U is characterized by non-satiation, then the full-income constraint is binding and household utility is increasing in farm profit the higher the profits from the farm, the better off the household and the optimal choices of L and A do not appear in the objective function. The problem can then be rewritten as
c1 ,c2 ,1 , 2

max U (c1 , c2 , 1 , 2 )

subject to

p(c1 c2 ) w( 1 2 ) * ( p, w, r ) w( E1L E2L ) rE A


where * is the profit function, which only depends on prices.

Basic Agricultural Household Model

This setup allows to 1. Maximize profit; then 2. Maximize utility

In other words: with complete markets, production decisions only depend on prices and plot characteristics, and not on household endowments or preferences. This is called the Separation Property: production decisions are separable from consumption choices (but not the other way around).

The Agricultural Household Model with Separability

u(c, )
Output, Consumption Good

c*
F ( L* , E A )

F ( L, E A )

w/ p

( w / p, E A )

Profit

L*

E L *

EL

Labor, - Leisure

Basic Agricultural Household Model

The Separation Property holds even if one market is missing (e.g., in our example, either land or labor). The Separation Property rarely ever holds in practice, as it is quite likely that more than one market goes missing.
When there are multiple (i.e., two or more) market failures, the Separation Property fails to hold, and household consumption is constrained by household production, so to speak.

Basic Agricultural Household Model: Multiple Missing Markets

Suppose now that both markets (land and labor) are missing. The Separation Property does not hold: the household no longer maximizes profit, and production decisions depend on the preferences of the household and its endowments.

Basic Agricultural Household Model


More specifically, and assuming for simplicity that there is only one individual in the household, we have max f U (c, ) subject to h
c , , L , L

pc pF ( L f Lh , E A ) wLh wLm

L f Lm E L

Lm M

Basic Agricultural Household Model

If Lm = M, the problem becomes max U (c, ) subject to


c ,

pc pF ( E L M , E A ) wM

But then, the first-order conditions yield

U FL Uc
and the production decision now depends on preferences and endowments (see graph).

The Agricultural Household Model with Non-Separability

C
u(c, )
F ( L, E A )

c* q *

wM

Lf
M

Labor

Lf M -Leisure

Empirical Evidence on Agricultural Household Models

Knowing what we know about market failures, we come to the crux of this section: What do the data have to say? In other words, does the Separation Property hold in practice? The short answer is that the bulk of the empirical evidence is in favor of rejecting the Separation Property.

Empirical Evidence on Agricultural Household Models


Benjamin (1992) tests for separation in Indonesia. Idea: Holding everything else constant, supply-side (i.e., production factors) variables should not affect labor demand, and demandside variables (i.e., consumption factors) should not affect labor supply.

Test: Household composition has no effect on the households labor allocation at the margin.
Benjamin cannot reject the null hypothesis.

Empirical Evidence on Agricultural Household Models


Problem: The test is not very powerful, since the bulk of the probability mass lies with non-rejection, i.e., a nonresult.

Even though Pitt and Rosenzweig (1986) also cannot reject separation in an earlier round of the same Indonesian data, these results should be taken with a grain of salt. The vast majority of empirical studies reject the Separation Property (Collier, 1983; Carter, 1984; Jacoby, 1993; Kevane, 1994; Barrett, 1996; Udry, 1999).

Empirical Evidence on Agricultural Household Models

For example, Jacoby rejects that the Separation Property holds in Peru. Idea: Households set their marginal productivity of labor equal to the market wage.

Test: a = 0 and b = 1 in the regression

MPLi a bWi ei

Jacoby rejects the null hypothesis of separation.

Agricultural Household Models

What to remember from all this? The following points are key: What happens when the Separation Property holds? 2. The Separation Property holds if there is only one market failure. 3. When the Separation Property fails to hold, production decisions depend on preferences and endowments. 4. The Separation Property has been largely rejected.
1.

