Sie sind auf Seite 1von 53

Topic 2

The HeckscherOhlin Model

Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Preview

Substitution between inputs


Factor prices and goods prices
Resources and output
Trade in the Heckscher-Ohlin model
Factor price equalization
Income distribution and income inequality
Optimal Trade Policy
Empirical evidence
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-2

Introduction
Ricardian Model: L is the only factor and
comparative advantage arises due to
productivity differences.
But this cannot be the only reason that nations
trade.
E.g., Saudi Arabia X oil to U.S., not because its oilfield workers are more productive but because
Saudi Arabia has more oil!

A more realistic view of trade incorporates


differences in resources (e.g., T, L, K, and
minerals).
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-3

Introduction (cont.)
In H-O:
Differences in resources are the only
source of trade.
Comparative advantage is determined by
the relative abundance of the factors of
production and the technology which
determines the relative intensity with which
different factors are used in the production
of each good.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-4

Introduction (cont.)
H-O is called factor-proportions theory
because of its emphasis on the importance of
factors available to the country and the
proportions of factors required to produce
different goods.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-5

Introduction (cont.)
To study H-O:
First, determine how factor-proportions
theory works in an economy that does not
trade.
Then examine what happens when trade
between 2 countries occurs.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-6

Assumptions of the H-O Model


1. 2 goods: cloth (C) and food (F)
2. 2 inputs: labor (L) and land (T)

Neither input is specific to an industry.

3. Define the following terms:

aTC = acres of T used to produce 1 yard of cloth


aLC = hours of L used to produce 1 yard of cloth
aTF = acres of T used to produce 1 calorie of food
aLF = hours of L used to produce 1 calorie of food
L = total amount of L and T = total amount of T
w = hourly wage and r = rent for 1 acre
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-7

Substitution Between Inputs


Unlike the Ricardian model, producers dont
have rigid input requirements so they can
substitute between the inputs.
E.g., A farmer may be able to grow more food per
acre if she is willing to use more L to prepare the
soil. The farmer can use less T if she uses more L.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-8

Fig. 1: Input Possibilities in Food Production

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-9

Substitution Between Inputs (cont.)


Input choice will be determined by the relative
cost of L and T.
E.g., if wages are low and rental rates high,
farmers will want to use more L and less T.

Input choices depend on w/r ratio.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-10

Fig. 2: Factor Prices and Input Choices


CC represents the relationship
between w/r and T/L in cloth
production.
FF represents this relationship
for food production.
CC lies to the left of FF
because for any given w/r, food
requires a higher T/L ratio than
cloth.
The production of food is landintensive, while cloth is laborintensive (T/L)F > (T/L)C

Input Choice
If the economy produces both goods
competition drives Pgood = cost of production in
each industry.
Cost depends on factor prices if r is high
Pgood that uses T will be higher.
If cloth uses very little T in production r
wont impact PC much. However, food uses
lots of T so r PF.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-12

Fig. 3: Factor Prices and Goods Prices


There is a one-to-one
relationship between the
cost of labor (w) and the
PC. As w PC because
cloth is the L-intensive
good.

Fig. 4: From Goods Prices to Input Choices

Goods Prices and Factor Prices


Fig 4. shows the close relationship between
PC/PF and T/L used in producing each good.
As (w/r) (PC/PF) as cloth is L-intensive.
Also as (w/r) producers substitute more T for
L because L is relatively expensive T/L
used to produce each good.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-15

Goods Prices and Factor Prices (cont.)


Note: PC/PF will raise the income of workers
relative to landowners. In fact, real wages rise
in terms of both goods and rental rates fall in
terms of both goods.
Why? When PC/PF T/L in production of
both goods now L has more T to work with
(i.e., MPL) and T has become more abundant
MPT.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-16

Goods Prices and Factor Prices (cont.)


In H-O, changes in goods prices have strong
effects on income distribution.
A change in relative prices always leaves owners
of one factor better off while owners of the other
factor are worse off!

Stolper-Samuelson theorem: P of a good


leads to real return to the factor used
intensively in the production of that good and
real return to the other factor.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-17

Resources and Output


We must now analyze how factor supplies
impact goods prices and output levels.
If PC/PF is given, then so is w/r and T/L used in
production. Also, the economy must fully
employ all T and L which helps determine
the output mix.
Analyze allocation of resources with a box
diagram.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-18

Fig. 5: The Allocation of Resources

Resources and Output (cont.)


In Fig 5., width = S of L and height = S of T.
Allocation of resources is given by a point in the box,
like pt 1.
If we know PC/PF T/L used in cloth and food. Slope
of OCC is (T/L)C and slope of OFF is (T/L)F.
Any point describing the allocation of resources must
lie on OFF and OCC. (Pt 1 lies on both.)
Note: OFF is steeper than OCC because (T/L)F >
(T/L)C.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-20

Resources and Output (cont.)


How does the mix of output change when
factor supplies change?
Fig. 6 shows S of T.
If we hold PC/PF fixed T/L are also fixed. So
draw a parallel line (at OFF) to OFF.
Resource allocation moves from pt 1 to 2.
Note: amounts of T and L used in cloth fall. So
T Q of L-intensive good (cloth) and Q of
T-intensive good (food).
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-21

Resources and Output (cont.)


Rybczynski theorem: if goods prices are fixed,
then S of a factor leads to output of the
good that uses that factor intensively and
output of the other good.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-22

Fig. 6: An Increase in the Supply of Land

Fig. 7: Resources and PPF


T shifts PPF outward and
biased toward food (T-intensive
good).
T expands production of Tintensive good, while L
expands production of the Lintensive good.
Thus, an economy with a high
T/L will be more effective in
producing the T-intensive good.
An economy will tend to
produce goods that are
intensive in the factors in which
the country is well endowed.

Trade Between Countries


Assume:
2 countries: home and foreign
2 factors: T and L
2 goods: cloth and food
Same tastes: RD curve is identical
Same technology
CRTS
Incomplete specialization
Only difference: (T/L)* > (T/L) home is L
abundant and foreign is T abundant
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-25

Fig. 8: Trade Leads to a Convergence of


Relative Prices
Since cloth is L-intensive,
home tends to produce
more cloth relative to food.
RS of home is lower and
pre-trade PC/PF is lower
than in foreign.
With trade, prices must
converge between two pretrade prices (i.e., point 2).

Trade Between Countries (cont.)


Without trade, D = S within each country.
DC = QC and DF = QF

With trade, this is no longer true. However, a


country can only spend what it earns.
PC x DC + PF x DF = PC x QC + PF x QF
value of consumption

Or

value of production

DF QF = (PC/PF) x (QC DC)

value of food imports = value of cloth exports


Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-27

Fig. 9: Budget Constraint with Trade


QF

QFt

-(PC/PF) t = slope

DF QF = (PC/PF) x (QC DC) is the


countrys budget constraint.
It is tangent to the PPF at the trade
production pt (t) and its slope =
-(PC/PF).
A country must consume somewhere
on this budget line.
budget line

QC t

QC

Fig. 10: Trading Equilibrium


Home

QF

DF
QF

MF

Foreign

QF

QF
DF

X*F

M*C

XC
DC

QC

QM

QC

DC

QC

Trade opens: in Home (PC/PF) DF and QF exports C and imports F; in


Foreign (PC/PF) DC and QC imports C and exports F.
In equilibrium, XC = M*C and X*F = MF. Shown by the shaded triangles.

Fig. 11: PPF for Two Countries


Q*F

QF

(PC/PF)*t (PC/PF)*a

(PC/PF)t
(PC/PF)a

Q*t
Qa = Da
Q*a = D*a

Qt

Home

QC

Foreign
Note: a = autarky and t = trade

Q*C

Trade Between Countries (cont.)


Fig. 11: Since cloth is L-intensive good and home is L
abundant, homes PPF is shifted out more in the
direction of cloth.
In autarky, (PC/PF)a is higher in foreign. If trade opens,
goods prices equalize to (PC/PF)t.
Home views the higher world (PC/PF)t QC and QF.
So home X cloth and M food.
Foreign sees a lower world (PC/PF)t Q*C and Q*F.
So foreign X food and M cloth.
Rule: Countries tend to export goods whose
production is intensive in factors with which they are
abundantly endowed.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-31

Trade and Income Distribution


Trade leads to a convergence of goods prices. And a
change in goods prices leads to a change in factor
rewards.
At home: (PC/PF) workers are better off and
landowners are worse off
Foreign: (P*C/P*F) workers are worse off and
landowners are better off.
Rule: In general, owners of a countrys abundant
factor gain from trade, but owners of a countrys
scarce factor lose.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-32

Trade and Income Distribution (cont.)


U.S. is abundant in highly skilled L and lowskilled L is scarce.
Trade makes low-skilled workers in U.S.
worse off permanently.
Negative impact of trade on low-skilled L is a
big political problem.
Industries that use low-skilled L (e.g., shoes,
textiles, apparel, rubber, leather, mining, and
agriculture) consistently demand protection from
foreign M and their demands attract sympathy
because they are already bad off to begin with!
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-33

Trade and Income Distribution (cont.)


Sometimes high-skilled L employed in an industry that
is intensive in low-skilled L (e.g., a CPA in textiles) will
favor M restrictions. In SR, she cannot immediately
shift industries. Yet, in LR, trade would improve her
earnings because trade favors skilled L.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-34

Factor Price Equalization


Without trade: PC/PF < P*C/P*F w < w* and r > r*
With trade: relative goods prices converge rewards
to T and L converge.
When home and foreign exchange goods, they are
indirectly exchanging factors.
Home lets foreign have some of its abundant L (not by selling
L directly) but by trading goods produced with a high ratio of
L/T for goods produced with a low ratio of L/T.

Home X its L embodied in the L-intensive good.


Conversely, foreign X its T embodied in the Tintensive good. Viewed this way, its not surprising
that w/r equalize.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-35

Factor Price Equalization (cont.)


Intuition: as home trades it QC and QF. The QF
releases T and L into the economy but relatively more
T is released because food requires a higher T/L ratio.
Thus, r while w because DL as QC in the Lintensive industry.
Exactly the opposite is happening in foreign. As trade
opens, Q*F and Q*C. As Q*C T* and L* are
released but relatively more L* is freed up. Yet, D*T
as Q*F r* and w*.
w/r are equalized because as long as they differ,
goods prices differ and trade continues to expand until
goods prices and w/r are equalized.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-36

Factor Price Equalization (cont.)


Problem: in real world, factor prices are not equalized.
Wages vary greatly across countries and quality of L alone
doesnt explain away the differences.

Problem with 3 model assumptions:


1. Both countries produce both goods: A country with
very high T/L may produce only food, while a country
with low T/L may produce only cloth. If countries are
radically different they may completely specialize
without w/r equalizing.
E.g., if PC/PF < P*C/P*F home sees higher PC abroad and
QC which drives PC. If, however, home completely
specializes in cloth, it cannot QC further to drive PC.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-37

Factor Price Equalization (cont.)


2. Technologies are the same: FPE doesnt hold if
countries have different technologies. A country with
superior technical knowledge may have higher wages
and rental rates than a country with inferior
technology.
3. FPE relies on convergence of goods prices: In reality,
goods prices are not fully equalized by trade. There
are transportation costs and barriers to trade (e.g.,
tariffs and quotas).

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-38

Does Trade Increase Income Inequality?


1970 2001: sharp wage inequality
Real wages of males at the 95th percentile rose 29%.
Real wages of males at the 10th percentile rose 0.2%.

Many people attribute wage inequality to world


trade and to X of manufactures from NIE (e.g., South
Korea and China).
Until 1970s, trade between advanced and developing
countries was called North-South trade because
industrialized (developing) countries are largely in the
northern (southern) hemisphere.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-39

Does Trade Increase Income Inequality? (cont.)


Trade was an exchange of northern manufactures for
southern primary products (e.g., minerals and
agriculture).
Since 1970, former raw materials exporters began to
sell manufactures to high-wage nations, like U.S.
NIE exports to advanced countries consisted of
shoes, clothing, and other non-sophisticated
manufactures whose production is intensive in the use
of unskilled L.
Advanced country exports to NIE are K-intensive
manufactures (e.g., scientific equipment, chemicals,
and aircraft).
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-40

Does Trade Increase Income Inequality? (cont.)


Many claimed that FPE had occurred.
Trade between advanced countries (abundant in
skilled L) with NIE (abundant in unskilled L)
wages of unskilled L in advanced countries.
This argument threatens economists support for free
trade. Even if trade makes it possible to improve
everyones welfare (through taxes and subsidies) this
is unlikely to happen. So many argue that we should
stop trading with low-wage countries to maintain the
middle-class.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-41

Does Trade Increase Income Inequality? (cont.)

Most empirical studies show that trade has


had a small impact on wage inequality in
U.S. Why?

1.

H-O predicts that trade affects income distribution


via a relative goods prices. So if trade is driving
income inequality, then prices of skill-intensive
goods should rise in advanced countries. This
hasnt happened.
Model predicts that relative factor prices should
converge. If wages of skilled L and wages of
unskilled L in advanced countries reverse is true
in NIE. Yet, China and Mexico have both faced
wage inequality.

2.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-42

Does Trade Increase Income Inequality? (cont.)


3.

Trade with NIE is only a small portion of spending in


advanced countries. If trade flows arent very large,
they cant have a large impact on income
distribution.

Most economists believe wage inequality in


U.S. is caused by technological advances,
which have devalued unskilled L.
E.g., Most HS educated L could not
operate machinery in a typical auto plant
in U.S.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-43

Gains from Trade Revisited


Without trade, nations must produce what
they consume. CPF = PPF.
A nation can consume more of both goods
with trade than in autarky.
If a nation can consume more of both goods
with trade, then it is feasible to give more to
everyone.
Trade expands the economys choices.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-44

Fig. 12: Gains from Trade in Home


QF

Before trade, Home produced


and consumed at pt 2.
With trade, produce at pt 1
and consume at pt 3.

DF
2

MF
1

QF

XC

Trade (pt 3) allows Home to


consume more of both goods
than it did in autarky (pt 2).
Homes budget constraint

(PC/PF)
DC

QC

QC

Gains from Trade (cont.)


So why is trade so controversial?
In reality, that everyone could gain from
trade does not mean that everyone
actually does!

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-46

Optimal Trade Policy


If every person were identical (tastes and
incomes were the same), the government (G)
would just choose a policy of free trade.
If people differ, the G must weight 1 persons
gains against anothers losses.
E.g., if some workers are already very poor
(apparel workers in U.S.) sympathy for trade
restrictions among the public. Rich consumers are
helped by paying lower prices for clothing while
poor workers are hurt by falling wages or layoffs.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-47

Optimal Trade Policy (cont.)

Economists dont favor these arguments for


3 reasons.

1. Any economic change (e.g., relative goods


prices, regulation, domestic tastes, or new
technologies) alters the income distribution.

If one argues that the G should restrict trade


because some are injured, then shouldnt it also
restrict any disruptive technologies or innovations
that cause some to suffer loses? (e.g., ipod, new
drug therapies, electric cars, etc)

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-48

Optimal Trade Policy (cont.)


2. Always better to allow trade and
compensate the losers because the costs of
trade restrictions are so enormous to
consumers.
Compensate losers with programs like TAA; or
wage subsidies for workers who enter new
industries or seek early retirement.
E.g., the annual cost to U.S. consumers per job
saved in specialty steel is $1 million/yr; $240,000
in frozen oj; $150,000 motorcycles; $60,000 in
sugar.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-49

Optimal Trade Policy (cont.)


3. Those who lose are often better organized
than those who gain which biases the
political process.

E.g., U.S. sugar industry has benefited from


tariffs and quotas for years. Our price is x2 world
price. Costs to U.S. consumers = $2 billion/yr or
$8 for every person. Gains to producers are as
large. If consumers lobbied Congress as much
as sugar growers do, then protection would stop.
However, $8 loss for a consumer vs. $100,000 to
a sugar grower means they lobby and
consumers dont!

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-50

Empirical Evidence
H-O is a major trade theory and its been extensively
tested. Overall, the tests are not supportive.
U.S. Tests: U.S. is a special case very wealthy vs
rest of the world and K/L is high.
Expect U.S. to export K-intensive goods and import Lintensive goods.
In 1953, Leontief showed a paradox: (K/L)X < (K/L)M.
In 1962, Baldwin also showed the Leontief paradox.
But found U.S. exported goods that were more skilled
L-intensive than its imports. And U.S. exported goods
that were technology-intensive requiring scientists
and engineers.
Data is consistent with the view that U.S. is a skilled L country that
makes sophisticated products.

Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights


reserved.

4-51

Empirical Evidence (cont.)


Perhaps Leontief paradox is explained by U.S.
advantage in developing new high tech products such
as aircraft, computer chips, and pharmaceuticals.
These products may use K and skilled L but be less Kintensive than older, established heavy industries (e.g.,
steel, autos, or oil).
U.S. does export goods using skilled L, scientists, and
entrepreneurship; while importing heavy manufactures
(like cars and oil) that use lots of K.
Clearly, goods the U.S. exports to Bangladesh match
H-O theory. U.S. exports industrial machinery and
Bangladesh exports clothing.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-52

Empirical Evidence (cont.)


Overall, when looking at global data, H-O doesnt hold
up!
This puts trade economists in an awkward position!
Empirical evidence does support Ricardian theory. But
the model is too limited to address income
distribution.
Most trade economists believe that assumption of
identical technologies should be dropped.
E.g., U.S. can produce more than China from any set of
inputs.
E.g., can alter H-O to allow 1 (U.S). L = 1.5 (U.K.) L. Because
of technology, U.S. labor is 50% more effective.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights
reserved.

4-53

Das könnte Ihnen auch gefallen