Intrahousehold Models: A Technical Aside


In the AHM, we assume that one utility function can represent the preferences of many individuals. This is inconsistent with the methodological individualism of economic theory. For such aggregation to be possible, a lot of structure needs to be imposed on the preferences of each individual of the household (Gorman, 1953).

Response to Aggregation Limitation

To overcome this, we can make strong assumptions about the intra-household distribution of resources For example, Beckers Rotten Kid Theorem assumes the household includes a benevolent dictator who redistributes resources efficiently, i.e., up to the point where everyones marginal utility of income is the same.

In this case, the household is (analytically) indistinguishable from a single individual.

Intra-Household Modeling
There is no good reason, however, to believe that the unitary AHM is a good representation of reality. In fact, evidence points to the fact it is not (Alderman et al., 1995). Manser and Brown (1980) and McElroy and Horney (1981) develop models of the household based on cooperative game theory (i.e., bargaining within the household). In this case, resources are allocated efficiently, but the allocation is determined by threat points (i.e., the utility achieved by each individual in case of cooperation breakdown).

Intra-Household Modeling

Browning and Chiappori (1994), for their part, only assume that the intra-household allocation is efficient. If markets are complete, the households production decisions are not a function of its preferences or endowments (this should be familiar to you by now.)

Intra-Household Modeling
Browning and Chiapporis (1994) requirement that the households allocation efficient is much weaker than the requirements of the unitary AHM. Why is that? As a result, these efficient household models are more realistic and true to form than the unitary AHM.

Additionally, it makes a lot of sense for a households allocation of resources to be efficient (but think of what could make the efficiency assumption not hold)

Empirical Evidence on Intrahousehold Models

Folbre (1984) originally asked why development microeconomists aggregate a number of individual preferences into a single utility function and offered a solid critique of the AHM. She then develops a conceptual framework with which to study households, based on four propositions.

Empirical Evidence on Intrahousehold Models


1. Altruism coexists with conflicts over distribution of goods and leisure time 2. Individual income shares are partly determined by bargaining power. 3. The relative bargaining power of men, women, and children changes over the development process. 4. Changes in bargaining power lead to changes in the distribution of goods and leisure time and affects the price of goods (including children) produced in the household.

Empirical Evidence on Intra-Household Models

Thus, Folbres paper constitutes the first pass at empirically studying intra-household models. Her empirical results contradict the benevolent dictator argument put forth by Becker, by and large, and indicate that the unitary household model might not be the best way to model households.

Empirical Evidence on Intra-Household Models

Similarly, Udry (1996) wishes to test the proposition that intrahousehold allocations are Pareto-efficient. After developing a relatively simple theoretical model, he proceeds to test empirically that gender has no effect on yields, i.e., whether a man or a woman exploits a given plot, the yield remains the same, ceteris paribus. Using data from Burkina Faso, he rejects the null hypothesis.

Empirical Evidence on Intra-Household Models

At the end of the day, he estimates that the output loss due to this inefficiency is about 6%, i.e., households operate at about 94% of their efficient level. Contrast this with Carrs (2011) qualitative evidence to the contrary. The evidence is thus damning to say the least both for the AHM and the efficient household model. Still, those models are often retained in the literature in order to study microeconomic phenomena that are external to the household.

Consequences for Policy

If households do not behave in a unitary fashion, then transfer programs may not reach their intended recipients (e.g., food distribution programs and children). Depending on our goals, we may need a good understanding of how resources are allocated within the household (e.g., it is often preferable to give cash or food to women rather than men).

Intrahousehold Allocation of Technology


In Lee and Bellemare (2011), we wanted to know whether owning a mobile phone was associated with increased prices for a cash crop.

Using data from a rural area of the Philippines, we find that household mobile phone ownership is not associated with a significant increase in the price of onions. When controlling for who owns the mobile phone within the household, however, we find that mobile phone ownership by the farmer or his spouse is associated with price increases, but not ownership by the farmers children. It thus looks as though the intrahousehold allocation of technology may also matter.

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen